Sometimes Way Myanmar
Sometimes Way Myanmar
Sometimes Way Myanmar
Agribusiness
and Food
Industries
Series
by
Eva Gálvez Nogales
Cover photograph
©FAO/Vasily Maksimov
The views expressed in this information product are those of the author(s) and do not
necessarily reflect the views or policies of FAO.
ISBN 978-92-5-108636-0
© FAO, 2014
FAO encourages the use, reproduction and dissemination of material in this information
product. Except where otherwise indicated, material may be copied, downloaded and
printed for private study, research and teaching purposes, or for use in non-commercial
products or services, provided that appropriate acknowledgement of FAO as the source
and copyright holder is given and that FAO’s endorsement of users’ views, products or
services is not implied in any way.
All requests for translation and adaptation rights, and for resale and other commercial
use rights should be made via www.fao.org/contact-us/licence-request or addressed to
copyright@fao.org.
Contents
Preface viii
Acknowledgements x
Executive summary xi
Abstract xiii
Acronyms xv
Chapter 1
Introduction 1
1.1 Background and scope 1
1.2 Objective of the study 2
1.3 Methodology 2
1.4 Structure of the study 3
Chapter 2
Framing the discussion: concepts, theoretical foundations
and application to agriculture 5
2.1 Spatial development initiatives 5
2.2 Definition of economic corridors and related concepts 8
2.3 Types of economic corridors 11
2.4 Theoretical foundations of economic corridors 13
2.5 Corridors and other territorial-based approaches for accelerating
agribusiness growth and attracting investment in developing
country agriculture 18
Chapter 3
Overview of the corridor profiles 25
3.1 Introduction to the mapping and selection exercise
of economic corridor initiatives in developing countries 25
3.2 African corridors and their policy background 26
3.3 Latin american corridors and their policy background 29
3.4 Asian corridors and their policy background 33
3.5 Summary of economic corridors selected 35
3.6 Framework proposed for the analysis of economic corridors 37
iv
Chapter 4
Introduction to the corridor cases 39
4.1 Corridor cases at a glance 39
4.2 Timeline of the corridors studied 48
Chapter 5
Effective direction 55
5.1 Corridor leadership and alignment of stakeholders’ visions
and goals 55
5.2 Corridor strategy and targeting modalities 56
5.3 Processes and tools for planning and launching
corridor programmes 68
Chapter 6
Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 75
6.1 Budget and sources of funding 75
6.2 Modalities of interventions 80
6.3 Laying the corridor basis: infrastructure development 83
6.4 Components geared towards widening national corridors 95
6.5 Corridor components dealing with regional integration:
from national to regional corridors 110
6.6 Specialization in value chains and market orientation 116
Chapter 7
Delivery at scale: corridor governance 125
7.1 Corridor leadership and alignment of stakeholders’ visions
and goals 125
7.2 Engagement models 131
7.3 Institutional arrangements and delivery mechanisms 134
Chapter 8
Gains and pitfalls of agrocorridor initiatives 145
8.1 Potential gains of agrocorridors for economic growth,
trade and connectivity 145
8.2 Pitfalls to avoid 153
Chapter 9
Guidance for making economic corridors work
for the agricultural sector 161
9.1 Best practices in economic corridor design and implementation 161
9.2 Checklist to guide the design and implementation
of an (agro-)economic corridor 167
Chapter 10
Conclusions 177
10.1 General conclusions 177
10.2 Looking forward: implications and suggestions for future studies 180
v
Annex 1
Glossary 181
Annex 2
Economic corridors identified 187
Bibliography 191
BOXES
1. Spatial planning and spatial development initiatives 6
2. Definition of corridors 8
3. Attributes of spatial development 14
4. Definition of economies of scale and scope, and agglomeration forces 16
5. Metatrends shaping the agricultural sector 20
6. Evolution of the PRA corridors: a moving target 50
7. Vision alignment among corridor stakeholders in the BAGC
and SAGCOT 57
8. The development of a corridor strategy: the case of the PRA Project 61
9. Rationale behind the design of the corridor programme pillars 66
10. The GMS Strategic Framework 2012–2022 69
11. How BAGCI and SAGCOT approach infrastructure development 85
12. The infrastructure component of the PRA Project 91
13. Examples of last-mile infrastructure development
in economic corridors 96
14. Corridor centres 99
15. Corridor financial facilities 100
16. Clustering in SAGCOT 104
17. Engaging the private sector in regional corridor programmes:
the case of GMS 112
18. Corridor specialization in agricultural value chains 117
19. Coordination problems between central and decentralized
public authorities 129
20. Institutional arrangements and delivery mechanisms
of the GMS corridor programme 135
21. Institutional arrangements and delivery mechanisms
of the PRA Project 139
22. BAGCI’s institutional arrangements and delivery mechanisms 141
FIGURES
1. Potential development path for corridors 9
2. IIRSA integration corridors or hubs 32
3. A framework for economic corridors 37
4. The three GMS corridors 42
5. Corridors of the CAREC programme 43
vi
Tables
1. Main features of the most prominent types of SDI 7
2. Types of economic corridors 11
3. Estimated world inward FDI stock by sector and region
in million US$, annual 21
4. Corridors identified in Africa 26
5. Policy and institutional framework informing the development
of African corridors 27
6. Corridors identified in Latin America and the Caribbean 30
7. Policy and institutional framework informing the development
of LAC corridors 31
8. Economic corridors identified in Asia 33
9. Policy and institutional framework informing
the development of Asian corridors 34
10. Summary of corridor profiles 36
vii
Preface
The report shows how corridors help improve physical connectivity and func-
tioning of markets, while generating economies of scale in agriculture and other
priority sectors. Based on the findings of the study, I have compiled two guidance
tools: the first is a checklist for designing and implementing agrocorridor policies
and programmes, while the second sheds light on good practices and common pit-
falls in agrocorridor development. I sincerely hope that policy-makers, practitioners
and territorial planners will find these tools useful to foster agribusiness competi-
tiveness in their respective localities, countries and regional groups.
