Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views

Why Governments Should Invest More To Educate Girls T. Paul Schultz

This document discusses why governments should invest more in educating girls. It presents three main reasons: 1) Returns to education tend to be higher for women than men, especially in countries where women are less educated initially. As education levels rise, returns decline more for men. 2) Children's health and education outcomes are more closely linked to their mother's education level than their father's. 3) More educated women participate more in the paid workforce, broadening the tax base and reducing distortions from taxation. These conditions justify disproportionately allocating public education expenditures toward women and girls. The document reviews evidence from many countries supporting higher returns to female education.

Uploaded by

Ahmed Fayek
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
34 views

Why Governments Should Invest More To Educate Girls T. Paul Schultz

This document discusses why governments should invest more in educating girls. It presents three main reasons: 1) Returns to education tend to be higher for women than men, especially in countries where women are less educated initially. As education levels rise, returns decline more for men. 2) Children's health and education outcomes are more closely linked to their mother's education level than their father's. 3) More educated women participate more in the paid workforce, broadening the tax base and reducing distortions from taxation. These conditions justify disproportionately allocating public education expenditures toward women and girls. The document reviews evidence from many countries supporting higher returns to female education.

Uploaded by

Ahmed Fayek
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 49

WHY GOVERNMENTS SHOULD INVEST MORE TO EDUCATE GIRLS

T. Paul Schultz

Yale University

September 12, 2001

Acknowledgments: I have benefitted from the comments of Lawrence Chickering on a previous draft of

this paper and the suggestions of the editor and two anonymous referees of the Journal of World

Development. I am grateful for the support of the Rockefeller Foundation, whose grant for research

and training on the family in low income countries contributed to many of the ideas summarized here. I

am responsible for any errors that remain.


Abstract

Women and men often receive the same percentage increase in their wage rates with advances in

schooling. Because these returns decline with more schooling, the marginal returns for women will tend to

exceed those for men, especially in countries where women are much less educated. The health and

schooling of children are more closely related to their mother’s education than father’s. More educated

women work more hours in the market labor force, broadening the tax base and thereby potentially

reducing tax distortions. These three conditions, it is argued, justify the disproportionate allocation of public

expenditures toward women’s education.

Keywords: Gender, Returns, Education, Development, Externalities, Taxes

JEL Codes: I21, I22, J16, J31


1. INTRODUCTION

Evidence from a growing number of countries in all regions of the world demonstrates that

increasing investments in women's human capital, especially education, should be a priority for countries

seeking to increase both economic growth and human welfare. The case for directing educational

investment to women is stronger, the greater the initial disparity in investments between women and men.

Although gender equity is one possible reason for supporting a reallocation of public educational resources

to favor females, the arguments advanced in this paper are based only on economic efficiency – or, in other

words, maximizing social output -- which can also justify governments investing more in women than in

men.

Enrollment in school represents the largest component of the investment in human capital in most

societies, and arguably the component over which public policy has the most immediate control through

its administration of public schools and regulatory capacity. This paper summarizes the mounting empirical

evidence from around the world that the social returns to the years of schooling of females are greater than

the return to males. The evidence comes primarily from representative household surveys and censuses.

Given the diversity of cultures, differences in production techniques employed at different stages of

economic development, different resources available to complement the labors of men and women, and

marked differences in skill specializations that women and men pursue in different parts of the world, there

will inevitably be some exceptions to these predominant patterns and empirical regularities (Boserup, 1970;

King and Hill, 1993; Schultz, 1995b; Behrman, 1997). But there are few instances in international

quantitative social science research where the application of common statistical methods has yielded more

consistent findings than in the area of gender returns to schooling. Therefore, most of my conclusions seem

2
warranted for most settings in the world, with, of course, differences in degree. This evidence may

explain why regions of the world which have achieved the most economic and social progress over the past

several decades are those -- among other things -- that have most successfully promoted equal educational

achievements for men and women. East Asia, Southeast Asia, and Latin America are examples of regions

in which significant progress has been made. Conversely, regions that have lagged behind in their growth --

notably South and West Asia, the Middle East and North Africa, and Sub-Saharan Africa -- have lagged

badly in their relative investments in women’s schooling, thus limiting women's contributions to economic

and social progress.

Although general conclusions about the impacts of social investments in men versus women are

consistent and reliable in most parts of the world, economic, social, and political conditions do vary in

particular countries and sub-populations. Therefore, strategies for responding and designing efficient social

policies to redistribute education by gender must be developed through research in particular settings.

Coordinated and focused country-specific programs of research are needed to evaluate policy options

within the institutional and cultural constraints of each country. While this paper reviews the reasoning and

research behind the policy initiative proposed here -- laying out their qualifications, limitations, and statistical

assumptions -- much new applied research will be needed to chart the most promising policy options.

Section 2 examines the evidence of the private wage returns to schooling for women and men, and the

general problems of assessing the productivity of male and female workers with different amounts of

education. Section 3 considers social externalities or benefits from schooling that are not captured by the

private individual or family, and asks how these differ for male and female schooling. Section 4 explores

briefly some of the public finance implications of reallocating human capital from men to women. Section

3
5 reviews some of the institutional options which could accomplish this reallocation of resources, and

section 6 concludes.

2. PRIVATE WAGE RETURNS TO SCHOOLING OF WOMEN AND MEN

The gap between men's and women's years of completed schooling is a rough but informative

indicator of the gender difference in many forms of human capital.1 The literature on human capital returns

was first built on evidence of wage differences among males in the US 1940 Census cross-tabulated by

their schooling and age (Becker, 1964). This first step of empirically implementing the calculation of a

lifetime private rate of return to schooling avoided the ambiguities posed by women and the problems of

inferring labor productivity for persons outside of the wage labor force. In most of the poorest populations

of the world women rarely work for a wage. Thus, the foremost problem in constructing a satisfactory

measure of the productivity of women with different amounts of schooling is to be able to explain which

women decide to work outside of their family for a wage (Heckman, 1980). Only with such an explanation

in hand, is it then possible to correct estimates of the wage function (which implies a return on schooling)

for the potential sample-selection bias due to the researcher only having data on the productivity of wage

earners.

Fortunately, the movement of women into the labor force over the last fifty years has been the most

significant development in labor economics of high-income countries. It has therefore been subjected to

much analysis. The three variables emphasized in models of the determinants of female labor force

participation are (1) the woman's own market wage opportunities (often proxied by her schooling and age),

(2) her sources of nonearned income that reduce her dependence on her own market earnings and thus her

market labor supply, and (3) the wage opportunities of her husband or extended family. Since the woman's

4
own wage is only observed if she works for a wage, it is the censored variable we want to correct for

sample selection bias. Also, many women do not have a husband or do not reside with other working

family members, although they may have access to a family support network. These family composition

variables, along with her fertility, should be treated as jointly determined with her allocation of time over

her lifetime, and thus they are not strictly independent of her labor supply, and cannot serve as an

exogenous basis for predicting whether she participates in the labor force. In other words, if she has more

children in the home, she tends to have paid a price in terms of her experience and productivity in the

market labor force, and she is also less likely to participate in market work, other things being equal. But

unless fertility is due to random arrivals of twins, for example, it cannot be used to infer the causal "effect"

of fertility or the presence of a young child on her time allocation. That leaves variables representing the

woman's claims on nonearned income, inherited assets, dowries, or social capital as the most likely source

of information to predict her probability of working in a wage job. This empirical approach to identifying

a sample selection model for women wage earners assumes that these nonearned income claims of the

woman do not affect the wage rate she could expect to receive in the market labor force. The greater her

nonearned income resources, the less likely she is to be in the wage labor force (Smith, 1980; Schultz,

1995a). Although this nonearned income variable may be difficult to assess in some settings and represents

a small fraction of a person's lifetime wealth, it provides, in many studies, a significant predictor for which

women (and men) participate in the wage labor force, and allows one to implement a statistical technique

for dealing with the potential sample-selection bias encountered in analyzing wage functions for women (and

men) (Heckman, 1980).

5
The wage determining function of women is specified in the same form as proposed by Mincer

(1974) for men, except that in the case of women the variable representing years of post-schooling

experience does not approximate with the same precision as for men the accumulation of labor market

experience that is expected to affect current productivity in wage employment. This is because women may

be less permanently attached to the labor force than men and spend more of these years after schooling

ends engaged in home production and child care activities which may not increase proportionately their

productivity in the wage labor force. Differences in the parameters of the wage function for women and

for men should, therefore, be approached with caution, and not presumed to reflect labor market

discrimination, for they may be measuring different things (e.g., Birdsall and Sabot, 1993). In this case at

hand, the postschooling experience variable measures the underlying concept of wage earning skills with

greater measurement error for women than for men, imparting a downward bias to its coefficient in

women's compared to men's wage function estimates.2

For representative samples, the logarithm of the hourly wage rates has been analyzed in many

countries in association with the schooling and postschooling experience of wage earners. An empirical

description of wage structures in countries in all regions of the world has emerged from which several

generalizations can be drawn. When the log wage is regressed on years of schooling, the estimated

coefficient on schooling indicates the percentage change in wages received for attending an additional year

of school. This schooling coefficient has the additional interpretation of a private internal rate of return on

the family's investment in that individual's schooling, if the opportunity cost of the time of the student while

she is attending school for that extra year approximates the private family cost of going to school, and other

simplifying assumptions are maintained (Mincer, 1974). This proportionate increase in wages associated

6
with an additional year of schooling tends to be about the same magnitude for women and men, whether

or not one performs the justified correction for sample-selection bias discussed in the previous paragraph.

