R12 Topics in Demand and Supply Analysis
R12 Topics in Demand and Supply Analysis
R12 Topics in Demand and Supply Analysis
Part 1
1. Introduction
Economics is a discipline that deals with factors affecting the production, distribution, and
consumption of goods and services. It is divided into two broad areas: microeconomics and
macroeconomics.
Microeconomics deals with demand and supply of goods and services at a micro level, such
as individual consumers and businesses. According to microeconomics, private economic
units can be divided into two groups of study:
The theory of the consumer that focuses on the consumption of goods and services.
The theory of the firm that focuses on the supply of goods and services.
This reading focuses on microeconomics and covers the demand and supply side of the
market.
where:
Let us take a hypothetical example of a demand function for the quantity of chairs
demanded in a small town. The demand function is given by:
The inverse demand function expresses the simple demand function in terms of price. The
above function can be rearranged and expressed in terms of P as:
P = 200 – 2Q
A demand curve is a graphical representation of the inverse demand function. The demand
curve plots the price on the y-axis and the quantity on the x-axis. It shows the quantity of a
good that consumers are willing to buy at any given price, all else equal.
Let us plot the demand curve given by the equation P = 200 – 2Q. Here, the intercept is 200
and the slope of the curve is -2. The slope of the demand curve is measured as the change
in price divided by the change in quantity.
The demand curve shows the highest quantity consumers are willing to purchase at
each price. When P = 200, the highest quantity consumers are willing to purchase is
0.
Similarly, the demand curve also shows the highest price consumers are willing to
pay for each quantity. When Q = 50, the highest price consumers are willing to pay is
100.
The slope of the demand curve is negative. This implies that as price decreases, the
quantity demanded increases.
Movement along the demand curve: When a good’s own price changes, the quantity
demanded changes, all else equal. This change is called a movement along the
demand curve. For instance, as price increases from 100 to 110, quantity decreases
along the line (demand curve) from 50 to 45.
Shift in the demand curve: A change in the value of any other variable will cause the
demand curve to shift. This is called change in demand. For instance, shift in demand
is caused by changes in consumers’ incomes, price of substitutes, and price of
complements.
Going back to our demand function, QD = 100 – 0.5P. Based on the mathematical principle
we just discussed, = -0.5. Assume the price is $60; the quantity demanded at this price
will be 70. The own-price elasticity of demand is: -0.5 x 60/70 = -0.4. This implies that when
the price is $60, a 1% increase in price results in a 0.4% decrease in the quantity demanded
for chairs.
Instructor’s Note
For all linear demand curves, elasticity varies depending on where it is calculated. Let us go
back to the own-price elasticity of demand for chairs to see which parts of the demand
curve are inelastic, elastic and unit elastic.
Inelastic: When elasticity is less than one, demand is inelastic. At low prices, quantity
demanded is high. This causes the P/Q ratio to be small which results in low
elasticity.
Unit elastic: An elasticity of 1 is said to be unit elastic.
Elastic: When elasticity is greater than one, demand is elastic. At high prices, quantity
demanded is low. This causes the P/Q ratio to be high which results in high elasticity.
Inference:
There are two special cases of linear demand curves in which the elasticity is the same at all
points – perfectly elastic and perfectly inelastic – though it is difficult to find real life
examples. Demand is perfectly inelastic (represented by a vertical demand curve) when the
quantity demanded is the same over a price range. Demand is perfectly elastic for a given
price (represented by a horizontal demand curve) when a change in price will cause the
quantity demanded to reduce to zero.
Elasticity
Perfectly Elastic Perfectly Inelastic
Horizontal demand curve Vertical demand curve.
Elasticity = ∞ Elasticity = 0
A small change in price can lead to
infinitely large change in quantity. All A change in price has no change in quantity
producers must sell at the market price, or demanded.
else consumers will shift to substitutes. Example: generic food such as bread.
Example: Gourmet food items.
The factors that help in determining whether the demand for a product is highly elastic are
as follows:
Substitutes: If there are close substitutes for a good and the price of the good
increases, then the quantity demanded for the good will decrease substantially
implying the demand is highly elastic. If there are no close substitutes, the demand is
less elastic.
Portion of budget spent on a good: If people spend a large part of their income on a
good, then the demand is likely to be elastic, e.g. cars. On the other hand, if people
spend only a small portion of their income on a good, then the demand is likely to be
inelastic, e.g. chocolates.
