Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

The Great Diverg

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 19

1

Making Sense of the Great Divergence. The Limits and Challenges of World History

Eric Vanhaute

Ghent University, History Department


Research Group Communities/Comparisons/Connections

Fellow Weatherhead Initiative on Global History 2014


Harvard University

eric.vanhaute@ugent.be
http://www.ccc.ugent.be/vanhaute

December 2014

Abstract

This essay reviews the impact of the Great Divergence debate on world-historical research,
in particular how it has sharpened the discussion regarding the potentials and limits of a
global perspective in social research. This paper covers four major arguments. One, the
Great Divergence, the single most important debate in recent World and Global History,
both enlarged and redirected the long standing convergence/divergence dispute in social
sciences. It unlocked new fields of research, introduced new approaches and created new
data and knowledge. Two, the dynamics within the Great Divergence debate push it to go
beyond its own terms and to transcend its own limits. Perspectives and methods tested
within the Great Divergence debate challenge more general interpretations of the history of
global capitalism. Three, global research on the processes of integration and hierarchy of
global capitalism needs to adopt a multilayered systems-perspective. Systems-analysis
incorporates comparisons and connections in an integrated, hierarchical frame, and it allows
for a combined structural, top-down (geometry) and agency-driven, bottom-up (frontier
processes) approach. I conclude with some epistemological reflections on the Great
Divergence debate as it stands now and the limits and challenges of a world-historical
perspective.

1. Explaining the Great Divergence: From the West to the East and Back
2. Understanding Convergence and Divergence
3. The Geometry and Frontiers of Historical Capitalism
4. Limits and Challenges: Can World History Survive Success?

1
2

1. Explaining the Great Divergence: From the West to the East and Back

World history took a different course after 1750. Great Britain and other
industrializing nations made the successful transition from an organic to a mineral-based,
fossil-fuel economy, releasing the Prometheus of technology-based and capital-intensive
growth (Landes, 1969; Wrigley, 1988). This pushed their productive and military strength to
unprecedented heights, resulting in an unparalleled, worldwide economic and geopolitical
dominance around 1900. This process has been coined in different iconic terms, including
The Rise of The West, The European Miracle, and the Great Divergence (McNeill, 1992
[1963]; Jones, 1981; Pomeranz, 2000). Soon after 1900, Max Weber wondered “to what
combination of circumstances the fact should be attributed that in Western civilization, and
in Western civilization only, cultural phenomena have appeared which (as we like to think)
lie in a line of development having universal significance and value.” Weber, 2003 [1930]:
13). For a long time, the Weberian research program was framed within Eurocentric
paradigms. Whether one researched the origins of the industrial take-off primarily in
Western European societies, like Max Weber or Karl Marx, or found it in the imperial space
that Great Britain commanded, like Eric Williams, almost all research started from and
circled back to Europe. The problem with his approach was that it left many hypotheses
regarding the technological, institutional, social, political or geographical conditions within
Great Britain, Europe or the West unchecked. It lacked a genuine comparative and systemic
framework that helps identify which conditions were, in retrospect, necessary or sufficient
to set Europe on its perceived industrial Sonderweg. Recently, new tendencies in Global and
World History have fundamentally altered the contours of and the dynamics within this
vibrant research field. In this context, a lot of scholars have re-oriented themselves, to use
the expression of the late Andre Gunder Frank. They started looking across the Eurasian
landmass in order to compare the European experience with that of China, East Asia or
Southern Asia. The whipping debate about the remarkable rise of global inequalities in the
last few centuries was, to a large extent, instigated by publications from the so-called
‘California school’. The authors included Andre Gunder Frank, Jack Goldstone, James Lee,
Kenneth Pomeranz, Roy Bin Wong, Robert Marks, and others. Although their views often
oppose, they generally agree on a rough comparability in economic performance between
China and Europe (or between the Yangzi Delta, its most developed region, and Britain and
Holland) until sometime in the 1700s. Some of these scholars have also argued that Western
Europe’s subsequent leadership owed much to its relations with areas outside Europe, which
provided far greater relief from the ecological pressures created by early modern growth
than East Asian cores could gain from their peripheries (Little, 2008). This intellectual return
to the East is primarily motivated by the observation that the scientific and economic
development of China in the centuries prior to the divergence makes it all the more puzzling
as to why industrialization and the subsequent rise to global power took place in the West.
The second trigger has been that since the late twentieth century, the economic and
geopolitical dominance of Europe or The West seems much less self-evident. The
subsequent economic growth-spurts of Japan, the Asian tigers and China, combined with the
latter’s growing geopolitical importance, begs the question of whether we are witnessing
‘The Rise of East Asia’ and to what extent this rise also implies the ‘Descent of the West’.
Perhaps it points to a ‘Great Convergence’, a catch-up process in economic and political
development between the two sides of the Eurasian landmass, or between The West and
The Rest?

2
3

This general research interest has mostly been framed in economic terms: What are
the causes of the wealth and poverty of nations? What induced the emergence of a new kind
of sustained and substantial accumulation of wealth and growth? Why did this create new
and unprecedented regional inequalities? In a recent overview of the debate, Peer Vries
examined a wide array of explanations proposed by economic growth theorists and
economic and global historians alike: natural resources, geography, labor, consumption,
capital accumulation, trade, conquest, institutions, legislation, culture and religion, state
actions, science and technology (Vries, 2013; see also Daly, 2015). He stresses that none of
the factors he studied can act as the one and only cause of the Great Divergence. There are
just too many different factors acting in conjunction in different ways over time: “The
Industrial Revolution and modern economic growth were neither foreseen, nor predicted or
planned. It would be a major error to look at pre-Great Divergence history as a race between
countries, which one would industrialize first.” (Vries, 2013: 55). Still, this begs the question:
What is the historical story behind this remarkable global transformation? Was the great
transformation mainly an internal European process with roots in its own history? Should
the causes be sought in global shifts? Did coincidence play a major role? Moving beyond the
discussions about the one and only ‘prime mover’, there is a growing opinion that the rise of
the West was a ‘contingent’ (conditional, not required) process, a process that was not
inevitable and could possibly not have happened. On the other hand, this change in the
course of world history was not just random, it could not have occurred just anywhere. It
was the result of a unique cumulative process, with roots inside and outside Europe.
Within a wide array of literature, three models of explanation can be discerned. The
first, and clearly the most longstanding tradition, has a distinctly Eurocentric character. It
chiefly evaluates the rise of Europe as a largely autonomous process, a result of internal
changes. Since the 1990s a new school points to Asia's age-old predominance and recognizes
many similarities between Western and Eastern societies until the nineteenth century. This
model seeks an explanation for the divergence in a non-predestined and even accidental
concurrence of circumstances. A third tradition distances itself both from the classic
Eurocentric and the (sometimes referred to as) Asia-centric explanations. It departs from an
increased interaction between the West and the East, from which European countries were
able to gain the most benefits after 1500. Thanks to several comparative advantages, this
increased interconnection enabled them to strengthen their position in the areas of trade,
knowledge and state power.
The founding literature about ‘The Miracle of The West’ sketches the rise of Europe
essentially as an internal process. As a consequence of key differences in social and cultural
life, Europe was able to break away from other regions in the world. Europe's position in the
global system changed dramatically between the fifteenth and the nineteenth centuries,
when it became the absolute dominant power in the new global system. This important
change is the result of a new internal dynamism within the European world, contrary to an
assumed stagnant Eastern society. This explanation model relies on Max Weber's research
program, which asserts that the West distinguishes itself via a steady and systematic
rationalization of thoughts, actions and institutions. The differences between Europe and the
non-West grew increasingly larger. Industrialization seems to flow automatically out of this
Western dynamism. This vision is shared by disciples of Max Weber (rational state), Adam
Smith (market economy) and Karl Marx (capitalist production relations) alike. For many who
adhere to the Weber premise, culture makes the difference: the development of new,