If there is a systematic difference between these estimates of the private return on schooling for men and

women, it tends to favor women more often than men, particularly in populations where women have in the

past received substantially less education than men (King and Hill, 1993; Schultz, 1988, 1995a; Duraisamy,

2000). Even when private internal rates of return to schooling are higher for women than for men, the

overall level of wages tend to be lower for women than men. In other words, the absolute magnitude of

both the opportunity cost of not working to attend school, and the wage gains associated with completing

an added year of school tend to be smaller for women than men, but the ratio of the wage gain to the

opportunity cost of schooling is roughly similar for men and women at each specific level of schooling, e.g.

primary, secondary, university.

There has been a long debate on how to get beneath this partial correlation between years of

schooling and log wages to disentangle the true causal effect that should inform public policy and would

represent the labor productivity effect that society could expect when it increases the schooling of

representative members of the population (Griliches, 1977). The most widespread worry is that other

factors affecting labor productivity are omitted from the analysis when estimating the effect of human capital

on wage rates, and these omitted factors may themselves be correlated with the observed measure of

human capital, i.e. years of schooling. The most frequently mentioned omitted variable is the "ability" of the

individual which is expected to raise productivity and to be positively related to schooling. The omission

of ability from the wage function leads in this case to an upward bias in the estimates of the return to

schooling. An analogous argument is made that family wealth may permit richer parents to borrow at lower

7
interest rates to invest in their children's schooling, and thus poorer families face a constraint on their credit

which leads them to invest less in their children's schooling than the rich (Becker, 1967; Jacoby, 1994;

NaRanong, 1998). Family wealth could also merely increase the demand for children's human capital for

consumption purposes, and this plausible hypothesis would also encourage the same tendency for relative

"over investment" by richer families in the schooling of their children compared to those of the poor. It is

less clear than in the case of omitted "ability," what the direction of the bias introduced by the omission of

parental wealth. If imperfect labor markets allow wealthy families to obtain for their children jobs for which

they are paid wages in excess of their marginal product, this omission of family wealth might bias upward

estimates of the wage returns to schooling, or conversely, the “over-investment” of wealthy families in less

promising students could introduce a downward bias.

This commonplace statistical problem of omitted-variable bias is compounded by an errors-in-

measurement bias that arises if the human capital stock variable, i.e. education, is itself not reported

accurately or measured precisely. Griliches (1977), among others, has illustrated how efforts to "control

for" omitted-variable bias which might be expected to otherwise overstate the wage returns to human

capital will also augment the errors-in-measurement bias that attenuates the estimates of the wage returns

to the poorly measured human capital input. The net effect of these generally offsetting sources of bias is

not obvious on a priori grounds. A proposed solution to this dilemma in econometrics is to specify a

suitable instrumental variable that is correlated with schooling, but is not likely to be related to the

worrisome omitted variables.3 For example, a locality-specific price for an input to produce the form of

human capital, such as a monetary price of school tuition or time price of attendance is often approximated

by the distance of the child's residence from the closest school. It would be desirable if this local price or

8
program variation across the sample that is used to predict schooling was closely related to the policy

instrument that society would be inclined to manipulate to change the demand for schooling. In other

words, if the wage returns to schooling exceeded or fell short of some equilibrium return, the natural policy

variable would be to build (or close) more neighborhood schools? It is also critical that this locality "price

of schooling" not be correlated with omitted determinants of the demand for schooling. In contemporary

program evaluation studies, estimates of the returns to schooling may be based on variation in school

attainment associated with an otherwise random policy variable should approximate the school returns for

those segments of the population who are most likely to be influenced in their school decision by the

program changes. Using this source of policy variation as the instrumental variable allows the researcher

to interpret the estimated return as not the average returns for an entire population but the marginal returns

for those treated and most likely to respond to the treatment by changing their schooling decisions.

A series of studies of returns to education in the United States using this instrumental variable

methodology has yielded estimates which are similar to those obtained by ordinary regression (least

squares), or sometimes as much as 10 to 20 percent higher. One might conclude that both sources of

parameter bias are relatively unimportant or they happened to cancel each other in standard statistical fits

of wages to schooling. Another possibility is that school returns differ at the margin for various segments

of the population, and this heterogeneity in wage response to the treatment provided by schooling accounts

for why different instrumental variables imply different estimates of returns; in other words the different

instruments affect the schooling of different groups whose returns actually differ from the average (Card,

1999). There are fewer investigations in low-income countries using instrumental variables to predict

schooling levels and wage functions for women and men. Parallel investigations of World Bank Living

9
Standard Measurement Surveys from Ghana and Côte d'Ivoire from the end of the 1980s, for example,

did not find the instrumental variable estimates of schooling returns were significantly different from those

reported by standard regressions (ordinary least squares), whereas wage returns to health, proxied by

height and weight-to-height-squared, tended to increase substantially when estimated by instrumental

variables, suggesting that heterogeneity and measurement error are more serious sources of bias in the case

of health than they are for schooling (Schultz, 1995b).

These problems of estimation bias are potentially as serious for the study of male or female wage

returns to schooling, and few indications have yet emerged that they operate to a different degree for men

and women. As noted earlier, there is some suggestive evidence that correcting for sample-selection bias

does increase schooling returns for women more than it does for men, but further research will be needed

to confirm the generality of this empirical regularity (Schultz, 1995a).

In conclusion to this section, it should be noted that there is an alternative to estimating wage

functions for men and women and comparing their returns to schooling. It involves estimating production

functions or cost functions, and derive from these estimates the marginal products of male and female labor

inputs with more and less schooling. I do not know of production functions that have sought to extract both

the marginal product of male and female labor, where labor inputs are disaggregated by levels of school

attainment. It has proven difficult to disaggregate labor by gender when estimating production functions,

perhaps because the labor input allocations are in fact endogenous, and likely to be related to unobserved

endowments of the workers or other omitted production input variables (e.g. Huffman, 1976; Quisumbing,

1996; Schultz, 1998; Fafchamps and Quisumbing, 1999). To perform the further disaggregation of labor

inputs by gender, age, and by schooling, may not yield precisely defined production function estimates, and

10
thus is not yet a source of insight into male and female returns on schooling which are comparable to those

widely derived from wage functions.

From the earliest investigations of the market returns to schooling it was taken on faith that rates

of return to additional years of schooling would have a tendency to decline at more advanced levels of

schooling. Individuals were assumed to first acquire the schooling skills that were most highly rewarded

in the labor market, and continue to invest in more skills until returns fall to the cost of borrowing further

capital (Becker, 1964; 1981). Psacharopoulos and Woodhall (1985) note that the highest returns to

schooling in the low income world occur at the primary school level, where most of the world’s population

reside, and that returns tend to decline at secondary and higher educational levels, particularly when social

returns include public school expenditures. This general pattern of diminishing returns to schooling justifies

expanding first basic education in low-income countries, before making large investments in more costly

higher education.4 If women tend to be concentrated at lower levels of education than men, and the returns

are generally higher at these lower levels of schooling, then closing the gender gap in years of schooling will

purchase higher returns than raising the overall distribution of schooling that leaves the existing differentials

between men and women unchanged.5

3. EXTERNALITIES OF WOMEN'S AND MEN'S SCHOOLING

A standard reason to expend public resources on an activity is that the individuals who determine

how much of that activity to demand (produce) do not take into account some social benefits and costs

associated with the activity, because they do not privately capture them or pay for them, respectively.

Social benefits and costs of schooling that are not borne privately by students or their families have been

discussed in the initial conceptualizations of human capital by Schultz (1961) and Becker (1964). But they

11
have not often been quantified so as to inform calculations of the social returns to schooling. Studies have

generally quantified only the public costs of education. Factoring these additional costs into the private

wage return calculation, of course, reduces the calculated social returns to schooling, most dramatically for

tertiary levels of schooling, where the public costs tend to be many times larger than the public costs of

primary or even secondary schooling per year per student (Psacharopoulos and Woodhall, 1985). But

discussions of social benefits of education remain abstract (e.g. they enhance the operation of democracy)

and not monetized in a form that they can be incorporated into the economic calculations of social returns.

