Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Dealing With The Costs of The COVID-19 Pandemic - What Are The Fiscal Options?

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

econstor

A Service of

zbw
Leibniz-Informationszentrum
Wirtschaft

Make Your Publications Visible.


Leibniz Information Centre
for Economics

Ambrocio, Gene; Juselius, Mikael

Research Report
Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19 pandemic –
what are the fiscal options?

BoF Economics Review, No. 2/2020

Provided in Cooperation with:


Bank of Finland, Helsinki

Suggested Citation: Ambrocio, Gene; Juselius, Mikael (2020) : Dealing with the costs of the
COVID-19 pandemic – what are the fiscal options?, BoF Economics Review, No. 2/2020, Bank
of Finland, Helsinki,
http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:fi:bof-202004092069

This Version is available at:


http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215777

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use:

Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.

Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.

www.econstor.eu
Bank of Finland

BoF Economics Review


2  2020

Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19


pandemic – what are the fiscal options?
Gene Ambrocio, Bank of Finland
Mikael Juselius, Bank of Finland

Abstract
The main problem facing policymakers during the corona virus pandemic is how to mitigate
its humanitarian and economic costs. Doing so invariably involves trading off some costs
against others as well as short-term against longer-term consequences. We provide an
overview of economic literature that is relevant for understanding these trade-offs in the
context of the current pandemic. We also discuss a range of fiscal measures that can be
adopted with the aim of achieving the preferred trade-offs at lowest cost.

Keywords: Pandemics; economic costs; COVID-19; fiscal policy.


JEL codes: H12; H81; I18.

We wish to thank our colleagues for valuable suggestions and comments. The usual disclaimer
applies.

BoF Economics Review consists of analytical studies on monetary policy, financial markets and
macroeconomic developments. Articles are published in Finnish, Swedish or English. The opinions
expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Bank of Finland.

Editors: Juha Kilponen, Esa Jokivuolle, Karlo Kauko, Paavo Miettinen, Juuso Vanhala

www.suomenpankki.fi
1. Introduction
Pandemics are associated with large-scale humanitarian and economic costs, and the cur-
rent COVID-19 pandemic appears to be no exception. Public sector policies can mitigate and
reduce some of these costs, albeit at the expense of incurring others. For example, strict
containment policies reduce the number of contagion cases, but impose large negative sup-
ply and demand shocks on the economy that can have both temporary and lasting effects.
Supportive fiscal measures can mitigate some of the effects, but impose a larger public debt
burden on future generations. This suggests that policymakers face important trade-offs, and
understanding them is crucial for choosing the appropriate policy actions today.
In this article, we provide an overview of results in the literature that help to clarify the dif-
ferent economic costs and trade-offs that pandemics might entail. While much of the litera-
ture focuses on short term costs, which are directly attributable to the pandemic, we also pay
attention to potential long term costs. Drawing on these general lessons, we make some
qualitative predictions for how the COVID-19 pandemic, specifically, is likely to affect the
Finnish economy. Based on this assessment we then highlight various policy options for ad-
dressing some of the key issues that are likely to arise.
Our analysis should be viewed as a modest attempt to structure thinking about the broad
range of economic issues that have been raised in the literature in relation to pandemics. At
the same time, readers should be aware of the obvious limitations. By their very nature, pan-
demics are rare events implying that not much data exists that help quantify their short- and
long-term impacts. Undoubtedly many predictions will turn out to be inaccurate, and much
will be learnt from the current pandemic as it progresses.
The rest of the article is structured as follows: next two sections review the literature on
the short- and long-term costs of pandemics, respectively. The fourth section relates this lit-
erature to the current COVID-19 pandemic. The fifth and sixth sections discuss various policy
options.

2. Short term economic costs of pandemics


The short term economic impact of a pandemic stems from three channels: (1) a temporary
drop in productive capacity (e.g. supply of labor and productivity due to suboptimal working
conditions) which is then propagated and amplified by (global) supply chains and complex
production networks, (2) reduced aggregate demand due to preventive and containment poli-
cies, and (3) reduced current and expected demand due to pessimistic expectations and un-
certainty. 1
A rapidly growing literature that assesses the effect of the current pandemic favors the
view that it reduces demand more than it disrupts supply. 2 The estimated overall economic
costs of the crisis from these channels are sizable with predicted average global slowdown in
growth ranging from 0.5% to as much as 10% for some countries. 3 Estimates from the OECD
suggest that these declines are predominantly due to demand and uncertainty channels
(Boone et al., 2020).
While the effects of the pandemic on disrupting supply is widely perceived to be tempo-
rary, the globalized nature of production networks imply that disruptions in supply can easily
transmit across countries and hence become amplified. Baldwin and Tomiura (2020) note

1 See e.g. Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (2020a, 2020b) and the subsequent articles in the VoxEU
eBooks.
2 These include Atkeson (2020), Baker Farrokhnia, Meyer, Pagel and Yannelis (2020), Eichenbaum et

al. (2020), Stock (2020), and many sections in Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (2020a, 2020b). Country-
specific analyses include Fang et al. (2020), Faria-e-Castro (2020), Simola and Solanko (2020), and
many sections in Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (2020b). See also a recent survey of global economic
experts here http://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/coronavirus-2/ as well as Guerrieri et al. (2020).
3 See e.g. Boone et al. (2020), McKibbin and Fernando (2020), and Ma et al. (2020). These estimates

are conditional on assumed scenarios on preventive and containment measures.