Acknowledgements
This book benefited greatly from the contributions of many individuals, and
particularly my former colleagues from the PRA Project in Peru from whom I
learned many valuable lessons on the potential of economic corridors for agri-
business development. I would like to express my deepest gratitude to Dr Javier
García-Verdugo Sales (UNED) for his excellent guidance and practical suggestions.
Thanks are extended to FAO colleagues who reviewed earlier drafts or contributed
insights and definitions. Finally, I wish to thank Larissa D’Aquilio for coordinating
the publication production process, Roberta Mitchell for the copy editing, Monica
Umena for the layout, Simone Morini and Lynette Chalk for quality control and
proof-reading.
xi
Executive summary
In times of economic crisis, development models that help create jobs, generate
wealth, mobilize public and private resources and stimulate key economic sectors
sustainably are more important than ever. While there are no universal solutions, a
development tool that seems to be gaining ground is the so-called “economic cor-
ridor”. This could be defined as a conceptual and programmatic model to structure
socio-economic responses to develop a territory, building on a linear agglomeration
of population and economic activities along existing transportation infrastructure
(adapted from Healey, 2004).
Many high-income countries and regions have placed corridors at the centre of
their economic and territorial development strategies. Similarly, over a decade ago
many of the most dynamic emerging and developing countries started using this
approach. Various international financial institutions are also employing corridors
as the core strategy for supporting regional integration processes in the Southern
Hemisphere. Likewise, private firms (either local or multinational) are increasingly
participating in corridors, together with their public sector counterparts.
Five factors may be behind the expansion of the corridor phenomenon. First, a
corridor is a “smart” tool for integrated territorial planning that combines inter-
ventions in infrastructure (and related services) with specific actions to boost key
sectors. Second, economic corridor programmes encompass a set of coordinated
actions that ensure a critical mass of investments with the ability to transform the
territory. Third, corridors are intrinsically conducive to generating multistakeholder
strategic alliances for development, with the participation of local and central public
authorities, private actors and donors, among others. The fourth factor is the symbi-
otic relationship between corridors and regional trading blocs, which often go hand
in hand. According to Ernst and Young (2011a), combining corridors and regional
trading blocs helps to deepen conventional country-based macro-analysis, in a way
that enriches strategic thinking about how to spur inclusive and sustainable growth
in the developing world. The last factor is that through years of trial and error, best
design and implementation practices have been identified, contributing to improv-
ing the performance of new and ongoing corridor interventions.
This study tries to shed some light on economic corridors in developing and
emerging countries. In their part of the world, the agricultural and agro-industrial
sectors are among the main employment generators and contributors to gross
domestic product (GDP). Naturally, many corridor initiatives in developing coun-
tries target the agricultural sector, which is why the study focuses on the potential
role of economic corridors as an engine of agricultural growth.
The report appraises economic corridor experiences with a strong agricultural
component in Central Asia, the Greater Mekong Subregion, Indonesia, Mozam-
bique, Peru and the United Republic of Tanzania. It also documents the evolution
of corridor interventions from purely transport sector-based initiatives, to logis-
xii
tics and trade corridors, and finally to economic corridors with a multisectoral
approach. It corroborates that agriculture has become a key part of economic cor-
ridor programmes, especially in the Southern Hemisphere.
The comparative analysis undertaken here seeks to establish a corridor typol-
ogy, and to identify the main drivers and components. It also describes corridor
budgets and sources of funding, stakeholders, and management and governance1
mechanisms. A large part of this cross-comparison focuses on the agricultural com-
ponent of corridor interventions, identifying the most recurrent activities under this
component, the financial resources involved, the most often selected subsectors or
value chains2 and target markets (domestic and international), the interface between
infrastructure and agro-industrial development and the positive or negative impacts
of corridor interventions on the agricultural sector.
Finally, the author proposes a checklist of necessary measures or elements that
those interested in developing agrocorridors can use as a reference for deciding what
activities to pursue, what organizational models are most suitable and clarify the
steps that need to be taken.
1
See Glossary.
2
See Glossary.
xiii
Abstract
Ms Gálvez Nogales holds two bachelor degrees in Economics and Business Admin-
istration from the University of Deusto, Bilbao, and a Ph.D. in Applied Economics.