3
4

Western cultural patterns related to labor, discipline, freedom, knowledge, etc. The West
was the first area to develop modern, rational institutions: a modern state-system, a modern
bureaucracy, an efficient military apparatus while also promoting individual property rights,
and a more or less efficient and ‘free’ market economy. Within this framework, strong
arguments have been made for a range of prime movers, such as Europe’s extraordinary
drive for invention and innovation and openness to borrowing ideas from others (David
Landes, Carlo Cipolla); the fundamental shift in European values, such as the rise of
individualism (Allen MacFarlane) and the rise of bourgeois values (Deirdre McCloskey); the
unique set of institutions and property rules (Douglas North); and an unprecedented
marriage of science and technology (Joel Mokyr).
Within the last two decades, new and comparative datasets undermined the image of
Europe's gradual lead in the centuries before 1800. According to these comparisons, the
Asian continent created at least 60 percent of the world's wealth in the eighteenth century
while containing 66 percent of the world population. According to some estimations, the per
capita income in East Asia (without Japan) was comparable with that of Western Europe
around 1700. So the gigantic reversal of fortunes mainly occurred after 1800. Studies that
distance themselves from a Eurocentric approach perceive the world until the eighteenth
century as a place of major similarities. Due to China's dominant position in the early-
modern world economy, comparisons usually concentrate on Europe versus China. Just like
Western European countries, China developed productive arable farming and intensive
industrial and commercial systems. The organization of property rights and markets was not
inferior to Europe, nor was the political organization less developed. Like other commercial
societies in those days, growth was limited by the boundaries of organic agriculture systems.
Assuming what they call a reciprocal comparative perspective, these authors made the
compelling claim that it can no longer be taken for granted that centuries before the
Industrial Revolution, European states experienced exceptional economic, legal, institutional
and political frameworks, allowing for the formation, integration and operation of more
efficient markets. Some authors have further minimized Europe’s rise as a short-term
interlude within the long-term dominance of Asian civilizations, due to a combination of
sheer luck and downright violence (Andre Gunder Frank, John M. Hobson). Kenneth
Pomeranz (2000) made the most compelling case not to consider the European path as a
‘normal’ outcome of history. Commercial capitalism and the Industrial Revolution did not
arise as the result of a long, progressive process; they arose from necessity. Contrary to
China, which could profit from its large, united empire, the European continent gradually
stalled in an ecological bottleneck: scarcity of energy and scarcity of raw materials. The
responses to this bottleneck (coal and industrial technology; colonization) gave Europe a
considerable advantage afterwards: more efficient technical knowledge and a network of
colonies (an Atlantic trade system). Until the nineteenth century, models of social and
economic development in the main centers of development around the world remained
based on agrarian, organic-energy economies and they did not create huge regional
inequalities. Why one eventually triumphs over the other is not the result of providence; it is
a concurrence of circumstances in which coincidence plays a major role (Marks, 2006).
Recent publications have labeled the revisionist image of the world before 1800 - a
world of striking similarities - as too one-sided or even wrong (Vries, 2013). They do not
advocate a return to former Eurocentrism, but argue that major imbalances in economic and
political power were not coincidental; they sprang from a different social organization in the
West and East. In his recent book, Vries diverges both from neo-classical growth theories

4
5

and the revisionist writings of ‘the Californians’: ”Whatever the outcome of that debate, it
simply is a myth that the economic history of early modern Europe would be the history of
the rise of a Smithian market (…) Actually it goes for all major countries that ever took off.”
He adds: “The coming of modern economic growth was not a natural continuation of
previous economic history, be it on a different scale: it was quite unnatural. It was not
something that was bound to occur if only certain blockades would disappear.” The
revisionism of the Californian School is, in turn, “very salutary, but I think there are very
good reasons to claim that revisionism went too far.” Instead of a world of remarkable
similarities, Vries sees “a world of striking differences” (Vries, 2013: 47, 401, 433). The
question remains, to what extent Europe's changing global position can be explained from
an internal dynamism. Since the Late Middle Ages, contacts with the outside world changed
Europe's position on diverse levels. First, its own capitalistic trade system gradually
incorporated other parts of the world in such a way that the fruits of this system chiefly
served the core. Second, Europe created a unique knowledge system via accumulation,
imports and adaptation. This knowledge system was the breeding ground of industrial
acceleration in the nineteenth century. Third, Europe applied this knowledge and technology
to the development of strong state systems and of unseen military strength. The result was
near absolute political and military dominance in the nineteenth century. A wide set of
explanatory stories have aimed to understand Europe’s changing role within a global
perspective and have stressed different external key factors: geography and climate, making
Eurasia, and Europe in particular, the most favorably endowed regions in the world (Jared
Diamond, Eric L. Jones); interactions among societies in Eurasia, instigating Europe’s
recovery since the Late Middle Ages (William McNeill, Janet L. Abu-Lughod); European
imperialism enabling its states to dominate peoples and resources beyond their scores (e.g.
the use of African labor: Joseph E. Inikori; Eurasian invasion of flora and fauna: Alfred Crosby;
a globalizing Europe-centered division of labor: Immanuel Wallerstein). The Rise of the West
completely upset relations on a world scale. The convergence of internal societal
transformations and external expansion beyond its old borders propelled Europe from the
periphery to the center of global events. In the remainder of this essay, I will argue that the
Great Divergence debate both enlarged and redirected the long-standing
convergence/divergence dispute in social sciences (part 2) and that its dynamics push it to
go beyond its own terms and to transcend its own limits by rethinking the history of global
capitalism (part 3). I will conclude with two more general sets of epistemological reflections,
one on the Great Divergence debate as it stands now, the other on the challenges of today’s
World and Global History (part 4).