At the macro economic level, schooling has been the most powerful "nontraditional" input discovered to

explain the puzzle of modern economic growth (Denison, 1962; Schultz, 1961; Kuznets, 1966; Jorgenson,

1995). Some cross-country regressions explaining aggregate growth with economic inputs and institutions

do not always find the anticipated partial correlation with measured changes in schooling (e.g., Benhabib

and Spiegel, 1994). But Krueger and Lindahl (1998) have argued that aggregate measures of adult

schooling are dominated by long run trends, and short run changes over time in these measures are mostly

measurement error, and not surprisingly, uncorrelated with growth rates.

Although there are few widely accepted empirical estimates of the macro economic externalities

of schooling on economic growth, there is microeconomic evidence of intergenerational externalities in the

production of human capital.6 The most salient examples are a number of home production processes

coordinated by the family that are affected by the schooling of its members, and for which society often

assigns a special value, or a social value in excess of the private benefits which individuals in these families

capture. Most of these exceptions relate to the formation of human capital in children, or investments in

the productivity of future generations. It is not obvious that societies should always be inclined to encourage

12
investments in future generations, for to sacrifice current consumption for future generations, whose income

might be greater than those currently living, is not necessarily desirable. But most societies appear to view

such human capital investments in children as an activity it is willing to subsidize. Consequently, if the

schooling of parents contributes to their children attaining more education, the parent schooling also

warrants a subsidy due to its externalities.

The conclusion of many empirical studies of child development is that increased schooling of the

mother is associated with larger improvements in child quality outcomes than is the increased schooling of

the father. This has been studied with birth outcomes (e.g. birth weight), child survival, good nutrition,

earlier entry into school, increased school enrollment adjusted for age, and more years of schooling

completed on reaching adulthood.7

There is a substantial empirical literature suggesting that adding to a mother's schooling will have

a larger beneficial effect on a child's health, schooling, and adult productivity than would adding to a father's

schooling by the same amount. This finding is consistent with recent studies grounded in the bargaining

models of family resource allocation which report increments to the nonearned income of mothers (that

empowers them) have a larger beneficial effect on the consumption and human capital of children than a

similar increase in the nonearned income of fathers (see reviews in Strauss and Beegle, 1996; Thomas,

1990, 1994; Quisumbing, 1995; Haddad, et al., 1997; Schultz, 1998; Alderman and King, 1998).

In assessing this interdisciplinary literature it is important that the schooling and resources controlled

by women are appropriately evaluated, and that confounding factors are suitably controlled. Some early

studies relied on the labor market earnings or total income of women to measure women's control of

economic resources (Kennedy and Cogill, 1986; Blumberg, 1988). These measures of "women's

13
bargaining resources" are less than satisfactory because they are affected by the women's market labor

supply decisions, and time allocation could also be affected by her fertility and correlated with her

compensatory child expenditure patterns. For example, using our previous results, women with more

inherited wealth and nonearned income may allocate less of their time to working in the wage labor market

and thus have less earnings, but allocate more time to child care and coordination of home production. This

should not be interpreted to indicate that these women had less economic control of resources in the family.

In both the unified family model and bargaining family models the productive value of the husband's

and wife's time are expected to modify consumption and investment patterns, because the value of the time

of family members enters into the opportunity costs of many consumption commodities and investment

activities, and thereby modifies the entire structure of family demands (Becker, 1981). Augmenting a

mother's schooling could increase her capacity to produce child human capital by a larger amount than does

the father's schooling increase his corresponding capacity. He also may spend less time than she does in

child care. Thus, if the mother's schooling produces more favorable child outcomes than does the father's

schooling, that is evidence of a favorable social externality associated with public investments in female

schooling, but it is not by itself evidence that women have different preferences for child human capital, or

that the unified model of family behavior must be rejected in favor of the bargaining model of the family that

can accommodate a world where men and women pursue different objectives with their own separable

resources.

A better approach to distinguish between the unified family model and forms of the family bargaining

model involves testing whether the personal distribution of nonearned income in the family affects the

allocation of household resources to child consumption and human capital investments. Perhaps the most

14
readily interpreted evidence of this form is when an individual's own nonearned income is associated with

a greater increase in child height, weight-for-height, and calorie intake, holding constant for the family's total

nonearned income and the shadow value of the time (i.e., wage rates) of both spouses. This empirical

regularity strongly suggests that the pooling of family resources is less than perfect. When women control

more nonearned income, indicators of child development improve by a greater amount than when men

control these resources, holding constant the total budget constraint for the family.

The next analytical problem in relating the schooling of mothers and fathers to child development

is caused by the modification of family composition with changes in the schooling of the parents. Family

living arrangements express the parents' preferences for patterns of consumption and investment. Marriage,

separation, divorce, and childbearing are all, to some extent, choices made by adults to improve their

expected welfare. How is one to deal with the self selection of those women who are living with a spouse,

or living on their own, or living with another relative? How is one to treat the potential earnings or

nonearned income of a man resident in her household, if he is not currently married to her? All these

ambiguities in what constitutes the appropriate evaluation of the child development externalities of mother's

and father's schooling should caution us from drawing definitive conclusions from the existing empirical

evidence, because most of this evidence is estimated from only husband-wife coresidential units. I would

conjecture that the conclusions noted earlier will not be reversed, if we learn how to control more

adequately for the joint determination of family composition and child development. But the challenge to

“endogenize” the family’s composition within our models of household production needs further research.

Most empirical studies of the effect of parent schooling on child development are flawed for the

purposes of this paper, because they include control variables that are likely to be affected themselves by

15
parent schooling. For example, a common practice is to control for family income, husband and wife

earnings, or fertility in assessing the effect of parent schooling on child development. But if these control

variables are thought to affect child human capital, and also are jointly determined by the mother's or

father's schooling, what can be learned from existing data? It is certainly no longer a "total" effect of

schooling on the child outcome, nor is it an acceptable estimate of a "net" effect. If the intervening variable,

such as family market income, is positively affected by the father's schooling, then it might be expected that

some of the beneficial effect of father's schooling would be captured by family income and the "net" effect

of father's schooling controlling for family income would be algebraically smaller than the total effect (not

conditioned on family income). If as seems more likely, family income is itself a family choice variable that

incorporates husband and wife labor supply decisions and joint specialization and reflects the preferences

of both father and mother, the direction of the (simultaneous equation) bias is not clear (Becker, 1981;

Schultz, 1981). Nonearned income, land, inherited assets may potentially serve as controls for nonhuman

wealth of the family, if they are not affected themselves by the schooling of the parents. These nonhuman

capital variables can then be used as instrumental variables to estimate the effect of lifetime family income

levels, approximated by variables such as total family expenditures per adult. As with family composition

variables discussed earlier, most direct controls for family incomes, parent earnings, or fertility make

estimates of effects on child human capital development difficult to interpret as an indication of the total

effects of mother's and father's schooling.

This interpretation of the empirical record needs much more nuanced study. One strategy

postulates the roles of unobservable variables, such as preferences for child schooling which differ for men

and women. Suppose men who prefer to have fewer children and better educated children seek wives who

16
are better educated and thus more productive in producing human capital in their children. These

(unobserved) preferences of men for lower fertility and higher "quality" children would lead them to make

the necessary sacrifices in other areas (i.e. reduce their other consumption) to marry better educated

women. Or more specifically, it would lead them to marry better educated women than they would be

expected to marry, on average, in the normal functioning of the marriage market without such

heterogeneous preferences. In this case, it becomes ambiguous whether the lower fertility and increased

child schooling associated with a mother's schooling is a causal effect of the enhanced home productivity

of a woman's schooling, the preferences of women for higher quality children, or an incidental outcome of

the marriage matching process, which involves men's and women's preferences.

In rural Bangladesh and India empirical evidence has been assembled, conditional on a structural

model, which suggests part of the correlation between women's schooling and their children's schooling is

due to the marriage matching process, and consequently can be attributed to men's preferences rather than

to women's differential productivity in schooling their children (Foster, 1996; Behrman et al. 1997). The

Indian study first notes that women's schooling does not contribute to increased agriculture productivity,

whereas men's schooling is strongly linked to the adoption of new agricultural technologies since the 1960s

and consequently to increases in rural incomes (Foster and Rosenzweig, 1995). Women's and men's

schooling may also not earn much of a private return in the daily rural wage labor market in India. A

remaining possible economic reason for sending girls to school in increasing numbers by rural Indian and

Bangladeshi families is that the better educated women are able to increase the schooling (and health) of

their children. Men who want better educated (healthier) children are thus motivated to marry a better

educated women with increased capacity to produce child human capital. An improved understanding of

17
the joint determination of the marriage market and these home child human capital production processes

could affect the magnitude of estimates of the technological productivity of female education on child human

capital, and plausibly reduce them in circumstances where women's schooling is privately valued by men

mainly for its productive effects on childrearing.

