BtoB CutEdge - Col PDF
BtoB CutEdge - Col PDF
BtoB CutEdge - Col PDF
Rachel Cole
Topic 3 What are the effects on the market of taxes and subsidies? 9
Topic 7 Efficiency 28
Topic 12 Productivity 52
Even if you have only had a week or two of economics lessons you will probably know by now that a demand
curve slopes downwards and a supply curve slopes upwards. The demand side seems pretty obvious. If you
can get something cheaper then you will want to buy more. Or as the economist would put it, there are
diminishing returns as you consume more of something, and so at higher quantities the amount you’re
prepared to pay for another goes down. But for supply it doesn’t seem so obvious. Of course firms would
like to make as much money as possible, but why do they only want to supply more when prices are higher?
Surely it’s cheaper to supply more per unit, and don’t firms offer discounts to people who want to buy more?
So here is the point of this article – why do most supply curves in textbooks slope upwards?
Before we look at the standard response to this question, let’s just use some common sense. Supply is
pretty well fixed for many goods and services. Say you want to go to a sold-out concert on Saturday and
you’ll pay anything for a ticket. Too bad. The concert promoters would lose their licence if they overfill the
seats. Maybe if there is so much demand and people are really prepared to pay anything the promoters will
decide to increase supply by offering one more night. But this is with reluctance (the band will lose their
day off, perhaps) and it will only happen if prices people are prepared to pay are high enough.
So why is it that costs rise when you produce more? It’s true that this is only a short run phenomenon
because clearly if the concert promoter knew in advance that you could sell more nights of the concert it
probably would be cheaper per night to book two. The whole reason for the shape of the supply curve is
based on the fact that some factors are fixed and you can’t increase output without incurring extra costs.
Costs of supply tend to go up because some factors of production are restricted in supply in the short run.
The amount of many goods and services currently available in the market cannot be increased
instantaneously. If you really want more you’ll have to pay more to get it shipped over from another
country, with the added expense of changing currencies and tariffs may have to be paid if sourced from
outside the EU. Or it may mean that people have to work overtime, for which workers will expect higher
pay. While this is not true for many mass-produced, processed and storable items, it is true for many other
things that we want to buy. Look at eBay and see prices go up as demand rises. If there’s more than one
person aiming to buy a unique item then prices rise. But if there are many items very similar for sale on
eBay then there doesn’t seem to be a bidding war, and you can just ‘buy it now’ for a reasonable price.
So one way to explain why supply curves usually slope upwards is that as the price of the product rises
producers will find it more profitable to offer goods and services for sale, given their existing productive
capacity. This is because any increase in costs incurred by increasing output will be covered by the higher
price.
Market power
A firm with monopoly power can restrict supply and thereby charge a lot more for it. Designer brands are
a clear example of this. Firms making perfume could probably sell a lot more if prices were lower, but this
would mean a fall in their enormous profit margins. Perfume has a low price elasticity, which means that
if prices fall total revenue falls. It is in the interest of firms to make as much profit as possible. Another law
of economics (that is, something which is true by definition) is that if demand has price elasticity below
one then the firm will make more money if it raises the price. In the scenario above where markets are
perfectly competitive then they can’t raise price. If they did then other firms would simply undercut them
and sales would fall to zero. But if a firm has any market power at all then it can raise price without losing
all of its market. When price elasticity of demand is inelastic the firm makes more money by supplying less
at a higher price. Lower supply at a higher price? Sounds like the supply curve is downwards sloping in
some cases. So if there is a degree of market or monopoly power, it seems that the supply curve is not
always upward sloping. It’s very difficult, however, to draw a supply curve in situations like this, because
clearly the supply depends on the price elasticity of demand. And because it’s not easy to draw you won’t
often see this type of supply curve in a textbook. But certainly most supply curves do have some degree
of uncertainty about them for the reason that demand is not perfectly elastic, which is why supply curves
always drawn going upwards is a little simplistic.
Another good example to think of is OPEC, the Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries, and the
way in which it works to keep the price of oil high. It has low oil production costs (less than $5 a barrel)
and has the most spare capacity of all the oil producer outlets. It sells 40% of the world’s daily oil supply,
and when it has political reasons to take a swipe at its Western buyers of oil it can restrict its supply. The
effect of course, owing to price inelastic demand for oil, is that prices zoom up. Why then don’t other
suppliers enter the market to take advantage of the higher prices? It may be that there aren’t stocks of oil
available in other countries, or maybe other countries just enjoy the price hikes because their own income
rises. Firms are much happier supplying when prices are high, and certainly don’t want to destroy that
equilibrium by starting a price war. This enters the field of game theory which you might look at when you
study oligopoly at A2 level.
be able to calculate that its elasticity is above one, not price inelastic as you might expect with a
steep curve. Can you explain that in common sense terminology?
3. Spare capacity is one reason why costs of production do not rise when demand rises. Does this
mean that a country should always aim to have a great deal of idle resources at all times?
4. Marginal costs can begin to rise while average costs are falling. Do you think firms use marginal or
average costs when choosing prices – or neither? If they use average costs are they being rational?
5. Market power appears to be the key determinant of prices and output for many goods and services.
However, the power is not always on the suppliers’ side. Buyers can also have market power. If the
government is seen as a powerful buyer of labour in the health service, what do you think is the
implication for the wages paid to nurses?
● Law of diminishing returns – if you keep adding more and more of a variable factor to a fixed
factor then the increase in output will eventually fall. It only holds true in the short run which
means that at least one factor is fixed.
● Law of increasing costs – as more of a variable factor is applied to a fixed factor, the cost of
producing an extra unit of output will rise.
Key Terms
● Fixed factor – when a firm cannot change how much it has. For example the number of A level
subjects you can do is determined by the amount of time you have. In the short run it’s fixed by the
number of hours in the school timetable. In the long run – after you leave school, say, you can take
as many extra A levels as you like as your life goes by. Or maybe your brain capacity is fixed too?
● Factors of production, or resources used to produce all goods and services. Economists call them
land, labour, capital and enterprise.
● Perfect competition – a market structure where there are many buyers and sellers, none of which
have any control over price.
● Market power – a measure of the control a buyer or seller has over price, because they can control
quantity supplied.
Imagine that you run a business. It is not making very much profit. You have tried all the normal things –
a bit more marketing, trying to get more investment in new technology, taking on or removing staff – but
things aren’t getting better. What can you do?
Well, you might consider changing the price of your product. The problem is that it is not always clear
which way you should go. If you raise the price, you’ll lose some customers, but if you cut the price you’ll
lose money on everything that you sell. Which is the best option? The answer lies in the value of price
elasticity of demand.
Elasticity is one of the most useful tools to an economist. A good understanding of it will not only help you
increase your grades but also help you if you ever need to do any marketing, which most people do at
some point in their lives. It is a measure of the response by either consumers or producers when something
changes in the economy. It measures the percentage of the response, not the total amount, so that we can
tell how big the change is relative to where it was before and also in proportion to how big the original
change was. This makes the calculations a little longer, but the only maths you need to know for this topic
is the rule for percentages: change over original times 100.
In some markets if a firm puts its prices up it will make more money. Yes, a higher price might mean you
sell less, but you get a higher revenue from the larger mark up on each item. Here’s an example. Say you
run an independent opticians. The staff want higher wages, the business rates are going up, and health
and safety regulations mean that you have to invest more money in the business. You need to increase
revenue to cover these costs. What do you do? The demand for opticians services is very inelastic – once
a family has started using one, it’s likely to be the family opticians for years. People don’t like switching
opticians so when fees go up the consumer is very unlikely to shift to another optician (especially when all
opticians are likely to be increasing prices for the same reasons). It is true that some people will stop going
to the optician at all as price increases, but total revenue for the optician is almost certain to increase
because there is some, but not much, alternative to local services. Opticians can charge virtually what they
like, and as prices rise total revenue for opticians increases proportionately. Therefore opticians are making
more money as they raise prices, although it reaches a point when people will hunt around for cheaper
options or not go for check-ups very often.
Let’s now consider what happens if the demand is price elastic. Price elasticity of demand is higher when
there are lots of substitutes, if the cost is a large proportion of income, if the good is perceived as a luxury
or if the time period under consideration is extended. One example is the very competitive market in
student loans. When you start a full-time higher education course beyond the age of eighteen, you will be
able to choose from a large selection of banks eager to offer you a cheap loan to cover your costs while
you are at college. The products offered are very similar, and the existence of close substitutes makes the
elasticity very high. The proportion of income spent on repaying this loan is also likely to be very high.
While this may not fit with all the other characteristics of high PED it is fairly likely that you’ll be very
sensitive to the various offers advertised by the major loan providers. For example, Barclays will give you a
free iPod, Lloyds a free rail card, and HSBC offers a combination of the two. That the offers are very similar
in monetary value indicates that the suppliers recognise that your PED is incredibly high. In other words,
you are very sensitive to price or other value changes. The lower the price the more the proportionate
increase in demand is likely to be. In very competitive markets the consumer does well because the
excellent choice forces down price and increases the options available.
The way to know what is going to happen to revenue, whether you raise or lower prices, is to look at the
marginal revenue. What happens at the margin, that is one extra unit increased or decreased, can show
whether the situation gets better or worse. If you raise the price and you gain more on each unit sold than
1. The formula is percentage change in income divided by percentage change in price. If one goes up the other goes down, and vice versa, so the sign is always negative. Because
a comparison between negative numbers is sometimes a little confusing (e.g. negative 3 bigger in effect than negative 1 but smaller numerically) we usually ignore the negative
sign. But when we look at income elasticity and cross price elasticity it is very important not to ignore it!
2. The figures in this section come from www.sussex.ac.uk/economics/documents.
a
S (elastic)
b
P1
a b
P1 P
a
P
a b
P0 P0
D1 D1
D0 D0
Q0 Q1 Q0
3. We use a Y (a Greek I) instead of I because I already stands for Investment in many economics contexts.
4. The Economist, 21 October 2006.
5. X in XED is short for a cross sign, but the more logical acronym is the initials of Cross Price Elasticity of Demand.
1. Is it rational for a firm ever to produce at a point where demand is inelastic? If you have learnt about
MC = MR you will know that the firm must always produce where MR is positive because MC is
always positive. And if demand is inelastic then MR is …… ?
Questions for Discussion
2. Firms make great efforts to reduce the PED for their products. For example they might increase
brand loyalty or improve the quality of service. Name three other ways in which they might try to
do this. Is this good for consumers?
3. Using the real world data, estimate the PED for each of the following and give a justification for
your decision:
Halal kebabs in Sheffield Hallam University campus (there’s just one halal food outlet on the
● Price elasticity of demand (PED) – the percentage change in quantity demanded in response to
a percentage change in price.
● Income elasticity of demand (YED) – the percentage change in quantity demanded in response
Key Terms
● Cross elasticity of demand (XED or CPED) – the percentage change in quantity demanded of
one product in response to a percentage change in price of another.
● Price elasticity of supply (PES) – the percentage change in quantity supplied in response to a
percentage change in price.
● Revenue – the amount of money a firm receives, calculated as price times quantity.
Governments intervene in markets in many ways: sometimes they want to discourage production or
consumption, in which case they raise a tax; and sometimes they want to encourage production or
consumption and might choose to offer a subsidy. There are many other ways in which governments can try
to alter our levels of production and consumption, but in this Back to Basics we will look specifically at taxes
and subsidies, illustrating them with simple diagrams, analyse who is paying the tax or receiving the benefit
of the subsidy (incidence), and discuss the contexts in which they are likely to be most effective. Finally we
will evaluate them by asking whether they are the best measures to achieve government objectives.
Taxes
Taxes are a requirement by law to pay money to government. There are two main types. Most of this article
focuses on indirect taxes, but we take a quick look at direct taxes first:
Direct taxes are taxes on income, such as income tax, which are taken directly or straight out of incomes.
Rather perversely, direct taxes can have an indirect impact on market prices. For example, when income tax
fell to 20p per pound in April 2008, then I’m sure I wasn’t the only person feeling a little bit better off at
the end of the month, and planning to increase demand for luxury products. This affects prices if enough
of us do that. So a cut in taxes is likely to put upward pressure on some prices. Similarly the 2010 cut in
corporation tax from 28% to 27% in 2011 (a proportion of a firm’s profits) might allow firms to cut prices.
So while it is true that direct taxes can have very significant effects on prices, the issue is more likely to
come up on a macro economics paper, rather than trying to apply the tax system to the ways in which
markets work in micro.
