Financial Viability Appraisal in Planning Decisions: Theory and Practice
Financial Viability Appraisal in Planning Decisions: Theory and Practice
Financial Viability Appraisal in Planning Decisions: Theory and Practice
April 2015
Financial Viability Appraisal
in Planning Decisions:
Theory And Practice
rics.org/research
Financial Viability Appraisal
in Planning Decisions:
Theory And Practice
rics.org/research
Peter Wyatt
Professor of Real Estate Appraisal
School of Real Estate & Planning
Henley Business School, University of Reading
p.wyatt@reading.ac.uk
Amanprit Johal
Global Research and Policy Manager
ajohal@rics.org
Pratichi Chatterjee
Funded by:
Global Research & Policy Officer
pchatterjee@rics.org
Contents
1.0 Introduction .................................................................................................... 5
2.0 Background ..................................................................................................... 6
2.1 Viability in forward planning............................................................. 7
2.2 Viability in site-specific appraisals................................................. 8
2.2.1 Estimation of scheme-specific development profit................... 9
2.2.2 Handling of development finance (and tax)................................... 9
2.2.3 Input uncertainty..............................................................................10
2.2.4 Estimation of land value..................................................................10
3.0 Viability appraisals for site-specific decision-taking
in planning ......................................................................................................13
3.1 Legislation..........................................................................................13
3.2 Government guidance......................................................................13
3.3 Industry guidance.............................................................................15
4.0 Viability appraisals in planning appeals .......................................17
4.1 Modelling approach...........................................................................17
4.2 Input uncertainty..............................................................................18
4.3 Profit....................................................................................................18
4.4 Finance.................................................................................................18
4.5 Landowner’s return...........................................................................19
5.0 Discussion ......................................................................................................22
6.0 Conclusions ...................................................................................................26
7.0 References ....................................................................................................27
8.0 Appendices ....................................................................................................28
8.1 Appendix A: Threshold Land Value.................................................29
8.2 Appendix B: Planning Appeals ........................................................32
9.0 Acknowledgements ..................................................................................39
List of Figures
Figure 1 Components of development value..........................................................19
Figure 2 Components of land value I.........................................................................19
Figure 3 RLVs for residential, commercial and industrial land uses.................23
Figure 4 Components of land value II........................................................................23
1.0 Introduction
The aim of this research project is to formulate consistent
approaches to land valuation within site-specific development
viability appraisal (DVA) based on a critical evaluation of the
theory and practice of appraisal. The project develops the
current research agenda into development appraisal and
valuation and its specific application within DVA in the UK.
It builds on research carried out by the University of Reading
over the last three years that has examined development
appraisal theory and practice, identifying a number of issues
inherent in development appraisal modelling in general, and
particular issues concerning the application to DVA.
This project categorises these modelling issues and
developed a set of research questions, which were then
addressed using a case study methodology. The cases
were drawn from the increasing number of disputes
concerning the level of planning obligations on individual
sites. The methodology included a document analysis of
proofs of evidence and decisions.
Section 2 of this report provides the background to the
research by discussing the viability issues that arise in
both area-wide and scheme-specific DVAs. Section 3 then
reviews the policy and guidance that has been published by
government ans industry in relation to DVA practice. Section
4 reports the findings of the empirical investigation of issues
arising from scheme-specific planning appeals.
2.0 Background
The grant of planning permission to change the use of positive residual amount that is sufficient to persuade
or to physically alter a piece of land usually leads to uplift the landowner to sell, this indicates viability. The basic
in value, often referred to as ‘development value’. There equation for calculating site value is:
have been attempts by the UK Government in the past to
capture some or even all of this uplift for the benefit of the
community (Allmendinger, 2011). However, a development
Value of completed development
value tax of this kind is not current policy. Instead, local
government is able to legally impose planning obligations Less Development costs (including planning
and infrastructure levies on landowners upon grant of obligations and infrastructure levy)
planning permission so long as they do not jeopardise the
Less Developer’s profit
economic viability of the proposed development.
Equals Residual land value
A development viability appraisal or DVA tests
economic viability. It is a financial model that is based
on the ‘residual method’ of land valuation because the
residual amount is that which is left to bid for the land So the uplift in land value from existing use value to
after deducting the estimated costs associated with a residual land value must adequately compensate the
development from the estimated value of the completed landowner, the developer and the community (in terms of
scheme. As well as construction costs and risk-adjusted planning obligations and CIL). DVAs are typically carried
return to the developer, the cost of planning obligations out at two stages in the planning process: at the policy
and the Community Infrastructure Levy (CIL) must also setting or forward planning stage and at the scheme-
be deducted from the development value. If there is a specific development control stage.
2.1 Viability in forward planning Financial viability appraisals are therefore necessary to
assess the extent to which a planning policy can be met
Christophers (2014) notes that the first official recognition or the extent to which adverse impacts of development
of viability in planning was in relation to the delivery can be mitigated. Often referred to as ‘area-wide’ DVAs
of affordable housing through the use of planning they typically consist of a set of valuations of hypothetical
obligations. Circular 6/98 (DETR, 1998) advised local development sites across a local authority area at a
authorities to ensure financially viability when negotiating particular point in time. The valuations incorporate the
the amount of affordable housing that could be supplied estimated financial implications of the proposed level of
from a development scheme. Circular 05/2005 (ODPM, planning obligations.
2005) provided guidance for planners when testing the To determine viability the estimated site values are
economic viability of planning obligations: viability was benchmarked against a ‘threshold land value’ (see
defined as a site’s ability to remain sufficiently “profitable” Appendix A for an explanation of threshold land value) and
at a given level of planning obligations. As the idea of therefore the basis on which this threshold is established
viability testing took hold, its remit was extended from site- and the level at which it is set is critical to development
specific development management to forward planning. viability appraisal at the policy-setting (area-wide) level.
PPS12 (DCLG, 2008) stated that viability considerations Essentially it is an estimate of the value at which a
should constitute part of the evidence base in Core landowner would be prepared to sell. If the estimated site
Strategies and other Development Plan Documents, and values are higher than the threshold land value the policy
PPS3 (DCLG, 2011) required local authorities to set targets target is considered viable. Local authorities are required
for affordable housing and to assess the likely economic to assess the likely cumulative impact on viability resulting
viability of these targets. Following the enactment of the from existing and proposed development regulations (such
2008 Planning Act by the then Labour Government and as the Code for Sustainable Homes), planning obligations
the introduction of the 2010 Community Infrastructure (including affordable housing requirements) and CILs.