2. Understanding Convergence and Divergence

Researching the Great Divergence has triggered a wide array of research, including
different sets of data, different research strategies, different scopes, scales and units of
analysis. The central question is whether these units - regions, states or the world economy -
permit meaningful comparisons and to what extent the units of comparison are connected
within broader webs or systems of interaction. Using multiple spatial frameworks has tended
towards more narrative approaches, and trans-regional comparisons have retained spaces of
varying sizes and definitions alongside nations and global systems as units of analysis.
Regardless of how the Great Divergence debate fares in future research, it has influenced

5
6

and stimulated work on various other areas and periods. This impact is clear in the way it
avoids the sharp categorical distinctions central to other approaches within modernization
and globalization studies. It does not a priori deduce a place’s prospects from its location
within global networks, it suggests the possibility of multiple paths of development, it
stresses several continuous, rather than dichotomous, variables, and it makes global ties
influential, but not decisive by themselves. It stresses that regional units of various kinds and
sizes remain important to the story of global economic history (Pomeranz, 2013).
This tension between diverging scales of analysis, between comparison and
connection, prompts one of most fundamental debates within the field of World and Global
History. How can we understand processes of regional convergence/integration versus
divergence/hierarchy in the ‘modern world’ within a global framework? How do we relate
tensions of divergence within a context of increased connections? This debate goes to the
core of social sciences. Over the past two centuries, social sciences developed a dominant
view that the modern world shows a pattern of more or less linear development in which all
positive trends over time converge into a more homogenized world (Wallerstein, 2014). By
and large, left and right shared the same belief in the inevitability of progress and the linear
upward pattern of social processes. This ideology of ultimate, positive convergence of all
states and peoples reached an apotheosis in the three decades after the Second World War.
At the same time, a number of analysts began to contest this linear model, arguing that the
modern world was also one of heterogenization and polarization (Palat, 2014). When
analyzing the social world, the linear versus polarizing models of historical development
became a debate about whether the various zones or countries would converge to an
approximately equal standard of economic, political and cultural structures. A global
perspective shows that, despite the many ways in which there has been convergence, there
has been simultaneous and strong polarization. Much of this can only be observed if
different scales of analysis are interconnected, if regions are not analyzed as self-contained
units, and if the global is not seen as an undifferentiated macro process. The need for a
global and historical perspective instigated three, interrelated research strategies facilitating
multilayered and multifocal frames of analysis. The first compares individual cases in ‘a two
way mirror’, equating both sides of the comparison (reciprocal comparative analysis). The
second strategy analyzes the interactions and interconnections between societies or
systems, and how those patterns of contact shift (network analysis, translocal/transnational
analysis). The third takes human systems in which various societies and their mutual
contacts are given shape as the central unit of analysis. Examples include economic systems
(the current world-system), migration systems, ecological systems (climate, disease), and
cultural systems. Human societies are always linked together by several of these systems
and act in reaction to these systems (systems analysis).
The debate about the Great Divergence has yielded large-scale comparative studies
on differences in geography, ecology, population, resources, wages, institutions, state
building, and so on. Key issues in comparative history are the questions: What is
comparatively being measured and how? How does one avoid explanatory reductionism,
methodological nationalism and analytical synchronism? Scholars of the ‘Californian school’
have made a strong case for the method of reciprocal comparisons, precisely to avoid
approaching non-Western histories from the stylized facts of European history and to turn
away from pre-determined world views (Bin Wong, 1997; Pomeranz, 2000; Austin, 2007;
Parthasarathi, 2013). The method of reciprocal comparison can give historical research more
analytical rigor, by forcing researchers to formulate problems, ask questions, look for

6
7

answers and develop explanations in a more structured and systematical way. The questions
about methodology and sources remain intensively debated. Which units are fit for
comparison and why? Which assumptions and models underlie any comparison with a
global ambition? (De Vries, 2011). Moreover, historians making comparisons often face the
challenges of a lack of data and scholarly work to create comparable accounts from widely
differing sources, compiled under very different assumptions and purposes (Berg, 2013).
Some collaborative networks responded to this challenge by compiling large-scale sets of
quantitative-economic data over time and space, such as prices, wages, and estimates of
GDP (The Global Price and Income History Project; The Madison Project). However, GDP
estimates exceeding the nineteenth century are tentative at best, useless at worst (O’Brien
and Deng, 2015). Wage-based proxy for living standards remain perilous, since until deep in
the twentieth century outside Western Europe wage labor was a small minority and took
different positions in different societies. Still, if carefully contextualized in regional stories,
these data can serve in reciprocal comparative analyses. For example, recent historical
research on Asia has produced some partial and regionally-specific evidence to suggest that
standards of living in Western Europe and maritime provinces of China and South India may
not have differed perceptibly before the late eighteenth century (Li and Van Zanden, 2012).
Comparative research explicitly raises the question of spatial dimensions. By definition,
world-historical research challenges conventional chronological and geographical frames. It
stresses both areal integration and differentiation (Lewis, 2011). Much historical work
continues to be done at a local, regional or national level in order to achieve control over
information and sources. This tension can regenerate national frameworks and essentialize
features of a nation’s history. This is clear in some efforts to resurge institutions as main
drivers of unequal development. For Acemoglu and his associates, economic performance is
largely explained by a country’s institutions, and in many cases these stem from early
colonial choices. While settler colonies, for example, usually created a liberal property rights
regime that promoted growth, in other colonies Europeans reinforced or introduced
coercive institutions. This ‘reversal of fortunes’ argument posits a single critical intervention
and one dichotomous variable (good or bad property rights), ignoring any effects of
subsequent global connections (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2012).
A wide range of recent World History studies has favored a network perspective.
Moving away from comparative histories brings up a whole new set of questions and
subjects about connectedness, entanglement, reciprocity and circulation. New metaphors,
such as flows, networks, webs, chains and new epithets such as trans, inter, cum and meta
aim to translate the experience of border-crossing interconnections. This includes topics like
human and labor migration, chains and networks of commodities, and long-distance trade,
including methods of navigation, finance, tariffs and price movements, and price
convergence. This angle explicitly questions spatial frameworks, creates decentering
narratives, and gives agency to the parties involved. It can also favor horizontal stories of
entanglement, which risk leveling out history (De Vries, 2013). Connections of whatever kind
are created and redefined in a world that is not flat. Stratification and inequality define the
direction and the impact of networks. Societal relations configure the world on different
levels or scales. In order to understand how they influence each other, a global framework
has to integrate connections and networks within (overlapping) scales and (overarching)
systems. Over time, these societal systems have grown from small to large, from mini-
systems such as chiefdoms, meso-systems such as civilizations, to the world-system of today.

