MR1346 ch3 PDF
MR1346 ch3 PDF
MR1346 ch3 PDF
45
46 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
______________
1 We accept the core assumptions of the realist paradigm: states are unitary actors
operating in conditions of a lack of a sovereign power, relations within the interna-
tional system are inherently conflictual in that states hold different preferences about
the distribution of scarce resources, and outcomes of interstate bargaining over
resources reflect the threats and incentives that, in turn, are based on the existing
power structure. These core assumptions are widely shared among scholars of inter-
national relations. The assumption of rationality is not an essential one. Although we
accept the view that states attempt to act in a purposive fashion, it is the underlying
context—the international system—that socializes states into certain behavioral
patterns. Within the realist paradigm, the power transition theory is most relevant to
the problem of anticipating the rise of a peer competitor, as it deals specifically with
the circumstances under which a challenge to the hegemon might take place and the
path such a challenge might follow. The power transition theory focuses on a dyadic
interaction, in opposition to the “balance of power” theory, which focuses on the
systemic structure. Contrary to what some proponents of each theory advocate, we do
not see the two theories as contradictory; they simply aim to explain different
questions. Though we use insights from the power transition theory, we do so selec-
tively. We do not subscribe to the idea of inevitability of conflict, nor do we accept the
strictly economic formulation of national power that is common among the power
transition theorists. For a recent review of the power transition literature, see
Jonathan M. DiCicco and Jack S. Levy, “Power Shifts and Problem Shifts: The
Evolution of the Power Transition Research Program,” Journal of Conflict Resolution,
43:6 (December 1999), pp. 675–704. For the seminal works in the power transition
literature, see A.F.K. Organski, World Politics, New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1958; A.F.K.
Organski and Jacek Kugler, The War Ledger, Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1980; and Jacek Kugler and Douglas Lemke (eds.), Parity and War: Evaluations and
Extensions of “The War Ledger,” Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1996.
For a prospective look at the power transition theory as it applies to potential conflicts
in the 21st century, see Ronald L. Tammen, Jacek Kugler, Douglas Lemke, Allan C.
Stam III, Mark Abdollahian, Carole Alsharabati, Brian Efird, and A.F.K. Organski,
Power Transitions: Strategies for the 21st Century, New York and London: Chatham
House Publishers, 2000. For a rebuttal of the proposition that the balance of power
and power transition theories are contradictory, see Randall L. Schweller and William
C. Wohlforth, “Power Test: Evaluating Realism in Response to the End of the Cold
War,” Security Studies, 9:3 (Spring 2000), pp. 60–107.
2 It is a basic assumption here that the state will remain a fundamental building block
of human global relations for the foreseeable future, even as its roles and functions
change in accordance with technological advances and the accompanying social
changes. The phenomenon has evolved enormously over the past few centuries, from
the dynastic state of overlapping jurisdictions to the contemporary demarcated state,
and it will no doubt continue to evolve and adopt to the new circumstances of greater
interdependence and communication. The growth—over the course of the 20th
century—of international organizations and the emergence of norms that delegitimize
the use of force have provided new conflict-resolution mechanisms for states and,
arguably, have placed some constraints on the use of force. However, such long-term
The Role of the Hegemon 47
_____________________________________________________________
trends have not altered the fundamental state-centric power basis of international
politics, even though they may have curtailed the incidence of armed interstate
conflict. As long as power remains the currency of politics among states, international
conflict and militarized disputes will be a potential outgrowth of power relations. For
some critiques of the “end of the state” literature, see Linda Weiss, The Myth of the
Powerless State, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1998; Stephen D. Krasner,
Sovereignty: Organized Hypocrisy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1999;
and Guenther G. Schulze and Heinrich W. Ursprung, “Globalisation of the Economy
and the Nation State,” The World Economy, 22:3 (May 1999), pp. 295–352. For the
impact of norms on state behavior, see Andrew P. Cortell and James W. Davis, Jr.,
“How Do International Institutions Matter? The Domestic Impact of International
Rules and Norms,” International Studies Quarterly, 40:4 (December 1996), pp. 451–
478.
3 The case of the United States is unique in modern history in that, in the first half of
the 20th century, it was among the most powerful, if not the single most powerful,
country in the world but, until the end of World War II, was not the hegemon and did
not use the full extent of its power to advance its position in the power hierarchy of
states. An explanation of U.S. behavior within the conciliate strategy of the existing
hegemon is offered below.