Indirect taxes are taxes on expenditure, such as value added tax (VAT). They are paid by any firm which
sells anything, unless it’s a small firm or a charity. When the government wants to alter production and
consumption patterns the main way to do this is by indirect tax rather than direct tax, as this will affect
prices. The reason that it is called indirect tax is that the consumer does not pay the money directly to the
government, but the firms which sold the goods or services must pay. The consumers do end up paying at
least part of these taxes, as the cost of the tax is passed onto the consumer. You will feel some effect from
the 20% VAT from January 2011.
Indirect taxes come in two versions too: specific taxes, which are a fixed sum per unit sold, and ad valorem
taxes, which are added on as a percentage of the price. The specific tax on wine in the UK currently
depends on the amount of alcohol, not the price at which it sells. This is shown in Table 1.
Table 1: The specific taxes per litre of wine since the March 2010 Budget
Wine (not sparkling): Exceeding 5.5% – not exceeding
15% alcohol by volume £2.25
Wine (not sparkling): Exceeding 15% – not exceeding
22% alcohol by volume £2.99
Source: www.hmrc.gov.uk
It doesn’t matter whether you buy vin de grotsville or chateaux de poshville, the tax is the same per volume
and strength. A specific tax is one which varies not with the price but with another factor, such as alcohol
strength.
The second type of indirect tax is the ad valorem tax. Ad valorem is the Latin for corresponding to the
value. The more something costs the higher the tax rate. VAT is the most well known example. If I buy
anything which might be seen as a luxury then I’m likely to have 20% tax hidden in the price.
Subsidies
A subsidy is a grant given to producers (or consumers). There are two main reasons that a government
might offer a subsidy to affect market prices:
It may be that the government thinks that the market price is too low for firms, and may want to support
the firms’ incomes to stop the firms shutting down. This will encourage production, which not only keeps
firms in business, but can mean that supplies of services are guaranteed, especially in the case of some
foodstuffs which are considered essential. Another advantage is that jobs are not lost in the industry. For
example the government subsidised £5,000 per car made in the UK in 2010.
By contrast it may be that the government thinks that the market price is too high for consumers, and
that if prices were lower people would consume an amount which more accurately reflects the value they
will gain from consumption. This is a situation where there are positive externalities. For example the
government subsidises train operating companies heavily (which may surprise you considering some
fares), helping to ensure unprofitable routes are kept running. That is, there is a social benefit.
The effect of subsidies is to lower prices but the cost to the government of doing this is high, as is shown
in the following diagrams. The consumer might feel better off because of lower prices but there may be an
opportunity cost to be paid through taxes. These can destroy incentives in an economy such as the desire
to work long hours, and the effects of the subsidy can be seen as worse than if the government hadn’t got
involved in the market at all. The amount paid and the amount that benefits the consumer and the
producer is shown neatly with a diagram showing the incidence of taxation.
tax
S
P2 e2
subsidy
S + subsidy
P1 e1
P3 e3
D
0
Q2 Q1 Q3 Q
Figure 1 shows the difference between an indirect tax and a subsidy. The indirect tax is the vertical distance
between the supply curves, and pushes prices and costs upwards. The subsidy is again the vertical distance
between the supply curves but instead pushes the costs or prices downwards. When calculating the total
Figure 2
P
S + tax
e2
P2
e1
P1
P1 - t
0
Q2 Q1 Q
The dynamics of the diagram work in just the same way for the ad valorem tax (except for the steeper slope
for the new supply curve). In Figure 2 the demand is drawn quite flat, implying that it is fairly price elastic
– this means that if prices change a little then demand changes proportionately more. So when taxes put
these prices up, the quantity reduces significantly, and the producer ends up paying most of the tax.
1. With a 10% increase in price causing an overall reduction in cigarette consumption by 3% to 5%, with young people and low waged more likely to cut consumption.
1. Draw a summary table similar to Table 2, but this time for subsidies. What pattern emerges?
2. If you have been studying macroeconomics you may have got the impression that subsidies are a
Questions for Discussion
supply side policy. The reason for saying this is that subsidies encourage firms to produce more and
at a lower price. However what is the difference between subsidies and a supply side policy? Think
micro, macro.
3. The price elasticity of demand is of crucial importance when considering the incidence of taxes and
subsidies, as discussed above when looking at the shift in supply curves. But is the price elasticity
of supply important? Remember that the shift in the supply curve is a vertical movement so if it is
very steep it will not move left or right very much.
4. If indirect taxes are the only way to stop people smoking, why not double the tax on cigarettes? Or
is the smoking ban (since July 2007) going to have more effect, with fines ranging from £30 to
£2,500?
● Indirect tax – taxes on expenditure, e.g. value added tax (VAT), tax on petrol.
● Incidence – who pays the tax (or receives benefit of the subsidy).
● Common External Tariff – the EU imposes some taxes on outside countries which all member
countries impose at the same rate. These vary from 7% (footwear) to 236% (food products).
Imagine that I need to lose some weight. I’m sitting typing this, feeling a little peckish just at the thought
of a diet. The last few biscuits in the tin seem to be calling out to be eaten. There is a decision to be made
– whether to eat another biscuit and carry on, or whether to switch off the computer and go for a run. How
much is just one more biscuit (the variable) going to affect my progress?
This decision is made at the margin, that is, what I will do next disregarding what’s happened up till now.
I might have been scoffing food all day or running a marathon, but an economist likes at times to ignore
what’s been done so far when deciding what to do next. What I’ve been doing all day does of course matter
when I add up my totals for the day, to see how I’ve done. But if I’m trying to reach a target or trying to
make some changes, then what I do next should be considered in isolation. And if every decision along the
way is made using the margin, then I will maximise, minimise or whatever my original target was.
One really useful concept that comes out of considering the margin is externalities. Externalities are
the spill-over effects, or impact on a third party when an economic transaction takes place. Everyone
knows that driving cars causes global warming but it doesn’t seem to have much effect on our decision-
making when we need a lift into town. It is not a reasonable economic policy to expect people to give
up their cars or to stop using fossil fuels to heat their houses. But you can look at whether people might
occasionally share lifts or turn the heating down when they could wear a jumper instead. In other words,
to change the levels of carbon that we emit, it is more effective to alter behaviour with incremental steps
rather than total bans. If we believe in market forces rather than authoritarian control then changing
people’s behaviour by means of the price system is the only viable option. The problem of externalities
can be addressed if the price system can be used to take account of the marginal social cost (or benefits)
rather than just the marginal private costs (or benefits).
So let’s look at the marginal social cost of my driving to work. The car is already taxed and insured, so
these costs are not part of the marginal cost. The marginal private cost (this is my personal spending) is
the petrol at £2, and any congestion or parking charge that I face. There is then the cost to other people
not part of the transaction, in other words, the third party effects. The people are paying the negative
externality – the extra congestion and the increased wait at traffic lights for other motorists, and the risk
to pedestrians such as a minute contribution to a person’s asthma or the increased risk to someone of
being run over. Add this increased externality to the marginal private cost and you get the marginal social
cost, the full cost to society of my driving to work. If I then add in the fact that it’s actually quicker and
better for me on my bike then the costs are outweighed by the benefits, and this explains why in fact I
never do drive to work. But I do have my own car – it’s just that making the journey to work is not
economic for me. By using a road toll or congestion charge the externalities can be internalised. The
big problem of course is knowing just how much the marginal externality is, and therefore the correct
amount for the tax or toll. Knowing how big the margin is becomes a very important question for
governments, high on the agenda for any modern democracy.
A second economic use of the concept of the margin is diminishing marginal returns. Let’s go back to
that packet of biscuits. When I have had four or five biscuits, I begin to find that each extra biscuit gives
me less enjoyment or payback. The concept is fundamental to the way in which cost curves are drawn,
and from there supply curves. It also explains why a production possibility frontier bows outwards. The
key thing here is that it is the extra enjoyment that is diminishing, not the enjoyment from eating the
biscuits as a whole. When the extra benefit exceeds the costs of buying the next item I’ll keep on buying,
and so this continues until the cost is the same as the marginal benefit. And where there is more than
one item I need to get the marginal benefit relative to price equal on every item to maximise my
enjoyment relative to the amount I have to spend.
1. www.ofwat.gov.uk
● The margin – the effect per unit of a small change in any variable.
● Allocative efficiency – where resources in an economy are shared out to maximise the benefit for
society as a whole. It would not be possible to make anyone better off without someone else being
made worse off.
● Diminishing marginal returns – as more of a unit is consumed or produced, the increase in
benefit or output will eventually fall.
● Externalities – the effects of an economic decision that are not accounted for by either the buyer
or seller, that is outside the private costs and benefits. They are also called the spill-over effects, or
impact on a third party when an economic transaction takes place.
Key Terms
● Marginal private cost – the cost to the individual or firm when one more unit is consumed or
produced.
● Marginal private benefit – the benefit to the individual or firm when one more unit is consumed
or produced.
● Marginal social cost – the cost to society as a whole when one more unit is consumed or produced.
● Marginal social benefit – the benefit to society as a whole when one more unit is consumed or
produced.
● Price system – where resources are allocated according to the forces of demand and supply, rather
than by governmental control.
Firms don’t exist unless they make a profit. But do all firms
have to make as much profit as they can? It might be better to This section looks at four tools
make increased investment now in order to get more profits in used to help us understand profit
the future. It might be that the people running the firm are maximisation at A2 level:
not the main beneficiaries of increased profits, and they might
A summary of essential theory
have other goals – especially if their pay is based on sales
of the firm
revenue rather than profit. Sometimes firms like us to think
An explanation of what MC =
they have other motives than profit maximisation – for
MR is using marginal analysis
example BP’s tagline is ‘Beyond Petroleum’ – but the bottom
Some ideas as to why MC = MR
line is in this case very focused on profits. In this Back to Basics
is useful for a firm
we are going to consider the objectives of firms, starting with
A selection of other goals
the profit maximising goal, to see first of all if it has any
besides profit maximisation
practical use in economics today.
that a firm might have
It’s easy to learn the formula for profit maximisation, that
marginal cost (MC) equals marginal revenue (MR). On a visit
to the head office at a locally-based multinational company one of my students asked the managing
director whether the firm actually operates at MC = MR. Of course the answer was a blank, and when we
got back to class it was asked why we bother learning the formula if real businesses don’t use it. The
answer is that many businesses do use it but don’t call it that. Many firms do use marginal analysis, and
most firms need to maximise profits in the long run if they are going to survive.
1. The technique of considering what would happen if one more or one less is produced is called marginal analysis. So when we assume that all firms aim to maximise profits,
for this so-called short-run equilibrium we say that the cost of producing the last unit, marginal cost, is equal to the increase in revenue for the firm when that last unit is
sold, marginal revenue. In brief, MC = MR. This can be explained by considering the situation when the two are not the same.
• If the marginal revenue was greater than the cost of producing one more unit, then the firm is missing out on potential profits – if the firm sold another good more would be
gained than lost.
• If marginal cost is greater than the amount the firm receives by making another unit then the firm would do better not producing it.
2. Friedman, Milton, ‘The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase Its Profits’, The New York Times Magazine, 13 September, 1970.
AC
E
C
A
AR
B
MR Quantity
The most efficient output point, or minimum average cost, is a possible aim for firms. It sounds as
though a firm would always want to be there, at C, but that is not the case. Only by coincidence would it
happen also to be at profit or revenue maximisation, except in the unique case of perfect competition in
the long run. A firm is always interested in lowering the entire cost curve, but there is never any particular
reason from the firm’s point of view for being at the lowest point of the existing average cost curve – it is
more important for a firm to relate its costs to the amount the output can be sold for. It could certainly be
rational from the government or the consumers’ point of view, but consumers aren’t usually the agents
making the pricing decision.
Welfare maximisation point – this (point D) is otherwise known as the point of maximum allocative
efficiency, or the point of socially optimum output, or the point of Pareto optimality, where no one can
be made better off without someone else being made worse off. It occurs where Price = MC, because
before this point the value that society puts on the next unit (price is read off the demand curve) is always
above the cost to society of producing the next unit (the firm’s MC). Except in perfect competition, welfare
maximisation is always at a lower price and a greater output than profit maximisation, or in other words,
the price is greater than the marginal revenue, and the price is equal to the marginal cost, therefore the
marginal revenue is not the same as the marginal cost. You cannot welfare maximise and profit maximise.
You can in perfect competition, which is where we move on to next, and it is a market structure where,
uniquely, the firm has the same marginal revenue as price.