Levy Regulations1 by the Liberal Democrat / Conservative According to the NPPF (DCLG, 2012: 42) the cumulative
coalition Government, local authorities are able to set a impact should not put implementation of the development
CIL for offsite infrastructure. As with planning obligations, plan at serious risk and should facilitate development
CIL is also subject to a viability test. throughout the economic cycle, in other words, be kept
The National Planning Policy Framework (NPPF), under review.
published in 2012, supersedes earlier planning policy Crosby et al (2013) discuss the methodological issues
in relation to planning obligations. It retains the need for surrounding area-wide DVAs, focusing on the inability of
forward plans to ensure that “… the scale of development conventional valuation techniques to deal with multi-site
identified in the plan should not be subject to such a scale appraisals and market shifts. Essentially, policy is set for
of obligations and policy burdens that their ability to be wide areas and enforced over long periods of time and
developed viably is threatened.” More specifically, with the viability testing methods struggle to deal with this.
regard to the issue of viability in particular, the level of The main issues surrounding area-wide DVA are therefore:
planning obligations
• The difficulty in spatially and temporally extrapolating
“… should, when taking account of the normal cost from a set of time-specific hypothetical sites to actual
of development and mitigation, provide competitive development sites;
returns to a willing land owner and willing developer
to enable the development to be deliverable” • Confusion over the approach to DVA for area-wide
(DCLG, 2012: 41) applications in relation to forecasting (or not) of growth
in revenue and inflation in costs; and
• The impact of using size-based levies on development
sites that are marginal in viability terms.
1 SI 2010 No 948
2.2.3 Input uncertainty There are examples of DVA studies which include a dozen
or more input variables, together with modelled changes
It is common practice to incorporate current values and
to these variables, that result in vast quantities of tabulated
costs in a development appraisal. For schemes expected
results that attempt to illustrate the sensitivity of the
to take a long time to complete or undertaken in phases,
output to changes in the inputs. How this output is used
two alternatives have evolved, re-appraisals and projection
is unclear, no indication of risk or probability is attached
models. With regard to the former it is unclear whether
to the output so the output is simply an array of possible
and what type of review mechanisms are employed by
output values.
vendors of development sites to try and capture potential
future revenue gains. Little is known about the structure, The impact of this uncertainty surrounding the inputs
triggers and so on (delayed starts and longer schemes) can be taken into account in development appraisal.
of these arrangements. With regard to the latter, revenue In some basic appraisals this can be as straightforward
from development is received on completion (usually) so as a contingency allowance on costs and the adoption
the rate of value change over the development period of a suitably high risk-adjusted return to the risk-
will influence the amount received. This can be assessed taker. However, there is also the ability to apply more
in either real or nominal terms. If the finance rate and sophisticated risk analysis techniques for identifying the
developer’s risk-adjusted return are real rates, i.e. impact on the outcome; sensitivity analysis, scenario
inflation-adjusted then the cash flow must be real (rather testing and simulation for example. This research
than nominal) too. However, it would appear that often will attempt to identify the level of risk analysis within
no forecasting of costs or revenue is undertaken due no planning appeals.
doubt to the level of uncertainty surrounding future value
change. However, it would also appear that the finance 2.2.4 Estimation of land value
rates applied are nominal which imply nominal change in
Granting planning permission for a change of use creates
values. Over short time periods the resulting inaccuracy
uplift in land value. To encourage supply, part of this uplift
may be small but for larger schemes with lengthy
will flow to landowners. To encourage development to
development periods it could be much greater.
take place, an appropriate level of return to developers is
Appraisers are also uncertain about current levels of required to compensate for risk. Within this context, local
costs and revenues. The output from a development authorities are required to set economically viable targets
viability model is very sensitive to changes in key inputs; for planning obligations and levies that are sustainable
rental and capital value, building costs and development over wide geographical areas and long periods of time.
period in particular, but many of the other inputs are ratios This is proving difficult and the moribund market has
of these key inputs. For instance, asset disposal fees are compounded the difficulties. Setting obligations and levies
expressed as a percentage of revenue; professional fees too high risks choking off supply and development of
are expressed as a percentage of construction costs; that supply, too low allows developers and landowners
profit is assumed to be a percentage of cost or revenue. to make excessive returns compared to the amount
In essence, estimates of future fees are affected by given back to the community. Where the developer or
uncertainty in: current levels of the input variable landowner believes their rewards are too low, these area-
(e.g. construction costs), estimated change in the level wide targets are tested on a scheme-by-scheme basis
of the input variable (e.g. building cost inflation), the using DVA.
parameter (e.g. fee rates) and future changes in the
Scheme-specific DVA involves inputting estimates of
parameters. As a consequence these ratios inputs are
expected revenue and expenditure, including planning
also stochastic variables.
obligations (whether affordable housing and/or CIL) and
It is well understood that development is an activity with the output is sometimes a profit sum but more usually
very high operational gearing and a degree of uncertainty a residual land value (RLV). The first approach raises
attached to the input value estimates due to poor data the question, where did the land value input come from?
availability, heterogeneity of sites, and volatility within The second approach raises the question, where did
and between markets (construction, capital/finance and the profit level come from, as discussed in section
various demand sectors). These characteristics mean 2.2.1 above.
that it is not difficult to make (justifiable, defensible) minor
Focusing on the second, more common, approach, RLV
alterations to modelling and input assumptions in order
can be either before or after policy compliant planning
to make significant changes to the output from the DVA
obligations. Where it is after planning obligations have
that would support a particular perspective. Moreover,
been deducted, the RLV can be compared to current
in some models the sheer number of inputs that can be
use value to determine the size of the uplift in land
legitimately included in a DVA may give the impression of
value. If this uplift is enough to persuade the landowner
spurious model accuracy, and the resultant detail that the
release the land for development then the site is viable.
model must deal with can encourage calculative practices.
However, the landowner’s decision may be influenced “The residual land value method of determining viability
by a number of issues; the size of uplift compared to assumes that a viable development will support a residual
the current use value, the size of the uplift compared land value at level sufficiently above the site’s existing use
to the cost of the planning obligations, any legitimate value (EUV) or alternative use value (AUV) to support a
alternative use value and the landowner’s expectations land acquisition price acceptable to the landowner.”
of how the policy situation may change are examples. HCA (2009)
Another influence particularly relevant to this paper is any
“An objective financial viability test of the ability of a
expectation that they can use the existing planning policy
development project to meet its costs including the cost
framework to reduce the amount of planning obligations
of planning obligations, whilst ensuring an appropriate site
that will have to be paid to the community. This issue may
value for the landowner and a market risk adjusted return
also be influential in determining the price a developer may
to the developer in delivering that project.” RICS (2012b)
be prepared to pay the landowner.