Time horizon: Long-run demand is more elastic than the short-run demand for most
products as people take time to adjust their consumption (quantity demanded) to
the new prices. In the long run, consumers will find alternatives. For instance, if
prices of cars increase, consumers will find alternative modes of transport in the
long run.
Discretionary vs. nondiscretionary : The demand for necessary goods is less elastic,
e.g. bread. While the demand for discretionary goods is more elastic, e.g. vacations.
Total expenditure is the total amount consumers spend on a product. It is the price
multiplied by the quantity.
Unit elastic: Total expenditure does not change at the point where demand is unit elastic.
The relationship between change in price and total expenditure is summarized in the table
below:
Ed > 1: elastic demand Price and total expenditure move in opposite directions
Ed < 1: inelastic demand Price and total expenditure move in the same direction
Part 2
If income elasticity of demand is 0.6, then it means that for every 1% increase in income, the
quantity demanded will increase by 0.6%. While own-price elasticity is usually negative,
income elasticity of demand can be positive, negative, or zero.
Positive income elasticity means that as income increases, quantity demanded also
increases. Negative income elasticity means that as income increases, quantity demanded
for these goods decreases.
Normal good: Income elasticity is positive. That is, as income rises, quantity
demanded (consumption of the good) also rises.
Inferior good: Income elasticity is negative. That is, as income rises, people buy less
of these goods. For example, bicycles in South Asia and fast food in US.
As discussed earlier a change in any variable other than own price would cause the demand
curve to shift. Therefore, a change in income will cause a shift in the demand curve.
Substitutes: Two goods are substitutes if one can be used instead of the other. The cross-
price elasticity of demand is positive for substitute goods. An increase in the price of a
substitute good would increase the quantity demanded of the subject good.
Complements: Two goods are complements if they are used together. The cross-price
elasticity of demand is negative for complement goods. An increase in the price of a
complement good would decrease the quantity demanded of the subject good. Example:
cereal and milk, and petrol and cars.
Example
A consumer’s weekly demand for coffee is given by the following demand function:
Assume the price of coffee is PA = 10, the price of tea is PB = 55, the price of lemon water is
PC = 10, and income is I = 2,000. Given this data, calculate the following:
Solution:
1. First, calculate the value of Q by plugging in the values for PA = 10, PB = 55, PC = 10, I =
2,000 in the demand function.
2.
1.
2.
3.
4.
5. is the own-price elasticity coefficient, which is -0.4 from the equation.
6. So, own-price elasticity of demand = = – 1.333
Buy more because when the good’s Buy more because there is an increase
Normal good price decreases, it is relatively cheaper in real income that increases the
than its substitutes. consumption.
Buy more because when the good’s Buy less because the increase in real
Inferior good price decreases, it is relatively cheaper income causes the consumer to buy less
than its substitutes. of the inferior good.
Giffen goods:
A Giffen good is an extreme case of an inferior good where the income effect dominates the
substitution effect. In this case, a decrease in price causes a decrease in quantity demanded
which implies a positively sloped demand curve. Hence Giffen goods are an exception to the
law of demand. The curriculum identifies rice in rural China as a possible Giffen good. When
the price of rice decreased, consumers in rural China with very low incomes decreased their
intake of rice and switched to alternatives such as meat that provided more calories.
Veblen goods
Like Giffen goods, Veblen goods also have an upward sloping demand curve and hence they
also violate the law of demand. However, the similarity ends there. The characteristics of
Veblen goods are described below:
Veblen goods are status goods; an increase in price increases the value to some
consumers and therefore their quantity demanded increases.
Veblen goods are based on the concept of conspicuous consumption. This means
that consumers derive utility from the fact that others regard them as someone who
consumes an expensive good. As the price of such products increase, consumers will
be inclined to purchase more to flaunt their affluence. For example, a Bugatti Veyron
car, a yacht, or a private island.
Part 3
Cost of production. The total cost of production is given by the equation below:
where:
w is the wage rate per hour
L is the number of labor hours
r is the cost per hour of capital and
K is number of hours for which capital is used.
Two factors that lower the cost of producing at a given level of output are:
It is not possible to identify the most efficient company by looking at just the TP values. AP
is a better measure of efficiency. Company X has the highest AP and is therefore the most
efficient.
The table below shows TP, AP and MP of labor for a firm across different levels of labor:
3 300 100 90
4 360 90 60
5 400 80 40
6 420 70 20
7 350 50 -70
Interpretation:
The total product (output) increases till the sixth unit of labor and declines when the seventh
unit of labor is added. Hence the total product is maximum (420) with 6 units of labor.