4 This is shown empirically in Jacob Bercovitch and Gerald Schneider, “Who Mediates?
The Political Economy of International Conflict Management,” Journal of Peace
Research, 37:2 (2000), pp. 145–165.
48 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
______________
5 Stuart A. Bremer, “Dangerous Dyads: Conditions Affecting the Likelihood of
Interstate War: 1816–1965,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 36:2 (1992), pp. 309–341;
William Brian Moul, “Balances of Power and the Escalation to War of Serious Disputes
among the European Great Powers, 1815–1939: Some Evidence,” American Journal of
Political Science, 32:2 (May 1988), pp. 241–275. Though the above studies do not deal
with the patterns of conflict in the last thirty years, there is no reason to believe that
such a basic characteristic of international conflict has changed.
The Role of the Hegemon 49
______________
6 The behavior described here is based on the concept of general deterrence, defined
as an adversarial relationship between two states in which the leadership in one state
would consider resorting to force to change the status quo but is deterred from doing
so because the leadership in the other state, knowing that the opponent is willing to
use force, maintains force of its own and makes it clear that it will retaliate against the
opponent’s use of force that is contrary to its own interests. If a hegemon were to rely
on outright coercion to sustain its role within the international state system, such a
stance would be bound to be short-lived, since it would raise the levels of dissatisfac-
tion among the other major actors in the state system. Even in conditions of huge
power disparity between the hegemon and other main actors in the state system, the
hegemon’s position would be untenable if all the other major actors were to unite
against it. On general deterrence, see Patrick Morgan, Deterrence: A Conceptual
Analysis, 2nd ed., Beverly Hills: Sage, 1983, pp. 42–43.
50 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
______________
7 The idea of conflict imposition as a tool of state policy against a perceived rival builds
on Richardson’s seminal work on arms races: Lewis F. Richardson, Arms and
Insecurity, Pittsburgh: Boxwood, 1960. Kadera proposed the concept of conflictual
behavior as a policy tool and provided a formal proof of the link between a state’s
power level and its ability to direct conflict against perceived rivals. The concept of
conflict imposition, as used here, builds on Kadera’s work. Though similar to “cost
imposition,” the term “conflict imposition” is more nuanced in that it refers to a grow-
ing set of conflictual relations (which entail costs), though not necessarily militarized
relations. Kelly M. Kadera, “The Power-Conflict Story: A Synopsis,” Conflict
Management and Peace Science, 17:2 (Fall 1999), pp. 149–174.
8 The value of conflict imposition as a policy tool in preventing certain actions and the
importance of greater capabilities for this deterrent to be effective has been demon-
strated by looking at U.S. use of force since the 1950s; see James Meernik, “Force and
Influence in International Crises,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 17:1
(1999), pp. 103–131.
The Role of the Hegemon 51
Second, the assessment is made at both the regional and global lev-
els. In other words, the hegemon assesses the proto-peer’s projected
power level in the region where the proto-peer is located as well as in
the international state system. In cases of power preponderance and
projections of no global peer emerging within a generation, a proto-
peer may still be present at the regional level. Since the hegemon has
global commitments, it cannot commit all its power and resources to
one region. However, a proto-peer can concentrate almost all of its
resources in its own region. The assessment and projections need to
take this disparity into account. Similarly, the hegemon needs to as-
sess the proto-peer’s level of dissatisfaction with a regional status
quo as well as with the larger rules of the international state system.
In conditions where peers and proto-peers likely to be competitors
are clearly present, the hegemon’s assessment is even more compli-
cated, because it needs to take into account the attraction of the
proto-peer to other dissatisfied actors and how that may impinge on
the global position of the hegemon.
All the calculations and assessments made above are fraught with
deep uncertainty because of the long time frame involved.
Extrapolations on the basis of existing trends have little use beyond
the short term, since nonlinear evolution is more the rule than the
exception when it comes to long-term projections. However, fore-
casting nonlinear change with any kind of confidence remains vir-
tually impossible, because no technique has yet been developed that
would predict a nonlinear occurrence before the actual event. 9 Since
the correct strategy can be discerned only retrospectively, the
hegemon faces the decision on how much conflict imposition it
should include in its strategy toward a proto-peer, knowing that the
range of error is bound to be substantial and to grow larger as the
time frame lengthens. Moreover, the assessment is subject to error
along both the power growth and revisionist axes.
______________
9 Charles F. Doran, “Why Forecasts Fail: The Limits and Potential of Forecasting in
International Relations and Economics,” International Studies Review, 1:2 (1999), pp.
11–41.