7
8

They have gotten larger, more complex, more hierarchical and more intertwined,
reconfiguring connections and networks time and again.
Over the last two decades, cross-regional comparative and interconnective research
has gained a wealth of new knowledge about the ‘birth of the modern world’. In order to
understand why processes resembled or differed, why interactions went one way and not
the other, one needs to understand the systemic logics that combine those patterns. A
systems perspective does not narrow the lens to the macro-boundaries, it aims to
understand how the different scales or frames of time and space within the system tie
together, forming a multitude of ‘worlds’. A 'world' is not a constant; it is bound by nested
human activity. It refers to social change that can only be understood in specific contexts of
space and time. For that reason, no single delineation can be absolute. On the contrary,
choosing a space and time perspective (where? when?) is linked to an intrinsic substantive
choice (which social change?). Consequently, a global or world perspective cannot apply
exclusive frameworks of space and time and cannot draw fixed boundaries. Neither do these
worlds consist of fixed scales; they overlap from small to large. Interactions between
external boundaries or internal scales create zones of contact and interaction that we call
frontiers. This is where different scales and social systems come together. Scales and contact
zones or frontiers are central concepts of analysis in contemporary world history and global
studies (Hall, 2000; Vanhaute, 2013; Cottyn, Vanhaute and Wang, 2015). Rather than
reducing an entity to the properties of its parts, a systems perspective focuses on the
arrangement of and relations between the parts that connect them into a whole, creating a
‘world’. Systems have a strong internal cohesion but are also open to, and interact with,
their external environments, resulting in continual evolution. World-systems are open
systems with operational closure, reproducing the very elements of which they are
composed (De Wachter and Saey, 2005: 165-166). From the moment these patterns of
reproduction have become irreversible (and the factors that can prevent its deployment
have become too weak or are no longer present), a system is functioning and has replaced
former systems. Systemic interactions between communities and societies are two-way,
necessary, structured, regularized and reproductive (Chase-Dunn et al 2014). ‘Worlds’ refer
to these nested interaction networks, whether these are spatially small or large. Until
recently, world-systems did not cover the entire surface of the planet. Only capitalism could
transform itself from ‘being a world’ to ‘the historical system of the world’. A comparative
world-systems perspective is a strategy for explaining social change that focuses on whole,
inter-polity systems rather than single societal units. The bulk of world-systems analysis has
been engaged with the so-called modern world-system, historical capitalism (Wallerstein,
2004). Historical capitalism combines a globalizing economic unity (based on extensive trade
and exchange relations and a hierarchical division of labor) with a multitude of political
entities (states, bound together in an inter-state system) and a multitude of cultures
(civilization traditions as world religions and state-bound, group-bound, class-bound and
gender-bound identities, tied together by a universalistic geo-culture). Research into
systemic processes of convergence and divergence should be based on three basic and
interrelated questions. One: What makes the system? What are the factors of internal
coherence and integration? Two: How does the system reproduce internal hierarchies and
stratifications? Three: Where are the boundaries of the system? What makes its frontiers? A
research strategy of incorporating comparisons turns away from the search for invariant
hypotheses based on more or less uniform cases. Its goal is to give substance to historical

8
9

processes through comparisons of its parts, conceptualizing variations across time and space
(McMichael, 1990; Chase-Dunn and Hall, 1997).

3. The Geometry and the Frontiers of Historical Capitalism

The Great Divergence is part and parcel of the chronology and geometry of historical
capitalism. Capitalism, as a social system, developed as a complex of stratified time,
stratified space and stratified social power relations. There is a persistent perception, in both
scholarly communities and popular opinion, that the recent rise to power of an array of non-
traditionally powerful countries is inverting an age-old trend of global divergence. This
rhetoric of globalization and global convergence by and large obscures long-term global
stratification, the reproduction of hierarchies in global power relations, together with the
emergence of new inequalities (Cox, 2012; Flemes, 2013; Jacobs, 2014). A structural-
historical view contends that the processes associated with globalization tend to reproduce
stratification and hierarchy in the capitalist system and that ‘globalization’ as a concept
mainly serves to legitimize neoliberal ‘modernization’ (Arrighi, Silver and Brewer, 2003;
Sharma, 2008; Korzeniewicz and Albrecht, 2012; Vanhaute, 2014). A global and historical
systems-analysis reveals the insistent multi-dimensional nature of global capitalism. Cycles
of global expansion contributed to the political upward mobility of a limited number of non-
core countries, while states in the core remained politically and economically dominant
(Clark, 2010; 2000; Kick and Davis, 2001). A considerable body of academic research
confirms that the stratified structure of the world-system has remained remarkably stable
over time, despite (varying levels of) upward and downward mobility (Kentor, 2000;
Babones, 2005; Mahutga, 2006). The processes associated with global growth do not benefit
all countries equally. They contribute to the reproduction of hierarchy and stratification in
the system.
In order to untie global processes of divergence and convergence, we need to map
and understand the interaction between short-term fluctuations and long-term change in
global capitalism. A dominant focus on ‘massive and large-scale change’ in the short-term
still leads to a large body of scholarly research that disregards long-term continuity and
stratification in the global system of power relations. Structural stratification remains one of
the - if not the - most defining features of the global system of power relations today (Arrighi
and Drangel, 1986; Chase-Dunn and Lerro, 2014). The work of the Italian-American political
economist and sociologist Giovanni Arrighi is a challenging attempt to reconcile the political
economy of capitalism with the call of global history to understand convergence and
divergence, integration and hierarchy beyond established core-periphery relations (Arrighi,
1994; Arrighi, 2007; Abbeloos and Vanhaute, 2011). His work shows in a comparative,
incorporated and historical way how modes of production, circulation, consumption, and
distribution are organized, and how they created and transformed modes of reproduction.
Since this perspective has no meaning outside the system-bound world-historical
coordinates, it rejects both abstract localism and abstract globalism (McMichael, 2013: 12).
Internal logics and transformations are formative to the system as a whole: “The
globalization of historical capitalism must instead be represented as involving fundamental
structural transformations of the spatial networks in which the system of accumulation has
been embedded.” (Arrighi, 2004: 538).