When we go from one unit of labor to two units of labor the marginal product (MP)
increases. This implies increasing marginal returns. The marginal product for the second unit
of labor is calculated as:
When a third unit of labor is added the MP decreases. This implies diminishing marginal
returns.
We will now analyze marginal revenue under two market conditions: perfect
competition and imperfect competition.
Marginal revenue under perfect competition
In a perfectly competitive market:
There are many buyers and sellers and the interaction between them determines the
equilibrium price.
All the firms are relatively small and the products sold by the firms are identical, or
homogeneous.
All the firms are price takers. They have no pricing power – that is, the individual consumers
and sellers cannot influence the market price of a good/service in any way.
Any quantity of the product can be sold at the market price. But, a small increase in price
would mean losing all sales. Example: wheat.
The demand curve is horizontal or perfectly elastic.
In a perfectly competitive market, MR = AR = P. Price is constant. This implies that total
revenue increases by P if the quantity increases by one unit.
The firms sell differentiated products and have a large market share.
There may not be any close substitutes.
Marginal revenue intersects the x-axis at the point where total revenue is maximized.
The marginal revenue and demand curve are downward sloping.
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost is the incremental cost of producing one more unit. It can be calculated by
dividing the change in total cost by the change in quantity. It is expressed as:
Economists distinguish between short-run and long-run marginal cost. Short-run marginal
cost is the cost of producing an additional unit assuming only labor costs vary and all other
factors of production are constant. Short-run marginal cost is directly related to wage price
and inversely related to productivity. Short-run marginal cost, . Long-run
marginal cost is the cost of producing one more unit assuming all factors of production are
variable.
Fixed and Variable Costs
Total cost can be broken down into fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs do not change with
the quantity of output. Variable costs change with the quantity of output. Average variable
cost is the ratio of total variable cost to quantity. It is expressed as:
Profit Maximization
A firm’s profit is maximized at a level of output where marginal revenue is equal to marginal
cost (MR = MC). If marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost, a firm can increase profits by
producing more. If marginal revenue is less than marginal cost, the firm should scale back.
This discussion assumes that marginal cost is rising with increased output.
Understanding the Interaction between Total, Variable, Fixed, and Marginal Cost
and Output
All the graphs we look at in this section are from a short-run perspective. In the short
run, one or more factors of production are fixed. Usually capital is fixed in the short run
while labor may change. The graph below shows the cost curves for a firm in the short
run.
Total fixed cost is constant or flat for any given output level. It does not change as
production varies.
Total variable cost increases as the quantity of output increases. For simplicity, it is assumed
to have a linear relationship with quantity. If there is no production, then TVC is zero.
The total cost for any quantity of output is the sum of total fixed cost and total variable cost.
It also increases as production increases and the quantity of output increases.
The graph below shows the MC, ATC and AVC curves for a firm in the short run.
Interpretation of the graph:
AVC Curve
The AVC curve is U-shaped but this can vary from company to company, or industry to
industry.
As output increases, average variable cost falls to a minimum and then increases. It falls,
because the total fixed cost is distributed over a large number of units.
ATC Curve
Like the AVC curve, the ATC curve is also U-shaped but higher than the AVC curve because:
o AFC is added to AVC for any given quantity of output.
o AVC increases more quickly than AFC decreases.
The distance between the ATC and AVC for any output quantity will be AFC.
MC intersects AVC at its lowest point, S. The corresponding quantity is . MC is greater than
AVC beyond
If the marginal cost of producing one more unit is less than the average variable cost (to the
left of the minimum point), then it will pull the AVC down.
Similarly, if the marginal cost of producing one more unit is greater than the average
variable cost (to the right of the minimum AVC point), then it will pull the AVC up.
The lowest point for the ATC is T, where MC equals ATC. Beyond T, MC is greater than ATC.
AFC
The difference between ATC and AVC for any quantity will be AFC. AFC is also the total fixed
cost divided by the quantity.
Average fixed cost falls as output increases because the numerator in the above formula is
constant while the denominator increases. Put differently, the total fixed cost is spread over
a larger output, so it slopes downward as output quantity increases.
The graph below shows the TR, TC, demand curve, and profit maximization under perfect
competition.