The concepts “competitive returns to a willing landowner”
The RLV can also be determined before policy compliant
(op cit), “price acceptable to the landowner” and “appropriate
planning obligations have been deducted. In this case, the
site value for the landowner” that are included in the National
difference between the RLV and the current use value is the
Planning Policy Framework are closely linked to the concept
amount available to persuade the landowner to release the
of threshold land value. Whilst the words ‘competitive’,
land and to fund the planning obligations. A key question
‘acceptable’ and ‘appropriate’ are somewhat nebulous, it
is how much of this uplift should go to the landowner to
is generally accepted that the landowner should receive an
provide sufficient incentive to sell? In other words, at what
additional sum over and above the amount that they could
price or threshold land value (somewhere between residual
sell the site assuming that it remained in its existing use.
land value excluding planning obligations and current use
value) would the landowner be prepared to sell? Recent guidance has attempted to define threshold land
value as “… the value at which a typical willing landowner
Previous research indicates no consensus regarding either
is likely to release land for development, before payment
the derivation or the level of threshold land value. Nearly
of taxes….” (LHDG, 2012: 28). If a site has no possibility
half of the studies investigated by Coleman et al (2012)
of permission for an alternative use then the starting point
regarded a scheme as viable if the residual land value
is based on its existing use only. If there is a prospect
exceeded a threshold land value that was equivalent to
of permission for alternative use(s) (for example, in a
existing or alternative use value. A similar number added a
development plan for an alternative use) there may be a
premium of 15-30% of either the existing or alternative use
higher alternative use value. If the site has planning consent
value as an incentive to the landowner to sell. A minority of
for an alternative use then a usually higher land value
studies specified market values as benchmarks, the basis
results. The alternative use land value then becomes the
indicated within a RICS Guidance Note (RICS, 2012b).
starting point for assessing threshold land value, although
Clearly the landowner requires some level of financial this use may also have planning obligations attached,
incentive over and above current use value. Estimating which would complicate the issue. Essentially threshold
this incentive is difficult because it attempts to quantify land value is based on existing use value plus a proportion
the amount of land value uplift that should go to the of uplift. The actual price at which a landowner would sell
landowner and the amount that should go to the will, by definition, be a market price or value. Market value
community. It is, essentially, a question of how the uplift is defined as an exchange price (IVS 2013) and theoretically
in land value, or betterment, should be distributed. So will have priced in planning policy requirements. In practical
the key unresolved question concerns the appropriate terms the identification of residual land value, existing use
allocation of the uplift between landowner and community. value, alternative use value and market value requires
myriad assumptions and this is confounding the setting of
As indicated earlier, if there is uncertainty over the level
policy and the drafting of guidance.
of planning obligations payable then this will increase
the option value element of land value (due to increased Many of the key issues can be illustrated by a simple
volatility), thus increasing land prices. This can lead to example. A site currently used as farmland has an existing
higher land prices in the market and a threshold land use value of £100 as evidenced by agricultural land sales
value that is based on market value will also increase. where there is absolutely no hope of any development in
Developers will appeal to have planning obligations foreseeable future. The site is allocated for employment
reduced and, if successful, this creates an environment use in the Local Plan. With this alternative use, the value is
of further uncertainty (as local authorities review their estimated to be £1,000 although, given local oversupply,
planning obligation targets downwards), higher land there is currently little demand from developers for such
prices and the process repeats. sites. There are no planning obligations tied to permission
for this use. If planning permission were granted for
It is not surprising that land value is therefore at the heart
residential development, it is estimated that the site would
of both the 2009 Homes and Communities Agency and
be valued at £10,000 assuming no planning obligations.
2012 RICS definitions of viability:
• Given the impact of taxation on finance it is odd that no In the section entitled ‘decision taking’, which sets out
mention of handling of tax is provided. policy in relation to site-specific planning (as opposed to
local plan making), the National Planning Policy Framework
(DCLG, 2012) does not mention viability. However, a viability
guidance note published recently (NPPF, 2014) provides
some direction in relation to viability for plan making and
decision taking. Of particular interest here is the guidance
in relation to viability appraisal for decision taking, which
raises a number of methodological questions.
2 http://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/2013/27/contents/enacted 3 http://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/1990/8/contents
The guidance begins by stating that “[d]ecision-taking obligations, and finance costs; the latter proving to be a
on individual schemes does not normally require an particularly complicated input to deal with on a scheme-
assessment of viability. However viability can be important specific basis. Perhaps the most challenging assumption
where planning obligations or other costs are being is the level of developer’s profit. First, should it be
introduced. In these cases decisions must be underpinned expressed as a cash sum percentage of costs or value
by an understanding of viability …” It also states that or should it be expressed as an annual rate of return.
“[t]here is no standard answer to questions of viability, nor The guidance acknowledges that the “return will vary
is there a single approach for assessing viability.” Whilst significantly between projects to reflect the size and risk
it seems reasonable for there to be variation in method, profile of the development and the risks to the project”
if there are no standard answers to questions of viability and recommends that a “rigid approach to assumed profit
then how are they to be resolved? Perhaps what is meant levels should be avoided and comparable schemes or data
here is that there may be no universal assumptions for sources reflected wherever possible.” In practice, this kind
developer’s profit, finance costs, threshold land value of information is rarely released into the public domain.
and so on. But should there be a common decision
Having taken these inputs into account, the resultant land
rule… Indeed, it would seem that there is one when it is
value should “… be informed by comparable, market-
stated that a “… site is viable if the value generated by its
based evidence wherever possible.” It is not clear whether
development exceeds the costs of developing it and also
this evidence relates to the existing use value of the site,
provides sufficient incentive for the land to come forward
alternative use values or whether it should include market
and the development to be undertaken.”
evidence for similar sites that have been granted planning
As with the Growth and Infrastructure Act, this guidance permission for developments comparable to the subject
suggests that viability assessments in decision-taking site. The latter would reflect levels of planning obligations
should be based on current costs and values except for at the time of the transaction so this raises a circularity
schemes that require phased delivery over the medium issue, as it is the level of planning obligations that is
and longer term (time periods that are not defined) when being estimated. The guidance states that the value
forecasts of costs and value may be considered. How “… will need to provide an incentive for the landowner
these forecasts might be undertaken at the scheme- to sell in comparison with the other options available.
specific level is not addressed. Those options may include the current use value of the
land or its value for a realistic alternative use that complies
The guidance continues in similarly ambiguous terms:
with planning policy.” Furthermore the guidance states
estimates of costs should be based on robust evidence
that, where transacted bids are significantly above the
that is reflective of market conditions. Build costs should
market norm, they should not be used as part of this
be based on appropriate data and should include
exercise. How these overbids are identified is not clear.
abnormal costs, infrastructure, policy costs and planning
3.3 Industry guidance This means that site value (whether an input into or output
from the model) should be based upon the market value
In 2012 the Highbury Group on Housing Delivery published of comparable land but taking into account planning policy
a note on development viability appraisals that referred to (in particular policy compliant planning obligations) as they
viability testing of individual schemes. It suggests that there exist now rather than at the date(s) of the market evidence.