Output maximisation – this occurs where total revenue and total costs are the same (TC = TR), or where
price per unit is the same as cost per unit (AC = AR). Be careful not to confuse this point with revenue
maximisation. It is also called the upper break-even point, where the firm is as large as it possibly can be
without making a loss (point E on Figure 1). The firm is making normal profits. This will occur at a higher
output than profit maximisation. A firm may wish to do this (and sacrifice present profit) if it wishes to
become larger and expand, perhaps into other markets, which may lead to higher future profit. A conflict
may exist between the owners of a firm (the shareholders), who may look for maximum profit, and the
managers, who do not own the firm and whose motivation may be linked more to growth and expansion.
If there is a divorce between ownership and control then the controllers may try to maximise output, but it
is doubtful that they will keep their jobs in the long run if they ignore the bottom line, or final profit figure.
Satisficing behaviour – satisficing is a made-up word, combining satisfying and sufficing – keeping the
owners (usually the shareholders) happy, and doing just enough to get by. This is a compromise, usually
between the extremes of profit and output maximisation. Having achieved the minimum level of profit to
stop shareholders selling their shares, for example, controllers of the firm can seek any objectives they
wish – improving their golf handicap, having a top sports-car or just fewer risks or keeping a business
family-run.
Limit pricing – a perfectly legal way to combat the threat of potential competition is to cut the price of
your product so that any new firm – which is likely to have higher average costs when it starts business –
will never be able to make a profit. A new firm is likely to start small scale and without the benefits of
economies of scale and therefore have higher average costs. A limit-pricing firm cuts its price so that it
*Spot the error? Marginal revenue is not always positive. True you always get more money coming in when
you sell another item. But you lose money on all the items you are already selling when you cut the price
to sell one more.
Questions for Discussion
1. What would you reply to the person who asks whether a firm is operating at MC = MR?
2. Are charities profit maximisers? What about public sector firms, such as the Post Office? What
would happen in the long run if they didn’t make profit?
3. If you ran your own business, how much profit would you need to make to keep running it? Most
people running their own businesses are happy to work for less pay than if they were working for
someone else – does this suggest they are satisficing? Or, that the pleasure of being your own boss
is worth a certain amount. Or do self employed people only accept less money because they think
that in the long run they will be able to make larger profits, have more leisure time, or control their
own – or others’ – working lives?
● Normal profit – this occurs where total revenue exactly equals total cost, or average revenue
equals average cost. The costs include land, labour, capital and enterprise (risk taking), and the risk
taker needs to make a profit in order to keep the resources in the current use. Normal profit is the
minimum profit needed to keep the risk taker keeping his or her assets in their current use.
Key Terms
● Supernormal profit – any profit above normal profit is supernormal profit. It acts as a signal to
other firms to enter the market. If there are no barriers to entry or exit, then firms will enter a
market where supernormal profits are being made. This increase in competition is likely to make
prices fall, and the increased competition for the factors of production is likely to put costs up – and
both of these will tend to erode supernormal profit in the long run. In other words you can only
make long run supernormal profits if there are barriers to entry or exit.
● Satisficing – this is a behavioural theory of the firm which suggests that firms make just enough
profits in order to keep those with vested interests in the company both satisfied enough to keep
their interests in the firm and making sufficient profits to keep the firm in business, whilst also
satisfying the interests of the people that run the firm and perhaps don’t enjoy the full benefits of
maximising profits. It was a word made up by Herbert Simon4 based on the idea that profit is not a
goal but a constraint – a certain minimum level must be made and thereafter other goals can be
pursued. Humans are not very good at maximising, and instead need to meet some certain minimum
points. This ‘bounded rationality’ might well be the best explanation of behaviour by firms. But all
firms must make some degree of profit to survive, and the more competitive a market the more that
goal coincides with profit maximisation. Simon's conclusions do not negate all that we have
discussed about profit maximisation – rather they show that they might be an extreme case.
Do bigger firms do better? Although several well-known names have disappeared as a result of bankruptcy,
it seems that the really big firms were best placed to weather the recession. Big companies such as Lloyds
Banking Group, General Motors and Citigroup have soaked up the shocks in the economy even if some of
them have had to accept government bailouts. Like many trends, big is now in vogue, but it has not always
been so. In this article we review why in some industries some firms are better being large in size and in
other industries being small-sized is efficient.
In the mid-1990s, small firms came into fashion. For example, Yahoo – with the same market value as
Boeing – employed 637 people as opposed to Boeing’s quarter of a million employees.1 But now big is
back in vogue as it was in the 1960s and 1970s. It’s never completely clear why the fashions change – some
are logical reasons, and some are panic decisions or perceptions that sway shareholders or other
stakeholders. Some industries will always be dominated by large firms, some will always have many
competing small firms, and many swing between these two extremes as market conditions change. One of
the main reasons for growing big is that the cost per unit of production goes down as more is made, and a
main reason for not growing is that costs can start rising per unit if the firm gets too large. This rationale
for the changing level of long-run average costs is called economies and diseconomies of scale, but it is
only one of the many reasons why firms do better when they are large, while others benefit from staying
small.
A large firm can often work at a lower cost per unit of output than a small firm. It can hire specialised staff,
bulk-buy in raw materials at cheaper prices, and can make 24-hour-a-day use of its large-capacity
transporting systems. But a small firm can also be more cost-efficient than a larger one because it can fully
control itself, and knows itself well, routing out inefficiencies as they arise, while a large firm can have
pockets of expenditure that are well hidden. A small firm can respond quickly when the market changes
because the firm has short chains of management, and there may well be good knowledge of what is going
on within a small firm. The benefits of large scale production are known as economies of scale, and in
many large scale businesses you can see them in operation. The costs of growing too large are diseconomies
of scale, when costs per unit start to rise as output increases beyond a certain level. The point at which
economies of scale turn into diseconomies depends on the type of business, the state of technology and
many other factors. For some types of output economies of scale set in at low levels of output – for others
they don’t set in even when the whole market demand is saturated.
Technical economies
The high cost of some specialised equipment may mean that it must be used day and night, weekdays and
holidays, in order to make it a worthwhile investment. These also apply to storage, transportation and
distribution networks. If you double the dimensions in a lorry (height, width and length) it will carry eight
times the volume. It still needs just one driver and one tax disk, and the fuel bill will not increase in the
same proportion as the volume. These technical economies can be applied to many aspects of large firms,
and are of course much more significant in industries which involve high-bulk output.
Indivisibilities
Some machines are not worth buying for just a small output. For example arable farms in the American
mid-West can use combine harvesters to the full and they are worth the large-scale investment. The
counter-argument to this is that small firms are often better at working out cooperative schemes, and
resources can be used efficiently if information flows well and markets work efficiently.
Some economies of scale relate to all industries, whether or not they depend on capital equipment.
Bulk buying
Large firms can negotiate good deals on buying raw materials, distribution and marketing. It is often in the
interests of firms to control the distribution outlets, such as car showrooms, or when ‘exclusivity deals’ are
offered to shops. This anticompetitive behaviour can be illegal, but large firms often have so much to gain
in that the legal costs are small in comparison to the potential gains.
Financial economies
In May 2009, Lloyds Banking Group was able to raise £5.6 billion by offering to all its current shareholders
the chance to buy heavily-discounted new shares in a ‘rights issue’. The take-up rate was 87% and investors
effectively gave the large firm, struggling with the debt it had inherited when it bought out HBOS, a cheap
and sizable loan but smaller firms would crumple under the weight of debt that Lloyds had. Many large
firms can enjoy a wider source of finance, and at better rates. Small firms often have no choice other than
to borrow from banks at very high interest – that’s always assuming they can get a loan at all in the current
economic climate.
Marketing
Large firms can spread the costs of using celebrities and clever advertising companies. Once a firm is big it
can stay big at a relatively low cost per unit. Would a small firm ever be able to sell age protection cream
in a market that is now dominated by firms such as Boots’ ‘Perfect and Protect’ which has been developed
with years of expensive research and – according to ‘reliable’ sources – is the ‘only anti-ageing cream that
actually works’?3
Economies of scope
When a firm diversifies, or offers a wider product range, it is said to be diversifying. Trying out new products
can be very risky, and there are often heavy research and promotion costs. But the benefits might be great.
In a large firm it may be possible to take these risks without putting the whole firm in jeopardy, because
other established parts of the business can carry through the firm if things go wrong. So a large firm can
afford to rake risks, offer the consumer more choices, and adapt with the market rather than sticking to its
comfort zone. These are sometimes called ‘risk-bearing’ economies.
SRAC1
SRAC2 SRAC3
SRAC4
LRAC
0
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 Quantity
4. R. Cole, ‘Why does the supply curve slope upwards’, Economics Today, Vol. 16, No. 1, September 2008. (You can obtain back copies of Economics Today on CD Rom from the
www.economics.ac website.)
2. Can a firm have economies and diseconomies of scale at the same time? Would you have to assume
that some were internal and some external?
3. Why does the LRAC not join together the lowest points on all the SRACs in Figure 1? By taking the
tangential points it is not taking the lowest points. To answer this you might have to consider what
would happen in the short run if output increased from any one point where SRAC and LRAC meet
– would costs fall more quickly in the long run if a different level of output was chosen?
4. If economies of scale are the same concept as increasing returns to scale, but from the viewpoint of
costs rather than output, what is the equivalent short run concept of the law of increasing costs?
5. Economies of scale must be a good thing if they mean that we use less of the world’s resources to
get the same amount of output. But perhaps they mean that firms just produce more and more,
and although prices might fall, the things that are made are not really wanted. The late J.K. Galbraith
discussed this in The Affluent Society back in 1958. You could buy a copy and set up an Economics
society in school to discuss it, if you want something to put on your UCAS application form!
● Economies of scale – falling long run average costs of production as output increases.
● Diseconomies of scale – increasing long run average costs of production as output increases.
● Internal economies or diseconomies of scale – the concept of changing long run average costs
Key Terms
● External economies or diseconomies of scale – the concept of changing long run average costs
applied to a firm within the collection of firms, or industry, changes size.
● Increasing returns to scale – this is the same concept of economies of scale, but looking from
the perspective of getting more output from the same inputs. Thus if you double inputs you get
more than a doubling of output.
Efficiency means that the cost of producing a given output is as low as possible. There are two main types
of efficiency that economists are concerned about – productive and allocative efficiency. It is important to
know whether a firm is efficient for many reasons – if the government is regulating an industry it will want
to know if a firm can cut costs and if so it might set price caps. If potential investors are going to put money
into a firm then they will want to know if costs are being kept to a minimum. And perhaps most significant
are the workers – if they see that the firm is inefficient it might affect their own productivity. Efficiency is
crucial to the customers – higher costs usually mean higher prices, and this will also affect our international
competitiveness and therefore our balance of payments. These issues are best considered by looking at
some examples of firms in the UK today. There are other kinds of efficiency that you might have learnt
about – dynamic and x-inefficiency, and these will be considered at the end.
Productive efficiency
Firms usually want to cut costs, because if this is done while revenues stay the same, profits will increase.
This does not mean that all firms aim to be productively efficient – that is because demand by customers
and competition from other firms are often more important in determining total profits. However, in very
competitive markets firms have to be productively efficient or they will make a loss. The following case
studies show how some firms and industries have been increasing their productive efficiency.
Tickets
If you buy a ticket to go on an international flight and you request a piece of paper telling you that you
have a right to fly, the chances are that your ticket will be organised from Mumbai in India. Mumbai is
technologically very advanced, and there is a large pool of skilled operatives of the IT equipment required
to produce the ticket. This means that the firms can be much more effective at adjusting prices to get every
seat filled. It is certainly more efficient to run a plane with every seat filled, even if some pay a lot less than
others. When governments start to carbon tax planes per flight rather than per person on the flight, there
will be further incentive to use planes only when every seat is filled.
Airports
British Airports Authority (BAA), the owner of Heathrow, Gatwick and Stansted airports, was reported to
the Competition Commission by the OFT, which ordered the company to sell off Gatwick in 2008; as a
monopoly it was judged to be inefficient. BAA controlled 65% of the national market (in terms of the
percentage of passengers using British airports) and 90% of passengers going via London. But will the firm
be more efficient broken up? Heathrow is by far the most dominant airport in the UK market – and with
its new Terminal 5 (T5) it will always be the most attractive to passengers. Even separated it is unlikely that
Gatwick is able to draw customers from Heathrow. BAA can also subsidise the building of a new runway at
Shipping ports
A much more competitive market is the shipping ports (The Economist, 26 May 2006). It might seem that
ports are unable to compete directly as ports themselves can’t enter a new market. Unlike airports (heavily
regulated) and roads and railways (heavily subsidised), ports are run by the private sector. One way to
measure the efficiency is to measure productivity – how much output can be gained from a certain amount
of inputs. The cargo handled per square metre of quay space shows that Britain’s ports are the most
efficient in Europe, with Southampton docks handling over 1000 units of cargo per square metre compared
to less than 500 in Le Havre. Competition is one of the best ways to reduce x-inefficiency, the rise in
costs that firms experience when there is no direct competition or the government effectively removes the
competitive forces by offering subsidies. This is discussed at the end of this article.