9
10

Since historical capitalism goes through cyclical phases of expansion and contraction,
it continuously creates and recreates zones of contact or frontier zones. It is frontier-making
through the recurrent waves of geographical expansion and socio-ecological incorporation of
nature, land and labor. This coercion to put human and extra-human natures into the service
of capital accumulation has gradually extended the zones of appropriation. These zones
produce 'cheap natures' in the form of labor, food, energy, and raw materials in order to
encounter capital’s rising costs of production (Moore, 2011; 2014; Hall, 2012). Capitalist
incorporation and expansion had been fuelled by the opening of the ‘Great Frontier’, a
metaphor for an interconnected set of shifting frontiers. Frontier expansion provided an
astounding wealth of nature that reduced production costs and increased profitability for
centuries to come. For example, each successive food regime “has particular conditions for
cheap food, and each relatively stable set of relationships are expressed in a world price
governing production, circulation and consumption of food (…). The food regime is premised
on forms of enclosure across tie and space. This dimension is critical because enclosure
alters ecological relations: substituting world-extractive for local-extractive processes,
thereby foreclosing local futures for a capitalist future driven by variable and unstable
market, rather than socio-ecological needs” (McMichael, 2013: 9). Frontiers generate
shifting sets of ‘localized’ activities to secure access to labor and land for ‘globalized’
commodity production (primarily agricultural, forest and mining goods). The sites where this
happens become frontier zones. Frontiers connect the expansion of global commodity
chains with the creation of unequal geographical and social spaces. As Beckert states in his
fascinating story about global cotton: “The geographical rearrangement of economic
relations is not just a noteworthy element of capitalism or an interesting aspect of its
history; rather the shifting recombination of various systems of labor, and various
compositions of capital and polities is the very essence of capitalism. (…) These frontiers of
capitalism are often to be found in the world’s countryside, and the journey through the
empire of cotton reveals that the global countryside should be at the center of our thinking
about the origins of the modern world” (Beckert, 2014: 440-441). Frontier expansion has
often been associated with problems of social, economic and ecological sustainability. This
results in the apparent need for these frontiers to be continually shifting towards new areas.
Frontiers embody historical processes of both incorporation and differentiation that create
and reorganize spatial settings. Frontier zones do not vanish after incorporation; they are
permanently replicated by converging and dialectical processes of homogenization (the
reduction of frontiers) and heterogenization (the creation of new frontiers) (Vanhaute, 2013;
Cottyn, Vanhaute and Wang, 2015). Analytically, a frontier perspective can grasp the
imbalances of incorporation processes, emphasizing the role of the margins and friction
zones. Due to the incomplete nature of incorporation, frontier zones are the prime locus of
negotiation processes about socio-economic commodification and socio-cultural
assimilation. This frontier-focus requires research into similarities and differences, into
connections and systemic changes. Frontiers determine exclusion and inclusion; they
enforce new rules while giving space for resistance. Frontier zones have been the locus of
both confrontation (war, resistance, lawsuits, intolerance, plunder, extraction, sabotage,
ecological degradation, segregation) and cooperation (biological symbiosis, marriage,
economic partnership, political bonds and treaties, celebration, conversion, gifts). Constant
renegotiation forms a fundamental process in the shaping of ongoing, accelerating,
retreating or stagnant incorporation processes. ‘Peripheral’ agents, such as peasant and
indigenous movements, act within these ‘fault lines’. Frontier processes create concrete

10
11

spatial settings, structured by asymmetrical power relations (Sassen, 2013). It is not the
finiteness of frontier processes, the prevailing idea of a homogenizing world (convergence),
but their permanence, the constant reproduction of instances of heterogenization
(divergence) that must be questioned in world history.

4. Limits and Challenges: Can World History survive Success?

Up to now this paper has addressed three major arguments. One: the Great
Divergence, the single most important debate in recent World and Global History, both
enlarged and redirected the long standing convergence/divergence dispute in social
sciences. It unlocked new fields of research, introduced new approaches and created new
data and knowledge. Two: the dynamics within the Great Divergence debate push it to go
beyond its own terms and to transcend its own limits. Perspectives and methods tested
within the Great Divergence debate challenge more general interpretations of the history of
global capitalism. Three: global research into the processes of integration and hierarchy of
global capitalism need to adopt a multilayered systems-perspective. Systems-analysis
incorporates comparisons and connections in an integrated, hierarchical frame, and it allows
for a combined, structural, top-down (geometry) and agency-driven, bottom-up (frontier
processes) approach. I will conclude with two more general sets of epistemological
reflections, one on the Great Divergence debate as it stands now, the other on applying a
global focus in social research.
The Great Divergence debate has sharpened the discussions on the potentials and
limits of a global or world-historical perspective. It has opened up fixed narratives that
universalize particular, space-time bound experiences. On the other hand, it risks recreating
new, fixed histories embedded in regional specificities. The only way to avoid new, fixed
master-narratives or re-emerging essentialist regional/national stories is to continuously
query new knowledge with comparative, interconnected and systemic research. In this
perspective, the Great Divergence debate has compelled us to rethink some fundamentals of
historical research. It shows how a change of perspective can change the whole story.
1. World historians are forced to invent and reinvent geographical schemes, to
question the limitations of regional frames, and to debate how to connect and integrate the
various spatial scales. Regions in a world-historical perspective are not a given; that is why
they lack a spatial precision as countries. They are also multidimensional and overlapping,
from the big Afro-Eurasian ecumene, maritime regions, border areas and rim zones, to small-
scale social agro-systems. Within a given region, people share clusters of traits or
connections that are different from those that they have with people beyond that region.
Interacting regional histories make the world economy; a developing world economy also re-
makes regions.
2. Capitalism is not an invention of eighteenth century England; it has its origins on a
world scale from its start in the long sixteenth century (recalling Marx's famous quote that
“world market and world trade date from the sixteenth century and from then on the
modern history of capital starts to unfold”) (Palat, 2014). This change in the time/space
perspective makes it clear that historical capitalism is something completely different from
the expansion of a free, Smithean market economy. It developed, using Braudel’s phrase, as
an anti-market where exceptional profits are reaped and monopolies are safeguarded; it
makes use of the relentless competition between states. Still, the image of ‘striking