is only a need for scheme-specific financial appraisals if The problem that arises is that the basis for this adjustment
the application is not policy compliant. The note becomes is what the viability appraisal is supposed to be identifying –
rather unclear on the matter of cost assumptions. It clearly a circular argument whereby the market value should
suggests that the appraisal should “… relate to the specific take into account the level of policy compliant planning
costs and values of a known development proposal based obligations but that market value will then be part of the
on the facts available at a specific point in time” but that assessment process by which the amount of planning
an “… assessment can model different development obligations are judged. Section 2.3.2 actually states this:
options and scenarios for different costs and values over
a development period.” It is ambiguous over whether that “Any assessment of Site Value … will have regard
means both a best estimate and a risk analysis around to prospective planning obligations and the point of
that estimate are required. the viability appraisal is to assess the extent of these
obligations while also having regard to the prevailing
Also in 2012 the Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors property market.”
published a guidance note (RICS, 2012b), which focuses in
the main on site-specific DVA. The guidance recommends Paragraph 3.4.5 on page 18 tries to capture it more fully.
a conventional residual approach to the determination It states that:
of either developer’s return or land value. Whichever “The Site Value will be based on market value, which
of these outputs is chosen it should be compared will be risk-adjusted, so it will normally be less than
to a corresponding ‘benchmark’ (page 4). The RICS current market prices for development land for which
recommends market value as a basis for determining planning permission has been secured and planning
an appropriate threshold land value. On page 12 the obligation requirements are known. The practitioner will
guidance states that: have regard to current use value, alternative use value,
“Site Value should equate to the market value subject market/ transactional evidence (including the property
to the following assumption: that the value has regard itself if that has recently been subject to a disposal/
to development plan policies and all other material acquisition), and all material considerations including
planning considerations and disregards that which planning policy in deriving the Site Value.”
is contrary to the development plan.” RICS (2012b)
The Planning Portal4 records details of planning appeals the estimation of residual land value or developer’s profit
and disputes over levels of planning obligations and these either included or excluded planning obligations (both
reveal some of the key issues raised above. It is therefore approaches have been adopted within the appeals)
timely to identify these cases and carry out a detailed also used a residual approach. Whether a cash flow or
document analysis of them to investigate the viability traditional residual was adopted was not a main issue in
issues that have arisen. Planning appeals uploaded to the any of the cases. The exception to this was the estimation
Planning Portal by the 20 November 2014 were accessed of existing use value which is often a comparative approach
and the search criteria specified appeals that had been not involving any development appraisal modelling.
completed by this date in England and included ‘planning
The general approach was to estimate the residual land
obligations’ as an appeal issue. A further refinement
value (RLV) of the development site taking into account cost
was that only appeals made by landowners, developers
of planning obligations and an appropriate return (profit) to
and house-builders were selected. A search based on
the developer. The amount of planning obligations would
these criteria returned 99 appeals. On inspection of the
reflect the policy target for affordable housing in the locality.
local authority websites, supporting documentation was
If the resulting RLV was higher than the existing use value
available for 32 cases. Summary details of these appeals
of the site and high enough to persuade the landowner to
are set out in Appendix B.
sell (i.e. it provides an adequate return) then the proposed
The examination of these appeals concentrated on development scheme was considered viable. If the RLV
the approach to appraisal modelling and, following the was negative, viability testing is undertaken at a range
discussion of viability modelling issues identified from the of affordable housing targets to determine what amount
literature review, the main categories for analysis were might be acceptable to both parties. Alternatively, where
identified as; choice of modelling approach, dealing with profit was the output, the viability appraisal tested whether
input uncertainty, assumptions regarding developer’s profit, the level of profit, expressed as a simple return on value
treatment of finance and benchmarking landowner’s return. or cost, was adequate for the developer. Again, in cases
where it appeared to fall below a reasonable level, the
4.1 Modelling approach determination assessed the level of planning obligations
required to create an acceptable return to the developer.
The precise details of the methods used were generally The two main issues that result are the basis of land value
not stated explicitly in the appeal documents but the use required where the output was profit and the basis of
of some form of residual approach; either expressed as profit where the outcome was land value. Allied to these
a cash flow or a traditional residual, was virtually universal. issues are the benchmarks against which the outputs are
More specifically, the residual method was used to assessed. If the output is a RLV then what should this be
estimate developer’s profit (where land value was an input), compared to (i.e. what is an acceptable return to the land
residual land value (where developer’s profit was an input) owner) and if the output is profit, what is an acceptable
or alternative use value. In addition, appeal cases involving profit margin?
4 http://www.planningportal.gov.uk
4.2 Input uncertainty In this case, in the model put forward by the appellant, the
default settings were 20% of GDV for private sales and
It is widely accepted that input uncertainty is a major issue 10% of GDV for affordable housing (and 20% on the costs
in valuation as a whole (IVS, 2014) and in development of commercial land use), resulting in a blended target profit
appraisal in particular (Coleman et al, 2012). Risk analysis margin of 18% of GDV. Larger schemes are regarded as
is a basic part of any development appraisal but it appears more risky, hence the relatively high benchmark set for
to be only intermittently carried out in the appeal cases. the Shinfield Road site, which was for 126 dwellings. In
the Poplar Business Park case (APP/E5900/A/217892) the
Forecasting of costs and values has been attempted profit margin for affordable housing was assumed to be
in a few cases but was rejected in 2008 in Godalming 7% of GDV, and the scheme was regarded as unviable.
(APP/R3650/A/08/2063055) and in 2009 in Bristol (APP Consequently, the inspector determined a 20% affordable
P0110/A/08/2069226). However, also in 2009, it was housing provision against a 35% target.
deemed reasonable for multi-phase schemes developable
over many years (Lydney APP/P165/A/08/2082407). Given that not all of the development viability appraisals
In the same year, the inspector rejected forecasting were based on the standard residual model but had
in another large development site at Innsworth in elements of cash flow within them, it might be expected
Gloucester (APP/G1630/A/09/2097181). But this inspector that the pre-finance IRR and the project IRR of the
recommended that in large longer term developments development cash flow would have been preferred
a further review during the development period was benchmarks but this was not the case. Even when IRR
undertaken, acknowledging that viability moves through was calculated, it was the basic returns on GDV and/or
time. This approach was later adopted in Beverley (APP/ cost which dominated discussions on viability.
E2001/V/08/1203215) in 2010.