1 Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19 pandemic
– what are the fiscal options?
that the largest global economies, which sit at the center of global trade networks, are hard-
est hit by the pandemic. Hence, the economic effects could easily transmit to other econo-
mies through supply chain contagion. They also note that the drop in global trade during the
Global Financial Crisis could serve as a useful benchmark for the effects of the pandemic
through this channel.
By and large, recent studies show that the economic cost of the pandemic can increase
with more stringent preventive and containment measures. This is largely due to the demand
channel. Baker Farrokhnia, Meyer, Pagel and Yannelis (2020) find that the pandemic triggers
an initial increase in expenditures followed by an overall decline in spending. They find that
greater levels of social distancing and other containment measures are associated with
larger drops in spending especially in the restaurant and retail services sectors.
Significant decreases in sales and profits will result in financial difficulties for many busi-
nesses. It is, for instance, well known that Small and Medium sized Enterprises (SMEs) are
more dependent on internal finance (e.g. Carpenter and Petersen (2002)) and are therefore
more vulnerable to banking and trade credit disruptions, as well as, temporary income
shocks. This consequently increases the likelihood of cascading bankruptcies which can re-
sult in largescale layoffs. In turn, job losses and reduced income for some households feed
back into the drop in demand. Numerous accounts in afflicted countries across the globe at-
test to these effects.
Finally, pandemics can also affect the ease of financing for firms through their impact on
stock markets. Baker, Bloom, Davis, Kost, Sammon, and Viratyosin (2020) find, through text-
based analysis, that news about the current pandemic has emerged as the most dominant
driver of U.S. stock market fluctuations. Further, results in Ramelli and Wagner (2020) sug-
gest that the stock market reactions to pandemic news imply that investors are wary of eco-
nomic amplification and contagion through financial channels.

3. Long term economic costs of pandemics


Like most pandemics in history, the COVID-19 global pandemic will probably also have some
lasting negative consequences for the economy. 4 These can arise from a number of sources
such as (i) reductions in the labor force due to mortality and morbidity, (ii) lost physical and
human capital due to bankruptcies and long spells of unemployment, (iii) changes in risk be-
havior and preferences, (iv) trade disruptions, and (v) risks to private and public debt sustain-
ability.
One key channel through which pandemics can have longer term consequences is their
potential effect on the capital labor ratio. If part of the labor force dies in the pandemic, the
capital labor ratio will increase. This should in turn lower the real (inflation adjusted) return on
capital and increase the real wage rate. This is indeed the key finding in a recent study by
Jorda et al. (2020), who look at aftermath of 12 major pandemics 5 since the 14th century.
They find that pandemics gradually lower the real interest rate by up to 2 percentage points
during the first 20 years, followed by a recovery for the next 10 years. In contrast, real wages
tend to rise by up to 5-10 percentage points during the same period. 6 That such effects can
be so long lasting is not surprising if already installed capital has a long lifespan and is run
down rather than dismantled.
A second key channel is destruction of capital. If the big demand and supply shocks dur-
ing the pandemic lead to widespread and possibly cascading bankruptcies, the loss of capital
can be sizable. And this may well prevent a return to the pre-pandemic growth trajectory for
several reasons. For one, the discovery and adoption of new technologies depends on re-

4 Historical comparisons to past pandemics such as the plague or the Spanish flu are done in Barro et
al. (2020) and several sections in Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (2020a).
5 Defined as pandemics where more than 100,000 people died.
6 Similar effects would emerge in case pandemics lead to increased morbidity in the labor force. Al-

mond and Mazumder (2005), for instance, document that reductions in fetal health during a pandemic
from e.g. malnutrition can lead to reduced educational attainment, increased rates of disability, lower
income, and lower socioeconomic status.