Breakeven Analysis
A firm is said to breakeven under the following conditions:
When a firm is operating at its breakeven point, the economic profit is zero. It might still be
earning a positive accounting profit.
A perfectly competitive market with no barriers to entry will attract new entrants. The
increased competition will lead to increased output and lower prices in the long run where no
firm is able to earn an excess return or positive economic profit.
Instructor’s Note
If economic profit is zero, accounting profit is called normal profit.
Under perfect competition, firms earn only normal profits in the long run.
The Shutdown Decision
The relationships that show when a firm must operate or shutdown are given in the table
below:
Operate Operate
Let us understand a firm’s breakeven and shutdown point using the graph below.
Assume the price at P3 is 150. If the competition is perfect, then P3 is the demand
curve and MR = AR.
At any point on the MC between P2 and P3, the firm is profitable because the average
revenue is greater than the average total cost.
The breakeven point is the point where P = ATC = MC. Graphically, it is the point
where MC intersects ATC. The corresponding quantity is the breakeven quantity, . Suppose
this price is 100.
Between A and B, the price is greater than AVC. The firm will continue to operate in
the short run even though it is not profitable.
To the left of A, the price is less than AVC. The firm will shut down.
Part 4
3.3. Understanding Economies and
Diseconomies of Scale
Economists use two time horizons based on how firms are able to vary the quantity of input:
short run and long run. In the short run, at least one of the inputs or factors of production is
constant. In the long run, all factors of production are variable.
The graph below shows a set of short-run total cost curves for each level of capital input.
Each STC curve has a corresponding short-run average total cost curve (SRATC). The STCs for
different plant sizes and the corresponding long-run average total cost curve (LRATC) is
shown in the exhibit below.
The factors contributing to economies of scale and a lower ATC are as follows:
Increasing returns to scale: increase in output is relatively larger than the increase in
input. The left side of Q3 shows increasing returns to scale.
Division of labor/management.
Technologically/economically efficient equipment that results in increased
productivity.
Effective decision-making.
Reduce waste and lowering costs through better quality control.
Bulk purchases resulting in lower prices.
Decreasing returns to scale: Increase in output is relatively less than the increase in
input. The right side of Q3 shows decreasing returns to scale.
Higher resource costs due to supply bottlenecks.
Improper management because of size.
Duplication of product lines.
Higher labor costs.
1. Introduction
This reading covers:
Perfect competition
Monopolistic competition
Oligopoly
Monopoly
Perfect competition and monopoly are two extremes of the market structure in terms of
number of firms and profits with the other types falling somewhere in between.
The number and relative size of firms supplying the product. The higher the number
of firms, the higher the degree of competition.
The degree of product differentiation.
Pricing power of the sellers. Are they price takers, or can they influence market
prices?
The relative strength of the barriers to market entry and exit.
The degree of non-price competition.
The table below summarizes the basic characteristics of the four market structures:
Perfect Monopolistic
Oligopoly Monopoly
Competition Competition
Number of Sellers Many firms Many firms Few firms Single firm
Barriers to Entry
Very low Low High Very high
and Exit
Some to
Pricing Power None. Price taker. Some Considerable
significant
Electricity
provider/any
utility company
Prices of
(water, cooking
Oranges; Milk; commercial
Example Toothpaste gas) as they are
Wheat airlines for a given
typically
route
controlled by a
government
authority
To understand this curve, let’s assume that the market demand is given by the following
equation:
We derived this based on two assumptions which are often not true in the real world:
Movement along the demand curve happens only if the price and quantity demanded of the
product changes, all else constant. If any factor other than price/quantity demanded
changes, then there is a shift in the demand curve. For instance, an increase in income will
cause the demand curve to shift up.
Elasticity of Demand
Special Cases
Perfectly elastic or horizontal Horizontal demand curve. At a given price, quantity demanded is
demand schedule infinite. ε = ∞. Ex: corn.
Perfectly inelastic or vertical Vertical demand curve. Quantity demanded is fixed irrespective of
demand schedule price. ε = 0. Ex: insulin.
Income elasticity of demand is the percentage change in the quantity demanded, divided
by a percentage change in income, all else equal. It measures how sensitive the quantity
demanded is to changes in income.
If the cross price elasticity is positive, then the two products are substitutes. Ex:
cereals and oats.
If the cross price elasticity is negative, then the two products are complements. Ex:
cereals and milk.
Instructor’s Note: Changes in own price causes a movement along the demand curve,
whereas, changes in income and price of substitutes cause a shift in the demand curve.