Another dimension of the marriage market, the quality of match between partners, could have

additional implications for private and social welfare. In this case there is also very little theoretical or

empirical research to build on, and the implications are thus speculative. It is necessary to make a number

of simplifying assumptions to illustrate the nature of the problem, although they can, in some cases, be

relaxed later. Suppose that an individual benefits not only from the increased production possibilities that

a more educated spouse brings to a marriage, as assumed in standard economic models of marriage

(Becker, 1981), but also is rewarded by a positive consumption complementarity between the husband's

and wife's schooling. For simplicity this matching benefit from the interaction of husband's and wife's

schooling might be assumed loglinear as are the schooling effects in the wage equation. Suppose further

that the marriage market matched the most schooled man with the most schooled woman, and so on down

through the schooling-ranked men and women, so that the rank correlation between the spouses education

is perfect, i.e., rho=1.0. Then, if the years of schooling were distributed similarly for men and women, the

summed welfare of the matched couples would be greatest given any total stock of schooling available to

the population, when the average gender gap in schooling was zero. This result depends on market returns

to schooling for men and women being the same, a pattern widely observed and noted in section 2. Of

course, the match correlation of schooling of husband and wife is not 1.0, as assumed, but perhaps between

.4 and .6 (Kremer, 1997). Nonetheless, there is a tendency for the gender gap in schooling to diminish with

18
economic development in this century, and perhaps for the correlation between the schooling of husband

and wife to increase.8

The final potential externality of schooling relates to fertility, which is widely found to be inversely

related to women's schooling (Schultz, 1973, 1981; Cochrane, 1979). If family planning programs are

currently subsidized by the state because a reduction in fertility is thought to bring a social benefit, then

increasing the schooling of girls should be subsidized for it is clearly associated, in a decade or less, with

diminished fertility. All societies do not support family planning because they desire to reduce fertility; some

endorse these programs to improve women's lifetime opportunities and strengthen their reproductive rights.

There are also a handful of instances in Africa where the first few years of female education seem to have

little effect on a woman's fertility, perhaps because of the low quality of available primary education, or the

counterbalancing effect of education on improved reproductive health and reduced sexually transmitted

diseases that contribute to subfecundity and thus prevent some women from having the number of births

they want. On balance, the evidence suggests that increments to the schooling of men, holding constant

the educational attainment of women, are associated in low-income countries with increases in fertility,

although this pronatal effect of male education seems to diminish as the country develops (Schultz, 1973,

1994). The social costs of high fertility and rapid population growth are difficult to scientifically quantify

(National Research Council, 1986), but many countries have concluded that their society stands to gain

in the long run by slowing rapid population growth, and this conclusion would justify assigning a higher

priority to women's education than to men's.

To conclude this section, if the private market wage returns are of comparable magnitudes for men

and women, but the social externalities associated with reduced child mortality, increased child

19
anthropometric capacities, increased child school enrollments, and decreased fertility are all linked more

positively to women's schooling than they are to men's schooling, and these outcomes are valued by society,

it is efficient for society to invest more in the schooling of women than of men. Whether these social

externality benefits associated with women’s schooling vary by the level of her schooling has not been

systematically explored across countries and levels of development. However, one investigation of

contemporary rural India found that mother’s literacy and some primary schooling had a larger effect on

the child’s school work and attainment than did her post-primary schooling, suggesting higher social returns

for the most basic levels of female schooling ( Behrman , et al. 1997). A deeper understanding of the

marriage market may sharpen our insights into these connections and how to manipulate them efficiently,

but is unlikely to reverse these basic findings. The magnitude of the subsidy that would be socially optimal

will depend on the value society assigns to slowing population growth and formation of more human capital

among its youth. Where female school enrollments are markedly lower than male, there is a prima facie

case for greater subsidies for female education. The only reason to revise this rule of thumb is if market

wage returns for female schooling fall substantially below those of male schooling, presumably due to an

overproduction of women's human capital given the social institutions prevailing in the labor market and the

derived demands for various types of labor in the economy. I have not found a compelling empirical study

that reports evidence of such an “overproduction” of women's schooling.

4. PUBLIC FINANCE AND IMPLICATIONS FOR TAXATION

Individuals are expected to weigh taxes as they do wages and prices in allocating their time and

determining the composition of their consumption and investments, to the extent that taxes differ among

productive activities, outlays, and persons. Because governments must realistically obtain their revenues

20
from taxes on readily monitored activities, such as work in the market that produces earnings, most taxes

discourage, although differentially, engaging in market production activities and thereby impose a dead-

weight efficiency loss on society. There are two ways that this loss due to taxes can be affected by the

gender gap in schooling. First, by increasing the share of social activities that are taxed, which allows the

government to lower the overall tax rate. Second, the tax rate can be raised on labor for which the supply

is more inelastic or unresponsive to the tax, in order to reduce the tax rate on activities which exhibit elastic

responses to the tax rate and hence are more distorted by the tax. Differences between the market labor

supply elasticity of men and women could, therefore, influence the efficient design of a tax system for

individuals and families and thereby modify social priorities for subsidizing the schooling of women versus

men (Boskin and Sheshinsky, 1983; Apps and Rees, 1988).

Some demographic groups in the population tend to increase, on average, their supply of labor to

taxable market activities as they become better educated, as do married women, whereas other groups are

less responsive, as with adult men. This empirical regularity is presumably because the elasticity of

women’s market labor supply with respect to their own wage ( and education) tends to be algebraically

greater than it is for men (Schultz, 1981; Killingsworth, 1983). This empirical regularity may be partly

understood in terms of men generally working full time in the market, and they are thus unable to increase

greatly their market labor supply when their education and wages rise. In contrast, women have until the

20th Century allocated most of their time to work focused in their home, which is often readily combined

with child care responsibilities, and thus women have been observed to increase their market labor supply

when their educational levels are higher or rising (Schultz, 1990; Fogel, 1999).

21
Moreover, estimates of family labor supply which allow for the simultaneous determination of a

couple’s labor supply find that the cross-effect of the husband’s wage ( or schooling ) tends to reduce his

wife’s market labor supply, whereas the effect of the wife’s wage (schooling) on her husbands labor supply

is not substantial or statistically significant (Killingsworth, 1983; Schultz, 1981). Consequently, the female

schooling effect is to directly increase women’s own labor supply and market earnings tax base, while the

cross effect of male schooling on her labor supply is negative, reinforcing the previous conclusion that the

market earnings tax base would expand more rapidly in a society given its average education level, if the

schooling of women were able to catch up to that of men.

If school administrators could accept more girls rather than boys at the margin to enroll in school,

this reallocation of education by gender would thereby contribute to increase the share of adult time

allocated to market work, and thus to broadening the tax base. This increment in the taxable share of social

output allows the government, in principle, to lower the overall tax rate and thereby reduce the dead-weight

loss associated with raising any specified amount of revenue.

A second objective in the optimal design of taxes is to set rates on different factors of production

to tax more heavily the inelastically supplied resources, such as Henry George’s tax on land, in order to

reduce the overall deadweight losses from a tax regime. The greater elasticity of women’s labor supply

compared with that of men’s would, according to this second objective of public finance, encourage

governments to tax more heavily the inelastically supplied source of labor --- that provided by adult men ---

and thereby be able to reduce the tax rate on women’s market labor supply. This less distorted structure

of differential taxes on the market earnings of women and men is ironically the opposite of the structure

adopted in some societies. In the United States, for example, married women pay the progressively higher

22
tax rate based on her husband’s earnings when she enters the labor force as a “secondary worker,”

perhaps to encourage married women to specialize their production within the home, rather than in the labor

market (e.g., McCaffery, 1997).

Thus, a redirection of human capital toward women should broaden the tax base and thereby

reduce tax distortions of consumption and production between market and nonmarket activities. In

addition, the market labor supply response associated with an increase in own schooling is more positive

for women than for men. This regularity may help explain the large increase in female market labor supply

in this century, first in the industrially advanced countries, and more recently throughout most other parts

of the world, at least in the nonagricultural sector of the economy (Schultz, 1981, 1990). One interpretation

of this regularity in labor market behavior of women is that it is due to the positive (uncompensated) wage

effect caused by increasing the schooling and hence market productivity of female workers. In the case

of male labor supply, increasing schooling and productivity is associated with little change in hours of labor

supplied to the market labor force, and in many countries there has been an actual contraction in male work

hours (Schultz, 1981; Killingsworth, 1983; Fogel, 1999). Moreover, estimates of family labor supply

models suggest that the cross-effect of the husband wage (schooling) on wife's labor supply tends to be

negative and substantial in magnitude, whereas the effect of the wife's wage (schooling) on husband labor

supply is not substantial nor statistically significant (Killingsworth, 1983). Consequently, the female

schooling effect on the women’s own market earnings tax base is positive, and the cross effect of male

schooling is negative, reinforcing the earlier conclusion that the market income tax base would expand in

most settings with a redirection of human capital formation or schooling from men to women.