BoF Economics Review 2


search and development which can be pro-cyclical (see e.g. Anzoategui et al. (2019)). More-
over, recessions and crises disproportionally affect small and medium sized enterprises
(SMEs) that tend to be more innovative (see e.g. Acemoglu et al. (2018) and Schmitz
(2020)). Lost capital in this segment of the firm distribution might be harder to recover.
Pandemics also affect certain sectors more severely than others. For instance, financial
and insurance activities, transportation and storage, accommodation and food service activi-
ties, and certain services face large-scale losses, whereas losses might be less severe in
other sectors. 7 This can lead to capital misallocation which is associated with permanent
losses.
The effects of lost capital mirrors the ones from lost labor, and include stagnant real
wages, increasing returns to capital, and rising unemployment. In addition, if productivity de-
clines for endogenous growth reasons, losses will accumulate over time. It is, for example,
unclear how quickly new startup firms can replace a sizable shortfall in capital. In the worst
case, this will take significant time and therefore lead to long-term unemployment and addi-
tional costs in the form of lost human capital.
The third way in which pandemics can have long term effects is through changes in risk
perceptions and preferences. 8 Pandemics can lead to greater awareness of both the econ-
omy wide and sector specific risks that they entail (Fan et al. (2018) and Bloom et al. (2018)).
Similarly, pandemics can increase the precautionary savings of households. 9 Together,
these forces reduce demand and lead to higher costs of business in affected segments. Ulti-
mately this can lead to a rebalancing of capital, with implications for jobs at risk and prices.
Pandemics can also have long-lasting adverse impacts on trade both through political and
economic channels (see e.g. Kerr (2009) and ECB (2016)). 10 For instance, the EU imposed a
10 year ban on British beef after the mad cow disease (Bloom et al. (2018)). Pandemics can
also be expected to increase trade costs as well as disruptions to global value chains as indi-
vidual firms in the chain go bankrupt. Together, these forces reducing the overall scope of
trade and increase the cost of production. On the other hand, pandemics can also create op-
portunities for industries that recover their productive capabilities relatively quickly to replace
impaired parts of global value chains.
The last channel through which pandemics can have lasting effects on economic activity
is public sector indebtedness. While large-scale fiscal measures are undoubtedly needed –
and indeed desirable – to stave off the worst near-term effects of a pandemic, it is clear that
that this will lead to a massive increase in public sector debt levels relative to GDP. This can
in turn have many negative consequences.
First, increases in public debt to GDP reduces fiscal space to handle future crises and in-
creases the likelihood of sovereign default. The scope for public indebtedness is not unlim-
ited but curtailed by the private sectors trust in the government’s willingness and ability to
raise future tax revenues. If this trust is eroded, the private sector will have to be compen-
sated by higher interest rates in order to be persuaded to hold public debt. This makes rais-
ing new debt expensive or even impossible. Taken to the limit, this will eventually lead to a
situation where the sovereign either has to drastically (and possibly disorderly) reduce the
size of the public sector, default on its debt or inflate it away. 11 But such defaults are costly
and come in the form of a temporary loss of access to international capital markets and more
costly borrowing after the default (see e.g. Cruces and Trebesch (2013) and Tomz and
Wright (2013)).

7 See e.g. Rassy and Smith (2013); Joo et al. (2019); Rosselló et al. (2017).
8 Rachel and Summers (2019) provide a macro model where e.g. the patience of societies depend on
the population structure.
9 Ferrero et al. (2019) and Rachel and Smith (2017) provide models where the age-structure of the

population matters for macroeconomic outcomes. In these models, societal impatience increases in
aging societies. Moreover, the old consume different consumption baskets (e.g. containing more
healthcare services) than the young.
10 Bloom et al. (2018) and Lustig and Mariscal (2020).
11 For recent theoretical work on sovereign debt see Gennaioli et al. (2018) and references therein.

3 Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19 pandemic


– what are the fiscal options?
Second, since human remaining lifespans can be shorter than sovereign debt maturities,
increased public indebtedness involve transfers from younger generations to older. 12 As
such, this can lead to increased savings and/or higher expectations of future inflation by the
most economically viable segments of the population. This can lead to reduced demand, em-
igration of high skilled labor, and future tax distortions.