Part 2
Economic costs: These include all explicit costs and implicit opportunity costs that
are required to acquire a resource or keep it in production.
Opportunity cost: This is the value of the next best opportunity that is foregone
when another alternative is chosen. For example, if a stay-at-home mom was
employed, she would earn $90,000 a year. In this case, the mother staying home had
given up the opportunity to work, and with it an income of $90,000.
Economic profit = total revenue minus opportunity cost.
The equilibrium (optimal) price and quantity are 5.71 and 38.57 respectively. Each firm is a
price taker, which means each firm in the market must sell the product at 5.71. The
equilibrium price is determined by the market and each firm is too small to influence the
price. If a firm decides to sell the product at 6 instead of 5.71, then it will not find any
consumers who are willing to buy at that price. The quantity produced by each firm is not
determined by the market. A firm may produce 10 or 10,000 units of the product to sell at
5.71 each. The optimal quantity is determined by the firm’s cost curves.
The graph below plots MC and ATC curves for an individual firm in a perfectly competitive
market selling oranges at the market price of 5.71.
This graph plots cost per unit on the y-axis and output quantity on the x-axis.
Generally, cost curves are U-shaped because of the law of diminishing returns. The
cost of selling oranges comes down as the quantity increases until it reaches a
minimum. Beyond that point (optimal quantity), increasing the output quantity
increases the cost.
MC curve intersects the ATC curve at its minimum point.
The horizontal line shows the market price of 5.71. It is also the marginal revenue,
average revenue and the demand curve (perfectly elastic). P = MR = AR = D.
Profit-maximization condition: The firm’s profit-maximizing condition is MR = MC.
The corresponding quantity is QC.
Link between a firm’s supply and MC curve: A firm’s supply curve is the portion of the
firm’s MC curve above the minimum point of its AVC curve. This is the upward-
sloping portion of the MC curve.
Assume the market price of oranges comes down to 4, the total fixed cost is 0, and
the variable cost of producing each orange is 5; ATC is 5. So, will the firm sell
oranges? No, as the cost is more than the market price. The supply will be zero. That
explains why the firm’s supply curve is an MC curve above the minimum point of
ATC.
Economic profit = TR – TC.
If the firm is able to successfully differentiate the product (e.g. Harley Davidson
motorcycles), then the firm acts like a small monopoly.
Characteristics:
The table below summarizes the similarities and differences between perfect competition
and monopolistic competition.
Perfect Competition (PC) vs. Monopolistic Competition (MC)
Part 3
5. Oligopoly
An oligopoly market has few sellers of a product and many buyers. These sellers are large
players in their industry who determine the prices or quantities. For example, credit card
companies such as Visa, MasterCard, and Amex.
Characteristics:
If firms do not collude, each firm faces an individual demand curve and a market demand
curve. There are several models that try to explain pricing in oligopoly markets:
Pricing interdependence
Cournot assumption
Nash equilibrium
Stackelberg model
According to this theory, a competitor will not follow a price increase, but will cut prices in
response to a price decrease.
Example: Let us assume a town has two cola suppliers: Coke and Pepsi. This type of
oligopoly is called a duopoly. Now, assume the initial equilibrium price of 1 liter Coke bottle
is 100 and the quantity is 5000.
Effect of price increase: If Coke increases its price from 100 to 105, what will Pepsi do?
According to the interdependence theory, Pepsi will not increase the price and consumers
will switch from Coke to Pepsi. The quantity demanded of Coke will decrease (see the elastic
portion of the demand curve).
Effect of price decrease: Instead, if Coke decreases the price to 95, then Pepsi will also
decrease the price to 95. The quantity demanded of Coke will increase when the price
decreases, but not by much because there is no substitution effect. Consumers do not
switch from Pepsi to Coke as both are selling at the same price. To the right of the kink, the
demand curve is inelastic.
Some important points:
There are two different demand curves in the model; combining them gives us the
overall demand, which is a kinked (bent) curve. A kink in the demand curve leads to a
discontinuous (with a gap) marginal revenue curve. One part of the MR curve
corresponds to the price increase part of the demand curve and the other to the
price decrease part of the demand curve.
Profit-maximizing rule: MR = MC.
Equilibrium price and quantity do not change so long as the marginal-cost curve of
the firm falls between the gaps in the MR curve.
The MC must change considerably for the firms to change their price.
Advantage: The model helps explain stable prices.