Following several work assignments in Spain and Peru, she joined the Food and
Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) in 2003, where she serves
as a Marketing and Agribusiness Economist.
xv
Acronyms
Chapter 1
Introduction
3
See Glossary.
4
Spatial/territorial development/planning are considered synonyms.
5
A definition of these concepts is provided in 2.1.
2 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
1.3 METHODOLOGY
The methodology includes a literature review on the subject of economic cor-
ridors and related concepts, comprising the economic theories underpinning this
approach. The literature review also serves the purpose of mapping out economic
corridor initiatives in low- and middle-income countries. Additionally, key docu-
ments are examined, describing territorial development and regional integration
strategies in which economic corridors are listed as a core approach to agricultural
growth and development.
Upon completion of the mapping exercise of economic corridor programmes, a
number of initiatives have been selected by applying a predetermined set of criteria.
These include the existence of an agricultural component, a minimum budget
allocation, and diversity of approaches, lead conveners and stakeholders. The
selected economic corridor cases include experiences from Central Asia, the Greater
Mekong Subregion (GMS), Indonesia, Mozambique, Peru and the United Republic
of Tanzania. Some of the chosen corridors are at country level while others involve
multiple countries.
The analytical core of the study consists of a comparative analysis of the selected
experiences concerning economic corridors with an agricultural or agribusiness
component in developing and emerging economies. This analysis is performed using
a comprehensive framework for characterizing and appraising the case studies, thus
exposing the main traits of the corridors, their strengths, weaknesses, preconditions
for their effectiveness, as well as performance.
6
See Glossary.
Chapter 1 – Introduction 3
The intended final outcome of the research is to produce a checklist that may
guide analysts and policy-makers in the design and evaluation of effective agricul-
tural components in the framework of an economic corridor programme.
Chapter 2
Framing the discussion:
concepts, theoretical foundations
and application to agriculture
This chapter delineates the concept of SDI and the different programmatic tools that
are encompassed under this umbrella term: economic corridors, clusters, industrial
parks, SEZs and technopoles. Although these SDIs are applied on the global scale,
in this study the accent is placed on developing and emerging economies. The dis-
cussion then centres on the definition and typology of economic corridor, with its
different nuances in approaches (e.g. economic, development and trade corridors).
The theoretical foundations behind corridors are briefly explained. Finally the dis-
cussion shifts towards the application of corridor schemes to the agricultural sector
as a means to attract investments.
7
Described in Chapters 4 to 7.
6 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 1
Spatial planning and spatial development initiatives
Spatial planning seeks to organize physically a geographic zone according to an overall strat-
egy. In keeping with the proposed strategy, the government seeks to influence the distribu-
tion of people and activities at various scales of space, as well as the location of infrastructure
and residential, business and natural areas. When doing so, it pays particular attention to
ensuring the coherence of sectoral policies that affect the territory.
The underlying objectives of spatial development tend to form a triangle linking three
goals: enhancing competitiveness (by promoting trade and investment, optimizing the use
of infrastructure and encouraging value-addition, among others); ensuring social cohesion;
and promoting the conservation of natural resources and cultural heritage (EC, 1999). This
triple goal of economic development, balance and protection (i.e. avoiding the production of
negative externalities) must be reconciled when planning the desired spatial transformation
of a country or region.
SDIs are the ultimate expression of spatial planning. According to CEMAT (2007), SDIs
are projects generated or driven by the public sector that contribute positively to territorial
development on different scales. SDIs are characterized for:
being designed and implemented based on specific geographic linkages (USAID, 2000);
constituting a cluster of mutually reinforcing development projects established to help a
geographic area thrive, as opposed to stand-alone initiatives (Du Pisanie, 2002);
being embedded in an institutional framework to facilitate their design, implementation
and monitoring (ibid.);
linking infrastructure and large-scale economic sectoral investments in defined geographic
areas (Thomas, 2009).
Examples of these interventions are highlighted in the analysis of the corridor experiences.
8
See Glossary.
Chapter 2 – Framing the discussion: concepts, theoretical foundations [...] 7
Table 1
Main features of the most prominent types of SDI
Prominent features
Type of SDI
Sectoral/
Overall purpose Geographic scope Emphasized feature
industry scope
Agro-industrial Value addition Urban (accessible distance Single sector/ Common infrastructure
park by processing from production area); multisectoral and logistics facilities
a few ha
Technopole Innovation Park + academic
and research institutions
Special Export and Urban (possibly near Single sector/ Advantageous economic
economic zone promotion of to port area if it is an multisectoral and regulatory
(SEZ) foreign direct export promotion zone); frameworks
investment (FDI) a few ha
units. For instance, in the Chilean province of Bío Bío there is a blueberry cluster
that covers 3 400 ha (FAO, 2010). Technopoles, industrial parks, SEZs and business
incubators have a more restricted geographic scope, as they generally take up only
a few ha usually located on the outskirts of a city. For example, Moroccan and
Tunisian food technopoles span over 100 ha on average (FAO, 2011).