The Role of the Hegemon 53
RANDMR1346-3.1
High
Compete
Hegemon’s perception of threat
Medium Constrain
Co-opt
Low
Conciliate
To pursue this strategy, the hegemon must assess the threat of the
proto-peer as low, based on a calculation that the proto-peer has low
revisionist tendencies and that such tendencies, even with a leap to
parity, will remain low. In fact, by choosing the strategy that is low in
conflict imposition, the hegemon is betting on the preservation of
the main elements of the rules even if the proto-peer were to over-
take the hegemon. There is also the expectation that if a proto-peer
The Role of the Hegemon 55
The higher the expected rate of power growth relative to the hege-
mon, the more conciliatory the strategy is likely to be. The higher
relative growth rate and expected power transition simply make the
cost calculations of potential competition with such a proto-peer
even less worthwhile. Conceivably, assuming a meteoric rise of a
proto-peer and that all the conditions necessary for the adoption of
the conciliate strategy are in place, the conflict-imposition content
would decline to virtually nil.
56 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
transition and retained for Britain many benefits of its earlier hege-
mony. Even today, the “special relationship” between the United
States and the United Kingdom reflects the earlier policy choice. A
contemporary example of the conciliate strategy might be the U.S.
policy toward the European Union, as the EU has similar interests in
upholding existing rules.
For this strategy to be pursued, the hegemon must assess the specific
proto-peer as a moderate threat, based on a calculation that it has
some revisionist tendencies but also that these tendencies could
change in response to threats and blandishments. The expectation is
that by the time the proto-peer attains parity with the hegemon, it
will subscribe to most of the rules. In other words, by choosing this
strategy, the hegemon is betting that the proto-peer’s revisionist ten-
dencies are not fundamental.
and lead at least to a higher level of conflict imposition within the co-
opt strategy or to a more punitive hedging strategy (the constrain
option). On the other hand, if such a proto-peer were to moderate its
revisionist inclinations and show greater acceptance of the rules,
then the hegemon’s assessment of the threat would decrease and
lead to a lower level of conflict imposition within the co-opt strategy.
If the proto-peer continued to accrue power at a fast rate and the
hegemon were convinced that it no longer retained any revisionist
tendencies because the co-opt strategy had worked, it might shift to
a conciliate strategy.
As for the range of conflict imposition within the co-opt strategy, the
primary determinants of its higher levels are the combination of the
projected rate of relative power growth and the extent of revisionist
tendencies. When both are on the high end of the spectrum (while
still fitting within the co-opt scale), then the co-opt strategy is likely
to have a high content of conflict imposition, bordering on the con-
strain strategy. When the two are related inversely to each other, that
is, either a moderate rate of power growth and more substantial
revisionist tendencies or a high rate of power growth and less pro-
nounced revisionist tendencies, then the strategy is likely to have a
The Role of the Hegemon 59
For this strategy to be pursued, the hegemon must assess the threat
of a specific proto-peer as high, based on a calculation that the
proto-peer has strong revisionist tendencies and that they cannot be
altered easily. The hegemon’s strategy focuses on constraining the
proto-peer, so that, finding its power aggregation rate decreased over
a prolonged period because of hegemon actions, it will shed some
revisionist aspirations (because they will seem increasingly distant or
unachievable) and reconcile itself to working within the hegemon’s
rules. The strategy entails mostly negatives because the hegemon
wants to throw up as many obstacles as possible to the proto-peer’s
power aggregation, since it sees the leap to peer status as leading to a
full challenge. In other words, by choosing this strategy, the hege-
mon is betting that the proto-peer potentially represents a funda-
mental threat and therefore wants to halt or at least slow its power
The Role of the Hegemon 61
The hegemon realizes that this hedging strategy may eventually shift
to an even more conflictual one, though it retains hopes that the
negative incentives may work. Thus, if the proto-peer continues to
accrue power faster than the hegemon and does so without moderat-
ing its revisionist tendencies (i.e., the constrain strategy fails), then
the hegemon’s assessment of the threat would grow and lead at least
to a higher level of conflict imposition within the constrain strategy
and perhaps even outright conflict (the compete strategy). On the
other hand, if the strategy shows signs of eliciting the desired
response, then the hegemon would decrease its assessment of the
threat and, to encourage the positive behavior, employ less conflict
imposition within the constrain strategy or shift to a lower conflict
imposition strategy (co-opt). Either way, this is a hedging strategy,
and it represents a temporary phase (though “temporary” may still
mean a decade or more).
The British policy toward Russia in the 1890s and into the early 20th
century (until 1905) provides an example of the constrain strategy.