Disadvantage: It does not tell us what the prices should be.
Cournot Assumption
Assume there are two firms with the output levels q1 and q2 respectively. Firm 1 chooses its
output as q1 to maximize profit based on the assumption that firm 2’s output level q 2 is
constant in the future. Similarly, firm 2 chooses its output as q2 to maximize profits by
assuming that firm 1’s output level is constant. Firms choose q1 and q2 simultaneously. Let us
now look at the price and quantity numbers associated with the Cournot assumption.
The firms do the best they can, given the actions of their rivals.
The actions are interdependent.
The firms do not cooperate (collude); each firm wants to maximize its own profits.
Example: WesCo and RifCo sell a similar product. Each company can employ a high-price
strategy or a low-price strategy. The profit for each strategy is shown. What is the Nash
equilibrium?
The four possible strategies are shown in the four boxes. For example, box 1 on the top-left
corner has WesCo adopting a low price strategy and RifCo adopting a low price strategy as
well. The profit for WesCo is 50 and that for RifCo it is 70. At any point in time, the
companies can be in only one box. It is not possible for WesCo to adopt a low price strategy
with profit of 50 (box 1) and RifCo to adopt a high price strategy with profit of 0 (box 2).
No matter where the companies start, they will end up in box 4 (lower left box).
Let’s start with box 1. The total profit of WesCo and RifCo is 120. They are both selling the
products at a lower price. It is in WesCo’s best interest to increase prices, and their profits
jump from 50 to 300 in box 4. It is in RifCo’s best interest as well if WesCo increases the
price, as RifCo can also increase the price. RifCo’s profit jumps from 70 to 350. The
combined profit of box 4 now is 650.
The combined profits are the highest in box 3, which is 800. Both the companies are
charging high prices. Box 3 is in WesCo’s best interest as it earns its maximum profit of 500,
but it’s possible only if RifCo also charges the high price. But RifCo is not happy here and
would lower the prices to increase its profit from 300 (box 3) to 350 (box 4).
When RifCo lowers its price to make a profit of 350 in box 4, WesCo’s profit falls from 500 to
300. The Nash equilibrium position in box 4 is what they arrive at finally.
Can both companies be better if they collude? Yes, if both the companies agree to collude
and charge high prices. If WesCo and RifCo agree to split the maximum profit of 800 equally,
then each company makes a profit of 400, which is better than the Nash equilibrium profit
of 300 and 350 profit respectively. Companies are said to form a cartel when they engage in
collusive agreements openly.
Factors that affect the chances of successful collusion:
Stackelberg Model
There is one dominant large firm and many small firms. The large firm sets the price and
has the first mover advantage.
Example: Say we have an oligopoly market where one firm has a significantly lower cost of
production than its competitors and has a 40% market share. A dominant or leader firm is
a firm with at least 40 % market share, greater capacity, lower cost structure, and is price
maker. A follower firm is a small firm that is a price taker – i.e. it accepts the price set by the
leader firm. Let us say there are five such firms in this market.
The graph below shows the quantity that will be supplied and the price charged by the
market leader, as well as by the other firms.
Part 4
6. Monopoly
This is a market structure in which a single company makes up the entire market. It is on the
opposite end of the spectrum as compared to perfect competition.
Characteristics:
Ex: Government created monopolies such as electricity or water supply in a major city.
Patent or copyright.
Control over critical resources – Ex: De Beers’ control of mining resources in South
Africa.
Government authorization – Ex: utilities like electricity, water, etc.
Strong brand loyalty which creates high barriers to entry (Rolex watches).
Network effect (Microsoft).
A natural monopoly is one where cost decreases with quantity. The firm is able to meet
most of the quantity demanded at a low cost, making it difficult for new firms to enter the
market.
Q = 400 – 0.5P
TR = P * Q = 800Q – 2Q2
MR = = 800 – 4Q
AR = 800 – 2Q
The average revenue for a demand curve is the same as the demand curve.
6.2. Supply Analysis in Monopoly Markets
The graph below shows the demand, MR, AC, and MC curves for a monopoly firm.
The profit maximizing level of output, Q, is when MR = MC. The corresponding price, PE, at
this level of output is determined by the demand curve.
Profit is based on the demand curve = TR – TC. Let’s say TC is given by:
TC = 20000 + 50Q + 3Q2 (the TC equation will be given; you need not derive it)
Given the total cost function, you can derive the MC curve as shown above. Supply and
demand can be equated to determine the profit-maximizing output.