There is much diversity in terms of sectoral or industry scope: some SDIs attach
themselves to a particular sector, while others are multisectoral. For example, clus-
ters are “geographic concentrations of inter-connected companies and institutions
in a particular field” or industry (Porter, 1998; p. 78). Technopoles and SEZs, on the
other hand, can either target single sector or multisectoral development. Corridors
are among the most complex schemes; not only are they multisectoral, but they
have other interrelated dimensions besides economic sector development, such as
infrastructure, urbanization and environmental sustainability (CEMAT, 2007).
Additionally, each type of SDI places emphasis on different matters. The core
element of technopoles is to bring together in one location (or in multiple nearby
interrelated locations) the necessary elements (shared facilities and services) for
making innovation happen (FAO, 2011). For SEZs, the underscored feature is
the provision of economic and regulatory frameworks (e.g. low tax and incentive
regimes, including exemptions on sales/value added and/or income taxes),9 which
9
For example, the transfer of assets in cases of shifting any industry from an urban area to a SEZ can be
exempted from tax on capital gains or an income tax deduction might be offered for a period of time.
8 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
are relatively more liberal than in standard locations. Industrial parks allow the pro-
vision of common infrastructure facilities, while also helping the industries present
there to gain from other benefits of clustering (FAO, 2006). Finally, corridors foster
economic activities along a transport and trade route by adding, to large-scale trans-
port and trade infrastructure development, policy and programmatic interventions,
with a holistic and multisectoral approach, as explained under the next heading.
A trend consistently observed across developing countries is the combination
of several types of initiatives in a geographic area. Particular corridors can contain
several industrial zones, SEZs and other SDIs. For instance, the Delhi-Mumbai
industrial corridor incorporates nine mega industrial zones (FAO, unpublished
research), and the GMS corridors include several cross-border SEZs and industrial
parks, as will be seen in Chapters 4 to 7.
BOX 2
Definition of corridors
figure 1
Potential development path for corridors
Transport corridor Logistics corridor Trade corridor Economic corridor Growth corridor
Transport Transport Logistics Trade Economic
infrastructure corridor corridor corridor corridor
+ + + + +
Transport services Logistics Trade facilitation Other economic Coordination of
coordination dimensions non-economic
elements
routes the corridor links large urban centres (with high economic density) and other
smaller nodes (intermediate cities and towns) that may exist in between the land
surrounding the corridor.
Gateways (e.g. airports and ports) that bond the economic nodes to the hinterland
or to global trade routes are particularly important (IDB, 2011), to the point that
some corridors are defined by their major gateways (e.g. the Maputo Development
Corridor connecting the port of Maputo to the industrial areas around Witbank
in eastern South Africa). Transport corridors may include short and long legs: the
short legs connect local or regional centres (urban and industrial zones), whereas
the long legs may incorporate road, rail, inland waterways and short sea shipping.
Depending on the number of transport modes that are being integrated, corridors
can be unimodal, bimodal or multimodal. Transport corridors can be approached as
individual projects or as part of a transportation network, for example, on a regional
basis. Furthermore, a network of transport corridors can be integrated into broader
infrastructure programmes that encompass for instance power and telecommunica-
tion networks.
The main function of transport corridors is to provide more efficient transport
services in terms of time, and economic and environmental costs (Arnold, Olivier
and Arvis, 2005), by improving both transport infrastructure and services. Con-
sequently, they reduce transport costs, sustain the rapid expansion of trade and
facilitate integration within the country or supranational region and into global
markets. This is particularly true for developing landlocked countries.10
10
According to estimates by the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD),
landlocked countries spend on average almost twice more of their export earnings for the payment
of transport and insurance services than the average for developing countries, and three times more
than the average of economies belonging to the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD). According to the United Nations Office of the High Representative for the
Least Developed Countries, Landlocked Developing Countries and Small Island Developing States,
of 48 landlocked countries worldwide, 30 are classified as developing countries, of which 16 are least
developed. Source: http://www.un.org/special-rep/ohrlls/lldc/default.htm [Accessed May 2013].
10 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Logistics corridors are corridors that not only physically link an area or a region
but also harmonize the institutional framework pertaining to logistics and all
technological, organizational and legal conditions for such transportation. Their
objective is to facilitate the efficient movement and storage of freight, people and
related information (Banomyong, 2008).
The concept of trade corridors lacks a precise widely agreed upon definition.
In simple terms it can be understood as a transport (or logistics) corridor where
additional trade facilitation efforts11 are being deployed. In physical terms, trade
corridors seek to improve trade flows (and more generally the movements of goods,
services and people) by connecting one or more adjoining countries, or by provid-
ing access to the sea for landlocked countries. From a functional standpoint, trade
corridors emphasize the need to eliminate barriers hindering the seamless movement
of passengers and goods by streamlining and simplifying trade/customs procedures
and trade policy. Examples of such barriers in transnational corridors are: incompat-
ible customs information technologies; the absence or inadequacy of transnational
legislation; operational obstacles stemming from heterogeneous transport, freight
and custom regulations; and incomplete networks of cross-border links.