Allocative efficiency
So far we have considered the concept of productive efficiency, cutting costs per unit of output, ignoring
the demand by the consumer. Now we turn to look at efficiency in terms of what is best to produce as a
whole. It’s no good making millions of an item if no one wants to buy them and they are going to sit unsold
in a warehouse for years. Output must be optimised in accordance to the amount people are prepared to
pay for the last unit produced, a concept we call allocative efficiency.
If goods and services in an economy are distributed so that no one can be made better off without
someone else being worse off, the market system is said to be allocatively (or Pareto) efficient.1 Another
way of explaining allocative efficiency is to say that the cost of producing the last item is exactly equal to
the benefit derived by the person prepared to pay for that unit, or marginal cost equals price. It may appear
to be a fairly abstract concept, but in practice it is clearly a good policy for government: which will make
people better off without any opportunity cost.
1. Vilfredo Pareto, (1909), Manual of Political Economy, English translation by A.S. Schwier, (1971), New York.
Reserved parking
In many school car parks you will see a bollard reserving a parking place for a visitor. If it’s just one-off
maybe you won’t mind, but if empty places are continually being held all day for an evening appointment,
surely you as an economist will be asking if there is a market solution? If markets were left to work
themselves to allocate resources then the result would be that the parking space would be used every
minute of the day, but the ‘law’ that the school can choose who parks there means that the allocation of
resources is very inefficient. Why not take action and ask your school finance officer to make people pay
for parking at your school? It would encourage some people to share lifts, and maybe others would come
by bike. And if you can to pay to book parking you would be more likely to find a place because the
evening visitors won’t be booked out for the whole day. The department might pay out of its budget, with
the result that there would be fewer resources for books and photocopies. But no, you may reply, this isn’t
fair. Only rich people can park, or the people at the top of the wage pile. The way round this is to give
everyone a proportion of parking permits for the term – this could even be done in a way so that the
‘deserving’ get more. If they want to park every day then they will have to buy some tokens – and the
people who would rather have the money could sell their tokens. This way the school isn’t extracting more
money but there will never be parking problems and the lower income people can gain at the cost of the
rich. So socialists can have a market solution too!
Waste collection
I know for sure that if I had to pay for every kilo of rubbish in my wheelie bin it would be almost empty
every week. But there often is no real incentive to recycle if there is no return to you, except the ‘feel-good
factor’. In the early days of bottled drinks there was a refund if you returned the bottle. The result was that
there were very few thrown away bottles. I remember picking up discarded bottles to take to a shop to
claim the cash deposit. So it is for all other recyclable rubbish: if we could get a financial return for the
efforts of recycling then we’re more likely to do it. When you save money in the bank you expect to get a
X-inefficiency
When firms don’t face any clear competition they are likely to become overweight in terms of costs. The
‘flab’ might be seen in the employees who are not adding as much to the business as they take in terms of
wages, or workers who are ‘clock watching’ and let hours drift by without adding to the bottom line that
is the profit. Two clear examples have been Marks and Spencer’s and Sainsbury’s, both of which have made
a recent comeback. Marks and Spencer arguably became complacent with its image in the 1990s of
respectability and fair quality, and was not prepared for the savage competition from low cost suppliers.
Sainsbury’s had become stale and ‘middle aged’, and has needed Jamie Oliver and several other marketing
tricks to renew its youthful image. Competition keeps a firm on its toes, makes it cut costs, and forces it to
adapt – or die.
Efficiency is a powerful concept that makes firms change; the consumer may not react immediately to
inefficiency, but ultimately in the market economy, consumer sovereignty can make firms fit and healthy.
Efficiency is at the heart of economics: it is about using resources to their full. Less input for more output
makes everyone better off in the end.
2. Perfect competition is the only market structure that is productively and allocatively efficient in the
long run. Does this mean it is the best market structure? Should governments aim to make all
industries perfectly competitive? What happens to research and development, investment and risk
taking when a market is fully competitive?
3. Email the financial controller or the chair of governors for your school with some suggestions about
Questions for Discussion
allocative efficiency. Here are some ideas, which I’ve asked the financial controller at my school – if
you get any replies at all I’d be interested to hear at coler@cheltladiescollege.org.
What has been the effect on paper use of charging each teacher and pupil for photocopying
take out?
Why don’t we have timer switches on lights in rooms where, for example, lessons never last more
the visit is an evening one. Would you consider sub-letting that parking space to make some
revenue, on the condition that the person who sublets it gets out by the required time?
4. How can you tell if a firm is allocatively efficient? The textbooks say that price equals the cost of
producing the last unit, P = MC. What signs of this can you see in the world in practice? Do you
think ‘green’ economists prefer productive or allocative efficiency?
5. Perfectly competitive firms are productively and allocatively efficient in the long run. But they
cannot achieve economies of scale, and small firms tend to duplicate the provision of resources. Do
you think perfect competition is quite as perfect as it sounds?
● Productive efficiency – when a firm operates at the lowest average cost. It is the lowest point on
the average cost curve. The amount of inputs relative to outputs is at a minimum.
● Allocative efficiency – when price is equal to the cost of producing the last unit. Or, resources are
allocated efficiently, and no one can be made better off without someone else being worse off.
Key Terms
● X-inefficiency – when there is no competition firms might become complacent and ineffectual in
cutting costs. A bit of wilderness treatment, being out there in the cold winds of competition might
well make them cut costs, take risks, and be innovative.
● Dynamic efficiency – efficiency in the above situations has only been considered in the static
sense – at this point in time, are costs at their lowest. Dynamic efficiency introduces the time
concept, that although a firm might be inefficient in the short run – maybe overspending on costs
– in time this might mean a larger market share and the chance to obtain economies of scale in the
long run.
How times change. Five or six years ago everyone was talking about cheap food. Now the big news is high
food prices, and other commodity prices too such as oil and metals. Prices of commodities tend to be very
variable, and especially so for agricultural products. Low prices can be just as damaging to various groups
as high prices are to others. Volatile prices tend to be damaging to exporting and importing countries, and
have implications for growth rates, investment, confidence, currencies as well as the more immediate
problems of poverty and cash crises on balance of payments. On average, primary products account for
about half of developing countries' export earnings, and many derive the bulk of their export earnings
from one or two commodities. There are good economic reasons for intervening to prevent wildly oscillating
prices, as predictability and stability is good for both consumer and producer. One method which has often
been used, for almost as long as economies have existed, is a buffer stock scheme.
200
Index Number
150
100
50
0
’86 ’87 ’88 ’89 ’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06 ’07 ’08 ’09 ’10
Source: http://www.indexmundi.com/commodities/?commodity=commodity-price-index&months=300
P2 c d
Ceiling
a b
P1 Floor price
f
Demand
Quantity
Now in another year when supplies of sugar are poor due to growing conditions there is a new equilibrium
at g. This is above the ‘ceiling’ intervention price and can be damaging to purchasers of the commodities,
and if it is a foodstuff there might be widespread problems if people cannot afford to eat properly. There
can be inflationary pressures across the economy, and export earnings might falter. So the scheme
operators decide to release some of their buffer stocks. The amount is distance c to d on the graph and
prices are now at a new equilibrium of P2 and supply has effectively shifted to the right causing a new
equilibrium at d.
When the intervention price is ‘too high’ at the bottom end of the price range
This means that the scheme enters the market too early, has to store too much commodity, and doesn’t
actually prevent any hardship of the producers. Why is it set too high? It is in the interests of suppliers
to get the highest price band possible, and if the scheme is set up by suppliers they tend to bias the
lower price limit upwards.
When the intervention price is too low at the top end of the price range
If the scheme has to sell when prices rise but there are inadequate stocks then the scheme will collapse
and prices will soar. This is likely to happen if there has been a series of poor harvests or yield of
commodities.
Adaptive expectations
If you are a producer and you know that the buffer stock scheme will buy anything you make at a
minimum price then you are likely to produce as much as you can. There is an incentive to produce more
and more, by using more fertilisers and pesticides and giving your crops a lot of attention. The result is
persistent surpluses; the scheme always has to buy and never to sell, so in the end it runs out of money.
Game theory
If you are part of a club that keeps prices high it is going to make you a large profit if you secretly over
produce and sell at the high price. Whatever the penalty for being caught as a cheat it’s unlikely to be as
large as the profits you can make. If everyone does this then production will be bulging out everywhere
and prices will collapse further than if perhaps there had been no organisation at all.
Time frame
The longer it takes for a price shock to revert to norm, the less likely it is that price stabilisation schemes
will be viable. Stocks will either become too abundant or disappear, depending on the type of shock.
20.0
US cents per pound (lb)
17.5
15.0
12.5
10.0
7.5
5.0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
In India the Ministry of Food in 2002 decided to create a buffer stock of two million tonnes
of sugar for a period of one year in order to mitigate the hardship of sugarcane growers. For
the last three sugar seasons, the industry had been carrying increasingly large stocks. The
carryover stocks from the 2001-02 sugar seasons were around 10 million tonnes. The
expected production in 2002 was around 17 million tonnes against domestic consumption
of around 18 million tonnes. Export demand for sugar was predicted to be around one
million tonnes. These forecasts meant that stocks of sugar would remain at around eight
million tonnes at the end of 2002.
(This data was found on the Department of Food and Public Distribution, Government of
India webpage in July 2002.)
By 2007 the price of sugar was soaring and the same webpage source explains the state of the sugar
market six years later.
The government in India announced release of three millions tonnes of sugar buffer stock
as from August 2008.
● Buffer stock – a store of a commodity which is used to keep prices stable. It can be sold as prices
start to rise, preventing further price rises. The stock is bought at low prices, which prevents further
price falls.
● Intervention price – the level at which the operators of the buffer stock scheme agree to enter
trading in the market with a floor and ceiling price.
● Hard commodity – a product which can be stored, such as oil or coal, and has usually been mined.
These commodities are easy to store and therefore a buffer stock system is feasible.
Key Terms
● Commodity – something which in supply has very low quality differences. There must be some
demand, but the demand does not distinguish between suppliers. Supply is often produced on a
large scale.
● Commodity market – where buyers and sellers of commodities trade. Because commodities are
fairly uniform there does not need to be inspection of the produce, and therefore trade is efficient,
large scale and often very sensitive to market changes. Commodity market prices are considered to
be a ‘leading’ or advance indicator of changes that are going to happen in the economy as a whole.
● Price volatility – the free market price tends to go up and down sharply, quickly, and over a wide
range. Primary products are the most susceptible to price volatility, owing to low levels of price
elasticity of demand and supply. Cobweb analysis helps explain price volatility.
Ask your parents or your grandparents how much a Mars Bar used to cost when they were young. 2p? 10p?
Compare it to the price today: the product is the same – or maybe even a little smaller – but the price in
pence is so much more. Now ask yourself whether the Mars Bar is really more expensive in terms of what
you are prepared to give up to get it. Does it feel more costly? The answer is that because everybody earns
a lot more and that all prices have gone up (on average) the real effect is very small or even unnoticeable.
Real values take into account the effects of inflation and the adjustment must be made before we can
make any observations about changes in an economy. That 2p that your grandma used to pay for her Mars
Bar would have been the same proportion of her pocket money as the current price is to you. And so long
as prices and incomes (and stored up income, that is, wealth) stay in line with each other, then inflation
does not seem to be a problem. First find out how much inflation there is, then accommodate to it. Thus,
some would argue, it is best to know what inflation is, and what causes it, and then live with it. Most would
say that high rates of inflation must be fought, but disagree about the degree to which it can be ignored.
For the lower your tolerance of inflation, the more you have to give up of other things in the economy,
such as jobs and cheap loans. The questions about inflation are: 1. How can we look at economics without
the distorting effect of inflation; 2. Why does inflation happen; 3. Does inflation matter; and 4. How low
should inflation be?
● Deflation – a general and sustained fall in prices, or a policy of reducing demand in an economy
as a means to reduce inflation.