4. The COVID-19 pandemic and the Finnish economy

Which of the many economic concerns associated with pandemics are likely to be the most
relevant for Finland in the current COVID-19 crises?
In its current form, the virus seems unlikely to result in large increases in the capital labor
ratio (point (i) above). The reason is that its severity increases with the age of those affected.
For instance, the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (2020) estimates that the
upper bounds for case-fatality rates are 0.2% for 20-44 year olds, 0.8% for 45-54 year olds,
and 2.6% for 55-64 year olds. These mortality rates make it unlikely that a large proportion of
the working age population will be lost to the COVID-19 pandemic. Moreover, the strong pub-
lic health responses to the virus are likely to reduce the number of cases, and hence the total
number of fatalities. Consequently, we should not expect as large increases in real wages,
reductions in unemployment, and reductions in the return on capital as has been the case in
historical pandemics. For the same reasons, we should expect faster recovery in supply, pro-
vided that early policy measures prevent large-scale bankruptcies and sectorial hysteresis.
The biggest risk from the COVID-19 pandemic is destruction of capital as a result of the
strong containment measures that have been adopted. If the containment measures are held
in place for a prolonged time without sufficient public support for vulnerable sectors, bank-
ruptcies and therefore unemployment will likely start to rise dramatically. For instance,
Huovari et al. (2020) estimate that a large fraction of the 50,000 firms and 200,000 in the ac-
commodation and food service and personal service sectors might be at risk in such a sce-
nario. Other sectors are also exposed to lesser or greater extent, and more than 100,000
workers have already been furloughed as a result of the dramatic collapse in demand.
The sectorial vulnerabilities are exacerbated by the external environment. Finland is a
small open economy and therefore heavily dependent on external demand and global value
chains. Ali-Yrkkö and Kuusi (2020) estimate that Finland will face major disruptions to supply
chains over the near-term. In certain sectors, such as electronic components and medical
products, dependency on intermediary imports can be as high 80%. It is clear that restoring
impaired supply chains can take significant time and constitute a major challenge going for-
ward. Finnish exports will also see a sharp reduction in demand as containment measures in
other countries start to bite.
A secondary issue in the wake of the pandemic is weakened household demand, which
might prevent a fast recovery. The main reasons are that lost household income is not nec-
essarily compensated by large wage increases later on and that households increase their
precautionary savings due to changes in risk perception.
Avoiding the threats of bankruptcies and weakened domestic demand requires a massive
fiscal response. Hence, one of the most lasting effects of the COVID-19 pandemic is likely to
be a sizable public debt overhang. Unfortunately, fiscal space in Finland has already been
eroded for much of the past decade as the Finnish government has maintained sizable
budget deficits in response to the global financial crisis. During this period, Finnish debt-to-
GDP rose from less than 40% to about 60% currently. This number is not excessively large
by international standards (Figure 1), but it will raise substantially as a consequence of the
expected drop in GDP combined with the large fiscal packages. Whether or not this becomes
a big problem depends on the future terms of credit for the Finnish government. While public
borrowing costs are currently low against the backdrop of the recent ECB quantitative easing
program, this does not necessarily predict that they stay low also in the future.

12 Rachel and Summers (2019) analyze demographic model of public debt in which the Ricardian

Equivalence does not hold.

BoF Economics Review 4


Figure 1. Public debt to GDP (in per cent)

Source: Statistics Finland, Eurostat, U.S. Department of Treasury, U.S. Bureau of Economic
Analysis, Macrobond.

5. Policy responses in the midst of pandemic


Given the adverse economic implications of the pandemic outlined in the previous sections,
decisive and timely economic measures are necessary to mitigate them. Fiscal policy plays a
central role in the policy mix. For instance, Benassy-Quere et al. (2020) among others have
called for and proposed policy responses to target specific channels and at specific phases
of the crisis. 13
In the peak phase of the crisis when preventive and containment policies are in place,
emergency support is needed to "keep the lights on." This is necessary in order to prevent
domino and feedback effects which can exacerbate and prolong the downturn and ultimately
raise the fiscal cost of the crisis. 14
Broadly speaking, fiscal policy prescriptions for immediate implementation can be catego-
rized into (1) providing additional funds for healthcare services, (2) support to households via
direct cash transfers or subsidies, temporary unemployment benefits, and incentives for firms
to retain workers such as through subsiding the wage bill (e.g. through short-work programs
such as the German Kurzarbeit), and (3) financial support to businesses via tax relief and
concessional credit lines. While supporting public healthcare services is the immediate and
primary concern, measures to support firms, especially small businesses, and households
should also be prioritized by fiscal policy. 15
Fiscal measures may be needed to bring immediate financial relief to firms. 16 These can
take the form of tax credits and deferrals, (potentially subsidized) bridge financing and credit
lines, as well as measures to support and maintain employment. Nevertheless, monetary and

13 See also other contributions in Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (2020b) for other examples of broad
policy recommendations.
14 See e.g. Saez and Zucman (https://econfip.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/03/20.Keeping-Businesses-Alive.pdf )

and Gourinchas (2020).


15 A recent UK survey of experts suggest that the most effective policy to combat the effects of the

pandemic is government credit support for businesses followed by unemployment benefits.


