Institutional Approach
Institutional Approach
Institutional Approach
Institutional approach
(excerpted from: Kesselman, M., Krieger, J. & Joseph, W.A. (2005). Introduction to comparative politics. 4th edition. USA:
Wadsworth Cengage Learning)
The module introduces you to what institutional approach is, the reason for its use in the study of politics, and the
foci whenever it is applied as a tool for analysis. What you understood about this approach will be applied in the given
country case study.
After reading the excerpted materials, you should be able to:
a. identify the strengths and weaknesses of the institutional approach
b. demonstrate their understanding of the institutional approach by applying it in comparing the legislatures and
executives of parliamentary and presidential systems
c. reflect on the applicability of parliamentary and presidential institutions in the Philippines
Key Concepts to Understand:
empirical approach institutions institutionalism institutionalization logic of appropriateness
logic of consequence new institutional approach normative approach
many institutions thicken naturally over time, developing their internal procedures and also
becoming accepted by external actors as part of the governing apparatus. In other words, the
institution becomes a node in a network and, in so doing, entrenches its position.
Institutionalization: The process by which organizations build stability and
permanence. A government department, for example, is institutionalized if it possesses
internal complexity, follows clear rules of procedure, and is clearly distinguished from its
environment.
Institution Role and purpose Examples
Legislature Representing the interests Parliaments, congresses,
of citizens; making law; national assemblies, diets
forming governments;
Executive Governing, making policy, Presidents, prime
providing leadership and ministers, ministers and
direction cabinets
Judiciary and Upholding and interpreting Supreme courts, courts
constitutional the constitution
courts
Bureaucracy Implementing policy Departments, ministries,
divisions, agencies
Political Parties Offering policy alternatives, Conservatives, liberals,
fielding candidates, forming socialists, greens,
governments and oppositions nationalists
governments agreed to create new institutions designed to improve financial supervision and to
encourage more consistent regulation of banking. We should perhaps focus more on these key
historical moments which spark institutional creativity. Although uncommon, they help us to view
institutions as a product of, rather than just an influence on, political action by individuals.
Second, governing institutions rarely act independently of social forces, especially in poorer,
less complex, and authoritarian states. Sometimes, the president is the presidency, and the
entire superstructure of government is a facade behind which personal networks and exchanges
continue to drive politics. In the extreme case of communist party states, for instance, the
formal institutions of government were controlled by the ruling party. Government was the
servant, not the master, and its institutions carried little independent weight. Even in liberal
democracies, it is always worth asking whose interests benefit from a particular institutional
set-up. Just as an institution can be created for specific purposes, so too can it survive by
serving the interests of those in charge. For example, the arrangement in the United States by
which electoral districts are designed by the dominant political parties in each state, allowing
them to manipulate the outcome of elections in a process known as ‘gerrymandering’, is a
distortion of democracy, but it suits the interests of the Republicans and the Democrats. In
addressing the collective benefit that institutions deliver, we should remember that the support
of powerful political and economic interests provides additional stability (Mahoney and Thelen, 2010: 8).
Overall, the institutions of government must be seen as central to liberal democratic politics, and
we must look not just at their definition and origins, but also at their purpose, effects, and
character (see Figure 5.3). They are the apparatus through which political issues are shaped,
processed, and sometimes resolved. They provide a major source of continuity and
predictability, and they shape the environment within which political actors operate and, to an
extent, structure their interests, values, and preferences. The institutional approach offers no
developed theory but does provide observations about institutional development and functioning
which can anchor studies of specific cases.
Definition Formal organizations with a political purpose, typically possessing
legal identity, and acquiring privileges and duties under law.
Origins May be deliberately created for a specific purpose, or may emerge
and evolve over time in response to a need, independently of the
conscious intentions of the people involved.
Political purpose To provide the framework within which decisions are made, issues
are shaped, and problems are resolved, but may come to serve
narrow interests, such as those of the wealthy and powerful.
Effects Generate norms which shape behaviour and expectations, promote
stability and predictability, and enable long-term commitments.
Character May be formal, with rules and hierarchies and employees, or may be
informal reflections of the need for social order (e.g., religion or
marriage).
Figure 5.3: Understanding political institutions
New institutionalism. The manner in which theories and approaches tend to go in and
out of fashion (or, at least, to evolve) is reflected in what happened to institutionalism in the
1950s and 1960s, when new approaches such as behaviouralism won support. The institutional
approach was criticized for being too descriptive and for looking at the formal rules of
government at the expense of politics in its many different forms, and fell out of favour. But then
the 1980s saw new research on social and political structures and a new interest in the reform
of institutions in developing countries. The result was the birth of what became known as new
institutionalism (March and Olsen, 1984).