5. POLICY OPTIONS TO INCREASE THE SCHOOLING OF WOMEN

23
The objective of increasing educational opportunities for women is probably as old as the gender

gap in schooling. Euripides may have even advanced some proposals for Greek Athens to open their

schools to women, as did Plato in his utopian Republic. The search for policy instruments to accomplish

this increase in women's education has a long social history. However, as with many forms of social policy,

rigorous evaluation of the success of various policy interventions are often neglected. As with many

praiseworthy goals, most policy reforms to advance the education of women have resulted in legislation

without mechanisms for enforcement, incentives to change behavior, or delineation of indicators of success.

Although there may be some successful policy initiatives, most are probably not effective, and the program

evaluation literature has made little progress in sorting out which policy strategies are more effective or

efficient. With their passage into law and with sequestered appropriations, the public need for action is

generally satisfied. Nevertheless, a number of countries in different regions -- notably in East Asia and

Latin America -- have achieved considerable success in promoting women’s education. The purpose of

this section is to collect a list of possible mechanisms that might advance women's schooling, to consider

which policies hold the greatest promise, to identify the information needed to monitor progress, and finally

to structure policy evaluation studies to refine the design of these initiatives (World Bank, 2001).

Differences in enrollments of boys and girls could arise because of either the decisions of families

or the operations of schools, or in other words, due to either private demands or public supplies. Schooling

can of course also be provided in the private sector, if public supplies are not responsive to private

demands. Conversely, gender discrimination in the operation of schools may exist because there is

widespread support for it in the community or in those segments of the community that have the political

power to modify educational institutions. This dichotomy between private demands and public supplies

24
may facilitate analysis of the determinants of schooling decisions, first at the level of individuals and families,

and then at the aggregate community level, where a more complex social equilibrium framework may offer

a fuller understanding of why some societies have pursued such different priorities in public education, as

say India, Sri Lanka, and Thailand.

Families are thought to weigh the costs and benefits of sending their children to school. In some

settings they decide it is more important for them to educate their boys than their girls. This could be

explained because the expected private rates of return, as discussed in section II, are larger for boys than

for girls over their children's lifetimes. Alternatively, the decision-making parents may not be altruistically

willing to view their children's lifetime gains as equivalent to their own, and they will discount these expected

productive gains of their children, unless the parents stand to personally benefit from these gains. In some

cultures, such as South Asia, sons are customarily responsible for supporting their parents in old age and

daughters are not. This would seem to suggest how cultural arrangements of marriage and intergenerational

support systems among kin could depress the incentives for parents to invest in the schooling of their

daughters compared with their sons. This plausible hypothesis is widely accepted, but it neglects a role of

the marriage market to assign a value to the daughter's schooling. Parents should then be rewarded by the

family of the husband of their daughter for rearing a daughter who has more schooling, if indeed female

schooling increases the woman's lifetime productivity and contributes to the welfare of her husband's family.

However, if noneconomic cultural constraints or social norms preclude the wife from working in

productive activities, e.g. if she is confined by purdah to labor only within her family's household, such

cultural impediments to labor mobility might reduce the economic contribution of an educated wife and curb

parental investments in the schooling of girls. A cultural system that promotes such an inefficient allocation

25
of resources should be subject to market pressures to change. If this explanation for low levels of female

schooling is plausible, say in areas of South and West Asia, how might public policy accelerate the cultural

shift to allow labor markets to allocate more of women's time to activities where her schooling enhances

her productivity? If a woman's only option in the rural labor force is to perform casual manual work by the

day, the wage premium for schooling may be limited. Women will need to engage in some farm

management tasks which involves the allocation of modern technological inputs for them to employ

productively their schooling. Culture-specific institutions may be designed to demonstrate how family

welfare is enhanced by educating females and allowing them access to managerial, nonagricultural, and

extra-familial jobs. Perhaps farm extension activities can directly assist in facilitating the off–farm

employment and migration process for better educated daughters?

The traditional approach to increase female enrollments has been to reduce the cost of schooling

to parents, by building schools closer to the population they serve, reducing tuition fees specifically for

females, providing girls with subsidies for their school uniforms or school feeding programs, and extending

fellowships for girls to attend boarding school where local secondary schools are not available. Bangladesh

has experimented since 1994 with fellowships for girls to continue in secondary school. Some of these

educational grants are treated as a bond which is forfeited if the girl marries before the age of 18 (Arends-

Kuenning and Amin, 2000). Mexico has provided poverty alleviation grants to poor rural mothers to keep

their children enrolled in school in a program called "Progresa". The Mexican grants are roughly pegged

at local child wage rates, but are marginally higher for girls than boys, because the gender gap in enrollments

in these poor Mexican communities emerges at the secondary school level. Evaluation studies have found

that in the communities that were randomly selected to receive the initial phase of the Progresa educational

26
grants starting in 1998, the enrollment rates of girls increased by more than boys, especially for children

after finishing primary school and first entering the junior secondary school (Schultz, 2000). More than two

million Mexican households were participating in Progresa by the end of 1999, and the new government

of Fox plans to expand the scheme to involve poor families in urban areas as well.

Three states of Brazil have experimented with educational grants for mothers in poor households

who enroll all of their children between the ages of 7 and 14 in school. In 2001, the Federal government

of Brazil plans to expand this approach, Bolsa Escola, to the national level, and coordinate it with two other

poverty alleviation programs. One program provides cash transfers for nutrition, while another expands

a youth program to discourage children from working in hazardous circumstances and to involve them in

additional educational activities, or PETI (Sedlacek, 2001). At the national level, Brazil’s enrollment rates

are relatively low, but completed schooling in the past few years is somewhat higher for girls than for boys.

Therefore, the Bolsa Escola makes cash transfers to poor mothers contingent on the enrollment of their

children in compulsory primary school, but does not explicitly favor girls.

There should also be administrative means to reduce gender inequalities in schooling within families.

For example, to be accepted at school an elder male child might be required to have his (younger) sister(s)

enrolled. Such quantitative restrictions, however, have problems: they neglect differences between children

in ability and motivation, and can place costly monitoring burdens on schools. Communities could be

rewarded when the female proportion of their graduating students exceeds a threshold, but this could have

the side effect of lowering the standards for a female compared with a male graduate, and such quota

targets could be misrepresented by teachers unless strictly audited by central authorities.

27
Another strategy assumes that parents in some cultures do not want their daughters educated with

boys. In South and West Asia and North Africa the schooling of girls may be restricted by the lack of sex

segregated schools, particularly at the secondary level. Are girls schools, which avoid mixing of the sexes

after the primary level, more successful? Do female teachers succeed to a greater degree in enrolling and

advancing girls compared with male teachers? Do particular facilities or qualitative features of schools

contribute to raising female enrollment rates by a larger percentage than male enrollment rates? There are

few studies of such school quality or supply interventions which are randomly allocated across communities

and confirm that public expenditures on female schools, female teachers, and female-oriented facilities

contribute cost-effectively to increase the educational attainment of women. But these are propositions that

could be tested within educational programs in Pakistan, Bangladesh, and some Middle Eastern countries.

A word of caution is nonetheless needed to indicate that any evaluation study of interventions must not only

succeed in introducing the intervention on a randomized basis, it must also collect representative surveys

of the local household population and link this information to the school with its measurement of student

standardized performance on tests along with information on teachers and classroom inputs. The matched

background population survey will determine which children enroll in school, as well as which student do

poorly and well within school. The population survey must measure the home economic and social factors

which affect private demands for schooling, such as the mother's and father's schooling, nonearned income

and asset of both parents, etc. For every dozen studies of gender differences in student classroom

performance, there is perhaps one that analyzes matched information about the school system's inputs, and

the characteristics of local families of both the children who are enrolled and those who are not enrolled

28
in school. Without analyzing these more difficult to collect overlapping school and population samples, most

policies designed to modify the gender balance of schools cannot be evaluated.

6. CONCLUSIONS

In many international statistical studies of the wage structure, it has been found that the increase in

logarithms of wage rates associated with an additional year of a worker's schooling is of about the same

magnitude for women as it is for men. Corrections for many statistical and conceptual problems that could

make this wage comparison misleading, such as sample-selection bias, omitted-variable bias, and

measurement-error bias, have not been found to alter systematically this general comparability of female

and male wage returns to schooling. The current balance of evidence indicates that these estimates of the

private wage returns to schooling tend to be, if different, somewhat higher for women than for men, holding

constant the level of education being compared. Since women tend to have less education than men, on

average, and returns tend to be higher at lower levels of schooling, the returns to schooling of the average

girl are higher than the average boy. This ranking in private returns is strengthened if the private direct costs

of education are added to the private opportunity costs, because boys often receive more family

educational expenditures (e.g., Sipahimalani, 1999). Consequently, private returns to an additional year

of schooling for the representative female exceed those for the representative male, and social returns that

factor in public expenditures on schooling are even more favorable to a general increase in female relative

to male enrollments.