● Real values – values with the effects of inflation removed.
● Consumer price index – the main tool used in the UK to measure the average price level. Increases
in this index are known as consumer price inflation.
Key Terms
● Retail price index – a measure of average prices in the UK, including the effects of mortgage
interest repayments, a significant component of the expenditure of 10 million households in the UK.
● Aggregate demand – the amount that will be spent in total at various price levels in an economy.
● Aggregate supply – the amount that firms are willing to supply at various price levels in an
economy.
● Wage-price spiral – the impact that increased wages has on prices which can further increase
wage pressures and therefore price pressures, ad infinitum.
● The monetarist view – changing money variables directly affects other monetary variables. For
example, the more money there is, the higher the prices will be if the amount of goods and services
remain the same.
One of the main reasons why the UK economy was so vulnerable to the 2008 credit crisis is that its
households had a very low savings ratio in the ‘noughties’ decade. For people in the UK and other rich
nations there has been a ‘trend to spend’, so when the crunch came, households were over-exposed
financially. In this article we are going to look at the impact of growth rates on the savings ratio and vice
versa, examine the size of the savings ratio over time, the multiplier, and how the current state of savings
ratios will affect you. The aim is to consider how these two macroeconomic variables, consumption and
saving, underlie much economic theory, without becoming wrapped up in Keynesian theories.
Consumption is a measure of current expenditure on goods and services. Saving is a measure of how
much is put aside for possible future expenditure on goods and services. The amount you spend relative to
how much you earn will vary at different stages in your life, and also in line with your confidence in the
economy. It will also depend on whether you think you’ll earn more or less money in the future and how
you think your career will progress. In the UK, household saving is clearly anti-cyclical – meaning that if
the economy is booming the percentage we save goes down. This doesn’t mean that the total amount we
save falls, but that as a percentage we spend more and save less. In a recession people start saving, which
helps restore balance in an economy that has been over-exposed to risk. But it is bad news if, like the
government, you want to see sales rising and the recovery get under way. But if households stop spending
too quickly this will cause other major problems in the economy. Spending keeps businesses in profit, and
therefore workers in their jobs. So there is a fine line between too high and too low a level of savings for
every economy, and this varies for different stages of the economic cycle.
12
10
-2
’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06 ’07 ’08 ’09
1.5
GDP growth, quarter on previous quarter, %
1.0
0.5
-0.5
-1.0
Six successive
falls in GDP
-1.5
-2.0
-2.5
’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06 ’07 ’08 ’09
Source: www.statistics.gov.uk
82 1450
79 1300
76 1250
73 1200
70 1150
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Source: www.nsandi.com
49.9
50 47.9
46.1 47.5
42.1
39.1 38.4 39.3
40 37.8 37.2 37.7 37.8 36.6 36.9 37.7
36.0
30
20
10
0
’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06 ’07
Source: http://docs.google.com/viewer?a=v&q=cache:NYzVzgj02gYJ:www.bnm.gov.my/files/publication/conf/hilec2009/01_
slides_zhou.pdf+statistics+savings+ratio+world&hl=en&gl=uk&sig=AHIEtbSNxYMbeSzH3rMdZnYOeva7_6z5QQ&pli=1
Why do Asian nations save more, on average, as the economy grows? One factor is a culturally cautious
outlook on life. Another is that as savings rise so do the benefits of saving, which in turn can fuel future
growth. Chinese people may have a longer view in their consumption requirements. China uses its savings
to buy much of the US debts (47% of GDP or over $7 trillion), putting China on a strong footing in
international negotiations on trade. And for China, exports are the main source of growth. In January 2010
it became the world’s biggest exporter by value. So although in the short term savings might dampen
Financial literacy
Perhaps one of the main reasons why people over-spend is that many are not financially literate. Companies
selling the finance might be said to have asymmetric information because they know more about what
they are selling than the buyer. We quite easily fall for what seems like cheap monthly payments not
realising what they add up to, and we quickly make assumptions. How many times have you fallen for the
slogan ‘0% finance’ or ‘pay nothing for six months’? Try the following question from a debt literacy quiz
conducted across the world in 2009.2
You owe £3,000 on your credit card. You pay a minimum payment of £30 each month. At an Annual
Percentage Rate of 12% (1% a month), how many years would it take to eliminate you credit card debt if
you made no additional new charges? (The answer is in the footnote)
• Less than 5 years?
• Between 5 and 10 years?
• Between 10 and 15 years?
• Never?
• Don’t know?
And here’s another one to try:
If interest rates are 20% how many years will it take to double a £100 debt? The answer is 3 years and ten
months (almost)3 but most people think it’s a lot longer.4
35%
Percentage of people surveyed
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
< 2 years < 5 years 5-10 years > 10 years Don’t Refuse
(correct) (widely know
wrong)
1. BBC World Service programme ‘Saving China’ 3 September, 2009. The programme is available to listen at: http://www.bbc.co.uk/worldservice/documentaries/2009/09/
090903_assignment_030909.shtml.
2. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/53/48/32023442.pdf. The correct answer is ‘never’. What is really scary, though, is that although 35% got the answer correct, one in five
admitted that they had no idea.
3. The formula is premium times interest rate to the power of the number of years (x). So it’s 100 x 1.2x then take logs of both sides so x log 1.2 = log 2, and divide both sides
by log 1.2. X is 3.801.
4. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/34/9/44280581.pdf OECD conference Brazil December 2009, result of independent research by phone of 1000 adults in 80 countries.
5. http://www.mckinsey.com/mgi/mginews/unleashing_ chinese_consumer.asp.
6. http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601101 &sid=agvBuODXiKKs.
25
% of average earnings
20
15
10
0
’78 ’80 ’82 ’84 ’86 ’88 ’90 ’92 ’94 ’96 ’98 ’00 ’02 ’04 ’06 ’08
Source: DWP
Consumption may fuel growth, but savings prevent us from long-term poverty. In the short term macro-
economists may like everyone to spend as much as possible to keep national income up, which will bring
short term benefits to income and wealth. Savings bring longer term prosperity to a country, but if they
grow too large they stifle the growth in the economy, reducing the size of the multiplier. The imbalances
caused by increased household debt have been highlighted as one other main cause of the credit crisis,
and this must be addressed if the future is going to avoid ‘the boom and bust’ extremes. One solution is
to start raising interest rates, which might slow the pace of the recovery but will stop households from
taking out even more debt. Household debt is becoming the trendy credit crisis now the banking system’s
credit crisis moves into history.
1. When household debt grows too large and there is a sudden cut in consumption, the effects can be
made less damaging to the economy by a cut in the interest rates by the MPC. Why do you think
interest rates were kept high in the 1990s in the Netherlands despite the sharp rise in household
Questions for Discussion
7. http://www.nsandi.com/pdf/QSS_Autumn09.pdf.
● Savings gap – the difference between actual savings and the amount of savings needed for wealth
to grow in line with incomes, estimated to be between £16.5bn and £66bn according to NIESR:
http://ner.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/191/1/79.
● Marginal propensity to consume – the amount of any extra income that is spent on goods and
services.
Key Terms
● Marginal propensity to save – the amount of any extra income that is put aside for future
purchases of goods and services.
● The multiplier – the magnified effects on income as money that is earned is re-spent in the
economy repeatedly through consumption within the economy.
● Anti-cyclical – when a variable moves inversely with the economic cycle. Savings as a ratio go up
when growth falls in western economies.
● Pension – a tax efficient source of post-retirement income, part of which the government provides
to people who have worked in the UK.
● Pension gap – the difference between actual pension outcomes and the amount of pensions
needed for post-retirement income to grow in line with incomes of people currently in work.
Economics is really a study of everyday life using common sense. Most people can have a good go at the
subject if they like thinking and keep up with the news. However there is one topic which the non-student
will get wrong every time, and sad to say, many A-level students get wrong too. Find someone who doesn’t
know much Economics and ask them this question:
“What happens to investment when the interest rate falls?”
I tried it on two non-students today at lunch and they both thought that investment would fall. The logic
in both cases went something like this:
If interest is the amount you get on your investment, then if interest rates go down you get
less for your investment, so people don’t want to invest so much.
This is completely the wrong answer. If interest rates fall, that is, the cost of borrowing money falls, then
people are more likely to invest because investment is an increase in the capital stock, an action which
either involves borrowing money or not spending money on something else (in which case the opportunity
cost is the money that would be gained if the money were saved). Investment can also be defined as an
increase in human capital, where resources are used to increase the skills and abilities of the current or
future workforce. You taking time to read this is an investment.
Jam tomorrow
Investment is generally seen to be a good thing in an economy. Likened to ‘jam tomorrow’, investment has
the promise of good things to come in the future, paid for by cutting back today.1 Investment brings good
things (jam) in the future because it means that the economy will be able to produce more output from the
same amount of inputs. We show this by shifting out the Production Possibility Frontier. It means that
the economy can make more of everything in the long run, when the economy can produce more without
anyone being made worse off.
1. The phrase ‘jam tomorrow’ is borrowed from Lewis Carroll’s Through the Looking Glass, written long ago in 1871, in which the White Queen offers Alice ‘jam tomorrow’ which
never comes because it’s always today. However, unlike the White Queen’s offer, the phrase is now taken to mean the promise of good times ahead in return for a little austerity
in the meantime.
1. What is the difference between saving and investment? Is there a causal relationship between the
two?
2. When interest rates fall, investment increases. Is this always true?
3. Investment is a component of aggregate demand but changes in aggregate demand also cause
changes in investment. This rather circular situation means that changes in investment cause
changes in investment – part of what’s known as the accelerator effect. Is this going to have the
same effect as the multiplier? Or does it have a different effect when investment starts to slow
down but spending is still rising?
● Circular flow of income – a model of the economy which shows spending and incomes, and the
interrelationship.
● Credit crunch – a sudden reduction in the ability to gain loans to finance borrowing, as lenders
lose their nerve in a tight money market. The effects of the tight borrowing make investment more
difficult and interest rates in commercial markets tend to rise.
● Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) – this is the international movement of funds that occurs when
multinational firms decide to increase their capital stock in another country or purchase a company
in another country.
● Hot money (or foreign portfolio investment) is the movement of funds from one country to
another, as speculators seek increased exchange rates, relatively high interest rates or an increase
in share prices.
● Human capital – the skills and abilities of the labour force.
● Injections – investment, government spending and exports: these cause money to enter the
circular flow.
● Leakages – savings, tax and imports: these cause money to leave the circular flow.
Key Terms
● Interest rate – the cost of borrowing money, or the return from saving. It can be seen as the price
of using money, and because the various uses have different levels of risk and time periods, the
prices vary. So there are many interest rates, but the most commonly used one in economics is the
rate set by the MPC.
● Investment – in economics, it is an increase in the capital stock, or build-up of assets. In
accountancy terms if stocks of goods are unsold from one year to another they appear as investment,
but their effects on the economy are to slow it down rather than the building up sense that the
economics investment implies.
● Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England (MPC) – a group of nine people which
meets at least once a month to set the rate at which banks borrow from the Bank of England in a
crisis (such as Northern Rock in the autumn of 2007).
● Federal Reserve (Fed) – the US decision maker of interest rates.
● European Central Bank – the euro-area decision makers of interest rates.
● Multiplier – the amount by which a change in an injection such as investment impacts upon
national income.
● Savings – the amount of income that is not immediately spent on consumer goods and services,
tax or imports.
On a train to London this morning I typed 1,000 words for this article, but on the way back I wrote just two
sentences. I put in the same number of hours and used the same laptop. But I can produce more with the
same amount of inputs in various contexts. In plain English, my productivity is much better in the morning.
When I have a week to write an article it takes me the whole week, but when I have just one day then the
result is always better. There is an optimum amount of hours and as the time allocation decreases, there
comes a point when the job can’t be done properly in the time available. Finding that point is a search for
increased productivity, or the most output relative to inputs. Economists study the efficient allocation of
scarce resources, so productivity is a basic concept. But what causes it, and what will be the effects of
increased productivity and is it something all should aim for?
Workforce motivation
There are two ways to consider motivation, just as there are two ways to spur a donkey to walk faster.
You can dangle a carrot on a string in front of its nose and it will walk forwards trying to eat it, or you
can beat it with a stick. On the carrot side with human beings, if workers are offered the prospect of
more pay or promotion they will want to work well, and are more likely to find ways to increase their own
productivity. If this motivation can be extended to the company as a whole, productivity can be improved.