Basic risk analysis in the form of sensitivity analysis 4.4 Finance
has been carried out on some valuations within some
schemes but the impact this had on the decisions is Assumptions regarding finance are linked to those relating
unclear within the inspector reports. to profit. 100% debt financing appears to be universal
and unchallenged and even the rate used appears non-
contentious with 7% adopted in four out of five cases
4.3 Profit where it is mentioned. As stated above, the return to the
developer is included as a cash sum, calculated as a ratio
There is no evidence from the appraisals that there is a to total development costs or gross development value.
generally accepted level of profit from development. In In reality very few developments are funded using 100%
evidence for the Clay Farm and Glebe Farm, Cambridge debt finance. Instead financing arrangements are usually
appeal (APP/Q0505/A/09/2103592 & 99) the developer’s a mixture of debt and equity funding and the developer
target return was quoted to be in the band of 18% to typically funds a proportion of the development costs as
21% of GDV. In the Jericho Canalside, Oxford appeal an equity provider. Consequently a true measure of return
(APP/G3110/A/08/2070447) it was agreed that the target on the developer’s investment should be a function of this
should be 15% of GDV or 20% of costs although they equity stake, i.e. a return on equity or, more correctly, an
also agreed that this was site specific and would vary equity IRR.
depending on the state of the market, the site and the
scheme. However, in the majority of cases where the
level of developer’s profit is discussed, figures equal
to or in excess of the two targets agreed at Jericho
were used. In the Shinfield Road, Reading case (APP/
X0360/A/12/2179141) the Inspector determined that:
“The appellants supported their calculations by
providing letters and emails from six national house-
builders who set out their net profit margin targets for
residential developments. The figures ranged from a
minimum of 17% to 28%, with the usual target being in
the range 20-25%. Those that differentiated between
market and affordable housing in their correspondence
did not set different profit margins. Due to the level and
nature of the supporting evidence, I give great weight it.
I conclude that the national house-builders’ figures are
to be preferred and that a figure of 20% of GDV, which
is at the lower end of the range, is reasonable.”
Figure 2 illustrates the uplift in land value from existing Uplift to community
use value (EUV) that is possible when a site is granted Threshold land value
Uplift
planning permission. A rational landowner would require
a premium over and above EUV to compensate for the Uplift to landowner
fact that the land has some development potential. In a Existing land value
DVA, the remaining share of the uplift up to the full RLV is Value in existing use
assumed to take the form of planning obligations. The key (disregarding hope value)
issue, therefore, is estimating what the landowner would
regard as an acceptable premium over and above EUV.
This determines the benchmark or threshold land value
From figure 2 it can be seen that, all else being equal,
the higher the EUV, the less uplift is available for planning
obligations. There have been cases (discussed below)
in which developers have sought to determine the level
of threshold land value by reference to the price paid for
the site. This raises an important practical question about
the assumptions made by both sellers and purchasers.
Purchasers could have paid too little or too much for a site
based on inaccurate assumptions; perhaps purchasers’
expectations in terms of planning permission were
unrealistic for example. Also, ‘perceived’ high and low
prices may be due to the fact that prices are a distribution.
There is an extensive real estate literature on valuation
accuracy and bias that suggests a wide variation in
valuations and prices in both residential and commercial
markets; with development sites being cited as one of the
most variable situations. These issues of valuation and
price uncertainty affect both price based and valuation-
based approaches to DVA.
Second, given that development land values are residuals Ref APP/C1950/A/09/2113786). Later in the same year,
and highly geared in relation to development values and the Planning Inspectorate dismissed an appeal in London
costs, prices of development land can be volatile in the (Appeal Ref APP/E5900/A/10/2127467) in which the
short term. An historic price may have been right at the developer argued that the current site value should be
time but should that price be relevant to a viability appraisal based on the price paid for the site back in September
undertaken at a different time in a different market state? 2007 (£13m) marked down using a land price index to
Perhaps more pertinently as far as DVA is concerned, what a value of £9.3m. The current use value of the site in its
if a purchaser paid a price that reflected the possibility that industrial use was approximately £3m and, together with
they could appeal the level of policy compliant planning the Council’s estimate of residual land value at £6m, this
obligations under the current viability regime? meant that the policy target of 35% affordable housing
was viable.
Regardless of the motivation, if values have fallen, a
threshold land value within the DVA based on purchase It would appear that developers trying to use the price
price would be at a level higher than current values would they paid for the site in the DVA are not succeeding if it is
suggest. This, in turn, would reduce the share available for decided that either they overpaid for the site by not taking
planning obligations, passing some of the value that would the correct level of planning obligations into account when
otherwise flow to the community back to the developer. purchasing or the price is out of date. Where the price is
recent and perceived to be a “correct” price, it might be
The use of price in DVA has been the subject of a number
taken into account. The next question that arises from the
of appeals. In 2005, an appeal decision in Norwich
appeals concerning land value is what should threshold
(Appeal Ref APP/G2625/A/04/1154768) rejected price paid
land value be based upon if it is not purchase price?
in favour of a valuation that reflected the cost assumptions
relating to the known policy planning obligations. However, A second possibility discussed in the guidance and
in contrast to the Norwich decision, in a later 2006 case in allowed in some appeals is the existing use value with or
Chilworth, the purchase price was used (Appeal Ref APP/ without an uplift to persuade a landowner to bring the
Y3615/A/06/2016787). The decisions continued to flip-flop land forward. The uplift appears arbitrary. In the case of
and in April 2008, in Homerton Road, London, it was Hampton Hill (APP/L5810/A/05/1181361) in 2007, both
decided that site value should not be based on purchase parties agreed that existing use value should be the basis
price. But the reason was that in this particular case the for the threshold land value. The local authority argued that
price was too high and had ignored policy requirements no uplift should be applied and that the landowner should
(Appeal Ref APP/U5360/A/07/2059530). However, later therefore accept existing use value only as an acceptable
that same year, using an appraisal model where land cost return. The appellant argued that the threshold land value
went in as an input and developer’s profit was the output, should be EUV plus 25%. The Inspector found for the
a developer successfully argued that the site value should appellant. However, in the Flambard’s Way, Godalming
be based on purchase price (Jericho, Oxford Appeal Ref appeal in 2008 (APP/R3650/A/08/2063055), although
APP/G3110/A/08/2070447). Given that the site was sold the Inspector also favoured a threshold land value that
by tender and other bids were close to the purchase price, was based upon EUV, the Secretary of State called in the
the inspector accepted its relevance even though it had appeal and preferred a market value approach.
taken place nine months earlier. The appeal was upheld
This third possibility is recommended by the RICS.
and the inspector set a contribution of 35% affordable
However, as indicated previously, it assumes all planning
housing rather than the policy requirement of 50%.
obligation policies are fully reflected in the valuation.
In 2010, in an appeal related to a multi-phase residential The RICS states:
development in Cambridgeshire (Appeal Ref APP/
“Site Value should equate to the market value subject
Q0505/A/09/2103599), the Planning Inspectorate took the
to the following assumption: that the value has regard
opposite view. It was decided that the price paid for the
to development plan policies and all other material
land was irrelevant on this larger scheme. If the landowner
planning considerations and disregards that which is
was allowed to use the purchase price in any subsequent
contrary to the development plan.” [RICS, 2012b, 12]
modelling, they were essentially insuring against any risk
of market movements downwards. The Inspector was not Market value based on comparable transactions was
prepared to accept such a fundamental transfer of risk. adopted in Holsworthy (APP/W1145/Q/13/2204429)
and in King Street, London (APP/H5390/A/13/2209347).