11
12

similarities’ in the Great Divergence debate departs from the (mostly intrinsic) idea that
agrarian market economies all over the world have the intrinsic potential to develop into
capitalist growth centers. Capitalism develops where new, transnational commercial-
financial elites ally themselves with assertive, mercantilist states. The commercial-agrarian
empires in the eastern part of the Eurasian continent were not built on such alliances
between capitalist and political elites. The new world-system, dominated by a European
center, disturbed the existing balances of power at the expense of former regional empires.
As Ravi Palat stated, "Economic agencies in Europe operated on an ever increasing scale in
contrast to those in societies based on wet-rice cultivation where the size of economic
agencies tended to become smaller and more specialized over time. This was the crucial
difference between interstate systems in Europe and Asia: the former was predicated on
capital accumulation, the latter was not. Moreover, the expansion of trade networks
generated by the intensification of rice cultivation and the spread of craft production also
led to dense networks of trade. The very density of trade networks meant that no single
person or agency could monopolize lucrative lines for any substantial length of time" (Palat,
2010: 263; Palat, 2013).
3. Most participants in the Great Divergence debate probably agree that its roots
need to be explored in all their complexity, in order to cover the enormous range of
transformations and innovations that arose with the emergence of modern economic
growth. Despite the call for more holistic methods of analysis, interpretation schemes in the
Great Divergence debate tend to remain monocausal; they still focus on the 'why not'
question (Daly, 2015). For example, China’s ‘failure' to precipitate the world’s first scientific
or industrial revolution has been explained in a variety of ways: political centralization, the
stifling cultural hegemony of the elites, and the lack of independent institutions (David
Landes); technological stagnation from the fourteenth century (Joseph Needham, Joel
Mokyr); the success and efficiency of the commercial-agricultural system dominating state
policies (Kent Deng), causing a ‘high equilibrium trap’ (Mark Elvin) and keeping wages low
(and thus preventing the search to labor-saving inventions) (Gunder Frank, Bob Allen). In
addition, the growth limits of a world-empire, in contrast to a world-economy (Immanuel
Wallerstein), and the lack of a colonial empire (Kenneth Pomeranz). Back in 2007, Arrighi
argued that we need “a more comprehensive model”, since “the really interesting question
is […] how and why China has managed to regain so much ground, so quickly after more than
a century of political-economic eclipse. Either way, a model of the Great Divergence must
tell us something, not just about its origins, but also about its development over time, its
limits, and its prospects." (Arrighi, 2007: 32).
4. The Great Divergence debate both enlarged and redirected the long-standing
convergence/divergence dispute in social sciences. It unlocked new fields of research,
introduced new approaches and created new data and knowledge. It has sharpened the
discussion on the potentials and limits of a 'global' or 'world' perspective. It has opened up
fixed narratives that universalize particular, space-time bound experiences. These dynamics
within the Great Divergence debate push it to go beyond its own terms and to transcend its
own limits. Perspectives and methods tested within the Great Divergence debate challenge
more general interpretations of the history of global capitalism. In addition, it urges historian
to contextualize, rethink and sometimes reject concepts forged within Western social
sciences. This is illustrated by the unceasing debates about the nature of (capitalist)
economy, nation-states and states, formal and informal institutions, useful knowledge, and
so on. While some authors stress the need for a more genuine supra-regional perspective,

12
13

superseding the disjuncture between European and non-European knowledge, others


conclude that this urges us to retreat into more particularistic frameworks: “Two-way
comparisons may prove inconclusive since each is liable to reflect back only the other. The
danger is of treating their differences as if they were of universal rather than special
significance. (…) and not concern ourselves so much with the Great Divergence between
Europe and the very different circumstances of China” (Jones, 2015).

The proliferation of Global and World History in research and education over the last
two decades has been impressive. This generated a swelling stream of publications on a
wide variety of themes; some of them became bestsellers. World History has got out of the
catacombs of Clio's realm, to become 'a house with many mansions' that will stand for a long
time to come (De Vries, 2013). The global building has become a landmark; it arouses
admiration and envy. It also creates confusion since its size and composition is constantly
changing. How does its global design relate to the many parts of the building? When and
why does the house accept new occupants? Who designs the new mansions? Does rapid
growth affect the outline and stability of the building? Is it still clear what belongs under the
roof of Global and World History? Nevertheless, having become a strong brand, Global
History has made an impressive march through the institutions, creating associations,
networks, journals, series, periodic conferences, educational programs, and professorships.
This has generated ongoing debates about content, methodology, data and sources, scales
and units of analysis (Manning, 2003; Stearns, 2011; Komlosy, 2011; Berg, 2013). I conclude
with what I see as five central ambitions in current world-historical research.
1. A world history perspective deconstructs both theories with universal aspirations
derived from the historical experiences of the peoples of Northwestern Europe and North
America, and the assumption of the state as a basic, self-enclosed and self-evident unit of
analysis. By doing so, world historians have opened new windows on the global past and
constructed visions related to this past from twenty-first rather than nineteenth-century
perspectives (Bentley, 2011; Palat, 2014). The past shows itself to us as a complex of
stratified time, stratified space and stratified social power relations. It calls for a holistic
systems perspective; it aims at creating new meta-narratives. Specialization is an inevitable
part of the production of new knowledge, but since history emphasizes contextual
understanding, new knowledge is of very limited significance without on-going attempts at
integration and synthesis. Global thinking does not decentralize or resurrect new
dichotomies ('clash of civilizations'); it links and combines; it questions existing hierarchies
(time, space, social) without flattening out history.
2. A world history perspective questions self-evident causalities and stories of path-
dependency. Patterns observed in a global frame are often as much the outcome of
geographical and historical contingencies as they are of historical necessity. Much of our
social theory is prone to teleology, seeking the roots of an inevitable present rather than
exploring contingency of past experiences (Pomeranz, 2015). World History does not
reconstruct a singular march of humanity toward modernity; it portrays messy worlds and a
multitude of historical experiences. It constructs visions of that past that are capable of
accounting for both fragmentation and integration on multiple levels (local, regional,
national, continental, and global). It builds frameworks that permit historians to move
beyond the issues that have been dominating social sciences since the nineteenth century:
cultural distinctions, exclusive identities, local knowledge and the experiences of individual