Russian challenges to British colonial possessions, its alliance with
France, and the potential for its power to grow rapidly because of
The Role of the Hegemon 63
To pursue this strategy, the hegemon must assess the threat posed by
a specific proto-peer as high, based on a calculation that the proto-
peer has fundamental revisionist tendencies that are unlikely to be
moderated by measures short of threat of force. By choosing a strat-
egy high in conflict imposition, the hegemon is betting that the
proto-peer represents a fundamental challenge to the rules and is
willing to risk war to prevent it. The hegemon’s assessment is that if
the proto-peer were to overtake it, then the hegemon’s current form
of existence would be threatened. In other words, the hegemon
expects a national calamity if it were to be overtaken by the proto-
peer. The fundamental difference in interests leaves little room for
positive incentives, and the hegemon expects that armed conflict
would accompany any power transition. Rather than trying to chan-
nel the proto-peer’s evolution into a more hegemon-friendly path-
way, the hegemon emphasizes punishing the proto-peer and pre-
venting any relative power. Given the assessment that the proto-
peer has fundamental revisionist tendencies, the hegemon has little
hope that less conflictual strategies might moderate the proto-peer’s
views. Moreover, the decision to embark on a compete strategy has
long-term consequences. Once adopted, it is likely that domestic
64 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
Two issues regarding the compete strategy arise when the hegemon
has preponderant power. First, a proto-peer that has such funda-
mental revisionist tendencies is less likely to appear because of the
dominant role of the hegemon and its ability to isolate such a proto-
peer at an early stage. Open flouting of the rules when the hegemon
wields an enormous power advantage is not a rational way to aggre-
gate power. Even dissatisfied proto-peers are likely to mute their
revisionist tendencies, and they are bound to have some stake in the
existing system. Second, the hegemon is likely to have a propensity
to view revisionist aspirations with caution, thus tending to over-
The Role of the Hegemon 65
The U.S. policy toward the USSR between the late 1940s and late
1980s provides an example of the compete strategy (with the most
conflictual period in the 1950s and 1960s). The United States
assessed the Soviet challenge as fundamental in that imposition of
Soviet rules on the international system would have meant, at a
minimum, a very different United States, both internally as well as in
terms of U.S. relations with other countries. There is no contempo-
rary example of the compete strategy, and such a shift seems im-
plausible in the short term, although, in the long term, a U.S. shift
toward such a strategy is plausible.
PRINCIPAL RIVALRIES
Even when the hegemon tries to prevent the emergence of a peer by
using highly conflictual strategies, a peer may emerge anyway.
Alternatively, an exogenous shock might turn a benign and coopera-
tive peer into a competitor. A transformation of an existing competi-
tor into a peer, or the metamorphosis of an ally peer into a competi-
_____________________________________________________________
peer, making it similarly cautious. However, the consequences of the prospect theory
may not apply in the same fashion to the proto-peer and the hegemon. For example,
if the proto-peer perceives the risk of losing its relative power status, then it might
adopt an extremely risky behavior to deal with the hegemon. The case of Japanese
behavior in 1941 is a case in point. Although prospect theory is in direct challenge to
rational choice approaches, empirical tests have shown its robustness in a variety of
applications. See Paul A. Kowert and Margaret G. Hermann, “Who Takes Risks?
Daring and Caution in Foreign Policy Making,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41:5
(October 1997), pp. 611–637; Rose McDermott, Risk-Taking in International Politics:
Prospect Theory in American Foreign Policy, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan
Press, 1998; and Kurt Weyland, “Risk Taking in Latin American Economic
Restructuring: Lessons from Prospect Theory,” International Studies Quarterly, 40:2
(June 1996), pp. 185–208.
68 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
tor, does not necessarily mean armed conflict with the hegemon.
Though a war between such a peer competitor and the hegemon is
certainly possible and the relationship may have numerous crises,
the enormous costs of such a conflict and the potential catastrophic
result that the loser would suffer dampen the prospects of such a
war. Instead, a contentious rivalry may ensue.
______________
11 Paul F. Diehl (ed.), The Dynamics of Enduring Rivalries, Urbana: University of
Illinois Press, 1998.
12 Gary Goertz and Paul F. Diehl, “The Initiation and Termination of Enduring
Rivalries: The Impact of Political Shocks,” American Journal of Political Science, 39:1
(February 1995), pp. 30–52.