Similarly, in March 2010 in Welwyn Garden City, an
It is not clear whether these transactions, on which the
Inspector repeated that the correct approach was current
market value was based, fully took into account the
existing use value and not price paid, reiterating that the
existing policies.
developer carries the risk, not the local authority (Appeal
5.0 Discussion
The grant of planning permission can produce significant commercial and industrial land uses in Reading over a
uplifts in land value and planning policy now acknowledges ten-year period from 2001 to 2010. Fixing a threshold land
that the three major stakeholders (landowners, developers value through this volatility means that the apportionment
and the community) can all participate in that added of uplift between landowner and community will vary
value. But the mechanism by which this participation is widely over time. DVA needs to operate within a flexible
implemented is fraught with difficulty. The central theme time framework that allows the impacts of changing market
of the development viability appeal cases that were states to be reflected in the modelling process. Many of
investigated is the application of residual development the appeals are associated with market shifts and the
appraisal modelling in general and the determination failure of DVA to flex in both downturns, when landowners
of threshold land value and its role in the modelling and developers suffer, and in upturns. There seems little
in particular. comment of the situation when a buoyant property market,
with highly volatile development residual values, increases
There are some general issues concerning the institutional
the development gains for landowners and developers –
background that has arguably failed to deliver a coherent
with no additional returns to the community. A mechanism
modelling process for property development in the UK (see
is required that can travel in both directions.
Crosby et al, 2013 and Coleman et al, 2012). But added
to that there is evidence from recorded planning appeals However, there appears little doubt that the central issue
of a confused picture concerning the ability to determine is the determination of threshold land value within the
the correct framework for assessing appropriate returns viability process. The value of a site that has potential for a
to developer, landowner and community. For example, change of use will be the higher of (a) its existing use value
developer’s return is highly site and market specific and or (b) alternative use value. If (b) involves development
significantly influenced by project finance structure. To date, activity that requires planning consent then it is usually
the industry’s response to these issues is to adopt broad estimated using the residual valuation method. There is
rules of thumb regarding level of developer and landowner little argument within both government policy and industry
return and to assume very simplistic financial structures. guidance that a developer should be able to obtain an
While some of this generality might (arguably) be acceptable appropriate risk-adjusted return from the development
for area-wide DVAs, it does not seem appropriate for site- scheme. The landowner will therefore receive the RLV
specific DVAs. that remains after the costs of development (including
developer’s profit and planning obligations) have been
One of the main problems with development appraisal is
deducted from the estimated value of the completed
the sensitivity of the residual output to changes brought
development (gross development value). Essentially, figure
about by input uncertainty and time. Sites are individual
2 is rearranged so that the share of uplift for planning
and site values change quickly and with far more volatility
obligations is input as a development cost, thus reducing
than developed real estate and other assets. As a
the RLV as shown in figure 4.
consequence, fixing cost and value inputs through time
magnifies the geared changes in RLV. Figure 3 illustrates
this point. The lines track changes in RLVs for residential,
7,500,000
6,500,000
Average House Price Nottingham £
5,500,000
4,500,000
3,500,000
2,500,000
1,500,000
500,000
0
-500,000
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Year
Residential RLV (no CIL) per ha assuming dph and 100 sqm dwelling size
Source: Compiled by authors using data from DCLG, VOA and CBRE
This residual development technique is a recognised with the RLV output, excluding planning obligations,
valuation method for assessing the market value of to determine the appropriate level of planning obligations.
development land and it gives some weight to guidance This introduces an element of circularity into the appraisal
put forward by the RICS that the market value of a explained below, which can be used by appellants to
development site should be the basis for threshold land their advantage.
value. At any point in time the RLV (the market value of a
If the land value used in the viability assessment is derived
development site) will reflect relevant policy on planning
from sales of similar sites, developers can argue that
obligations, i.e. the ‘cost’ of these obligations are included
the land value benchmark should be based on these
in the valuation as an input. Theoretically, a landowner
transactions – it is prime facia evidence of market value.
should be willing to sell a development land when its RLV
In fallen markets this may not be as favourable as using
is higher than existing use value and the price reflects
historic price but is the next best alternative.
the new use. On this basis there does not appear to be
a problem and the RICS guidance is correct. However, If market values of comparable sites are to be used as
it appears that this model may have been misapplied the basis for the determination of threshold land value,
in practice. Some of this misapplication surrounds the the critical assumption is that the comparable evidence
crucial market value special assumption concerning is adjusted to take account of current policy in relation to
the inclusion of policy compliant planning obligation planning obligations. If this were done correctly then the
assumptions. If they are not fully taken into account market valuation would necessarily confirm that the policy
in DVA, landowners and developers can manipulate compliant planning obligations were affordable and there
the situation to their financial benefit. These issues are would be no reduction in planning policy obligations on
discussed below. appeal, precisely because of the circularity issue. The
input land values are adjusted to take account of the cost
In the appeals, some appellants have argued that the
of planning obligations, and those are the obligations
market value of the site should not be used and the
that the DVA is trying to estimate. Both the use of either a
historic purchase price for the site should be used instead.
current purchase price or a current market value therefore
However, Planning Inspectors in a number of cases have
suffers from the same issue. If the price and the valuation
identified this as an attempt to shift some of the risk of
are correct under the planning obligation policy special
development activity from the developer to the community
assumption, they will automatically confirm that the
even though developers use risk-adjusted profit margins
policy planning obligations are affordable. The planning
in their original decision-making. One of the significant
obligations will only be unviable if the market value is
risks associated with development is input uncertainty
less than the EUV. A simple example will illustrate. Two
caused by market changes over time. Once land price
similar sites, A and B, each have a RLV before planning
has been fixed at the commencement of the developer’s
obligations of £100,000. The developer already owns
involvement, the impact of subsequent market changes
site A, having paid £85,000 in a much better market, and
will fall on the developer. If they are able to shift any
wants to buy the other one as well. The owner of site B
downside risk associated with these market shifts onto
is holding out for £80,000 given the price paid for the
the community by fixing the land price in any subsequent
site A. Current planning obligations are expected to cost
viability appraisal, that appraisal should incorporate a
£30,000 so a residual valuation identifies the RLV after
more moderately risk-adjusted return to the developer in
planning obligations to be £70,000 for each site. However,
order to reflect the reduced level of risk. There was no
the developer has just won an appeal on another site
evidence of such risk adjustment by appellants trying to
and the inspector referred to market values evidenced
use purchase price in DVAs. The historic purchase price
by transactions. The developer now purchases site B for
should never be used in a DVA.