When I worked in the headquarters of a FTSE 100 firm one summer what impressed me was the free
food, the gym and the onsite hairdresser. I was told by everyone that “they treat us well” and staff
turnover was very low. This means that new people do not have to be trained in new jobs, and time is
not wasted trying to appoint suitable people. Absenteeism was also relatively low and the company was
highly competitive.
Another way to get workers to do more is the stick approach, e.g. threaten them if they do not improve.
If workers are not punished for working slowly then there is no reason for them to go any faster than the
slowest worker. You will probably know of the type of job where you find yourself staring at the clock
waiting to get through the hours, and you will want to take breaks for as long as possible. About 100
years ago F.W. Taylor wrote about scientific management and that a manager must provide targets to
reach and all workers should be subject to ‘time and motion studies’.1 This in turn provided the basis for
1. Frederick W. Taylor, The Principles of Scientific Management, (New York: Harper Bros., 1911).
Competitive environment
If the government has implemented successful supply side policies such as deregulation there is likely to
be pressure in firms to cut costs and use better technology. If firms can enter and leave the industry
easily – that is, it is contestable – then firms are likely to be productive even if there are not many firms
actually producing.
Management
A well-organised firm divides its labour effectively and enjoys the benefits of specialisation, economies
of scale and derives the most that it can from its workforce. Good management uses the strengths of its
resources to the maximum.
The UK record
Why are cars and restaurant meals cheaper in the US than the UK? Part of the reason is the productivity,
with the US producing more than 30% more GDP per worker, as shown in Figure 1.
120
80
60
40
20
0
Japan UK = 100 Canada Germany Italy France G7 exc. UK US
Source: ONS
Since 1991 the UK has experienced faster productivity growth than all the other G7 countries. The UK GDP
per worker productivity grew by 39% between 1991 and 2007, compared to the G7 average (excluding the
UK) of 29%.2 UK productivity growth at over 3% a year over the last 16 years sounds impressive. This
compares with just over 2% for the other G7 countries. Don’t be too fooled by the statistics, however,
because a larger productivity growth might mean that the economy was very unproductive at the beginning.
10% of 10 is the same as 1% of 100 in absolute terms. Also remember that charts such as Figure 1 showing
UK = 100 does not mean that UK productivity isn’t changing! It grows but the UK is being used as the base
for comparison.
Arbitrary targets
Productivity is often measured using arbitrary targets. For example, in the NHS it is calculated using how
many people are treated, short term survival and health gains after treatment and by assessing patients’
experiences. Hospitals can improve their ‘performance’ by targeting these specific areas, while other
areas such as long term survival or minutes waiting in the emergency room might be the real issues.
2. http://www.anforme.co.uk/blog/?cat=273.
3. http://www.telegraph.co.uk/health/1576999/NHS-gets-more-money-but-productivity-falls.html, 30 January 2008.
4. http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/health/7610103.stm.
2. At my school we have new software which measures who writes the quickest and the longest
reports, how long everyone spends writing them, the number of mistakes and who starts earliest in
the morning or logs off latest at night. Are speed and quantity a good indicator that the teacher
has thought up useful things to say about the student? Is this a carrot or a stick approach to
management?
3. Mass production relies on productivity improvements, and the concept is fundamental to capitalism.
But productivity is also a core concept of central planning – if you cannot motivate people to work
harder in order to make more profit or higher wages, productivity targets is the obvious way to
motivate workers. Are there any other concepts that are common to the extreme forms of economic
belief?
4. Look at the views of productivity expressed in Extracts 1 and 2. What do you think has caused
productivity changes in the postal service?
● Production – total output, measured by total incomes, total spending or the total amount produced
in money terms. It differs from productivity in that there is no sense of inputs.
Key Terms
● Productivity gap – this is the difference between productivity changes in different countries.
Productivity in the UK measured as GDP per hour worked increased by 49% from 1991-2007 which
was the fastest growth rate of any G7 country over this period, and compared to the average
(excluding the UK) of 36% meaning the productivity gap compared to the rest of the G7 is widening.
This is good for UK competitiveness.
● Index numbers = 100 – often you will be given data on productivity, and for ease of comparison,
index numbers are used. These show percentage changes relative to a base year or base country.
The base or comparator is given the value 100, and a figure for 130, say, for the US means it is 30%
more productive, relative to its inputs.
Macroeconomics is the study of what goes on in the economy as a whole. Whereas in microeconomics we
look at what explains the demand, say, for individual goods, or the output of individual firms, it is the
demand and supply in aggregate that we study in macroeconomics. The word aggregate here has exactly
the same meaning as it does in football when the away and home scores are combined – putting the
respective components together for each team. In terms of demand and supply, the individual quantities
are added together against the average price level. We can derive one crucial diagram that can be used to
explain many concepts, for example, the impact on output and jobs as a whole of changes in prices, costs,
wages, exchange rates, interest rates, or government policy. This article explains the reasoning behind the
two curves.
Aggregate Demand
Aggregate Demand (AD) shows the total expenditure on goods and services in an economy at any price
level. Spending by consumers makes up about 60% of aggregate demand. We call this consumption, and
in the diagram below it is labelled C. The remainder comprises spending by firms on investment projects
(investment, I), the government’s annual outlay (government spending, G) – for instance on health,
education and defence; and the amount that people abroad spend on our domestic production (exports,
X). To calculate aggregate demand we subtract the value of imports (M). This is because spending by
anyone in the UK on goods and services from abroad is not a factor in terms of demand pressure for UK
resources. Instead, imports are taken into account when we look at shifts in aggregate supply, see below.
Putting together these components C + I + G + (X – M) we can draw an AD curve, Figure 1. What this shows
us is that when prices are high there is less demand, point A on the curve. When prices are lower, planned
expenditure is higher, point B. Few would disagree that the curve is downward sloping against the price
level.
Aggregate Demand = C + I + G + (X – M)
A common question at A level is “Why is the AD curve downward sloping?” The reasons for the downward
slope are open to debate. Here is a selection of reasons you might give:
AD
This shaded area will be constant for any point on the curve. We assume here that total real income is a
constant (that is, disregarding the effects of inflation) and any rectangle that is drawn under the curve
must have the same area, for example those drawn with dotted lines. Therefore the AD curve is a downward
sloping curve. Good point. This of course is true if you make a large amount of other factors constant – but
again the theory is not very useful as a tool for explaining macroeconomic changes.
1. The Latin phrase meaning other things are equal is a useful tool for isolating economic impacts. When it comes to evaluation in your argument you need to think of what would
happen when other things are not equal (ceteris non sunt paribus).
Aggregate Supply
Aggregate Supply (AS) shows the total amount that firms are willing to produce at any given price level in
the economy. According to many economists2 firms are willing to produce more if prices are in general
higher – this way there is more scope for making a profit, and less efficient firms can join with the very
efficient ones to increase supply (part A in Figure 3). Firms are willing and able to produce more as prices
rise.
This is only true up to a certain point, or so the theory goes. As the economy runs short of workers with
the right skills or land in the right places, so there will be less scope for profitable expansion as prices rise.
The squeeze on profits as costs go up are known as bottlenecks (point B) and make the AS curve get
steeper. As prices go up even further so the point will come when firms cannot produce any more and make
a profit on it as costs become prohibitive. This is known as full capacity in the economy and is shown by a
vertical AS curve (point C). Firms will not be able to produce any more, whatever the price they can
achieve. It’s the same concept as the production possibility frontier – the firms are producing at their
maximum potential and efficiency and there are no unemployed resources.
Not everyone agrees with this analysis – the so-called neo-classicists would argue that there can be no
genuine equilibrium unless the economy is at full capacity. For example, if there is wasted land where you
live, it will eventually get used by some business if the price is low enough. So, the argument continues, in
the long run, all factors of production will be used if the price falls, so the AS curve can only be drawn as
a vertical line – full capacity. In considering this counter-argument in your answers you will earn marks for
evaluation.
2. In the Keynesian school of thought, an economy can be in an equilibrium position even when it is not at full capacity – that is, there can be some unemployed resources and
no tendency for the economy to change. Neo classicists, by contrast believe that there can only be equilibrium when markets have ‘cleared’ – there cannot be unemployed
resources in the long term – instead, prices of these resources fall until they find employment.
AD
AS
Ye Yf Real National
Income
Ye is the point of equilibrium in Figure 4, but this is at a lower level of real national income than Yf which
represents the full employment level of national income which corresponds to the economy being on the
Production Possibility Frontier. Because Ye is less than Yf, this means that the economy has an output gap
which means that it is operating inside its PPF. Equilibrium will be disturbed when either the AD or the AS
curve shifts due to some sort of exogenous shock. For example, if government increases its spending it will
shift the AD curve out to the right and will cause equilibrium to shift to a higher level of real national
income. On the other hand, if a major component of firms’ costs suddenly rises, such as an increase in
National Insurance contributions, this may cause AS to fall (other things being equal) and a new equilibrium
will be achieved at a lower level of real national income.
Where do we go next?
Rises in the price level are known as inflation, and rises in national output are known as economic growth.
An understanding of what shifts either Aggregate Demand or Supply will furnish us with an explanation of
these important macroeconomic indicators. If AD is rising we could call it demand-pull inflation, and if AS
is decreasing (leftwards or upwards shift) we might say that it is cost-push inflation. Once we know the
causes of inflation it is much easier to cure it; similarly, if we know the causes of economic growth then
perhaps we can determine its pace! But a fuller investigation into what causes shifts in AD/AS curves will
have to be left to a further article.
Questions for Discussion
1. What are the factors that underlie the Aggregate Demand curve?
2. What arguments can you put forward for the AD curve being downward sloping?
3. How would you account for the vertical element in the AS curve?
4. How would the AD curve be affected if interest rates were lowered?
5. How would the AS curve be affected if there was a sudden increase in oil prices?
● Aggregate Supply – the amount that firms are wiling to supply at any given price within an
economy.
● Multiplier – the magnified impact of a change of injections on the total change in national income.
Key Terms
● Injections – Investment, Government Spending and Exports. These all push pressure into the
circular flow of income.
● Leakages – Savings, Taxation and Imports. These all take pressure from the circular flow of income.
● Keynesians – economists who believe that aggregate demand can be boosted in a recession to
stimulate aggregate demand, therefore preventing a very deep recession and high levels of
unemployment.
● Neo-classicals – people who believe that aggregate demand boosts will only lead to inflation in
the long run, and that an economy is best left to market forces to determine the long run equilibrium
level of prices and unemployment, i.e. laissez faire.
As a teacher I probably spend two hours a week by the photocopier. Sometimes queuing, maybe cursing
when it jams, but eventually after several attempts I get the machine to operate in a way that I can tolerate.
It’s not uncommon for my students to be given an apology with a photocopied handout – the holes in the
wrong place, the pages slightly out of order, or just a few copies having some pages missing where the
machine had overheated and malfunctioned. As I give out my sheets I tell the class that I just don’t have a
comparative advantage in photocopying. Actually I don’t have an absolute advantage either. In this article
I will explain my economic advantage in what seems like a failure scenario.
To understand the concepts of absolute and comparative advantage, it’s best to think in terms of costs.
How much does it cost the headteacher to employ me for the two hours of photocopying? Could she buy
that photocopying any more cheaply from someone else? It’s made simpler if you could imagine that
teachers are paid by the hour and produce a certain value in every hour that they teach, and that they also
produce value when photocopying but not as much per hour.
The headteacher at my school pays me around £30 an hour when I’m at work, which makes it expensive
photocopying – and that’s before all the damage I’ve done kicking the paper-feeder and the queue I’ve
caused by doing the job just before lessons start when everyone else also wants to photocopy. There’s a
willing junior secretary who will do the job, and she’ll take far less time, make fewer mistakes, and can
prevent the build-up of a queue by using the machine when all the teachers are in lessons. This is a clear
cut economic decision – the school will get more output from the same input by employing secretaries to
do all the photocopying.
If it is so clear cut, why doesn’t my school do it? There are three obvious reasons. First, when I get two
freed-up hours the school won’t save any money as I won’t accept a cut in my pay. Second, the secretaries
are always too busy. Third, I know exactly what I want photocopied and it will be quicker for me to do it
than explain to someone else how to do it. None of these are very good economic arguments. The first two
are shown to be flawed by using the theory of absolute advantage, and the third can be shown to be weak
by comparative advantage.