https://cfmsurvey.org/
16For macro-prudential and monetary policy implications, see also relevant in Baldwin and Weder di
Mauro (2020a, 2020b). See also Brunnermeier et al. (2020) for proposals on liquidity facilities for Eu-
rope (https://scholar.princeton.edu/sites/default/files/markus/files/covid_liquiditylifeline.pdf).
5 Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19 pandemic
– what are the fiscal options?
macro-prudential policy play a supplementary role in ensuring the well-functioning of financial
markets and access to private credit by businesses. When providing financial relief to firms,
De Vito and Gomez (2020) find that bridge loan policies to augment business cash holdings
are more effective than tax deferral policies. 17
In light of the multiple channels through which the pandemic impacts the economy, finan-
cial distress in the private sector may not just be a liquidity problem but also one of solvency.
In this case, a fiscal stimulus is needed to augment policies designed to provide liquidity and
mitigate disruption in financial markets. A key conceptual difference is that a liquidity facility,
such as a bridge loan, is eventually repaid and is thus fiscally neutral while a subsidy entails
a fiscal cost. The appropriate policy mix minimizes the risk of moral hazard and excessive
bailouts while limits the cost to the government. This can, for instance, be achieved by liquid-
ity support via bridge financing to firms.
In addition, fiscal measures may be needed to provide financial relief to households. First,
policies which subsidize the wage bill and incentivize firms to retain workers can mitigate un-
employment and loss of income to households. Cahuc et al. (2018) find that the cost of poli-
cies such as the German Kurzarbeit may be low relative to the benefits in terms of jobs
saved. Second, direct transfers to households have been proposed which compensate for
unemployment or reductions in wage income. Finally, some have also called for uncondi-
tional cash transfers to households in order to spur demand. Model-based analysis suggests
that borrower households benefit the most from unemployment insurance policies (Faria-e-
Castro, 2020).
Overall, state-contingent (i.e. conditional on ex-post outcomes) subsidies, which grant fi-
nancial support to firms who maintain their workforce, may be more appropriate than blanket
subsidies. Drawing on lessons from the Global Financial Crisis and the Great Recession, Fu-
jita, Moscarini, and Postel-Vinay (2020) argue for carefully crafted and targeted policies
meant to stave off layoffs. 18 This is to prevent moral hazard, unintended bailouts, crisis profi-
teering, and excessively increasing the fiscal cost of the stimulus. State-contingent subsidies
also have the benefit of minimizing the need to gauge the appropriate scale of the policy ex-
ante as the situation ex-post will determine the actual extent of the subsidy. On the other
hand, it also means that the cost to the government will also be contingent on the scale of
the crisis. Blanket subsidies may induce moral hazard in that firms may fire and then rehire
workers to take advantage of such policy measures.
A particularly interesting state-contingent policy in this regard has been proposed by Greg
Mankiw. 19 The idea is that the firm or household receives funds today in return for a future
payment, e.g. in 1 or 2 years. The amount to be repaid may then be subject to a discount or
subsidy depending on how the crisis has affected the recipient. The subsidy can be gener-
ous, say, if the household loses a large proportion of its income or the firm experiences a
substantial drop in sales while maintaining its workforce. 20
Channeling the stimulus through the private banking sector enhances the speed and effi-
ciency through which funding is transmitted to households and the non-financial private sec-
tor. 21 Existing financial linkages and networks between banks and households and firms

17 This result is based on scenario analysis using 2018 balance sheet information of 14 thousand listed
firms from 26 countries. If the drop in demand due to the pandemic translates to a 75% drop in sales,
the average listed firm will run out of cash in about one year and about a third of firms would be illiquid
within six months.
18 https://voxeu.org/article/labour-market-policy-response-covid-19-must-save-aggregate-matching-capital. In an earlier

article (Fujita and Moscarini, 2017) the authors find that some workers who were laid off during the
Global Financial Crisis were eventually recalled by their former employers to do the same job they left.
This holds even for some workers whose terminations were thought of as permanent.
19 Blog post on March 23, 2020 at http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/
20 Further, firm subsidies could be additionally indexed to industry-wide sales growth so that industries

which are less affected by the crisis do not free-ride on the program.
21 The stimulus funds itself are aimed at and transferred to the non-financial private sector. Engage-

ment with the private banking sector can take the form of (1) providing guarantees to (potentially sub-
sidized and conditional) commercial bank-issued credit lines to firms and households who in turn re-
ceive (conditional) tax credits and subsidies which serve as collateral for the credit lines and (2) ensur-
ing that private banking sector has sufficient liquidity to meet demand.

BoF Economics Review 6


should be efficiently utilized to rapidly direct funding to individual firms. As banks obtain fees
from such activities, this can enhance financial stability by providing much-needed revenues
to the financial sector that is already likely to suffer large loan losses due to the crisis. On the
other hand, there is also the risk that bank discretion can lead to unintended credit alloca-
tions or channel a potentially excessive amount of the stimulus to "bailing out" the banking
sector. Thus, it is crucial that the stimulus package contains objective and well-defined guide-
lines to the extent possible.
Finally, clear communication of policies can also boost private sector confidence and can
mitigate negative feedbacks between pessimistic expectations and demand. For instance,
Binder (2020) shows that news of the Fed policy response to the pandemic makes consum-
ers more optimistic on unemployment and inflation. Enders et al. (2019) find that German
firms' expectations are also shaped by monetary policy announcements. 22 From this per-
spective, doing too much is better than doing too little. As Gopinath (2020) and Furman
(2020) argue, although policy mistakes are inevitable, communicating timely, coherent, and
sufficiently aggressive policy responses is necessary in order for them to be effective.