Social benefits or positive externalities related to investments in the human capital of children in the

form of child health, stature, and schooling are larger with an increment in the schooling of their mother than

their father. Fertility is also inversely related to female education in virtually all populations and often fertility

29
is directly related to male education in low income agricultural societies. Consequently, when population

growth is thought to impose social costs, female schooling should be assigned a higher priority than male

schooling, other things being equal.

Combining the larger private wage returns and the beneficial social externalities associated with

female schooling, there is a strong economic efficiency case to reduce the gender gap in schooling,

particularly where child survival is relatively low and fertility is relatively high. From a public finance

perspective, the increased schooling of women can be expected to increase the participation of women in

the market labor force (and not reduce that of men) and thereby broaden the society's tax base. The

effects of taxes on the distortion of the allocation of time and resources between market and nonmarket

production can thus be reduced, given the public sectors revenue requirements.

The economic efficiency case for redirecting social investments toward the education of women

is strong, but the mechanisms that can accomplish this objective have not been rigorously studied. They

involve for the most part understanding more precisely how the family will respond to different inducements.

Will subsidies for girls’ education repay the public sector and shift the gender balance of enrollment rates

in families, or is the family demand for male relative to female schooling price inelastic? If women are

largely restricted from working outside of their family and reaping many of the productive advantages that

come from their schooling, how does a society intervene and design a culturally acceptable program to

change this pattern of lifetime allocation of women's time? One strategy may be to encourage rural

industries that employ locally more educated women, as occurred in Taiwan and China, and to some

degree in Korea and Thailand, and may now be occurring in Bangladesh. A few decades ago these

factories were viewed by some observers as exploiting rural women by paying them excessively low wages.

30
Another assessment of this situation may be in order. How effective is such rural industrialization in

increasing women's employment in the wage labor force in South and West Asia and the Middle East?

How do rural employment opportunities in non-agriculture influence the gender gap in schooling? Can such

a pattern of development be sustained in sub-Saharan Africa? Will this pattern of development in rural

areas have the expected effect on the investment of rural families in female schooling and will it also

accelerate the rural-urban migration of these better-educated women?

In conclusion, it should be emphasized that macro indicators of development confirm the

conclusions drawn here from the micro economic studies of individuals and families. Countries that have

equalized their educational achievements for men and women in the last several decades have on the

average grown faster. Except for the indigenous populations in which a substantial disparity persists

between the schooling of boys and girls, Latin America has provided nearly as many years of schooling to

females as to males (if not always of the same quality), and the growth record of this continent until the

1980s debt crisis was impressive. East Asia has increased the schooling of women much faster than that

of men, closing a historically pronounced gender gap in these patriarchal societies in a few short decades.

Southeast Asia draws on Malay cultural roots that were less gender biased, and sometimes even

matriarchal, and the schooling of women increased in this region more rapidly than that for men, but the

initial gaps were often smaller than in East Asia. Despite recent financial crises in the region, the economic

growth record remains one of great success. South and West Asia has achieved less uniform and lower

average growth. This region is notable for investing relatively less in basic education and much less in

women relative in men, possibly accounting for their subpar growth performance until the 1990s, despite

high investment rates in nonhuman capital. Sub-Saharan Africa has had the worst growth record, the most

31
political turmoil, highest rate of population growth, lowest domestic investment rates, and has attracted the

least foreign investment. Africa, with the exception of South Africa, provided schooling mainly to males,

although women were heavily engaged in the subsistence and market economies, and should therefore have

had as much to gain from schooling as did men. Why African women received such a small share of

schooling resources is a puzzle which has not been accounted for by analysis. This traditional disparity is

changing in Africa as young women are catching up to men in terms of schooling, and even surpassing them

in such countries as Kenya. This paper has focused on the microeconomic evidence from household

surveys and censuses of the private productive returns and social externalities of human capital and

schooling by gender. Merging school administrative and household survey information on the school and

family inputs, enrollments, and test scores should provide a firmer basis for evaluating national policy

options to equalize educational opportunities between females and males, and also between the poor and

rich families, and rural and urban areas. The improvements in time series on educational attainment and

earnings of the adult workforce by age and sex should provide countries with a reliable monitoring

mechanism to assess private returns to schooling. At an aggregate level such merged administrative/survey

data may also improve cross-country analyses of the contributions of education and health to modern

economic growth, which are currently limited by poor data and ad hoc frameworks that lead to fragile and

implausible growth regressions (Krueger and Lindahl, 1998). Eventually, inter-country differences in

economic growth may shed light on the determinants of and consequences of the gender gap in schooling

and even help to quantify the value of the social externalities associated with female schooling, which

remains an important, if controversial, element of the microeconomic case surveyed here, which justifies

increased public subsidies for female schooling in many parts of the world.

32
33
NOTES

1. The gender gap in schooling tends to mirror a host of other, more difficult to measure gender

differences in human capital, such as (1) early childhood nutrition and health care (e.g. often proxied

by reduced adult height, called stunting), (2) nutritional status determined by nutrient intakes relative

to energy demands of work, as modified by protective health care (e.g. often proxied at low income

levels by weight-for-height or BMI, called wasting), (3) different types of years of schooling for

which the market returns differ (e.g. training to be teachers or nurses versus engineers and doctors,

and other indicators of quality or resource intensity of that training), and (4) on-the-job training

opportunities (often associated with sex segregation of jobs and promotional ladders), etc.

2. On the other hand, if postschooling experience of a woman is measured by her realized years of

experience working in the labor force, then this more precisely measured experience variable is also

a choice variable of the adult woman, which is likely to be “endogenous” to the wage function (i.e.,

correlated with the wage error), because it is jointly determined with lifetime specializations between

home and market production and hence realized market wages. An analogous problem arises when

studying the determinants of men’s wages, when researchers want to estimate the productive returns

to job tenure or seniority on the job (Altonji and Shakotko, 1987)

3. Another approach is to estimate wage returns to schooling using only the variation between

individuals who share the same omitted variables, when these unobserved variables might otherwise

bias the resulting cross sectional estimates. For example, between siblings the relationship between

education and wages may not be modified by shared variables representing their parents’ wealth and

some common family genetic endowments, and between fraternal and identical twins, which share

34
even more aspects of their early childhood environment and genetic predispositions (Griliches, 1977;

Solon, 1999).

4. There are aggregate growth theories that assume an externality due to human capital formation, but

I am familiar with only a few empirical analyses of modern growth performance of national (or

regional) economies that find evidence of externalities, or in other words that find income growth

effects of schooling at the aggregate level exceed systematically the income growth which is privately

realized by individuals in the form of wage differences of workers according to their schooling.

5. The literature on these issues is enormous and full of complexities that cannot be adequately examined

in the scope of this paper. The evidence of mother’s education lowering her child mortality was

widely accepted after the Latin American Census samples of the 1960s and 1970s were cross

tabulated and World Fertility Surveys became available for a widening sample of low-income

countries in the 1980s (e.g. Behm, 1976, 1980; Caldwell, 1979; Schultz, 1980; Cochrane et al.,

1980; Rosenzweig and Schultz, 1982a, 1982b; Farah and Preston, 1982; Mensch et al., 1985;

Barrera, 1990; Thomas et al., 1990). The studies of anthropometric indicators (i.e., height and

weight) of child health began somewhat later, but also clearly indicated that better education of the

mother was correlated with better height and BMI indicators for her children (summarized in

Behrman and Deolalikar, 1988, 1989; Behrman and Wolfe, 1984, 1989; Strauss and Thomas, 1995,

1998). Schooling of children is commonly related positively to maternal education (e.g. Behrman,

1997; Rosenzweig and Evenson, 1977; Chernichovsky, 1985; King et al., 1986; Duraisamy, 1988;

Duraisamy and Malathy, 1991; Holmes, 1997; Malathy, 1993; Jacoby, 1994; Rosenzweig and

Wolpin, 1994; Glewwe and Jacoby, 1994, 1995; Lloyd and Blanc, 1995; Haveman and Wolfe,

35
1995; Lavy, 1996; Subbarao and Ramey, 1995; Tansel, 1997; Holmes, 1997; Behrman et al., 1997;

NaRanong, 1998; Sipahimalani, 1999). Going beyond education, studies differ in how they measure

women's control over resources, employing first labor market productivity and then wealth and non-

earned income (Kennedy and Cogill, 1986; Senauer et al., 1986; Engel, 1988; Blumberg, 1988;

Kennedy and Peters, 1992; Haddad and Hoddinott, 1994; Thomas, 1990, 1994; Thomas and Chen,

1994; Hoddinott and Haddad, 1995). The studies also control in different ways for the endowments

of the husband, family income, and family composition. As argued in this paper, there are serious

analytical problems with most methods for dealing with family composition, and consequently there

is continuing search for better methods to model explicitly marriage matching and marital status (e.g.

Boulier and Rosenzweig, 1984; Schultz, 1994; Foster, 1996; Behrman et al., 1995, 1997).