Economic corridors encompass analytical and policy dimensions. The analytical
dimension defines the corridor on the basis of spatial-functional forms and patterns
(reinforcing the idea that corridors are linear clusters of land uses that interact with
each other such that the whole is greater than the sum of its parts (Albrechts and
Tasan-Kok, 2009). The policy dimension interprets corridors as policy and spatial
planning instruments (ibid.). One of the key features defining economic corridors
is their ability to attract investment and generate economic activities along an area
or region. Yet to achieve this, physical connectivity and logistics facilitation must be
in place (Banomyong, 2008).
Economic, development and growth corridors are frequently employed in an
interchangeable manner referring to the elevation of an area to a certain level of
development (Campbell, Maritz, and Hauptfleisch, 2009). However, development
or growth corridors could also be interpreted as those where non-economic ele-
ments (e.g. health systems, environment protection [green corridors], and cultural
dimensions) have been added to economic initiatives. For the sake of simplification,
in the present document all these terms are considered synonyms.
While it is important to distinguish between transport, trade and economic
corridors, they are all inherently designed for fostering spatial economic growth,
through the improvement of primarily transport and logistics services available to
cities and countries along the corridor. Moreover, there is a natural, evolutionary
relationship between trade and economic corridors. This relationship pushes cor-
ridor stakeholders increasingly to incorporate new economic promotion elements
in the original strategy of transport (and trade) corridors, as in the cases of the GMS
corridor programme and the East and southern Africa corridors (Arnold, 2006),
analysed in Chapters 3 to 7. Furthermore, whether they are labelled one way or
another, corridors must make economic sense in order to be viable. This implies
11
See Glossary.
Chapter 2 – Framing the discussion: concepts, theoretical foundations [...] 11
the existence of nodes with substantive economic density and additional growth
potential, and the possibility of amplifying the potential for economic growth of
areas in between core economic nodes. As ADB (2011c; p. 3) puts it, a corridor from
“nowhere to nowhere through nowhere” would never be meaningful.
The transition across the various sequenced stages may take place in different
ways and at a different pace. This depends on the stakeholders (whether public or
private investments are leading the way); market orientation (which will largely
depend on the predominance of foreign direct investment (FDI) or more domestic-
bound investors); policy focus (policies friendly to small and medium enterprises
[SMEs] vis-à-vis policies favouring large industrial enterprises and logistics compa-
nies) and sectoral priorities (ADB, 2011c).
Table 2
Types of economic corridors
12
For the purpose of this report, “cross-border” is between two or more countries sharing borders,
“transnational or multinational” refers to several countries (not necessarily neighbour nations), and
“regional” encompasses all the countries in a region.
12 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
of thinning national borders. Some corridors are relatively short in length, e.g. the
Maputo Corridor that links Mozambique and South Africa, while others are defined
by the transnational region they serve, such as the GMS corridor (Arnold, 2006).
In supraregional or cross-border regional corridors, the emphasis is on regional
cooperation (e.g. transport and trade facilitation, and policy harmonization) across
the countries involved (ADB, 2011c). This leads to important differences in stake-
holders, policy space and institutional options for coordinating actions compared
with subnational regional planning (Marrian, 2001).
Also regarding their geographic scope, most economic corridors comprise both
urban and rural areas. However, some economic corridors develop predominantly
in an urban context. These are known as urban corridors (UN-HABITAT, 2010a;
2010b; 2012), in which several urban spaces of various sizes, including megaci-
ties, are linearly connected through transport networks that improve connections
between cities and open up the hinterlands (UN-HABITAT, 2010a; 2012). Many
urban corridors are experiencing the fastest growth rates and the most rapid met-
ropolitan transformation. In these corridors, urban planning (metropolitan areas
and major cities and towns) goes hand in hand with the development of strategic
transport infrastructure (and other regional infrastructure networks including, in
particular, the water and sewage infrastructure) required to support urban growth,
and a long-term strategy for the integrated development of agricultural, industrial
and mixed-use areas (Rodrigue, Comtois and Slack, 2009; GAA, 2012).
As regards the sectoral scope, most economic corridors are multisectoral as they
target several industries and sectors simultaneously. However, on some occasions,
corridor initiatives are monosectoral, i.e. they focus on one major sector alongside
transport/infrastructure development. In this case, they are usually labelled upon
the selected sector: energy corridor, health corridor, agricultural corridor, and min-
ing, multimedia hi-tech, industrial manufacturing and tourism corridors, and so on.
Some examples include several energy corridors (oil, gas, electricity and hydrogen
corridors) serving the European Union (EU)13 (Marín-Quemada, García-Verdugo
and Escribano, 2012); the Caspian Region Energy Corridor (Mavrakis, Thomaidis
and Ntroukas, 2006); the Sarawak Corridor of Renewable Energy in Malaysia
(Sovacool and Bulan, 2012); the Multimedia Super Corridor in Malaysia (Bunnell
and Coe, 2005); the Lao Tourism Corridor (Travers, 2008); the Mauritanian Mining
Corridor (World Bank, 2008b); and oil corridors in many African countries.