£80,000 and submits an appeal in relation to site A quoting
If the use of market value is deemed to be the correct the market comparable of £80,000 to argue for a reduction
approach, as indicated above, its practical derivation in planning obligations to £20,000. If the RLV had been
is problematic. Normal valuation practice is to adjusted to take account of the policy compliant planning
assess developments with relatively homogeneous obligations, the outcome should have been £70,000 and
characteristics by direct capital value comparison using a decision that the site was viable. Theoretically, the use
a unit of comparison such as a price per square metre of a policy compliant RLV will always produce a policy
or, for residential land, price per hectare with suitable compliant set of planning obligations unless, as indicated
adjustments for location and physical differences. For above, the RLV falls below EUV or AUV.
more individual development sites, especially in the
It is unclear whether planning inspectors realise that actual
commercial sector, a residual method is used (see RICS
purchase prices and market valuations of comparable
guidance notes on comparative valuations (RICS, 2012a)
sites raise the same circularity issue. What is clear is that a
and development land (RICS, 2008)).
number of decisions have used purchase price or market
In the appeals, DVA was based on the residual method value based on comparable transaction evidence and this
but the direct comparison method was often used to is an open invitation for developers to overpay for sites
determine either the land value input where profit was in the knowledge that the current application of DVA will
the output or the benchmark against which to compare enable them to use these prices in assessing reduced
levels of planning obligations; either directly by inserting the It does not resolve any of the difficulties associated
price or indirectly by using the prices as comparables for with input uncertainty. But those are inherent within the
market valuations. What is the solution? In early cases, one residual valuation method and no resistance to the use
approach was to adopt EUV plus a premium to persuade of this method in DVA was found in the appeal cases.
landowners to release the land. However, this takes no This is despite the theoretical and practical criticisms
account of the substantial variations in the uplift from EUV levelled at it (see Coleman et al 2013, Crosby et al
to RLV. For example, a planning consent to allow residential 2013). The decision in the Shinfield case amounted to a
development on a greenfield site can generate a very large proportionate sharing of the land value uplift, essentially
uplift in land value whereas a consent to change the use a tax on the development gain. Consequently, despite
of a brownfield site from commercial to residential land its advantages over alternative approaches, it might be
use might generate a much smaller uplift from EUV. The viewed as a politically difficult solution to implement.
greenfield site would require very substantial premiums to
AUV does impact on this proposed solution. If there are
persuade a landowner to sell. In a number of the appeal
no planning obligations associated with the AUV, then
cases, EUV was above RLV even before any planning
AUV becomes the starting point for the uplift in value. If
obligations were deducted. In these cases no planning
there are planning obligations associated with the AUV
obligations were required. Effectively the EUV plus a
then the solution becomes less complicated. Assuming
premium approach is confounded by the heterogeneity
the same basis for planning obligations in both the grant
of development sites.
of the proposed permission and the alternative use
Finally, we are left with the approach that was adopted in planning permission (say 50% of the uplift), the AUV can
the appeal involving the site at Shinfield Road, Reading be ignored and the planning obligations for the proposed
(op cit). In that case the landowner and community development are simply 50% of the difference between
shared equally the land value uplift from EUV to a RLV RLV for the proposed development and the EUV, as if the
that ignored the effect of any planning obligations. This AUV didn’t exist.
approach addresses the issue of changing viability
through time and avoids the circularity issue that afflicts
threshold land values that are based on market values
or purchase price.
6.0 Conclusions
This research has examined appeal cases relating The problem centres on the difficulty in selecting an
to scheme-specific DVAs where the level of planning appropriate threshold land value, whether it is reliant
obligations was one of the issues in dispute. It has upon purchase price, comparison-based market value
identified threshold land value as the main point of or EUV plus a premium. One solution is to avoid setting
contention. The discussion in this paper has therefore a threshold land value altogether. By estimating EUV and
concentrated on this aspect. an RLV that ignores planning obligations, the Shinfield
appeal case split the uplift in value between the landowner
The present position is confused and conflicting. There
and the community. This approach has the trace of a
is evidence within appeal cases that planners, planning
development gains tax – the rate was 50% in the Shinfield
inspectors and surveyors acting as evidence providers
case – but it tracks changing market states and shares the
are doing so within a poor quality modelling environment.
profits of development between developers, landowners
Coleman et al (2012) indicate how little change there has
and the community in a way that is more equitable and
been in the development appraisal modelling framework
responsive than current approaches.
compared to the investment property modelling framework
over the same time period. The appeal cases have In addition to the conclusions on threshold land value
provided evidence that the institutionalised background that dominate the DVA issue, we also make two further
has not supplied the expertise necessary to carry out recommendations, one concerning the reporting of cases
rigorous development modelling in the English planning and the availability of information and the other the timing
system and that educators, trainers, learned societies, and of reviews.
industry have failed to deliver this expertise. In particular,
Publically available information on these cases varies
the research questions whether planning inspectors are
widely and needs to be made more transparent and
sufficiently versed in the expertise of development appraisal
consistent. In some cases there is only the basic planning
and finance to be able to spot the inconsistencies.
information and the Inspector’s report; in others, details of
The paper has examined the various approaches to the appraisals and viability assessments are available for
determining land value and supports the view that the scrutiny. If landowners and developers wish to challenge
use of historic purchase price is flawed as it attempts to area-wide and site specific community contributions, they
transfer one of the primary risks of development – changes need put their reasoning and evidence, including financial
in market state and its impact on costs and values within details, into the public domain.
the development – to the community. The risk-adjusted rate
Finally, one of the main problems with development
of return already rewards developers for taking these risks.
appraisal is the sensitivity of the residual output to
In addition the paper suggests that the market value changes brought about by input uncertainty and time.
approach is only theoretically correct if applied as per Sites are heterogeneous and site values change quickly
the assumptions set out in the RICS Guidance Note. and with far more volatility than developed real estate and
A correct application of market value would protect the other assets. As a consequence, fixing cost and value
community from changes in market state and ensure inputs through time magnifies the geared changes in
that any site brought forward for development would be RLV. In weak markets fixed planning obligations will act
able to provide policy compliant planning obligations. against the policy imperative, which attempts to bring
If market value is based on comparable evidence without sites forward for development, and in strong markets
proper adjustment to reflect policy compliant planning may restrict the amount that the community receives
obligations, this introduces a circularity, which encourages relative to landowners and developers. This has important
developers to overpay for sites and try to recover some implications for the Community Infrastructure Levy.
or all of this overpayment via reductions in planning
obligations. However, a correct interpretation of market
value would not persuade landowners to bring forward
sites for development in weak land markets and so acts
against the policy imperative. A possible solution lies
in the use of existing use value but, if that is not related
to the development in any way, it becomes a very blunt
instrument that takes no account of a landowner’s
perspective when deciding to bring a site forward
for development.
7.0 References
Allmendinger, P (2011) New Labour and planning: from new right to new left,
Routledge: Abingdon, Oxon
Crosby, N., McAllister, P. and Wyatt, P. (2013) Fit for planning? An evaluation
of the application of development viability appraisal models in the UK
planning system. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design,
40 (1). pp. 3-22
Geltner D., Miller, N., Calyton, J. And Eichholtz, P. (2007) Real Estate
Analysis and Investments. Thomson: Mason, Ohio.
LHDG (2012) Viability Testing Local Plans: Advice for Planning Practitioners.