13
14

societies and states. It facilitates the study of large-scale, border-crossing comparisons,


processes and systems (Bentley, 2011).
3. A world-historical perspective adopts multiple spatial scales; it does not erase
regional frames, it reinvents them. Interacting regional histories make up the world
economy; a developing world economy re-makes regions. We need more bottom-up,
regionally-focused research, especially on today’s ‘global South’. The research must have
global structures and dynamics as its objective. New research perspectives like reciprocal
comparisons (regions as subunits), integrating comparisons (cycles as subunits) and frontiers
(processes of integration/resistance) allow for a more bottom-up oriented focus within
global research.
4. A world-historical perspective encourages more inter-disciplinary and trans-
disciplinary approaches and alternative academic models based on teamwork, networks,
collaboration and joint projects across the globe. In order to move world history to a new
stage, it is very important that we remove the mental and material barriers that prevent the
development of this kind of integrated research programs.
5. Last but not least, a world-historical perspective pushes for more cosmopolitan
thinking; it questions old and new processes of integration, differentiation, adaptation and
resistance. It creates emancipating stories; stories that connect human actions within a
broader human-made world. It allows peoples to re-imagine their future. This is not a plea
for legitimizing stories, but for a morally charged program. World History does not trade a
national perspective for other exclusive frameworks, either global or sub-national. It does
not essentialize new concepts like the non-West, the Global South or the subaltern. It tells us
about the complexity of both the past and present worlds. It makes moral claims about the
way in which the world functions today and how it could function tomorrow. Since
differences and diversity are basic components of the human story, the global perspective
shows that understanding and handling differences is an important moral skill. Claims,
interpretations and evaluations cannot be made solely within the framework of our own
known world; they must reflect the complexity of human history. With the global
perspective, history strikes back. It integrates time and place, deals with interactions and the
hierarchy of scales in the human world. This makes it a barrier against the threat of an
undifferentiated multitude of new stories, and it advances the levels of ambition, time, place
and themes, of questions and answers. Historicizing does not create a new, totalizing
master-narrative, only a lack of historical knowledge can do that. A global perspective is, by
definition, highly ambitious; it interrogates processes of 'world-making', of social change, in
a broad time-space context. It compares, it connects, it incorporates, it systemizes. Global
and World History deconstruct world-making processes and construct new world-making
narratives. That is why the global perspective is inclusive. It includes outer worlds and outer
times in our world; it includes 'us' in our narrative.

14
15

References

Abbeloos, J.F. and Vanhaute, E. (2011). "Cutting the Gordian Knot of world history: Giovanni
Arrighi’s model of the great divergence and convergence", Journal of World-Systems
Research, 17, 1, pp. 89-106.

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson J. (2012). Why Nations Fail. The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and
Poverty, Crown Business.

Arrighi, Giovanni (1994). The Long Twentieth Century: Money, power, and the origins of our
times. New York, NY: Verso Books

Arrighi, Giovanni (2004). "Spatial and Other “Fixes” of Historical Capitalism", Journal of
World-Systems Research, 10, 2, pp. 527-539.

Arrighi, Giovanni (2007). Adam Smith in Beijing. Lineages of the Twenty-First Century.
London: Verso.

Arrighi, Giovanni (2010). "Postscript to the Second Edition", The Long Twentieth Century:
Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times, Verso, pp. 371-386

Arrighi, G. and Drangel, J. (1986). "The Stratification of the World-economy: An exploration


of the semiperipheral zone", Review (Fernand Braudel Center), 10, 1, pp. 9-74.

Arrighi, G., Silver, B. J. and Brewer, B. D. (2003). "Industrial Convergence, Globalization, and
the Persistence of the North-South Divide", Studies in Comparative International
Development (SCID), 38, 1, pp. 3-31.

Austin, Gareth (2007). "Reciprocal Comparison and African History: Tackling Conceptual
Eurocentrism in the Study of Africa’s Economic Past", African Studies Review, 50, pp 1-28.

Babones, S. J. (2005). "The Country-Level Income Structure of the World-Economy", Journal


of World- Systems Research, 11, 1, pp. 29-55.

Beckert, Sven (2014). Empire of Cotton. A Global History. New York: Knopf.

Bentley, Jerry H. (2011). "The Task of World History", in: J. H. Bentley (ed.) The Oxford
Handbook of World History, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.1-16.

Berg, M. (2013). "Global History. Approaches and New Directions", in: M. Berg (ed.), Writing
the History of the Global Challenges for the 21st Century, Oxford, Oxford University Press,
2013, pp. 1-18.

Bin Wong, R. (1997). China Transformed. Historical Change and the Limits of European
Experience, Ithaca, NY.

15
16

Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Thomas D. Hall (1997). Rise and Demise: Comparing World-
Systems. Boulder, CO: Westview.

Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Bruce Lerro (2014). Social Change: Globalization from the
Stone Age to the Present. Paradigm Publishers.

Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Hiroko Inoue, Teresa Neal and Evan Heimlich (2014). "Global
history and world-systems", Paper Institute for Research on World-Systems, University of
California, Riverside (http://irows.ucr.edu/papers/irows86/irows86.htm)

Clark, R. (2010). "World-Systems Mobility and Economic Growth", Social Forces, 88, 3, pp.
1123-1152.

Cottyn, Hanne, Vanhaute, Eric and Wang, Yang (2015). "A world-systems frontier perspective
to land. Unravelling the uneven trajectory of land rights standardization" (forthcoming).

Cox, M. (2012). "Power Shifts, Economic Change and the Decline of the West?", International
Relations, 26, 4, pp. 369-388.

Daly, J. (2015). Historians debate the Rise of The West. Routledge.

De Vries, J. (2011). "The Great Divergence after Ten Years. Justly Celebrated yet Hard to
Believe", Historically Speaking, 12, 4, pp. 10-25.

De Vries, J. (2013). "Reflections on doing global history", in: M. Berg (ed.), Writing the
History of the Global. Challenges for the 21st Century, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2013,
pp. 32-47.

De Wachter, A. and Saey, P. (2005). “Trajectories of regions and spatial integration in the
worldsystem”, Tijdschrift Voor Economische En Sociale Geografie, 2005, 96, 2, pp.153-167.