Agribusiness is one of the most commonly prioritized sectors that are supported
by and expected to act as an engine for growth in developing country corridors. At
times, the whole economic corridor programme revolves around agricultural and
agribusiness development concentrated around a major infrastructure investment or
set of interrelated infrastructure projects. In this case, the corridor can be described
as an agricultural corridor or agrocorridor. In reality, these agricultural corridors
are a bisectoral solution, in the sense that they try to create synergies by simultane-
ously developing both the agricultural and the infrastructure sectors (e.g. transport,
13
Reaccess project (7th Framework Programme of the European Commission), information available
at: http://reaccess.epu.ntua.gr/VirtualLibrary/EnergyCorridors.aspx [last accessed August 2013].
Chapter 2 – Framing the discussion: concepts, theoretical foundations [...] 13
14
See Glossary for a definition of PPPs.
14 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 3
Attributes of spatial development
economic nodes in a large spatial area, so that transport costs and agglomeration
benefits for the total area increase as a whole. An explanation of agglomeration
economies and other related concepts is offered in Box 4.
People, regions and countries specialize in producing certain goods and services
for which they have an advantage. Greater specialization allows them to take full
advantage of economies of scale. Scale economies generate an uneven pattern
of specialization and trade (of both intermediate and final outputs), and market
dominance, ultimately creating an irregular mosaic of economic development across
regions and countries.
If trade is largely shaped by economies of scale, then those economic regions
with most production will be more profitable and will therefore attract even more
production. This is known as the “home market effect”, i.e. the “gravitational force”
that attracts imperfectly competition towards large markets, creating geographic
agglomerations of economic activities (Ottaviano and Thisse, 2004). This implies
that instead of spreading out evenly around the world, production will tend to
concentrate in a few locations, which will become densely populated (by firms and
people) and will also enjoy higher levels of income.
The home market effect is enlarged by some amplifiers that give rise to circular
causation in locational decisions, according to the core-periphery model. Such
amplification effect ends up creating the uneven development of two regions: a
“core” region where the majority of the population concentrate, which specializes in
a competitive economic sector, leaving a small minority in the “periphery” to live off
a less competitive activity (Krugman, 1991). The core-periphery model also explains
north-south uneven development. For over a century and a half global economic
activity has concentrated in the Northern Hemisphere, creating an uneven display of
economic tissue, far denser in the north (core) than in southern peripheral regions.
Economic integration,15 i.e. the abolition of the various restraints of trade
between nations, has remained central in the territorial debate, whether it refers to
integrating cross-border regions or lagging and leading countries.
Migration and factor mobility in general, happen on three geographic scales: the
urban-rural scale, between lagging and leading regions within a country, or between
countries. Human capital moves to where it is abundant, not scant (World Bank,
2009a). The reality is that skilled migrants naturally seek places where workers with
similar high-level specialized skills abound. Recognizing scale economies and their
interaction with the mobility of people and products implies changing conventional
ideas about what is needed for economic growth. According to the World Bank
(2009a), countries should facilitate labour mobility if they wish to prosper. The
willingness and ability of workers to move seems to be an adequate gauge of their
economic potential and desire for advancement. The implication for policy-makers
is that the market force which pulls skilled people together should not be interfered
with, nor underestimated. Smoothing the flow of educated migrants, upgrading
their capacities, while minimizing the potential adverse effects of such migration,
are important elements of SDIs.
15
See Glossary.
16 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 4
Definition of economies of scale and scope, and agglomeration forces
Economies of scale are concerned with the reductions in cost per unit resulting from
increased production. They can be internal to the firm (when the cost per unit depends on
the size of the firm), or external when the lowering of costs is due to external factors (e.g.
proximity to workers, customers and people with new ideas).
External economies of scale will increase the productivity of an entire industry,
geographic area or economy. The external factors are outside the control of a particular
company, and encompass positive externalities that reduce the firm’s costs. Such positive
externalities can be localized producing agglomeration economies called localization econo-
mies, which can be defined as “cost reductions because economic activities are located in
one place” (McDonald and McMillen, 2007). Such economies of scale are shared by firms
in the same industry and location. The decision of firms regarding their location might be
altered by infrastructure investments capable of modifying the equation of transportation
costs, or as Carciofi (2012; p. 67) notes: “the development of infrastructure rebalances the
centripetal and centrifugal forces behind locational decisions”.
There are more generally available external economies of scale that thrive on economic
density or urbanization economies (World Bank, 2009a). In spite of the clear correlation
between the size of the settlement and the type of economies of scale that they are likely to
provide, “the size of settlements matters less than their function” (ibid.). For example, with
reasonable transport costs, towns can be large enough to facilitate internal scale economies
but not to generate external ones, whereas medium-size cities are often large enough for
localization economies due to their relatively thick input markets,16 but not for urbanization
economies – especially those involving knowledge spillovers − generated mainly by large
cities. The main implication for policy-makers is to focus on the functions of cities as nodes
of high economic density and make the most of their dynamic business environment.
The causes or microfoundations of agglomeration include the following centripetal forc-
es: labour market pooling, input sharing and knowledge spillovers (Marshall, 1890), as well
as economies derived from concentration of demand and natural advantages. These forces
are external factors to the firms, but internal to the industry, generating shifts in their cost
curves and enhancing the economic performance of the agglomerated firms. Some of the
various aspects of economic performance from clustering are enhanced innovation; higher
input (labour/capital) demand or price (wage/asset value); greater productivity; reduced
costs; and location decisions or firm “births” (Cohen and Morrison Paul, 2007).
The term economy of scope was coined by Panzar and Willig (1981) to describe a rather
intuitive property of production consisting of the cost advantages derived from the scope
(rather than the scale) of the firm. It can be defined as the reduction of an enterprise’s costs
deriving from enlargement of scope, either as a result of increasing the number of different
goods produced or of producing in more than one location (Teece, 1980). The existence
of economies of scope in production is the necessary condition for outsourcing to occur
because, without it, vertical disintegration along the global value chain has no advantage in
reducing the production costs of the intermediate products.
16
See Glossary.
Chapter 2 – Framing the discussion: concepts, theoretical foundations [...] 17
17
See Glossary.
18 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
account both private and public sector interests, in an effort to avoid an arbitrary
selection (not on economic grounds) of prioritized sectors and industries, which has
been a recurrent feature of traditional development interventions.
The theory also seems to highlight the advantages of spatial development
approaches for enhancing regional integration. Falling transport costs increase trade
more with neighbouring, not distant, countries. With a decline in transport costs,
countries should trade more with countries that are further away. But trade has
become more localized than globalized. Countries trade more with nations that are
similar, because more than ever the basis of trade is the exploitation of economies of
scale, rather than differences in natural endowments. The main rationale behind this is
that falling transport costs make specialization possible. The resulting policy implica-
tion is that falling costs change the composition of international trade and increase
the sensitivity to such costs. Therefore, for late developers, policies to decrease trade
and transport costs should be a substantial element of their growth strategies (World
Bank, 2009a). This explains why economic integration is increasingly important.
The debate is still open in terms of identifying the best practices for incorporating
agricultural development strategies into spatial development programmes, because
of the specificities of the agricultural sector (e.g. dependence on natural resources
endowment and highly influenced by climate change).
The concept of corridors has its roots firmly entrenched in the transport sector
but, over time, it has accumulated progressive layers of spatially bounded interven-
tions targeting multiple economic sectors.
One of the keys to designing agrobased corridors successfully is to understand
the main features of the extended agricultural sector and the metatrends18 reshaping
it, as seen in Box 5. Agriculture is evolving from its traditional form – a labour-
intensive and lesser capital-intensive sector dominated by unskilled workers,
and characterized by long and fragmented supply chains – to become a modern
economic activity that uses skilled labour. It is also highly standardized, input
intensive, concentrated and capital and technology intensive (e.g. some tractors now
deploy global positioning systems [GPS] to apply fertilizers to cropland more pre-
cisely). This transformation is being spurred on by several factors, such as income
and population growth; urbanization and female employment; political economy
change; and modern technology (FAO and UNIDO, 2009).
Countries and regions where agribusinesses are not agglomerating spontane-
ously, or not at the desired pace, might wish to catalyse this agglomeration process
by implementing SDIs targeting the sector. Furthermore, the overwhelming pres-
sure exerted by these compounded trends on developing country agribusiness
forces them to become more global while remaining competitive and sustainable.
Paradoxically, the more globalization forces expose the agricultural sector to far-
reaching changes, the more local solutions emerge to foster local competitiveness,
and the more attention is being paid towards agro spatially bound initiatives.
The last few years have seen a surge of interest in developing country agriculture
by both countries and multinational firms; the former in support of their food secu-
rity strategy and the latter motivated by potentially high returns on investment. On
the other hand, some developing nations are making strenuous efforts to mobilize and
facilitate foreign and domestic investment in their agricultural sectors. For them, FDI
is a potentially important contributor to filling the investment gap, which has been
identified as an underlying cause of the recent food crisis and the difficulties develop-
ing economies encountered in dealing with it (FAO, 2009a). Economic corridors can
be instrumental in rallying investments in targeted sectors, including agriculture.
Investment in agriculture is positively correlated with production levels, food
security and poverty reduction (FAO, 2012b). Regrettably, over the past decades,
the level of agricultural investment in developing economies has declined, mostly
due to the downturn in public and international donor spending.19 Yet, to feed the
world’s growing population, investment in primary agriculture and downstream
services (including storage, processing and market facilities) needs to be augmented
by 50 percent in 2050, i.e. US$83 billion per year of additional investments (FAO,
2009b; 2012a; 2012b). The gap in required investment levels is even larger when
considering public goods that are essential for agribusiness development such as
roads, electrification and large-scale irrigation projects that were not included in the
above estimate.
18
See Glossary.
19
The share of official development assistance directed to agriculture has fallen from around 10 to
5 percent (Hallam, 2011).
20 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 5
Metatrends shaping the agricultural sector
According to Reardon and Barrett (2000), five major trends are fuelling this evolution.
1. Increase in scale and concentration at the firm, spatial and sectoral levels. Agricultural
supply chains are progressively operating at a global scale thanks to a policy environ-
ment that encourages free trade, as well as to the availability of new production, pro-
cessing and logistics technologies (FAO and UNIDO, 2009). On the one hand, globali-
zation forces are generating the spatial agglomeration of agroprocessing firms and,
on the other, a faster pace of concentration and vertical integration in agricultural
chains. These processes result in a diminishing number of economic players (a few
multinational agribusiness companies) exerting their power over global buyer-driven
supply chains, at least for many commodities (Reardon and Barrett, 2000; Reardon,
Pingali and Stamoulis, 2006; Ruben, Slingerland and Nijhoff, 2006).