Absolute advantage
If my cost of producing an extra unit (that is, marginal cost) is less than the cost of someone else producing
that unit then I have an absolute advantage. If I can produce more value for the school by teaching more
lessons or helping students with problems I have an absolute advantage in teaching Economics. If the
secretary is the most efficient at photocopying then she has an absolute advantage in that. I should
specialise in teaching and the secretary in photocopying. Even if it means taking on more secretaries the
school will get better value from its resources if it uses this division of labour. In fact most schools do have
secretaries with time allotted for this as this is now required by national agreement.1
At this point most people writing about absolute advantage give some figures to prove the case. It is
important to have an analytical tool to use to describe what is going on, but I find it is best using pictures.
If you like you can use the numbers on these figures to extract cost ratios, but alternatively you can just
look at the slopes and see which is steeper relative to an axis, and which is further away from the origin.
The production possibility frontier (PPF) shows the most that can be produced if resources are used to the
full. If the resource here is time, I could spend an hour teaching (producing £30 in value) or an hour
photocopying (producing £20 in value). I will do a combination of both and because I can’t just do the
1. Raising Standards and Tackling Workload National Agreement between Government, employers and five teaching unions, January 2003.
20
10
10 20 30 Value of output
from photocopying
Given these facts, it is clear that for every hour worked there will be £30 worth of output from each worker
if we specialise. We can then ‘trade’ what we produce – actually the school does this, as schools are run a
little like a planned economy – but effectively I ‘buy’ the copying from the secretary and there is more
output at a lower price. The PPF can be seen to shift outwards in Figure 2 when people start specialising,
and then they ‘trade’, in line with their absolute advantage.
20
10
10 20 30 Value of output
from photocopying
So we are producing more value, and that’s even ignoring the fact that the amount we are paid is different.
Looking briefly at costs rather than output, say that the secretary costs £10 an hour and I cost £30, but
the secretary does it in less time. If I could be persuaded to teach more classes rather than photocopy the
school makes a net gain of £20. You don’t need a degree in management to see that employing more
secretaries is a good decision, even if the teachers get cross. The head teacher could even give the money
saved back to both types of staff – so everyone could gain.
The principle of absolute advantage demolishes the first two reasons for not getting the secretary to do
my photocopying. The school does save a lot of money although it might not be clear and it might take
time and angry unions to change the timetable. And if the secretaries are too busy then a school which
Comparative advantage
The comparative advantage argument is that even though I might be better at both activities, I am
relatively better at one rather than the other. I am able to produce much more value for the school by
teaching (£30 relative to the £10 which the secretary could earn as a teaching assistant). Let’s now assume
that the secretary can only produce £15’s worth of copying in an hour, and I can produce more than the
secretary per hour (£20) in terms of copying because I know what I’m doing and would take longer to
explain how to do it rather than do it myself. Here it is still better if I specialise and then trade, because I
can produce more value in each hour worked, and can buy in the copying at a lower cost.
20
10
10 20 30 Value of output
from photocopying
We can still produce a higher value of output between us if I stick at what I am best at, and the secretary
does what she’s best at. I have an absolute advantage in both activities – better money earned by teaching
than she could get and also I am better at doing my own photocopying because I am sure of what I’m
doing, even if I do get frustrated. However it would still be better for me to do an extra hour of teaching,
worth £30, with which I could ‘buy in’ photocopying as long as that didn’t cost more than £30. In Figure
3 I could get £30’s worth of photocopying if the secretary did it, rather than £20’s worth if I did it. Okay,
the secretary would take longer, but the total bill for her is less than £20. So the school has paid less and
got more out. I have got a comparative advantage in teaching and the secretary has a comparative
advantage in photocopying, even if I’m actually better at both. The secretary is relatively better at copying
than me, her opportunity cost is lower, and therefore by specialising and ‘trading’ we can get more output
from the same amount of inputs.
This can be shown by adding a new PPF in Figure 4 which shows the total amount that can now be
produced if there was specialisation and trade. More output from the same amount of inputs is the same
as saying there is a shift outward of the PPF. This is shown by the new PPF shown in orange. It’s a slightly
complicated issue in that in just one hour I can’t now gain the full £30 value of copying. But I could if more
secretary time were used, and that would still be profitable because the secretary is working for only £10
an hour but producing a value of output of £15. That is why the right-hand section of the PPF is shown as
a broken line.
This can be applied to workers, firms and whole countries. Yes there are some assumptions such as there
needs to be enough demand and there must be either constant or increasing returns to scale. Transport
and transaction costs of traded goods and services must be cheap and the exchange rate benefiting both
sides. We also ignore any external costs as production levels rise. But if you can ignore these things, you
10
10 20 30 Value of output
from photocopying
1. A doctor is earning £80 an hour in a clinic, but paperwork is taking up 10 hours a week and she
doesn’t get anything extra for that. Her managers have tried to persuade her to delegate paperwork
to a secretary but she insists she is the most efficient person to do her own paperwork. Imagine you
Questions for Discussion
are a management consultant brought in to help improve the productivity in the clinic and to make
the doctor delegate and morale improve to reduce staff turnover. What would you suggest?
2. How much should the secretary be paid in the photocopying example? Should the rewards from
specialisation be shared between the teacher and the secretary, or taken by the organisation that
governs the trade? In a free market would the gains from trade be split equally?
3. Rice is grown quite cheaply in Italy but much more cheaply in Vietnam. The UK buys a lot of rice
from Italy – why is that?
4. One of the main arguments in favour of globalisation is that more trade means everyone can be
better off with no one being worse off. However every year there are protests at any talks aimed at
increasing trade between countries. What is it about the terms of trade that might mean that not
all countries enjoy the benefits of comparative and absolute advantage?
● Absolute advantage – when an economic agent can produce more efficiently than another
economic agent, or uses fewer resources per unit of output, or has higher productivity.
Key Terms
● Comparative advantage – when an economic agent can produce relatively more efficiently than
another economic agent, or has a lower opportunity cost in the production when compared to
another economic agent.
● Law of comparative advantage – the principle that economic agents should specialise in the
activity in which they have a comparative advantage, meaning that there will be more output for
the same amount of inputs.
At around $1.50 to a pound, sterling hit a five-year low against the dollar. Only a few months previously
you could buy more than two dollars to a pound, which made going to America for the January 2009 sales
shopping very attractive. By contrast in 1985 a dollar cost you almost a whole pound. So the questions I
find myself asking are what causes these currency changes, what will be the effects on exports and
imports, and is a falling exchange rate a quick and easy way to get rid of problems of competitiveness?
There is much more to ask about exchange rates, but this article just aims to demystify a few starter
questions about the value of the pound.
When Mervyn King, the governor of the Bank of England, announced that yes, Britain was at the threshold
of a recession, the pound immediately fell in value.1 Why? The reason is that currency traders who are
holding pounds will sell if they suspect that interest rates will fall. Falling interest rates mean that they get
less return on their currency holdings, so they sell their pounds. More pounds relative to demand on the
market makes prices fall, and so the pound falls against the dollar. Strange really, when there were clearly
worries about the US economy. But confidence is a relative thing.
So what actually determines the value of one currency in terms of another? Clearly interest rates, confidence
and speculation are major factors, but there are basic economic forces influencing the currency movements,
which boil down to simple demand and supply.
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Source: DWP
1. Speech on 21 October 2008, one of only three that he gives annually on the state of the economy.
e1
P1
e2
P2
D1 (Exporters
demand £s)
D2
Q2 Q1 Quantity of pounds
Or an international casino?
However, only a small fraction – about 5% – of the pressure on exchange rates comes from trade in goods
and services. Speculation is a far bigger influence on exchange rates than the physical effects on trade of
exports and imports, and it is the buying and selling of currencies in the expectation that prices will change
in the near future which causes most currency movement. If people holding pounds for speculative
purposes think that the pound will fall then they will sell pounds, which is what has been happening
recently as the pound is falling against many currencies. This must mean that people do not want to hold
pounds, or at least that holding other currencies offers a greater return. The problem in countries such as
Hungary, South Korea and Argentina in Autumn 2008 was that so many people were convinced that the
credit crunch was going to make the currencies fall that they sold the currencies in enormous quantities,
and the increase in supply itself pushed the prices right down. As a currency trader you can make money
by selling a falling currency and buying it back when it’s cheaper, and buying one that’s about to rise. It’s
like a massive casino, as Keynes said – you can make money if you know what is going to happen.
Figure 3: The pound against the euro, since it was formed in 1999
1.70
1.65
1.60
1.55
1.50
1.45
1.40
1.35
1.30
1.25
1.20
1.15
1.10
1.05
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Source: http://www.taprofessional.de/charts/Pfund-Euro-Bar-Chart.htm
1. Textbook theory tells us that if interest rates fall then the pound will fall. The argument is based on
‘hot money’ leaving the country, the supply of pounds increasing and the price falling. Why then
do so many who struggle in A Level examinations feel tempted to argue that the pound will rise?
2. When should I buy my holiday money? Visit Google finance and find the trend for the pound
against the currency of the place you are visiting. (If you really could answer this question then I
Questions for Discussion
● Exchange rate index – a basket of exchange rates, weighted according to the amount of trade
that the countries do in these currency forms.
Key Terms
● Foreign exchange market – where buyers and sellers of currency come together and exchange.
This is most likely to happen online, but also happens when you go into a bank or other retail outlet
to get foreign currency.
● Speculation – the buying and selling of currencies in the expectation that prices will change in the
near future.
We have had the National Minimum Wage (NMW) since 1999 and have grown quite used to it. It seems
a good time to look at both its rationale and impact over more than a decade. Does it make people
better off or does it put workers out of jobs? Is it a way of ensuring that workers aren’t exploited or
does it just make UK firms uncompetitive? Would a regional minimum wage be more effective than a
national one?
Before looking at the numbers, a recap of some of the key data handling tools you will need. When looking
at income distribution, that is, the gap between the incomes of various groups within an economy
compared say, to the average, the most commonly used measure of averages is the median.1 Let us also
look at deciles. Keep everyone in the country lined up in your mind, in order of incomes. Now divide up the
people into 10% groups. There will be nine dividing lines between the ten groups and the middle one is
the median. These dividing lines are called deciles, and they are useful for making comparisons between
groups. Having discovered the median, we can now measure poverty. You might not think poverty exists
in the UK today, but it is alive and well. Not absolute poverty, earning less than a couple of pounds a day
– this measure is not very useful here. But poverty, as defined in relative terms, is earning 60% less than
median earnings or under.
Introduced on 1 April 1999 the NMW was introduced at 48% of the level of all employees’ median hourly
earnings. At £3.60 for those aged 22 years old+ it was targeted to impact upon almost 1.3 million people
who were then being paid below that rate, 5.6% of all workers. By 2008 the NMW was 52% of the level of
median earnings, meaning that it had increased its redistributive potential. The NMW has moved closer to
earnings levels in the lowest decile. This is below the relative poverty definition of 60% of median incomes,
so the NMS is targeted at the poor. But it has not brought earnings much closer to those in the top decile,
because top earnings have raced away. So it has been seen to redistribute incomes, but most significantly
in bringing the lowest paid into line with others in the lowest decile. When compared to the lowest decile
the NMW has increased from 87% in 1999 to 92%. When compared to the highest it has risen only 1% to
23%, meaning that a worker on the NMW earns 23% of someone earning in the lower end of the top 10%
income bracket.
There are still 1.1% of workers earning below the NMW, which includes people under 16 or people working
for themselves or informally, e.g. in the family. It includes people on apprenticeships or on a training
course, who are usually exempt. If you have a job such as being a caretaker then your free accommodation
can be offset against your wages so again you might legally work below the NMW.
In 2004 an NMW was introduced for 16-17 year olds. There are some other issues that this brings up. As a
teacher I of course think that 16-17 year olds would benefit from staying on at school but the NMW might
encourage them to think they could do better working. But it applies to weekend and holiday work too,
and can prevent younger workers from falling into unemployment traps. Most students of that age still
have to work to pay for the essentials in life such as phone credit, and they have very little wage negotiating
power because there aren’t many jobs going that can only be done outside lesson time, relative to the
supply of workers.
Raising the rate in Autumn 2009 by only 7p to £5.80 was the first time the rate was increased below the
rate of inflation (if you use the CPI measure). A recession changes the impact of the NMW, making it more
likely that people will be priced out of work, and it also changes people’s perception of the NMW.
Unemployment is a lagging indicator, so although the world recession may be over, the full effect of rising
1. If you lined up everyone in the country in order of how much they earn, and found the middle person, he or she would be the median. Median is really useful because it tells
us about how we are doing relative to other people, that is, relative incomes. If you took the mean, total income divided by the total number of workers, it would be too high,
because the mean gets dragged up by the very high salaries at the top end of the scale. The mode isn’t very useful as it doesn’t tell us about how well some people are doing
relative to others. It just tells us the most common.