Flemes, D. (2013). "Network Powers: Strategies of change in the multipolar system", Third
World Quarterly, 34, 6, pp. 1016-1036.

Hall, Thomas D. (2012). "Incorporation into and merger of world-systems", in Salvatore J.


Babones and Christopher Chase-Dunn (eds), Routledge handbook of world-systems analysis,
London and New York: Routledge, 2012, pp. 37-55.

Jacobs, Lindsay M. (2014). Shadows of the Future. A network analysis of the structural
evolution of the global power system between1965 and 2005. Unpublished PhD Thesis,
Ghent University.

Jones, Eric L. (1981). The European Miracle: Environments, Economies, and Geopolitics in the
History of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Jones, Eric L. (2015). "Peer Vries on the History of Economic Growth", Tijdschrift voor Sociale
en Economische Geschiedenis (forthcoming).

16
17

Kentor, J. (2000). Capital and Coercion: The economic and military processes that have
shaped the world economy, 1800-1990. New York, NY: Garland Publishing Inc.

Kick, E. L., & Davis, B. L. (2001). "World-System Structure and Change", American Behavioral
Scientist, 44, 10, pp. 1561-1578.

Komlosy, Andrea (2011). Globalgeschichte. Methoden und Theorien. Stuttgart: UTB.

Korzeniewicz, R. P. and Albrecht, S. (2012). "Thinking Globally About Inequality and


Stratification: Wages across the world, 1982–2009", International Journal of Comparative
Sociology, 53, 5-6, pp. 419-443.

Landes, David S. (1969). The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial
Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.

Lewis, W. L. (2011). "Geographies", in: J. H. Bentley (ed.) The Oxford Handbook of World
History, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 36-53.

Li B. and Van Zanden; J.L. (2012). Before the Great Divergence? Comparing the Yangzi Delta
and the Netherlands at the Beginning of the Nineteenth Century, The Journal of Economic
History, 72 (4), pp 956-989

Little, Daniel (2008). “Eurasian Historical Comparisons. Conceptual Issues in Comparative


Historical Inquiry”, Social Science History, 2, pp. 235-261.

Mahutga, M. C. (2006). "The Persistence of Structural Inequality? A network analysis of


international trade, 1965-2000", Social Forces, 84, 4, pp. 1863-1889.

Manning, Patrick (2003). Navigating World History. Historians Create a Global Past.
Palgrave/Mc Millan, Saint Martin's Press.

Marks, Robert B. (2006), The Origins of the Modern World. A Global and Ecological Narrative
from the Fifteenth to the Twenty-first Century. Rowman & Littlefield Publishers (2nd
edition).

McMichael, P.D. (1990). "Incorporating Comparison within a World-Historical Perspective:


An Alternative Comparative Method", American Sociological Review, 55, pp. 385-397.

McMichael, P.D. (2013). Food Regimes and Agrarian Questions. Halifax and Winnipeg:
Fernwood Publishers.

McNeill, William H. (1992 [1963]). The Rise of the West: A History of the Human Community.
Chicago: University Of Chicago Press.

17
18

Moore, Jason W. (2011). “Transcending the Metabolic Rift: A Theory of Crises in the
Capitalist WorldEcology” The Journal of Peasant Studies, 38, 1, pp. 1-46.

Moore, Jason W. (2014). “The Capitalocene, Part I: On the Nature and Origins of Our
Ecological Crisis. Part II: Abstract Social Nature and the Limits to Capital”, in:
http://www.jasonwmoore.com/Essays.html

O’Brien, Patrick and Deng, Ken (2015). "Can the Debate on the Great Divergence be Located
Within the Kuznetsian Paradigm for an Empirical Form of Global Economic History?"
Tijdschrift voor Sociale en Economische Geschiedenis (forthcoming).

Palat, Ravi (2010). “Convergence Before Divergence? Eurocentrism and Alternate Patterns of
Historical Change,” Summerhill: Indian Institute of Advanced Study Review, 16, 1, pp. 42-58.

Palat, Ravi (2013). “Power Pursuits: Interstate Systems in Asia”, Asian Review of World
Histories, 1, 2, pp. 227-263.

Palat, Ravi (2014). "Dependency Theory and World-Systems Analysis", in: P. Duara, V.
Murthy and A. Sartori (eds), A Companion to Global Historical Thought, Wiley Blackwell, pp.
369-383.

Parthasarathi, P. (2011). Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not: Global Economic
Divergence, 1600 - 1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Parthasarathi, P. (2013). "Comparison in Global History", in: M. Berg (ed.), Writing the
History of the Global. Challenges for the 21st Century, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2013,
pp. 69- 82.

Pomeranz, Kenneth (2000). The Great Divergence: Europe, China and the Making of the
Modern World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Pomeranz, Kenneth (2013). "Writing about divergences in global history. Some implications
for scale, methods, aims, and categories", in: M. Berg (ed.), Writing the History of the Global.
Challenges for the 21st Century, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2013, pp. 117-128.

Pomeranz, Kenneth (2015). "Scale, Scope, and Scholarship: Regional Practices and Global
Economic Histories" (forthcoming).

Sassen, Saskia (2013). "When the Center No Longer Holds: Cities as Frontier Zones", Cities,
34, pp. 67-70.

Sharma, S. D. (2008). "The Many Faces of Today's Globalization: A survey of recent


literature", New Global Studies, 2, 2, pp. 1-27.

Stearns, Peter (2011). World History. The Basics. Routledge.

Vanhaute, Eric (2013). World History. An Introduction. Routledge.

18
19

Vanhaute, Eric (2014). "Historicizing Global Studies. About Old and New Frontiers of World-
Making", in: Potentials and Challenges of Global Studies for the 21ste Century, Global
Europe. Basel Papers on Europe in a Global Perspective, No. 105, Institute for European
Global Studies, Universität Basel, 2014, pp. 50-59.

Vries, Peer (2013). Escaping Poverty. The origins of modern economic growth, Vienna
University Press.

Wallerstein, I. (2004). World-systems analysis. An introduction, Duke University Press.

Wallerstein, I. (ed.) (2014). The World Is Out of Joint. World-Historical Interpretations of


Continuing Polarizations. Boulder-London: Paradigm Publishers.

Weber, Max (2003 [1930]). Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Dover
Publications

Wrigley, E.A. (1988). Continuity, Chance and Change: The Character of the Industrial
Revolution in England. New York: Cambridge University Press.

19

You might also like