13 Paul R. Hensel, “An Evolutionary Approach to the Study of Interstate Rivalry,”
Conflict Management and Peace Science, 17:2 (Fall 1999), pp. 175–206.
14Thomas Gautschi, “History Effects in Social Dilemma Situations,” Rationality and
Society, 12:2 (May 2000), pp. 131–162. A psychological explanation of this pattern is
based on the decisionmakers’ use of established behavioral templates in interpreting
others’ actions. Valerie M. Hudson, “Cultural Expectations of One’s Own and Other
Nations’ Foreign Policy Action Templates,” Political Psychology, 20:4 (December
1999), pp. 767–801.
The Role of the Hegemon 69
______________
15 Russell J. Leng, “When Will They Ever Learn: Coercive Bargaining in Recurrent
Crises,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 27:3 (September 1983), pp. 379–419.
16This is a widely supported finding. Paul K. Huth, “Enduring Rivalries and Territorial
Disputes, 1950–1990,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 15:1 (1996), pp. 7–41.
17 William R. Thompson, “Principal Rivalries,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 39:2
(June 1995), pp. 195–223.
18Thompson has suggested a distinction into three main types: regional, global, and
regional-global. The categories suggested here are similar, though not the same as
Thompson’s categories. Regional rivalry falls outside the scope of our peer competitor
work.
70 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
Principal rivalries usually last for decades and generations, since they
pit states that are the most powerful and roughly comparable in
power against each other. Because they are powerful, the states
involved can draw on massive resources to fuel the rivalry. In an
overall sense, principal rivalries are enormously expensive, since
they entail war-like expenditures for decades. Global and global-
regional rivalries differ somewhat in their propensity for war. On the
basis of limited historical data, global rivalries tend to be relatively
pacific in that open warfare between the two rivals is not a given, and
war is often waged by their proxies and on the periphery of their
areas of control. Eventually, one side wins but not necessarily as a
result of a war between the two principals. Internal collapse or
downgrading of power of one of the principals, due to exhaustion,
and either a power transition to a new hegemon or a strengthening of
the old hegemon’s position, has been the primary way of ending a
global principal rivalry.19 In this sense, the outcome of the U.S.-
Soviet rivalry is typical. Global-regional rivalries are more war-
prone, if the limited historical data provide any indication of a larger
pattern. The rise of a European regional leader has led to a milita-
rized competition in almost every case during the past three cen-
turies.
______________
19Thompson, “Principal Rivalries,” p. 211.
The Role of the Hegemon 71
Whether or not the rivalry leads to armed conflict, the drawing of the
United States into a principal rivalry is something that the intelli-
gence community must anticipate at the earliest possible time, so as
to alert the national decisionmakers and allow them to take appro-
priate steps either to head off the rivalry or prepare for it. Thinking
about the emergence of a peer competitor boils down to the follow-
ing point: under current conditions of U.S. power predominance in
the world, the most important task is the early warning of an emerg-
ing principal rivalry. Unfortunately, identifying an evolving principal
rivalry before it starts is impossible with any certainty. One problem
is that the origins of the demand for positional goods—status—in the
international state system are murky and difficult to translate into
operational terms.21 Moreover, some proto-peers may have a deep
______________
20Kim and Morrow provide a formal proof of how risk-proneness and different eval-
uations of the meaning of a subregional conflict may lead to a major war. Woosang
Kim and James D. Morrow, “When Do Power Shifts Lead to War?” American Journal of
Political Science, 36:4 (November 1992), pp. 896–922.
21Higher status means higher costs, by way of increased expenditures on defense (to
uphold that status) and greater likelihood of using the military, yet the benefits of such
72 The Emergence of Peer Competitors: A Framework for Analysis
_____________________________________________________________
a status are not easily identifiable. Hans Kammler, “Not for Security Only: The
Demand for International Status and Defence Expenditure: An Introduction,” Defence
and Peace Economics, 8:1 (1997), pp. 1–18.
22Structural theories posit little choice for states and decisionmakers, treating a drift
toward confrontation among the major powers as a given and as inevitable. Such a
line of thought, dismissing choice and regime latitude in deciding to engage in
competition, is overly deterministic, and empirical evidence does not support it. The
realist paradigm is helpful in that it provides a way of thinking about the behavior of
states and how they advance their interests, but the prioritization of interests is inter-
nally determined. John A. Vasquez, The War Puzzle, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1993; Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and David Lalman, War and Reason:
Domestic and International Imperatives, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1992;
and Patrick James, “Structural Realism and the Causes of War,” Mershon International
Studies Review, 39 (1995), pp. 181–208.