Elasticities
The impact that the NMW has on employment and wage levels is dependent on many things, but one
major factor is the price elasticity of demand (PED) and price elasticity of supply (PES). If there is
no real alternative to a certain type of worker, then if the price of the worker goes up, the worker will still
be employed but other costs might have to be made elsewhere. We say that the price (or in this case,
‘wage’) elasticity of demand is low. This means that prices (wages) can rise but quantity doesn’t change
much. In jobs where PED is low, the NMW is likely to have little direct effect on employment levels, and
workers as a whole gain more revenue. The reverse is true if PED is high. If wages go up the employer will
look for alternatives, such as increased use of machinery. For example if a café owner has to pay higher
wages for the person cleaning the dishes, there will be a strong incentive to buy a bigger dishwashing
machine.
The application of elasticities also applies to the supply side. This means that workers respond differently
when the NMW changes. In many types of unskilled work, where virtually anyone could do the job, if there
is an increase in the wage the market may be flooded with people willing to put in some hours. But if it’s
a skilled job or not very pleasant working conditions, then an increase in NMW will not have an enormous
influence on the number of people willing to work. The effect on employment levels depends too on how
high the out-of-work benefits are. If benefits are very high and it is easy to live on benefits then an
increase in minimum wage will have little effect. But supply becomes more elastic or responsive when there
isn’t an easier alternative.
The usual question you will see on the NMW concerns the likely effect on employment or unemployment
levels. One of the clearest ways to illustrate the impact using the elasticity arguments is to use two NMW
diagrams, one with low elasticity and the other with high. See Figures 1 and 2.
One of the biggest problems for economics students in exams is in choosing to apply this concept to
employment or unemployment. It’s just two letters different but it can make the difference between an A
and an E in your grade. If you want to discuss employment you must identify the equilibrium point before
the NMW was imposed, point A in Figure 1 for example. Then you should show that employment falls to B
as demand contracts as wages rise. But if you want to show the effect on unemployment you also need to
take into account point C, which incorporates the extension in supply – the fact that more people are
willing to work when wages are higher. So the impact on unemployment, B to C, is much larger than the
impact on employment, A to B.
But there might be no effect on employment or unemployment if the NMW is imposed below the
equilibrium wage. See Figure 3. If the going wage for a good secretary in London is £15 an hour there will
be no direct effect on employment when the NMW rises. It won’t have an impact on poverty either, so a
secretary on this wage might not be able to cover daily living costs. It might be that there is an indirect
effect on people on higher wages, and therefore it will have an impact on employment, unemployment or
poverty, and this is when we start looking at differentials.
W b c
NMW NMW
We e
W b c
NMW NMW
We e
We e
W b c
NMW
NMW
0
B A C Quantity of Workers
Differentials
The gap between the wages of workers, that is, the differential, has an important economic function in the
economy. Sometimes there are problems caused by differentials, for example between people doing the
same or similar jobs, such as those employed directly and those employed by a temping agency, or between
men and women, full-timers and part-timers. Most of these differentials are illegal or in the process of
becoming illegal, and not central to the argument here. Let’s consider the paying of workers different
amounts for valid economic reasons. If I pay more for a good typist then he is more likely to stay working
for me, and there is an incentive for poor typists to improve so that they can earn more. If a good chef is
Not working?
Many argue that the NMW does not work, and it would not be improved by regionalising it. They want it
cut in real terms, to restore labour market flexibility, one of the competitive advantages of the UK economy.
The argument may say that the price floor must cause unemployment, but it is hidden from the figures as
people who are displaced from work may leave the job market. It might not relieve poverty if the worker is
the second earner in a household, or if there are other income streams that the worker might rely on. The
impact on costs ratchets up costs, and is a deterrent to foreign investors. It might not be the wage that is
the problem but the lack of jobs or the fact that people are moving in and out of worklessness. Another
problem is that it entices people into low-skilled jobs, such as minimum entry nursing,2 which will not
provide a career development and so these workers will eventually leave. Better for potential nurses to do
a degree in nursing. The starting wage is perhaps only £5,000 higher but the dividends will come in the
long run. The counter argument is that the minimum wage is good, but not yet enough to lift people out
of poverty or worklessness. While it can be shown that the national minimum wage might have little effect
on employment or unemployment, perhaps policies should be more clearly targeted on solving poverty
problems.
It’s a good thing to read biographies about people who have tried living on the NMW such as Fran Abrams’
Below the Breadline or Barbra Erhenreich’s Nickel and Dimed. There are many books like this, and TV
programmes too which suggest that even working full time the NMW won’t cover basic living costs in some
parts of the country. You will have your own opinion on the NMW, but you must be able to see the counter
arguments.
2. Nurses entering the profession with no qualifications do earn around £15,000, well in excess of the minimum wage, but it might be argued that this is still a wage floor, and it
is influenced by differentials from the NMW.
2. What would be the main problems of a regional minimum wage? Enforcement? Fairness? Employers
relocating? The ‘postcode lottery’ where people could earn very different wages across regional
borders? Having considered some of the costs, assess whether the benefits in terms of poverty and
employment might be outweighed by these costs.
3. Do you agree that the NMW should be increased more slowly in a recession? Might there be an
implementation lag – that is, by the time the new rates kick in the economic cycle will have moved
on?
4. Should the NMW be linked to average earnings or to the cost of living? If the former, remember
then there are problems when earnings are falling, and if it is average earnings which type of
average should be used? If linked to the cost of living then might there be regional issues, or
problems for some groups. For example if you’re a vegetarian you might have seen fresh vegetables
increase in price far more quickly than meat, and it seems unfair to base your cost of living on what
you never buy. Is there a better alternative?
5. Should out-of-work benefits be cut to increase the price elasticity of supply? What are the economic
arguments for raising benefits?
● National minimum wage – a price floor in the labour market, legally binding on employers, in all
areas of the country.
● Regional minimum wage – a price floor in the labour market, legally binding on employers, which
varies between geographical areas in the country. It might be linked to the cost of living.
● Elasticity of demand – the responsiveness of demand to a change in a factor such as price or
wages. Here we have been considering how firms change their demand for employees when there
is a legally imposed minimum wage.
● Elasticity of supply – the responsiveness of supply to a change in a factor such as price or wages.
Here we have been considering the way in which workers or non-workers react when there are
different wages on offer in the labour market.
● Decile – when data is presented in a serial order, a decile marks boundaries between 10% band
widths. Deciles are used for comparison between sets of data, and have the advantage that they
are not distortions on the extremes of a distribution.
Key Terms
● Income gap or Income inequality – a measure of the gap between the incomes of various groups
within an economy often shown by plotting the average incomes of those between the lowest and
highest decile (see www.statistics.gov.uk). The wage difference between these two tends to widen
in periods of economic growth, and can be altered by changes to taxes and benefits.
● Unemployment rate – the percentage of the workforce (that is, able and willing to work) that is
not currently employed.
● Unemployment traps – this occurs where it is not worth people starting work, owing to loss of
other income such as unemployment benefits.
● Cost of living – a measure of how much has to be spent to maintain living standards. It is usually
measured by comparing the prices of a selection of items known as the ‘basket of goods’, and
persistent increases in this cost is measured in an inflation index.
● Absolute poverty – a measure of those earning less than a certain nominated amount of income
over a certain time period, for example £2 a day.
● Relative poverty – a measure of poverty using the distribution of incomes of one group in relation
to another, e.g. earning 60% less than median earnings or under.
“With the FTSE Aim 100 having plummeted 64% in 2008 to 1852 – far worse than the FTSE 100 31%
tumble and the FTSE 250’s 40% crash – investors are hoping for a better year this year,”1 This might have
been a headline from any business newspaper in 2009. You can guess something dramatic was happening,
but the use of index numbers can make it quite hard to follow. The aim of this article is to help you feel
more confident in handling numbers-with-no-units, the strangely simple-looking index numbers, which
are perhaps even simpler than they appear to be.
Maths is what puts many people off economics. But the only maths you really have to understand fully at
A level is percentage change, and to be able to apply this to various contexts, one of which is index
numbers. Index numbers are used to collect data from various sources and give a special kind of average.
They are a simplifying device for showing changes and comparisons in data by showing percentage changes
relative to a chosen base year, which is normally given the value 100, but when more detailed changes are
wanted such as the stock market sometimes 1000 is the base. A base is simply a comparison year, and there
is some evaluation you might do about which date is chosen for a comparison, which we discuss at the end.
100
80
60
40
20
0
’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05 ’06 ’07 ’08 ’09 ’10
The index shown is an average of Halifax and Nationwide house price indices. House price projections are based on a range of forecasts from ‘Forecasts for the UK economy:
a comparison of independent forecasts’, October 2008 (compiled by HM Treasury). Source: http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/inflationreport/ir10nov1.ppt
Figure 1 is a simple use of an index. The base year has been chosen as the peak in UK house prices, and it
is therefore easy to see the falls since October 2007 in percentage terms. It is also useful in that you can
see when prices in 2009 fall to the level that they were in 2004. Rather than house prices in raw terms, it
is easy to see what has happened on average over a defined period of time.
Before going on to look at some of the problems of index numbers, we look at some of their other
applications, and then incorporate the concept of weights.
1. A. Monaghan, ‘The New Year brings a key resolution’, The Daily Telegraph, 5 January 2009.
Weighted indices
An index should be able to tell you how you have been affected by changes in the economy. Because of
this, it is a useful tool for policy makers to decide how much your allowance should rise if you are on
government income, for instance job seekers’ allowance, maternity benefits or pensions. But just knowing
how much prices have changed on their own is of little relevance. If you are a pensioner you are less likely
to be worried about the rising cost of school fees but rather more worried about the changing price of
heating fuel. If you are a parent claiming paternity or maternity benefits then the cost of nappies might be
more significant than that of a can of Red Bull. Whilst on income support the price of rent might be more
significant than that of bingo tax. The point of these examples is to illustrate that the cost of living index
should be related to what people actually buy, and in the proportion that they buy these things.
The way in which an index is related to the amount actually bought or traded is by using weights, to form
a trade weighted index. Clearly if the stock markets were not weighted then a spike in the price of a small
firm could make things look a lot more optimistic than they actually are. The change in share price must be
multiplied by the market capitalisation which shows how much the company is worth if you multiply price
per share with the number of shares issued. Then as with all weights, you divide out the weights at the end
so that the rather random total of the number of shares is removed, just their influence on prices remains.
80
60
40
20
0
1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
a = Cost of three minute telephone call from New York to London; b = Average ocean freight and port charges per short ton of import and export cargo; c = Average air transport
revenue per passenger mile. Data is measured relative to costs in 1990. Source: www.bbc.co.uk http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/shared/spl/hi/guides/457000/457022/html/nn3page1.stm
Here the base year for three types of cost is 1930 and changes are shown relative to this year. Clearly the
changes for satellite charges cannot be based on 1930 as the technology had not been developed then, so
there is another base used in 1970. The use of index numbers is a powerful and simple tool to show some
dramatic changes in the fall in transport and communication costs.
120
Index Numbers
110
Britain = 100
100
90
80
70
’90 ’91 ’92 ’93 ’94 ’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04 ’05
Source: ONS
A very common use for index numbers is to show changes between sets of data, for example by country,
removing the absolute values and just showing the relative changes. It’s a common trick by examiners,
trying to see whether you can understand that one set of data has been chosen as a base, given the value
Index numbers can actually cause more problems than they solve and you should be careful before handing
them to politicians. But as economists just remember that they are meant to be there to help!
● Index – a device for showing changes in trends, usually relative to a base year or a comparator
country.
● Weights – a system for attaching the significance or importance of one item relative to another.
For example a weight can show the proportion spent on certain goods and services in a chosen
basket or selection of items.
● Basket of goods – a selection of goods and services chosen to be a representative sample of what
people spend their money on.
● Market capitalisation – the value of a company when calculated as share price multiplied by
Key Terms
number of shares.
● FTSE 100 – the top 100 shares listed on the London Stock Exchange, when ranked by market
capitalisation.
● CPI – the Consumer Price Index, used as the main indicator of the average price level in the UK
since December 2003. More details and a comparison with other price indices can be found at
www.statistics.co.uk.
● Base year – a year chosen for comparison. It is usually chosen for being a ‘normal’ year and
therefore the percentage change since then will give a clear sense of change over time.
● Exchange rate index – a composite index of exchange rates in a basket of currencies, linked to
the amount traded.