Diversification
Diversification
Diversification
Financial markets[show]
Financial instruments[show]
Corporate finance[show]
Personal finance[show]
Public finance[show]
Financial regulation[show]
Standards[show]
Economic history[show]
v·d·e
In finance, diversification means reducing risk by investing in a variety of assets. If the asset
values do not move up and down in perfect synchrony, a diversified portfolio will have less risk
than the weighted average risk of its constituent assets, and often less risk than the least risky of
its constituents.[1]. Therefore, any risk-averse investor will diversify to at least some extent, with
more risk-averse investors diversifying more completely than less risk-averse investors.
Diversification is one of two general techniques for reducing investment risk. The other is
hedging. Diversification relies on the lack of a tight positive relationship among the assets'
returns, and works even when correlations are near zero or somewhat positive. Hedging relies on
negative correlation among assets, or shorting assets with positive correlation.
It is important to remember that diversification only works because investment in each individual
asset is reduced. If someone starts with $10,000 in one stock and then puts $10,000 in another
stock, they would have more risk, not less. Diversification would require the sale of $5,000 of
the first stock to be put into the second. There would then be less risk. Hedging, by contrast,
reduces risk without selling any of the original position[2].
The risk reduction from diversification does not mean anyone else has to take more risk. If
person A owns $10,000 of one stock and person B owns $10,000 of another, both A and B will
reduce their risk if they exchange $5,000 of the two stocks, so each now has a more diversified
portfolio[3].
Contents
[hide]
1 Examples
2 Return expectations while diversifying
3 Maximum diversification
4 Effect of diversification on variance
5 Diversifiable and non-diversifable risk
6 An empirical example relating diversification to risk reduction
7 Diversification and globalization
8 Corporate diversification strategies
9 History
10 See also
11 References
12 External links
Examples
The simplest example of diversification is provided by the proverb "don't put all your eggs in one
basket". Dropping the basket will break all the eggs. Placing each egg in a different basket is
more diversified. There is more risk of losing one egg, but less risk of losing all of them. In
finance, an example of an undiversified portfolio is to hold only one stock. This is risky; it is not
unusual for a single stock to go down 50% in one year. It is much less common for a portfolio of
20 stocks to go down that much, even if they are selected at random. If the stocks are selected
from a variety of industries, company sizes and types (such as some growth stocks and some
value stocks) it is still less likely.
Further diversification can be obtained by investing in stocks from different countries, and in
different asset classes such as bonds, real estate and commodities like heating oil or gold[4].
Maximum diversification
Given the advantages of diversification, many experts recommend maximum diversification, also
known as “buying the market portfolio.” Unfortunately, identifying that portfolio is not
straightforward. The earliest definition comes from the capital asset pricing model which argues
the maximum diversification comes from buying a pro rata share of all available assets. This is
the idea underlying index funds.
One objection to that is it means avoiding investments like futures that exist in zero net supply.
Another is that the portfolio is determined by what securities come to market, rather than
underlying economic value. Finally, buying pro rata shares means that the portfolio overweights
any assets that are overvalued, and underweights any assets that are undervalued. This line of
argument leads to portfolios that are weighted according to some definition of “economic
footprint,” such as total underlying assets or annual cash flow.[6]
“Risk parity” is an alternative idea. This weights assets in inverse proportion to risk, so the
portfolio has equal risk in all asset classes. This is justified both on theoretical grounds, and with
the pragmatic argument that future risk is much easier to forecast than either future market value
or future economic footprint.[7]
In general, the presence of more assets in a portfolio leads to greater diversification benefits, as
can be seen by considering portfolio variance as a function of n, the number of assets. For
example, if all assets' returns are mutually uncorrelated and have identical variances , portfolio
variance is minimized by holding all assets in the equal proportions 1 / n[8]. Then the portfolio
return's variance equals var[(1 / n)x1 + (1 / n)x2 + ... + (1 / n)xn] = = , which is
monotonically decreasing in n.
The latter analysis can be adapted to show why adding uncorrelated risky assets to a portfolio,[9]
[10]
thereby increasing the portfolio's size, is not diversification, which involves subdividing the
portfolio among many smaller investments. In the case of adding investments, the portfolio's
return is instead of (1 / n)x1 + (1 / n)x2 + ... + (1 / n)xn, and the variance of the portfolio
return if the assets are uncorrelated is which is increasing in n rather than decreasing. Thus, for
example, when an insurance company adds more and more uncorrelated policies to its portfolio,
this expansion does not itself represent diversification—the diversification occurs in the
spreading of the insurance company's risks over a large number of part-owners of the company.
If one buys all the stocks in the S&P 500 one is obviously exposed only to movements in that
index. If one buys a single stock in the S&P 500, one is exposed both to index movements and
movements in the stock relative to the index. The first risk is called “non-diversifiable,” because
it exists however many S&P 500 stocks are bought. The second risk is called “diversifiable,”
because it can be reduced it by diversifying among stocks, and it can be eliminated completely
by buying all the stocks in the index.
Of course, there's nothing special about the S&P 500; the same argument can apply to any index,
up to and including the market portfolio of all assets.
The Capital Asset Pricing Model argues that investors should only be compensated for non-
diversifiable risk. Other financial models allow for multiple sources of non-diversifiable risk, but
also insist that diversifiable risk should not carry any extra expected return. Still other models do
not accept this contention[11]
History
Diversification is mentioned in the Bible, in the book of Ecclesiastes which was written in
approximately 935 B.C.[14]:
Diversification is also mentioned in the Talmud. The formula given there is to split one's assets
into thirds: one third in business (buying and selling things), one third kept liquid (e.g. gold
coins), and one third in land (real estate).
The modern understanding of diversification dates back to the work of Harry Markowitz[17] in the
1950s.
See also
References
1. ^ Sullivan, arthur; Steven M. Sheffrin (2003). Economics: Principles in action. Upper Saddle
River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall. pp. 273. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
http://pearsonschool.mobi/index.cfm?
locator=PSZ16o&filter_161=&filter_423=&filter_422=&filter_424=&filter_281=&filter_425=&
programFilterTypeList=161%2C423%2C422%2C424%2C281%2C425&PMDbSiteid=2781&P
MDbSolutionid=6724&PMDbSubSolutionid=&PMDbCategoryid=815&PMDbSubcategoryid=2
4843&&PMDbProgramID=23061.
2. ^ Fama, Eugene F.; Merton H. Miller (June 1972). The Theory of Finance. Holt Rinehart &
Winston. ISBN 978-0155042667.
3. ^ Sharpe, William; Gordon J. Alexander, Jeffrey W. Bailey (October 30, 1998). Investments.
Prentice Hall. ISBN 978-0130101303.
4. ^ Campbell, John Y. Campbell; Andrew W. Lo, A. Craig MacKinlay (December 9, 1996). The
Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691043012.
5. ^ Goetzmann, William N. An Introduction to Investment Theory. II. Portfolios of Assets.
Retrieved on November 20, 2008.
6. ^ Wagner, Hans Fundamentally Weighted Index Investing. Retrieved on June 20, 2010.
7. ^ Asness, Cliff; David Kabiller and Michael Mendelson Using Derivatives and Leverage To
Improve Portfolio Performance, Institutional Investor, May 13, 2010. Retrieved on June 21, 2010.
8. ^ Samuelson, Paul, "General Proof that Diversification Pays,"Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 2, March 1967, 1-13.
9. ^ Samuelson, Paul, "Risk and uncertainty: A fallacy of large numbers," Scientia 98, 1963, 108-
113.
10. ^ Ross, Stephen, "Adding risks: Samuelson's fallacy of large numbers revisited," Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 34, September 1999, 323-339.
11. ^ .Fama, Eugene F.; Merton H. Miller (June 1972). The Theory of Finance. Holt Rinehart &
Winston. ISBN 978-0155042667.
12. ^ E. J. Elton and M. J. Gruber, "Risk Reduction and Portfolio Size: An Analytic Solution,"
Journal of Business 50 (October 1977), pp. 415-37
13. ^ (French) see M. Nicolas J. Firzli, Asia-Pacific Funds as Diversification Tools for Institutional
Investors, http://www.canadianeuropean.com/yahoo_site_admin/assets/docs/FONDS_DASIE-
PACIFIQUE_REVUE_AF_APR_09.95131642.pdf, retrieved 2009-04-2
14. ^ Life Application Study Bible: New Living Translation. Wheaton, Illinois: Tyndale House
Publishers, Inc.. 1996. p. 1024. ISBN 0-8423-3267-7.
15. ^ Ecclesiastes 11:2 NLT
16. ^ The Only Guide to a Winning Investment Strategy You'll Ever Need
17. ^ Markowitz, Harry M. (1952). "Portfolio Selection". Journal of Finance 7 (1): 77–91.
doi:10.2307/2975974. http://jstor.org/stable/2975974.
External links
Macro-Investment Analysis, Prof. William F. Sharpe, Stanford University
Portfolio Diversifier, Dynamically-generated diversified portfolios
Asset Correlations, Dynamically-generated correlation matrices for the major asset
classes
An Introduction to Investment Theory, Prof. William N. Goetzmann, Yale School of
Management
Overview of Managed Futures