Local Housing Delivery Group: London. http://www.local.gov.uk/c/
document_library/get_file?uuid=e317f7aa-488b-40fb-9e5c-
c18417e678dc&groupId=10180
8.0 Appendices
2. Percentage of Gross
Development Value Share of Land Value Uplift
The HCA document also noted that some area-wide
The HCA noted that some area-wide viability studies viability studies had used the concept of share of uplift
had used percentage of gross development value in land value (between existing use value and theoretical
(GDV) as a benchmark to assess threshold land residual land value ‘unencumbered’ by planning
value. The percentage uplift from current use value obligations) as a basis for estimating threshold land
to residual value is a form of development land value value. In the hypothetical example, assuming an uplift of
taxation and the proportion of completed scheme £1,800,000 and an AUV of £200,000, a 50/50 share of
value would seem to be a simple heuristic rather than the financial gain from planning permission between the
a logically based threshold value. Comparable market community and the landowner would produce a threshold
prices, in the rare cases where they exist, will have land value of £1,100,000.
been reduced to the extent that they ‘price in’ the
prospect of planning policy requirements, as noted Following this guidance, a number of organisations
above. It might be argued that valuers are capable representing sometimes conflicting and sometimes
of adjusting market evidence of land prices to take overlapping groups have produced further guidance.
this into account (see RICS, 2012 for example) but Prompted by the Housing Minster, the Local Housing
there has been no investigation as to whether this Delivery Group’s remit was to produce:
is a robust approach. Crosby et al (2012) argue that “…practical advice for planning practitioners on
there is no economic reason to expect land costs to developing viable Local Plans underpinned by a
be any specific proportion of development value. In commitment from the HBF (Home Builders Federation)
the hypothetical example above, since the ratio is a and LGA (Local Government Association) to engage
product of previous transactions using the 20% of their members in applying this advice and continuing to
GDV as a threshold would tend to reinforce the policy develop the guidance over time, as we all get to grips
status quo. with the implementation of the new National Planning
Policy Framework (NPPF).” (Local Housing Delivery
Group, 2012, 4)
It seems clear that an attempt was being made to The drawbacks of TLV based on current use value plus
create some consensus among representatives of the a premium are twofold. First, there is no empirical basis
community (represented by LGA) and the real estate for the level incentive premium that is unlikely to be the
development sector (represented by the HBF) about the same for all types of development or points in time. As
approach, method and assumptions for viability testing. the Prince’s Foundation for the Built Environment5 asks:
However, with regard to the crucial issue of Threshold will landowners sell at prices developers can afford given
Land Value, the guidance is ambiguous. It begins by the scarcity of capital, burden of sunk land costs, level
stating the commonly accepted premise that TLV “should of debt on balance sheets, money needed to finance full
represent the value at which a typical willing landowner is range of infrastructure levies and planning obligations?
likely to release land”. It then advises the viability modeller Some landowners are locked into option agreements
to base TLV “on a premium over current use value” or that they cannot fulfil, others (such as family landowners)
on alternative use value. However, almost immediately have investment horizons that are far longer than most.
this statement is qualified. The report suggests that the Others are becoming partners with developers and
premium above current use value should be determined house builders, the contractual details of which cannot be
locally and be based on evidence. There is no hint as to reflected in a simple premium.
how this should be done or where the evidence might
Second, if the premium is based on a percentage of
come from. Indeed, the complexity surrounding the use
current use value, this does not relate to the value of the
of TLV is revealed when reasons as to why the premium
land in its developed state. Rational landowners would
might significantly vary are described (Local Housing
seek a return that reflects the value of the proposed
Delivery Group, 2012: 30):
development. Geltner et al (2007) suggest that this return
• In areas where landowners have long investment comprises two value premiums over and above current
horizons and they are content with current land use, use value. The first is a ‘growth premium’ that reflects the
the premium will be higher than in those areas where present value of the future growth in value of the land after
key landowners are more minded to sell. Essentially, it has been developed. The second is an ‘irreversibility
the premium will vary over space. premium’ which reflects compensation for giving up the
• Landowner’s return will vary substantially depending option to develop some time in the future. Basing TLV on
on whether the land is urban or rural. The report current use value plus a percentage of current use value
suggests referring to “… market data and information would not properly account for these premiums.
on typical minimum price provisions …” and “… if local This issue of landowner’s return, based on a share of
market evidence is that minimum price provisions uplift in value, was raised by Barker (2004). Planning Gain
are substantially in excess of the initial benchmark Supplement (PGS) was to be based on the uplift between
assumptions, then the plan will be at significant risk current use value and ‘Planning Value’. This raised some
unless Threshold Land Values are placed at a higher methodological questions: how would a valuer be able
level, reflecting that market evidence” (p30). There is to find evidence of current use value (defined as market
significant blurring between a TLV set using current value without hope of future development). Planning value
use value plus premium or market prices. was to reflect all factors affecting market value including
• Similarly, due to the effect of hope value, landowners’ planning obligations. In fact, planning value would ‘often
returns will differ substantially between small, edge be the price paid for the land’ and ‘it will often fall to
or settlement, greenfield sites and other large the developer to take account of PGS liability when
greenfield sites. negotiating the purchase of the land’ (p7). So planning
value is reduced to reflect PGS liability and is used to
• A ‘viability cushion’ should be established to ensure determine the amount of PGS liability. Barker did not
‘marginal’ sites still come forward, to guard against the resolve the circularity issue.
potential that small changes to external circumstances
could render many sites unviable. In other words, the Recent guidance from the Homes and Communities
premium will vary over time. There is no guidance Agency (HCA, 2012a) provides little clarification, stating
as to how such a cushion should be derived or what that establishing a TLV is ‘difficult’, although it does
magnitude it should take. expand on this by explaining that:
• Some sites are allocated as development sites in “The threshold of existing use value, or existing use
the development plan and costs are incurred in their value plus a premium, may not be the best benchmark
promotion. for testing viability in some land markets, particularly
land currently in agricultural use. In these cases,
The guidance then points out that “reference to market
because the value uplift resulting from a planning
values can still provide a useful sense-check”, albeit
consent is much more significant than for urban
using market values “risks building-in assumptions of
sites, landowners (sic) expectations may be better
current policy”
benchmarked by a comparable or other assumed land
value” (HCA, 2012: 5)
5 Delivering Sustainable Urbanism: SLIM - A Strategic Land Investment Model, The Prince’s Foundation for the Built Environment, undated
Appendix B
Table 1 Planning Appeals
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
continued
9.0 Acknowledgements
We would like to acknowledge the contribution of
the RICS Research Trust for the major part of the
funding for this project.
We would also like to thank the University of Reading’s
Research Opportunities Programme for providing the
additional funding to enable BSc Real Estate Second Year
student Kiyan Hui to spend two months over the summer
participating in the research full time, helping to plan the
research and collecting and collating evidence and, since
then, being involved in other aspects of the research
helping to bring the project to its conclusion.