As in most empirical generalizations, there are exceptions where the positive partial correlation

of the father’s schooling with the child’s schooling is higher than that of the mother’s schooling, often

in populations where there is more variation in father’s than mother’s education, due to the majority

of mothers having little or no schooling, as in a study of Pakistan or sub-Saharan Africa (King, et

al. 1986). Other studies have excluded families without both a father and mother in residence, which

can reduce sample size substantially and alter the estimated effects of mother’s and father’s schooling

on child development indicators (e.g. Lam, 2000).

6. For example, in Taiwan the difference between the average years of schooling completed of men

and women born between 1917 and 1921 was 4.2 years according to the 1976 Family Income and

Expenditure Survey. By 1995, men and women born between 1966 and 1977 reported a gender

gap in schooling of .23 years. By age thirty virtually all women in Taiwan were married, and the

36
correlation of schooling of wives age 30-34 and their husbands was about .4 in 1976 and this

correlation had increased to nearly .6 by 1995. (Schultz, 1998). Measurement of the match

correlation is complicated when, as in most modern societies, virtually all women are not currently

married. Then it is necessary to again correct the estimate of the match correlation for the selection

of the sample of currently married couples.

7. Although this empirical generalization may still be valid for most countries, there are now documented

exceptions where virtually all members of young birth cohorts have completed primary schooling, and

a shortage of secondary educated workers has emerged. Wage returns at this intermediate level of

schooling are then likely to exceed the returns earned at the primary level (Schultz, 1988). See the

case cited of Egypt in Birdsall and O’Connell (1999).

8. Assessing the effect of health status on worker productivity poses a parallel issue that increases in

the intake of nutrients or anthropometric proxies for the stock of health tend to have a larger effect

on worker productivity at lower levels (Strauss, 1986; Strauss and Thomas, 1995, 1998). Evidence

on gender differences in health status are more fragmentary. Certainly in population of South and

West Asia where the gender gap in schooling is large, we might expect the gender gap in health to

also be relatively large. The low ratio of female to male child survival (after the first month of life) in

India is now well studied and coherently linked to women's low productivity and high dowries. In this

case, one would expect a given increment in health status might yield a greater market productivity

return for women than for men, although I know of no analysis confirming this pattern, perhaps

because of the limitations on women working in manual labor outside of their families.

37
REFERENCES

Alderman, H. and E.M. King, (1998), “Gender Difference in Parental Investment in Education,”

Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 9:453-468.

Altonji, J.G. and R.A. Shakotko, (1987), “Do Wages Rise with Job Seniority,” Reviews of

Economic Studies, 54:437-459.

Apps, P.F. and R. Rees (1988) "Taxation and the Household," Journal of Public Economics

35(3):355-369.

Arends-Kuenning, M. and S. Amin (2000), “The Effects of Schooling Incentive Programs on

Household Resource Allocation,” Population Council Policy Research Division Working Paper

No. 133, New York.

Barrera, A. (1990) "The Role of Maternal Schooling and its Interaction with Public Health Programs in

Child Health Production," Journal of Development Economics 32:69-91.

Becker, G.S. (1964) Human Capital, New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

Becker, G.S. (1967) "Human Capital and the Personal Distribution of Income," Woytinsky Lecture,

University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI.

Becker, G.S. (1981) A Treatise on the Family, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Behm, H. (1976) La Mortalidad en los Primeros Anos de Vida en los Paises de America Latina, San

Jose, Costa Rica: CELADE.

Behm, H. (1980) "Socioeconomic Determinants of Mortality in Latin America," in Socioeconomic

Determinants and Consequences of Mortality, Geneva: WHO.

38
Behrman, J.R. (1997) "Mother's Schooling and Child Education," processed, University of

Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.

Behrman, J.R. and A. Deolalikar (1988) "Health and Nutrition," in H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan,

eds., Handbook on Economic Development Vol. 1, Chapter 15, Amsterdam: North Holland

Publishing Company.

Behrman, J.R. and A. Deolalikar (1989) "Seasonal Demands for Nutrient Intakes and Health Status in

Rural South India," in D.E. Sahn, ed., Causes and Implications of Seasonal Variability in

Household Food Security, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Behrman, J.R. and B.L. Wolfe (1984) "More Evidence on Nutrition Demand: Income Seems

Overrated and Women's Schooling Underemphasized," Journal of Development Economics

14:105-128.

Behrman, J.R. and B.L. Wolfe (1989) "Does More Schooling Make Women Better Nourished and

Healthier?" Journal of Human Resources 24:644-663.

Behrman, J.R., N. Birdsall and A. Deolalikar (1995) "Marriage Markets, Labor Markets and

Unobserved Human Capital," Economic Development and Cultural Change 43:585-601.

Behrman, J.R., A. Foster and M.R. Rosenzweig (1997) "Women's Schooling, Home Teaching, and

Economic Growth," Journal of Political Economy, 107(4):632-714.

Benhabib, J. and M.M. Spiegel (1994), “The Role of Human Capital in Economic

Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 34:143-174.

Birdsall, N. and C. Graham (eds.) (2000), New Markets, New Opportunities?, Washington DC:

Carnegie Endowment for International Peace and Brookings Institution.

39
Birdsall, N. and L. O’Connell (1999), “Putting Education to Work in Egypt,” Carnegie

Endowment for International Peace, Global Policy Program Working Paper No. 5, Washington,

DC.

Birdsall, N. and R. Sabot (eds) (1993) Labor Market Discrimination in Developing Countries,

Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Blumberg, R.L. (1988) "Income under Female Versus Male Control," Journal of Family Issues 9:51-

84.

Boserup, E. (1970), Women’s Role in Economic Development, London, St. Martin’s Press.

Boskin, M.J. and E. Sheshinski (1983) "Optimal Tax Treatment for the Family," Journal of Public

Economics 20:281-297.

Boulier, B.L. and M.R. Rosenzweig (1984) "Schooling, Search, and Spouse Selection," Journal of

Political Economy 94:712-732.

Caldwell, J.C. (1979) "Education as a Factor in Mortality Decline," Population Studies 33:395-413.

Card, D., (1999), "The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings," Vol 3A, Chapter30, Handbook of

Labor Economics, (eds) O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Co..

Chernichovsky, D. (1985) "Socioeconomic and Demographic Aspects of School Enrollment and

Attendance in Rural Botswana," Economic Development and Cultural Change 33:319-332.

Cochrane, S.H. (1979) Fertility and Education, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Cochrane, S.H., J. Leslie and D.J. O'Hara (1980) "The Effects of Education on Health," The World

Bank Staff Working Paper 405, Washington, DC.

40
Denison E.F. (1962) The Sources of Economic Growth in the United Stated and the Alternatives

before us, Committee for Economic Development, Supplementary Paper No. 13, New York

Duraisamy, P. (1988) "An Econometric Analysis of Fertility, Child Schooling and Labour Force

Participation of Women in Rural Indian Households," Journal of Quantitative Economics 4:293-

316.

Duraisamy, P., (2000), “Changes in Returns to Education in India, 1983-1994: By Gender, Age-

Cohort, and Location,” Economic Growth Center Paper No. 815, Yale University, New Haven,

CT (forthcoming in Economics of Education Review).

Duraisamy, P. and R. Malathy (1991) "Impact of Public Programs on Fertility and Gender

Specific Investment in Human Capital in Children in Rural India," in Research in Population

Economics, Vol. 7, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

Engel, P.L. (1988) "Intrahousehold Allocation of Resources: Perspective from Psychology," in B.L.

Rogers and N.P. Schlossen, eds., Intrahousehold Resource Allocation, Tokyo: United Nations

University Press.

Fafchamps, M. and A.R. Quisumbing (1999) "Human Capital, Productivity, and Labor Allocation in

Rural Pakistan," Journal of Human Resources 34(2):369-406.

Farah, A.A. and S.H. Preston (1982) "Child Mortality Differentials in Sudan," Population and

Development Review 8:365-383.

Fogel, R.W., (1999), “Catching Up with the Economy,” American Economic Review, 89(1):1-21.

Foster, A. (1996) "Analysis of Household Behavior When Households Choose Their Members,"

processed, University of Pennsylvania.

41
Foster, A, and M, Rosenzweig (1995) "Learning by Doing and Learning from Other: Human Cognital

and Technical Change in Agriculture," Journal of Political Economy, 103(6):1176-1209.

Glewwe, P. and H. Jacoby (1994) "Student Achievement and Schooling Choice in Low Income

Countries: Evidence from Ghana," Journal of Human Resources 29:842-864.

Glewwe, P. and H. Jacoby (1995) "An Economic Analysis of Delayed Primary School Enrollment and

Childhood Malnutrition in a Low Income Country," Review of Economics and Statistics 77:156-

169.

Griliches, Z. (1977) "Estimating the Returns to Schooling," Econometrica 45:1-22.

Haddad, L. and J. Hoddinott (1994) "Women's Income and Boy-Girl Anthropometric Status in Côte

d'Ivoire," World Development 22:545-553.

Haddad, L., J. Hoddinott and H. Alderman (1997) IntraHousehold Resource Allocation in Developing

Countries, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Haveman, R.H. and B.L. Wolfe (1995) "The Determinants of Children's Attainments," Journal of

Economic Literature 33:1829-1878.

Heckman, J.J. (1980) "Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error" in Female Labor Supply, (ed)

J.P. Smith, Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.

Hoddinott, J. and L. Haddad (1995) "Does Female Income Share Influence Household Expenditure,"

Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 57:77-96.

Holmes, J. (1997) "Measuring the Determinants of School Completion in Pakistan: Analysis of

Censoring and Selection," Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 794, Yale University,

New Haven, CT.

42
Huffman, W (1976) "The Value of the Productive Time of Farm Wives," American Journal of

Agricultural Economics 58:836-841.

Jacoby, H. (1994) "Borrowing Constraints and Progress Through School: Evidence from Peru," Review

of Economics and Statistics 76:145-158.

Jorgenson, D.W. (1995) Productivity, Vol I. Postwar U.S. Economic Growth, Cambridge MA: MIT

Press.

Kennedy, E.T. and B. Cogill (1986) "Income and Nutritional Effects of the Commercialization of

Agriculture: The Case of Kenya," Processed, International Food Policy Research Institute,

Washington, DC.

Kennedy, E. and P. Peters (1992) "Household Food Security and Child Nutrition," World Development

20:1077-1085.

Killingsworth, M. (1983) Labor Supply, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

King, E.M. and M.A. Hill (eds), (1993) Women's Education in Developing Countries, World Bank,

Baltimore MD: John Hopkins University, Press.

King, E.M., J.R. Peterson, S.M. Adioetomo, L.J. Domingo and S.H. Syed (1986) Change in the Status

of Women Across Generations in Asia, Santa Monica, CA: The Rand Corporation.

Kremer, M. (1997) "How Much Does Sorting Increase Inequality," Quarterly Journal of Economics

112(1):115-139.

Krueger, A.B. and M. Lindahl (1998), “Education for Growth in Sweden and the World,”

Princeton NJ:Princeton University.

43
Kuznets, S. (1966) Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure, and Spread, New Haven CT, Yale

University, Press

Lam, D., (2000), “Generating Extreme Inequality,” Population Studies Center, University of

Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI.

Lavy, V. (1996) "School Supply Constraints and Children's Educational Outcomes in Rural Ghana,"

Journal of Development Economics 51:291-314.

Lloyd, C.B. and A.K. Blanc (1995) "Children's Schooling in SubSaharan Africa: Role of Fathers,

Mothers, and Others," processed, Population Council, New York, NY.

McCaffery, E.J. (1997), Taxing Women, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.

Malathy, R. (1993) "Women's Choice of Work and Fertility in Urban Tamil Nadu, India," Economic

Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 695, Yale University, New Haven, CT.

Mensch, B., H. Lentzner and S. Preston (1985) Socioeconomic Differentials in Child Mortality in

Developing Countries, New York, NY: United Nations.

Mincer, J. (1974) Schooling Experience and Earnings, New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

NaRanong, V. (1998) "Gender, Credit Constraints, and Education in Rural Thailand," Economic

Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 792, Yale University, New Haven, CT.

National Research Council (1986) Population Growth and Economic Development: Policy Questions,

Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

Psacharopoulos, G. and M. Woodhall (1985) Education for Development, New York, NY: Oxford

University Press.

44
Quisumbing, A.R. (1995) "The Extended Family and Intrahousehold Allocation," Food Consumption

and Nutrition Division, Dis. Paper 3, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington,

DC.

Quisumbing, A.R. (1996) "Male-Female Differences in Agricultural Productivity," World Development

24:1579-1595.

Rosenzweig, M.R. and R.E. Evenson (1977) "Fertility, Schooling and the Economic Contribution of

Children in Rural India," Econometrica 45(5):1065-1080.

Rosenzweig, M.R. and T.P. Schultz (1982a) "Child Mortality and Fertility in Colombia," Health Policy

and Education 2:305-348.

Rosenzweig, M.R. and T.P. Schultz (1982b) "Market Opportunities, Genetic Endowments and the

Intrafamily Distribution of Resources," American Economic Review 72:803-815.

Rosenzweig, M.R. and K.J. Wolpin (1994) "Are There Increasing Returns to Intergenerational

Production of Human Capital," Journal of Human Resources 29:670-693.

Schultz, T.P. (1973) "A Preliminary Survey of Economic Analysis of Fertility," American Economic

Review, 63:(2):77-78.

Schultz, T.P. (1980) "Interpretation of Relations among Mortality, Economics of the Household, and the

Health Environment," in Socioeconomic Determinants and Consequences of Mortality

Differentials, Geneva: WHO.

Schultz, T.P. (1981) Economics of Population, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

Schultz, T.P. (1988) "Educational Investment and Returns," in H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan, eds.,

Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 1, Chapter 13, Amsterdam: North Holland.

45
Schultz, T.P. (1990) "Women's Changing Participation in the Labor Force," Economic Development

and Cultural Change 38:451-488.

Schultz, T.P. (1994) "Marital Status and Fertility in the United States," Journal of Human Resources

29:637-669.

Schultz, T.P., ed. (1995a) Investment in Women's Human Capital, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago

Press.

Schultz, T.P. (1995b) "Human Capital and Development," in Agricultural Competitiveness, 22nd

International Conference of Agricultural Economics, (eds) G.H. Peters et al., Aldershot, England:

Dartmouth Pub. Co.

Schultz, T.P. (1996) "The Demand for Children in Low Income Countries," Vol. 1, Chapter 13,

Handbook of Population and Family Economics, (eds.) M.R. Rosenzweig and O. Stark,

Amsterdam: North Holland Pub. Co.

Schultz, T.P. (1998) "Women’s Roles in the Agricultural Household, Bargaining and Human Capital

Investments," Agricultural and Resource Economic Handbook, (ed), B. Gardner and G. Rausser,

Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Co. (forthcoming).`

Schultz, T.P., (2000), “Progresa’s Impact on School Enrollments from 1997/98 to 1998/99,”

International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC.

Schultz, T.W. (1961) "Investments in Human Capital," American Economic Review, 51(1):1-17.

Sedlacek, G. (2001), “Three-in-One Social Policy: Insurance, Assistance, and Investment through

Latin America’s Conditional Targeted Transfers,” Inter-American Development Bank,

Washington, DC.

46
Senauer, B., D. Sahn and H. Alderman (1986) "The Effects of the Value of Time on Food Consumption

Patterns in Developing Countries: Evidence from Sri Lanka," American Journal of Agricultural

Economics 68:920-927.

Sipahimalani, V. (1999) "Education in Rural India," unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University,

New Haven, CT.

Smith, J.P. (ed.), (1980) Female Labor Supply, Princeton NJ, Princeton University Press.

Solon, G., (1999), “Intergenerational Mobility in the Labor Market,” in D. Ashenfelter and D.

Card (eds)Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3, Chapter 29, Elsevier Science, Amsterdam.

Strauss, J. (1986) "Does Better Nutrition Raise Farm Productivity?", Journal of Political Economy

94:297-320.

Strauss, J. and K. Beegle (1996) "Intrahousehold Allocations," MSU International Development

Working Paper No. 62, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI.

Strauss, J. and D. Thomas (1995) "Human Resources: Empirical Modeling of Household and Family

Decisions," in J. Behrman and T.N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook in Development Economics, Vol.

3A, Chapter 34, Amsterdam: Elsevier.

Strauss, J. and D. Thomas (1998) "Health, Nutrition and Economic Development," Journal of Economic

Literature 36(2):766-817.

Subbarao, K. and L. Ramey (1995) "Social Gains from Female Education," Economic Development

and Cultural Change 44(1):105-128.

Tansel, A. (1997) "Schooling Attainment, Parental Education, and Gender in Côte d'Ivoire and Ghana,"

Economic Development and Cultural Change 45:825-856.

Thomas, D. (1990) "Intra Household Resource Allocation: An Inferential Approach," Journal of Human

Resources 25:635-664.

47
Thomas, D. (1994) "Like Father, Like Son; Like Mother, Like Daughter," Journal of Human Resources

29:950-989.

Thomas, D. and C.L. Chen (1994) "Income Shares and Shares of Income: Empirical Tests of Models of

Household Resource Allocation," Working Paper 94-08, Santa Monica, CA: The Rand

Corporation.

Thomas, D., J. Strauss, and M.H. Henriques (1990) "Child Survival, Height for Age and Household

Characteristics," Journal of Development Economics 33:197-234.

World Bank Staff, (2001), Engendering Development Through Gender Equality in Rights,

Resources, and Voice, World Bank and Oxford University Press, New York.

48

You might also like