800 – 4Q = 50 + 6Q
Q = = 75
= 750 – 10 Q.
MC = P [1- ]
Profit-maximizing price =
If MC = 75 and the own price elasticity of demand = 1.5, what is the profit-maximizing price?
A natural monopoly is a market where the average cost of production falls over the relevant
range of consumer demand. There are three possible cases for output and pricing:
Profit is maximized by
PM (the corresponding
No regulation producing this output. Notice
LRMC = MR QM price on the demand
of monopoly. that the price is highest and
curve)
quantity produced is lowest.
Left unregulated, monopoly will maximize profits by producing the quantity for
which MR = MC
Government regulation may attempt to improve resource allocation by requiring
average cost pricing or marginal cost pricing.
What a monopolist charges for their product and how much quantity is supplied lie on two
extremes: on one end the price and quantity supplied may be equal to that of perfect
competition where there is a uniform price, and on the other end is discriminating
consumers on some grounds, which leads to different prices for the same product.
Ex: In restaurants, lunch is cheaper than dinner, or weekday prices are different than Friday-
Sunday prices.
Consumer is charged maximum he is willing to pay; sellers are able to capture all
consumer surplus.
Consumers are charged different prices for the same product (airline tickets).
The monopolist is able to measure exactly how much each consumer is willing to pay
and what their preferences are. Prices vary for each consumer and unit. In some
cases, public price disclosure may not be permitted. So, one customer is not aware
of how much another customer is paying for the same product.
Unlike first degree, the monopolist is not able to exactly measure consumer’s
preferences, or his willingness to pay before pricing the product.
Consumer charged differently based on how much he values the product. Ex: a TI
BAII Plus Professional.
Another instance is where consumers are charged differently based on the quantity
sold. Ex: Quantity discounts (the price per unit decreases as the number of units sold
to a consumer are higher) are often seen. Family fare airline tickets (different fare if
the number of passengers traveling is more than 2) is another example.
Some amount of consumer surplus is captured in this form of discrimination.
Example
My monthly demand for visits to the local gym is given by: Q = 25 – 5P where Q is the
number of visits per month and P is the price per visit. The gym’s marginal cost is 1 per visit.
1. What the X-axis and Y-axis intercepts for the demand curve?
2. If the gym charged a price per visit equal to its marginal cost, how many visits would
I make per month?
3. What is my surplus at this price?
4. How much could the club charge per month for a membership fee?
Solution:
1. Q = 25 – 5P, P = 5 –
2. If P = 1, then Q = 25 – 5 * 1 = 20
3. Consumer surplus =
4. The club could charge a membership fee of 40 to extract all the consumer surplus. In
addition, it must charge 1 per visit. This pricing method is called a two-part tariff.
Example
Monopolists have considerable pricing power and may charge consumers in different ways.
Exporters charging higher prices for denim jeans in the international market compared to
local markets is an example of:
Solution: C
For regulated monopolies, there are several possible solutions in the long run:
Price = marginal cost. But this will be less than long-run average cost. So there must
be a government subsidy to compensate for the loss. Ex: Amtrak.
National ownership. But the problem is consumers are not willing to accept price
increases once the price is fixed even if the input price increases.
Regulated, authorized monopoly. P = LRAC. Investors make a normal profit, but the
challenge is to identify the monopolist’s realistic LRAC.
Franchise monopolistic firm through a bidding war to select a firm whose P = LRAC.
Part 5
For example, in an industry, assume the five largest firms in the industry have a market
share of 25%, 15%, 10%, 10% and 10%. The 5-firm concentration ratio would be 70%.
Advantages:
Disadvantages:
Unaffected by mergers among top firms. Assume the top two firms by market share
merge and the market shares of five largest firms are 40%, 10%, 10%, 10% and 2%
now. The 5-firm concentration ratio would be 72% instead of 70%, which is not very
different from what it was earlier. But the largest firm has a high market share of
40%, which is not evident in the concentration ratio number.
Does not quantify market power.
Does not consider barriers to entry.
Does not consider elasticity of demand.
Sum of squared market shares of N largest firms in a market (ranges from 0 to 1). A
number close to 1 indicates it is concentrated or monopolistic.
For example, assume the market shares of four firms are 50%, 20%, 10% and 20%.
The HHI is 0.52 + 0.22 + 0.12 + 0.22 = 0.34.
Advantage:
Disadvantage: