British Decline or The Politics of Declinism?: Books Reviewed
British Decline or The Politics of Declinism?: Books Reviewed
British Decline or The Politics of Declinism?: Books Reviewed
Books reviewed
C. Barnett (1987; 1st edn. 1986) The Audit of War: The Illusion
and Reality of Britain as a Great Nation. Basingstoke: Macmillan,
viii + 359pp., ISBN 0-333-43458-7.
P. Clarke and C. Trebilcock (eds) (1997) Understanding Decline: Perceptions
and Realities of British Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, xv + 313pp., ISBN 0-521-56317-8.
B. Collins and K. Robbins (eds) (1990) British Culture and Economic
Decline. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 208pp., ISBN 0-297-820-38-9.
A. Gamble (1994) Britain in Decline: Economic Policy, Political Strategy
and the British State (4th edn). Basingstoke: Macmillan, xxi + 263pp.,
ISBN 0-333-61441-0.
W. Hutton (1996a) The State We’re In (revised edn). London: Vintage,
xxix + 370pp., ISBN 0-099-36681-9.
P. Kennedy (1989; 1st edn. 1988) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers:
Economic Change and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000. London:
Unwin Hyman, xxviii + 898pp., ISBN 0-006-86052-4.
D. Marquand (1988) The Unprincipled Society. London: Fontana,
viii + 292pp., ISBN 0-006-86153-9.
S. Pollard (1982) The Wasting of the British Economy: British Economic
Policy 1945 to the Present. London: Croom Helm, viii + 199pp., ISBN
0-709-92083-0.
S. Pollard (1989) Britain’s Prime and Britain’s Decline: The British Economy
1870–1914. London: Edward Arnold, xii + 324pp., ISBN 0-340-53913-5.
© Political Studies Association 1999. Published by Blackwell Publishers, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF and
350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA 252
Review Article
Are debates about ‘decline’ still pertinent as Britain faces the twenty-first
century? One of the foremost preoccupations of Britain’s political elite,
and of leading intellectuals throughout the twentieth century, has been
with the question of ‘decline’: whether it has occurred, why it has done so
and what should be done to remedy it. Indeed, decline may provide one of
the defining motifs of political discourse in the ‘short’ twentieth century
(Hobsbawm 1994). This essay surveys the extensive interdisciplinary lit-
erature on British decline, and asks whether this still provides an appropri-
ate analytical ‘frame’. Though ‘decline’ has long been the object of political
and historical analysis, we argue for an intepretative shift so that the
phenomenon of ‘declinism’, a state of mind relatively autonomous of the
actual, historical decline of Britain as a world power, comes more clearly
into view. Our sense of the inadequacies of declinist narratives has been
sharpened by recent interviews with some of the leading intellectual com-
mentators on this aspect of British politics: Correlli Barnett, Samuel Brittan,
Jonathan Clark, Stuart Hall, Will Hutton, David Marquand, Sidney Pollard,
Bill Rubinstein and Martin Wiener (collected in English and Kenny
1999).
Defining decline
The simplest definition of ‘decline’ suggests that the term refers to a trace-
able process whereby Britain diminished as a world power: an historically
observable phenomenon which can be neatly defined, measured and demon-
strated. This is sometimes termed ‘absolute decline’. In this guise, decline
arguments have been found wanting in intellectual circles and have rarely
been seriously maintained. As we shall see, there are simply too many senses
in which aspects of life have improved in qualitative and quantitative terms
for such a notion to be sustainable when applied to British experience
in an aggregated fashion, or to the economy as a whole (Supple 1997;
Gamble 1994).
The predominant usage of decline is therefore in the ‘relative’ sense, in
relation to rivals. In these respects, it has appeared to many that there has
been a striking diminution in British power, defined in terms of military
power, international weight and economic productivity. It should be noted,
however, that, while relative decline of this kind is an apparently traceable
process, it is also one rich in ambiguities, and indeed always has been so.
Decline arguments have, since the late nineteenth century, attracted a strong
set of counter-arguments, and these have in many respects dislodged explan-
ations that rely upon declinist teleologies. In the current climate, the balance
between declinists and sceptics appears to have tilted towards the latter.
Similarly, many aspects of Correlli Barnett’s thesis (and indeed his research
methodology itself) have been convincingly questioned by specialist scholars
(Edgerton 1991; Tomlinson 1997; Clarke 1997; Contemporary Record
1987). Rather than seeing Britain as anti-technological, anti-scientific and
anti-industrial, some historians contend that in fact Britain has been
a powerful twentieth-century scientific force, that British engineers and
scientists have played a leading part in industry and government, and that
the state has been an important supporter of technology and science
(Edgerton 1996). Again, Wiener’s emphasis on the anti-industrial impact
of rural preoccupation has also been questioned. Peter Mandler has recently
pointed out that: cultures absorbed in their rural past are not necessarily
anti-modern; England between 1880 and 1914 was actually less charac-
terised by a nostalgic interest in the countryside than were other European
countries; and inter-war England was again less absorbed in rural nostalgia
than other European cultures and was certainly not backward-looking
(1997). Indeed, it is worth asking just how many pre-First World War
English people, let alone Scots, Welsh and Irish, were in fact preoccupied
by a rural-nostalgic approach. Enthusiasts for such an approach can be
found, but it is doubtful whether they were truly representative.
In particular, two central points emerge from the extensive controversies
generated by the provocative claims of Barnett and Wiener. First, even if
the arguments about British culture were conceded, and there is consid-
erable doubt on this point, could one demonstrate beyond reasonable
doubt the connection between such features of British culture and the
retardation of economic growth? No wholly convincing causal connection
has yet been established. Second, if relative British failure is to be sub-
stantially explained by recourse to cultural explanations of this type, then
it is necessary to demonstrate that Britain’s rivals were less flawed by such
supposed cultural hindrances. Attacks on the cultural critique have fre-
quently focused on the fact that Britain’s competitors were at least as likely
to exhibit the same cultural tendencies as those which supposedly inhibited
British competitiveness. As Bill Rubinstein has rightly pointed out, modern
industrial economies have been built in cultures containing many anti-
capitalist elements; indeed, British culture may well have been less hostile
to industrial development and entrepreneurship than that of its rivals (1993).
The economy
If cultural arguments have been significantly questioned, then what of more
directly economic theories? One line of argument involves the identification
the era of ‘Fordism’ may signal the arrival of a new ‘accumulation regime’
organised around different materials and outputs and ‘heralding shifts into
the ‘information economy’’ (Castells 1997), ‘post-Fordism’ (Amin 1994),
the post-industrial society (Bell 1973), or the era of ‘flexible specialisation’
(Hirst 1997). Such theories, though debatable, suggest that the decline of
manufacturing in Britain might be seen as a particular instance of a larger
transformation, however traumatic, in this particular context.
Institutions
A third group of explanations of British decline might be termed ‘institu-
tional’. British decline as a world power has occasioned a search for culpable
parties, and the institutions of the political, financial and administrative
system have frequently been depicted as the culprits. A recent example is
Will Hutton’s argument concerning the supposedly sclerotic nature of much
British institutional life (1996a). His writings give prominence to criticisms
of key structures in Britain and press the claim made by others that
institutional arrangements can hinder (or foster) productivity. Numerous
commentators have alleged different institutional weaknesses: the finance-
industry relationship (Ingham 1984); the City-Treasury-Bank of England
‘nexus’ (Pollard 1982); the military-fiscal state which emerged from the
seventeenth century and powered the drive for imperial expansion, fuelled
by the political economy of ‘gentlemanly capitalism’ (Cain and Hopkins
1993); and the corporatism of the post-war years (Middlemas 1979).
Though these are all significant theses in their own right, here there is
space only to observe one important characteristic common to all: they each
rely upon the idea of path dependency to suggest that societies can be locked
into particular development trajectories. Once the initial conditions are estab-
lished, it becomes almost impossible to break out of them. Studies of differ-
ent sectors and industries confirm the vicious cycle which affected each at
different points. But path-dependency thinking has been heavily criticised in
the institutionalist literature. Critics reply that: ‘[h]armful and sub-optimal
patterns can persist for a time but provided a society remains reasonably open
and pluralist, older patterns will become outmoded and will eventually be
displaced’ (Gamble in English and Kenny 1999). Similarly, the arguments
developed by Hutton, with their strong echoes of the Nairn and Anderson
thesis, have been taken to task by some critics for substituting concern
with the political-constitutional forms of political life for substantive issues
of political economy (a perennial hazard of institutionalist explanations):
what evidence is there that political-institutional ‘modernisation’ would
necessarily spill over into the economic sphere (Hay 1995)? Again, in a
sustained critique, Desai (1996) questioned Hutton’s obsessive concern
with relative GDP growth rates, his critical fixation with the City, his
analysis of Thatcherism and his use of Keynes (see Hutton’s reply, 1996b).
The state
In institutional accounts, much attention has been paid to the role of the
British state and its relationships with other economic actors and domains.
Some have forcefully argued that it has done too much. To the economic
commentator Samuel Brittan, for example, democracy brought overgovern-
ment, with economic intervention by the state holding back rather than
encouraging growth (1977). The perversion of the market order during the
twentieth century has indeed been held by some to have caused British
decline, with an erosion of industrial competitiveness being so marked that
calls grew for the rolling back of the state. According to this view, govern-
ment should intervene less in the economy, public expenditure should be
cut back and taxation consequently lowered (Green 1987).
To others, however, the state has not done enough. David Marquand, in
particular, has argued that Britain suffered from not possessing what
he labelled a ‘developmental/entrepreneurial’ state (1988). Greater priority
should have been placed by the state, in post-war Britain, on the modern-
isation of the economy. Too weak and too distanced from business, the
state did not provide the assistance with funding, research and development
necessary to promote long-term growth and programmatic modernisation.
Marquand pinpoints the exceptional character of British political culture,
forged in the hey-day of Empire and laissez-faire, and argues that this
saturated the minds of the political and bureaucratic elites which governed
Britain into the twentieth century. This kind of argument has been
bolstered latterly by Michel Albert’s (1993) characterisation of a ‘Rhenish’
model of capitalism, based upon the features of the Japanese and Germanic
economies, which is deemed to be the antithesis of the Anglo-American
model, with its limited patterns of state intervention, lack of planning
instruments and shareholder driven economic culture. The developmental
state thesis, like some of the other theories discussed here, also relies on a
pathological understanding of British failure, locating the origins of the
latter in the absence of characteristics found in rival economies.
Some have held that the state spent too highly on the military. It has
been argued that too great a concentration on military expenditure, par-
ticularly once a power’s relative decline has begun, will further deepen that
international standards, there has been considerable state and private in-
vestment in this area; it is simply not true to argue that military expenditure
has occurred at the expense of civil research and development. Moreover,
it is far from accepted that higher levels of spending on the latter would in
fact have solved the problems of British industry (Edgerton 1996). Again,
our understanding of British political and economic history has been
greatly enriched by decline debates, but primarily through the detailed
work of those sceptical about overarching declinist theses.
pursued at different points? At what moments might this have been pos-
sible or impossible? This is because a combination of teleological, patho-
logical and structuralist arguments have often been adopted. Interestingly,
the period of greatest anxiety about decline has coincided with the greatest
prosperity in British history. Are not living standards a crucial measure of
economic performance and, if they are, is it plausible to suggest that modern
British experience is really best approached in terms of decline? Equally
important here is the question of need and expectations, the latter being
especially linked to more popularised decline sentiment:
Conclusion
Decline has been a concept central to late twentieth-century discussions of
British economic performance and national identity alike. Yet, there are
serious analytical grounds for doubting whether this ‘trope’ remains useful
in pinpointing and diagnosing the principal processes within British polit-
ical economy. Nor is this to argue that a form of economic triumphalism
founded upon mythological British virtues, historically the reverse side of
the coin to breast-beating about decline, should be installed in favour of
the latter. Though these are extremely difficult phenomena to judge, there
is evidence that intellectuals are becoming more sensitised to the limitations
of the narratives which have underpinned the teaching and interpretation
of central periods in British history. These are increasingly seen as ob-
structing rather than aiding our understanding of the peculiar and typical
ways in which the British polity and economy have developed. Pinning
down the causes of, and remedy for, decline has, for a long time, repre-
sented a kind of ‘holy grail’ for historians and political commentators in
Britain. Our suggestion is that this approach to decline should now be sup-
planted by a more extensive analysis of the political construction of declinist
arguments in different periods, with particular attention paid to the role of
declinism in the relationship between intellectuals and British politics.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank David Marsh and three anonymous
referees for their comments on an earlier draft of this essay.
Notes
1. The categories deployed here to organise the literature on decline should clearly be treated
with flexibility. The boundaries between them are, in certain cases, necessarily blurred:
some writers could arguably be included under more than one heading. Nevertheless, we
believe that as an organisational framework, these categories have considerable value in
clarifying the nature of decline debates.
Bibliography
Albert, M. (1993) Capitalism against Capitalism (London: Whurr).
Amin, A. (ed.) (1994) Post-Fordism: A Reader (Oxford: Blackwell).
Anderson, P. (1963) ‘Origins of the Present Crisis’, New Left Review, 23, 26–53.
Anderson, P. (1987) ‘The Figures of Descent’, New Left Review, 161, 20–77.
Bell, D. (1973) The Coming of Post-Industrial Society: a Venture in Social Forecasting
(New York: Basic Books).
Brittan, S. (1977) The Economic Consequences of Democracy (London: Temple Smith).
Budge, I. (1993) ‘Relative Decline as a Political Issue: Ideological Motivations of the
Politico-Economic Debate in Post-War Britain’, Contemporary Record, 7:1, 1–23.
Cain, P. J. and Hopkins, A. G. (1993) British Imperialism: vol. i, Innovation and Expansion
1688–1914 (London: Longman).
Castells, M. (1997) The Information Age: Economy, Society and Culture; Volumes One,
Two and Three (Oxford and Malden, MA: Blackwell).
Clarke, P. (1997) ‘Keynes, New Jerusalem, and British Decline’, in P. Clarke and C. Trebilcock
(eds), Understanding Decline: Perceptions and Realities of British Economic Performance
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Coates, D. (1994) The Question of UK Decline (London and New York: Harvester
Wheatsheaf).
Coates, D. and Hillard, J. (eds) (1987) The Economic Decline of Modern Britain (London:
Harvester Wheatsheaf).
Contemporary Record (1987) ‘Symposium: Britain’s Post-war Industrial Decline’, Con-
temporary Record, 1:2, 11–18 (with contributions from Correlli Barnett, Paul Addison,
J. C. Barker, Sir Alec Cairncross and Margaret Gowing).
Crafts, N. (1988) British Economic Growth Before and After 1979: a Review of the
Evidence (London: Centre for Economic Policy).
Desai, M. (1996) ‘Debating the British Disease: The Centrality of Profit’, New Political
Economy, 1:1, 79–93.
Edgerton, D. (1991) ‘Liberal Militarism and the British State’, New Left Review, 185, 138–69.
Edgerton, D. (1996) Science, Technology and the British Industrial Decline 1870–1970
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Elbaum, B. and Lazonick, W. (1986) ‘An Institutional Perspective on British Decline’, in
B. Elbaum and W. Lazonick (eds), The Decline of the British Economy (Oxford:
Clarendon Press).
English, R. and Kenny, M. (eds) (1999) Rethinking British Decline (Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Feinstein, C. (1992) ‘The Benefits of Backwardness and the Costs of Continuity’, in A. Graham
(ed.), Government and Economies in the Post-War World: Economic Policies and
Comparative Performance, 1945–85 (London: Routledge).
Gamble, A. (1991) ‘From Empire to De-Industrialisation—The Problem of British Develop-
ment’, Culture and History: 9/10 (Copenhagen: Academic Press), 85–104.
Gerschenkron, A. (1962) Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press).
Gray, J. (1993) Beyond the New Right: Markets, Government and the Common Environ-
ment (London: Routledge).
Green, D. (1987) The New Right: the Counter-Revolution in Political, Economic and Social
Thought (London: Harvester Wheatsheaf).
Habakkuk, H. J. (1962) American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Hall, P. (1986) Governing the Economy: the politics of state intervention in Britain and
France (Cambridge: Polity).
Harvie, C. (1985) ‘Liturgies of National Decadence—Wiener, Dahrendorf and the British
Crisis’, Cencrastus, 21, 17–28.
Hay, C. (1995) ‘Structure and Agency: Holding the Whip Hand’, in D. Marsh and G. Stoker
(eds), Theory and Methods of Political Science (Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Hirst, P. (1997) Governing Flexibility (London: Routledge).
Hobsbawm, E. (1994) Age of Extremes: the Short Twentieth Century 1914–1991 (London:
Michael Joseph).
Hutton, W. (1996b) ‘Still Debating the British Disease: A Reply to Desai’, New Political
Economy, 1:3, 393–397.
Ingham, G. (1984) Capitalism Divided?: the City and Industry in British Social Develop-
ment (Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Kirby, M. W. (1992) ‘Institutional rigidites and economic decline: reflections on the British
experience’, Economic History Review, 45, 637–660.
McCloskey, D. M. (1973) Economic Maturity and Entrepreneurial Decline: British Iron and
Steel 1870–1913 (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press).
Mandler, P. (1997) ‘Against “Englishness”: English Culture and the Limits to Rural Nostalgia
1850–1940’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society (6th series), 7, 155–175.
Marquand, D. (1997) ‘Travails of an Ancien Régime’, in The New Reckoning: States,
Markets and Citizens (Oxford: Polity).
Middlemas, K. (1979) Politics in Industrial Society: the Experience of the British System
since 1911 (London: Andre Deutsch).
Nairn, T. (1963) ‘The British Political Elite’, New Left Review, 23, 19–25.
Nairn, T. (1964) ‘The English Working Class’, New Left Review, 24, 43–57.
Pollard, S. (1981) ‘Entrepreneurship, 1870–1914’, in R. Floud and D. McCloskey (eds), The
Economic History of Britain Since 1700: Volume 2, 1860–1939 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press).
Robbins, K. (1990) ‘British Culture versus British Industry’, in B. Collins and K. Robbins
(eds), British Culture and Economic Decline (London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson).
Rubinstein, W. D. (1981) Men of Property: The Very Wealthy in Britain since the Industrial
Revolution (London: Croom Helm).
Rubinstein, W. D. (1987) Elites and the Wealthy in Modern British History: Essays in Social
and Economic History (Brighton: Harvester).
Rubinstein, W. D. (1990) ‘Cultural Explanations for Britain’s Economic Decline’, in B. Collins
and K. Robbins (eds), British Culture and Economic Decline (London: Weidenfeld &
Nicolson.
Rubinstein, W. D. (1993) Capitalism, Culture and Decline in Britain 1750–1990 (London:
Routledge).
Sandberg, L. (1974) Lancashire in Decline: A Study in Entrepreneurship, Technology and
International Trade (Columbus OH: Ohio State University Press).
Supple, B. (1981) ‘British Economic Decline Since 1945’, in R. Floud and D. McCloskey
(eds), The Economic History of Britain Since 1700: Volume 2, 1860–1939 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press).
Supple, B. (1997) ‘Fear of Failing: Economic History and the Decline of Britain’, in P. Clarke
and C. Trebilcock (eds), Understanding Decline: Perceptions and Realities of British
Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Tomlinson, J. (1997) ‘Correlli Barnett’s History: The Case of Marshall Aid’, Twentieth
Century British History, 8:2, 222–238.
Dr R. English Dr M. Kenny
School of Politics Department of Politics
Queen’s University Belfast University of Sheffield
21 University Square Northumberland Road
Belfast BT7 1PA Sheffield S10 2TU
email: r.english@qub.ac.uk email: m.kenny@sheffield.ac.uk