6. Policy responses for the long term


If large-scale bankruptcies during the immediate pandemic phase can be avoided, reduced
demand is likely to be the biggest problem that firms face in the longer term, especially in
specific sectors. This calls for continued and significant fiscal stimulus to boost demand (e.g.
direct transfers to households and firms as well as targeted limited-time VAT and other tax
cuts) to help avoid hysteresis effects and aid to recovery phase. 23 Also, different measures to
reduce default in the near-term after the health crisis are called for. For example, temporary
relief for banks from the agreed framework to reduce NPLs in the EU has been suggested.
The COVID-19 pandemic has led to a greater awareness of both the economy-wide and
sector-specific risks that such events entail and their associated costs. 24 One way to mitigate
these costs is to provide greater insurance. 25 On the public side, the need for such insurance
can be reduced by building capacity for pandemic prevention (e.g. emergency legislation, in-
ternational coordination, hygiene standards, and immunization), detection (testing proce-
dures, real-time surveillance), and response systems (e.g. spare emergency healthcare ca-
pacity). 26 This also prepares the ground for economically less costly “test, track, and isolate”
strategies that may be preferable to containment in the long run. Beyond such measures, in-
ternational risk sharing and coordination (e.g. centralized stockpiling of vaccines, etc.) would
ensure that resources can be deployed where they are most beneficial.
Greater international policy coordination is also needed in trade. Facilitating the restora-
tion of global supply chains in the immediate recovery phase should have high priority. For
instance, temporary removal of barriers to trade, such as tariffs, can be considered in indus-
tries that are heavily dependent on global supply chains.
While large-scale fiscal measures are needed – and indeed desirable – both during and in
the near aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic, it is also clear that public sector debt level will
rise as a consequence. Although some measures may end up being fiscally neutral (e.g.
credit lines and liquidity facilities which are eventually repaid), the fiscal stimulus is expected
to entail a significant cost to the government. For example, Benassy-Quere et al. (2020) esti-
mate these measures to cost about 2% of GDP for the case of a one month lockdown period
in Europe while Garicano (2020) proposes a EUR 500 billion package. This can lead to con-
cerns about public sector debt sustainability, put strains on international economic coopera-
tion, and generate inflationary pressure.

22 See also Mertens et al. (2020) and Coibion et al. (2020). See as well Ambrocio (2020) who shows

that fluctuations in consumer sentiment in Europe resemble demand shocks while heightened house-
hold uncertainty leads to higher unemployment and inflation.
23 See e.g. several contributions on Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (2020b).
24 Ramelli and Wagner (2020); McKibbin and Fernando (2020).
25 von Peter et al. (2012).
26 Bloom et al. (2018).

7 Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19 pandemic


– what are the fiscal options?
How should the fiscal stimulus be financed? Gali (2020a, 2020b) proposes a money-fi-
nanced stimulus and argues that it is more effective than a debt-financed stimulus although
the difference shrinks at the effective lower bound. He also stresses that care must be taken
in its implementation in order to preserve central bank credibility. A money-financed stimulus
shifts some of the economic risks of a large scale fiscal stimulus from debt sustainability to
inflation.
On the other hand, Krugman (2020) argues that a large-scale debt-financed stimulus is
sustainable in a low interest rate environment. While increasing public debt burdens and in-
ternational risk sharing is desirable to mitigate the immediate economic fallout from the pan-
demic, credible state-contingent commitments to reduce debt burdens in the medium to long-
term may be desirable to prevent issues with public debt sustainability and strains to eco-
nomic cooperation. 27 Further, specifically for Europe and given limited fiscal space in some
countries, many experts call for a unified European fiscal response especially in the area of
financing the stimulus through the issuance of a Euro-wide pandemic bond (in tandem with
ECB accommodation). 28

27 For example, this might entail transfers from countries with more to those with less fiscal space to
prevent long lasting hysteresis effects. The same applies more broadly at an international level. See
e.g. Alesina and Giavazzi (2020) and other relevant contributions in Baldwin and Weder di Mauro
(2020b), among others.
28 This view is shared by many experts and endorsed in many contributions to Baldwin and Weder di

Mauro (2020b) among others.