New institutionalism: A revival of institutionalism that goes beyond formal rules and
looks at how institutions shape decisions and define interests.
Institutional approach 4
This looks not just at the formal rules of government but also at how institutions shape
political decisions, at the interaction of institutions and society, and at the informal patterns of
behaviour within formal institutions. This lent itself well to comparative politics as researchers
undertook cross-national studies, many of them interested in better understanding the process
of democratization. Revealing just how many variations there can be on a theoretical theme,
Peters (1999) identifies seven strands of new institutionalism, ranging from the historical to the
international and the sociological.
The institutional approach offers two main reasons for supposing that organizations
shape behaviour. First, because institutions provide benefits and opportunities, they shape the
interests of their staff. As soon as an organization pays salaries, its employees acquire
interests, such as ensuring their own personal progress within the structure and defending their
institution against outsiders. March and Olsen (1984: 738) suggest that institutions become
participants in the political struggle:
The bureaucratic agency, the legislative committee and the appellate court are arenas
for contending social forces but they are also collections of standard operating
procedures and structures that define and defend interests. They are political actors in
their own right.
Second, sustained interaction among employees encourages the emergence of an
institutional culture, which can weld the organization into an effective operational unit.
Institutions generate norms which, in turn, shape behaviour. One strength of the institutional
approach is this capacity to account for the origins of interests and cultures, rather than just
taking them for granted. As Zijderveld writes (2000: 70), ‘institutions are coercive structures that
mould our acting, thinking and feeling’.
The new institutional approach suggests that much political action is best understood by
reference to the contrasts between the logic of appropriateness and the logic of consequences.
The former sees human action as driven by the rules of appropriate behaviour, and hence
institutions shape activity simply because it is natural and expected, not because it has any
deeper political motive. For instance, when prime ministers visit an area devastated by floods,
they are not necessarily seeking to direct relief operations, or even to increase their public
support, but may just be doing what is expected in their job. In itself, the tour achieves the goal
of meeting expectations arising from the actor’s institutional position. ‘Don’t just do something,
stand there’, said Ronald Reagan, a president with a fine grasp of the logic of appropriateness.
When an institution faces an obligation to act, its members are as likely to be heard asking
‘What did we do the last time this happened?’ as ‘What is the right thing to do in this situation?’
They seek a solution appropriate for the organization and its history.
Logic of appropriateness: The actions which members of an institution take to conform
to its norms. For example, a head of state will perform ceremonial duties because it is an
official obligation.
Logic of consequences: The actions which members of an institution take on the
basis of a rational calculation of altruism or self-interest.
This emphasis within the institutional framework on the symbolic or ritual aspect of
political behaviour contrasts with the view of politicians and bureaucrats as rational actors who
define their own goals independently of the organization they represent. In other words, their
actions are shaped by consequences, or the political returns they expect to achieve from
those actions; they are faced with a problem, they look at the alternatives and at their personal
values, and they choose the option that provides the most efficient means to achieving their
goals. In short, institutions provide the rules of the game within which individuals pursue their
objectives (Shepsle, 2006).
Institutional approach 5
Enhancement Activity 1:
After reading and trying to understand what institutional approach is all about,
you can test your understanding by defining the following terms:
1. Empirical approach
2. Normative approach
3. Institutional approach
4. Logic of consequence
5. Logic of appropriateness
Enhancement Activity 2:
You had been reading about the difficulties that our country had been going
through since the implementation of the Enhanced and then General to
Modified General Community Quarantine. For more than three months,
through news coverage and other web sources, you witnessed the struggles of
our ordinary people, the locally stranded individuals, the repatriated OFWs, the OFWs in
other countries seeking for assistance from our government, the front liners, education
sector, among others. Added to these stories of our time is the controversial enactment of
the emergency bill, now called, Anti-Terror Act of 2020 which earned opposition from some
sectors of our society. Considering all of these, do you consider the enactment of the Anti-
Terror Act of 2020 in compliance with the logic of consequences or logic of
appropriateness? Why?
Institutional approach 7
Enhancement Activity 3:
Based from what you understood, write in the appropriate column what you
consider to be the strengths and weaknesses of the institutional approach.
Strengths Weaknesses