BoF Economics Review 8


References
Acemoglu, D. Akcigit, U., Alp, H., Bloom, N. and Kerr, W. (2018). Innovation, Reallocation,
and Growth. American Economic Review, 108(11), pp.3450-3491.
Alesina, A. and Giavazzi, F. (2020). The EU must support the member at the centre of the
Covid-19 crisis. In Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic
Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes, (pp. 51-56). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Ali-Yrkkö, J., and Kuusi, T. (2020) Korona-sokki talouteen – Missä määrin Suomi on riippu-
vainen ulkomaisista arvoketjuista? ETLA Muistio No 87.
Almond, D., and Mazumder, B., (2005). The 1918 Influenza Pandemic and Subsequent
Health Outcomes: An Analysis of SIPP Data. American Economic Review, 95 (2), pp. 258-
262.
Ambrocio, G. (2020). Inflationary household uncertainty shocks. Working Paper.
Anzoategui, D., Comin, D., Gertler, M., and Martinez, J. (2019). Endogenous Technology
Adoption and R&D as Sources of Business Cycle Persistence. American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics, 11(3), pp.67-110.
Atkeson, A. (2020). What will be the impact of Covid-19 in the US? Rough estimates of dis-
ease scenarios, NBER Working Paper No. 26867.
Baker, S., Bloom, N., Davis, S., Kost, K., Sammon, M., and Viratyosin, T. (2020). The un-
precedented stock market impact of Covid-19. NBER Working Paper No. 26945.
Baker, S., Farrokhnia, R.A., Meyer, S., Pagel, M., and Yannelis, C. (2020). How does house-
hold spending respond to an epidemic? Consumption during the 2020 Covid-19 Pandemic.
NBER Working Paper No. 26949.
Baldwin, R. and Tomiura, E. (2020). Thinking ahead about the trade impact of Covid-19. In
Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Economics in the Time of Covid-19, (pp. 59-72). CEPR
Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Baldwin, R. and Weder di Mauro, B. (Eds.) (2020a). Economics in the Time of Covid-19.
CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Baldwin, R. and Weder di Mauro, B. (Eds.) (2020b). Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis:
Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes. CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Bank of Finland (2020). Suomen talous taantumaan koronaviruksen takia. Suomen talouden
väliennuste, Euro & Talous, maaliskuu 2020.
Barro, R., Ursua, J., and Weng, J. (2020). The Coronavirus and the Great Influenza Epidemic:
Lessons from the "Spanish Flu" for the Coronavirus's Potential Effects on Mortality and Eco-
nomic Activity. NBER Working Paper No. 26866.
Benassy-Quere, A., Marimon, R., Pisani-Ferry, J., Reichlin, L., Schoenmaker, D., and Weder
di Mauro, B. (2020). Covid-19: Europe needs a catastrophe relief plan. In Baldwin and Weder
di Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes,
(pp. 121-28). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Binder, C. (2020). Coronavirus Fears and Macroeconomic Expectations. Working Paper.
Bloom D. E., Cadarette D. and Sevilla J.P. (2018). The Economic Risks and Impacts of Epi-
demics. International Monetary Fund, F&D Magazine, June 2018.

9 Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19 pandemic


– what are the fiscal options?
Boone, L., Haugh, D., Pain, N., and Salins, V. (2020). Tackling the Fallout from Covid-19. In
Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Economics in the Time of Covid-19, (pp. 37-44). CEPR
Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Cahuc, P., Kramarz, F., and Nevoux, S. (2018). When Short-Time Work Works. CEPR Dis-
cussion Paper 13041.
Carpenter, R. and Petersen, B. (2002). Is the growth of small firms constrained by internal fi-
nance? Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), pp. 298-309.
Cochrane, J. (2020). Coronavirus monetary policy. In Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.),
Economics in the Time of Covid-19, (pp. 105-108). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Coibion, O., Georgarakos, D., Gorodnichenko, Y., and Weber, M. (2020). Forward guidance
and household expectations. NBER Working Paper No. 26778.
Cruces, J., and Trebesch, C., (2013). Sovereign Defaults: The Price of Haircuts. American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5 (3), pp. 85-117.
De Vito, A. and Gomez, J.-P. (2020). Estimating the Covid-19 Cash Crunch: Global Evidence
and Policy. Working Paper.
Eichenbaum, M., Rebelo, S., and Trabandt, M. (2020). The Macroeconomics of Epidemics.
NBER Working Paper No. 26882.
Enders, Z., Hunnekes, F., and Muller, G. (2019). Monetary policy announcements and expec-
tations: Evidence from German firms. Journal of Monetary Economics, 108, pp. 45-63.
European Central Bank (2016). Understanding the Weakness in Global Trade - What is the
New Normal? ECB Occasional Paper No. 178.
Fan V. Y., Jamison D. T. & Summers L. H. (2018). Pandemic risk: how large are the ex-
pected losses? Bulletin of the World Health Organization.
Fang, H. Wang, L., and Yang, Y. (2020). Human Mobility Restrictions and the Spread of the
Novel Coronavirus in China. NBER Working Paper No. 26906.
Faria-e-Castro, M. (2020). Fiscal Policy during a Pandemic. Working Paper.
Ferrero, G, M. Gross and S. Neri (2019). On secular stagnation and low interest rates: De-
mography matters. International Finance, 22(3), pp. 262-278.
Fujita, S. and Moscarini, G. (2017). Recall and Unemployment. American Economic Review,
107(12), pp. 3875-3916.
Furman, J. (2020). Protecting people now, helping the economy rebound later. In Baldwin and
Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever it
Takes, (pp. 191-196). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Gali, J. (2020a). The Effects of a Money-Financed Fiscal Stimulus. Journal of Monetary Eco-
nomics, forthcoming.
Gali, J. (2020b). Helicopter money: The time is now. In Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.),
Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes, (pp. 57-62).
CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Garicano, L. (2020). The Covid-19 bazooka for jobs in Europe. In Baldwin and Weder di
Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes,
(pp. 129-138). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.

BoF Economics Review 10


Gennaioli, N., Martin, A., and Rossi, S. (2018). Banks, government bonds, and default: What
do the data say? Journal of Monetary Economics, 98, pp. 98-113.
Gopinath, G. (2020). Limiting the economic fallout of the coronavirus with large targeted pol-
icies. In Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act
Fast and Do Whatever it Takes, (pp. 41-48). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Gourinchas, P.-O. (2020). Flattening the pandemic and recession curves. In Baldwin and
Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever it
Takes, (pp. 31-40). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Guerrieri, V., Lorenzoni, G., Straub, L., and Werning, I. (2020). Macroeconomic implications
of Covid-19: Can negative supply shocks cause demand shortages? NBER Working Paper No.
26918.
Huovari, J., Keskinen, P., Busk, H., Godenhielm, M., Alimov, N., Ruuskanen, O-P., (2020).
PTT-ennuste: Kansantalous. Kevät 2020, Helsinki.
Joo, H., Maskery, B., Berro, A., Rotz, L., Lee, Y., and Brown, C. (2019). Economic Impact of
the 2015 MERS Outbreak on the Republic of Korea's Tourism-Related Industries. Health Se-
curity, 17(2).
Jorda, O., Singh, S., and Taylor, A., (2020). Longer-run economic consequences of pandem-
ics. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2020-09.
Kerr, W. (2009). Political Precaution, Pandemics and Protectionism. The Estey Centre Jour-
nal of International Law and Trade Policy, 10(2), p. 1-14.
Krugman, P. (2020). The case for permanent stimulus. In Baldwin and Weder di Mauro
(Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes, (pp. 213-
219). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Lustig. N. and Mariscal, J. (2020). How Covid-19 could be like the Global Financial Crisis
(or worse). In Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis:
Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes, (pp. 185-190). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.
Ma, C., Rogers, J., and Zhou, S. (2020). Global Economic and Financial Effects of 21st Cen-
tury Pandemics and Epidemics. Working Paper.
McKibbin, W. and Fernando, R. (2020). The global macroeconomic impact of Covid-19:
Seven scenarios. Working Paper.
Mertens, K., Lewis, D., and Makridis, C. (2020). Do monetary policy announcements shift
household expectations? CEPR Discussion Paper 14360.
OECD (2020). Coronavirus: The world economy at risk. Interim Economic Assessment,
March 2020.
Rachel, L. and T. Smith (2017). Are low real interest rates here to stay? International Journal
of Central Banking, 13(3), pp. 1-42.
Rachel, L. and L. Summers (2019). Public boost and private drag: government policy and the
equilibrium real interest rate in advanced economies. BPEA Conference Draft, Spring
Ramelli, S. and Wagner, A. (2020). What the stock market tells us about the consequences of
Covid 19. In Baldwin and Weder di Mauro (Eds.), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis:
Act Fast and Do Whatever it Takes, (pp. 63-70). CEPR Press: VoxEU.org eBook.

11 Dealing with the costs of the COVID-19 pandemic


– what are the fiscal options?
Rassy and Smith (2013). The economic impact of H1N1 on Mexico's tourist and pork sectors.
Health Economics, 22(7).
Rosselló, J., Santana-Gallego, M., and Awan, W. (2017). Infectious disease risk and interna-
tional tourism demand. Health Policy Plan, 32(4), pp. 538-548.
Schmitz, T. (2020). Endogenous Growth, Firm Heterogeneity and the Long-Run Impact of Fi-
nancial Crises. Working Paper.
Simola, H. and Solanko, L. (2020). Domestic and global economic effects of COVID-19 con-
tainment measures : How does Russia compare internationally? BOFIT Policy Brief 2020 No.
6.
Stock, J. (2020). Data gaps and the policy response to the novel coronavirus. NBER Working
Paper No. 26902.
Tomz, M., and Wright, M., (2013). Empirical Research on Sovereign Debt and Default. An-
nual Review of Economics, 5(1), pp. 247-272.
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (2020). Severe Outcomes Among Patients
with Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19). Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report 69,
343-346.
von Peter, G., von Dahlen, S. and Saxena, S. (2012). Unmitigated disasters? New evidence on
the macroeconomic cost of natural catastrophes. BIS Working Papers No. 394.

BoF Economics Review 12

You might also like