2. Changes in commodity and subsector composition on two fronts. First, broad com-
modity shifts associated with rising incomes20 and with new or expanding existing
uses (fuel21 and feed, respectively) are taking place. The second front is the so-called
“supermarket revolution”, occurring in both developing and industrialized markets
(Reardon, Timmer and Minten, 2010). This term alludes to the consecutive waves22
of diffusion of supermarkets (referring to all sorts of modern retail activities) in the
developing regions of Africa, Asia and Latin America. The revolution or rise of super-
markets has manifested itself in sales growing at a spectacular rate, far faster than
GDP growth rates. It has had profound impacts on agrifood systems, some positive
(lower food prices for consumers and market opportunities for farmers and proces-
sors producing quality-differentiated food products), and some negative (exclusion
of small-scale actors ill-equipped to meet supermarkets’ stringent procurement
requirements) (Reardon et al., 2003; Reardon, Timmer and Minten, 2010). The rise
of modern retailing has come at the expense of the traditional wholesale channel.
3. Amplified multinationalization and export orientation of agricultural supply chains.
4. Mass adoption of coordination and control mechanisms (e.g. grades and standards)
reshaping the governance of agricultural chains.23
5. The use of production factors has been intensified at all stages of the value chain
(production, processing and retailing) in terms of professionalization of the labour
force and higher capital intensity.
20
When consumers move up into higher-income brackets they tend to substitute starchy food staples
with higher-value, more processed and convenient food products, such as fruit and vegetables, oils
and processed grains, meat and dairy products (FAO and UNIDO, 2009).
21
Several food crops (e.g. corn, soybeans, sugar cane and wheat) are increasingly being grown for
producing biofuel.
22
The first wave swept much of South America, East Asia (outside China) and South Africa; the
second wave, Mexico, Central America and much of Southeast Asia; the third wave, China, India
and Viet Nam; and the last is currently taking place in Bangladesh, Cambodia and West Africa
(Reardon, Timmer and Minten, 2010).
23
See Glossary for a definition of governance and value chains.
Chapter 2 – Framing the discussion: concepts, theoretical foundations [...] 21
BOX 5 (Continued)
To make up for the fall in public spending and overseas development aid, many
developing economies are committed to promoting investment in their agricultural
sectors.24 Seemingly, these efforts have paid off: inward FDI stock in developing
country agriculture increased 6.4-fold between 1990 and 2009 (UNCTAD, 2011)
and has risen even more since (FAO, 2012a). In the same period, inward FDI stock
in food and beverages increased 6.1-fold in developing countries and 6.4-fold in
developed countries (UNCTAD, 2011). See Table 3 for further information.
The rise of FDI inflows into developing country agriculture is particularly
remarkable, given the current worldwide downturn in FDI, induced by the global
economic crisis (UNCTAD, 2012). This success is compounded by the supe-
rior performance of developing and transition economies – investments to these
economies surged, increasing their share in global FDI flows to 45 percent in 2011
(UNCTAD, 2012). FDI activity in primary and extended agriculture in recent years
has been exceptional, particularly in a context where FDI flows into most industries
substantially declined (UNCTAD, 2009a; 2011; 2012). In spite of this recent spike,
the share of total FDI that is directed to agriculture remains low with respect to
other sectors.25 A survey performed by FAO (2012a) revealed that FDI flows into
Table 3
Estimated world inward FDI stock by sector and region in million US$, annual
Agriculture, hunting, Food, beverages and tobacco All sectors
forestry and fishing
Developed
3 733 16 328 76 100 487 649 1 562 296 12 296 706
economies
Developing
4 850 31 053 11 036 67 670 517 200 5 120 182
economies
Transition
– 2 995 – 13 172 1 652 624 121
economies
Source: UNCTAD (2011; Annex Table 24); and UNCTAD-STAD, FDI series. Inward and outward foreign direct
investment flows and stocks. Annual, 1980–2011.
Note: US$ at current prices and current exchange rates in millions.
24
Traditionally, investment promotion has been associated with attracting and facilitating FDI to a
particular country, but has evolved over time to become applicable to lower levels of the economy,
such as channelling investment into specific cities or regions within a country or a particular economic
sector. Furthermore, the concept has since been applicable to domestic private investment as well.
25
The absence of available updated FDI data by sector/industry for developing countries precludes a
deeper analysis of sectoral differences.
22 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
agriculture were below 5 percent of total FDI inflows, and in the majority of cases
even under 2 percent.
The reasons behind this FDI surge are manifold and complex. They include both
cyclical factors (e.g. the steep rise in agricultural commodity prices in 2007–2008,
speculation on land and other natural resources, and search for alternative energy
sources) and structural drivers (e.g. growing population, rising consumption rates
and market demand for food and biofuels) (FAO, 2012a; 2012b). The bulk of
agricultural FDI flows has been directed to the food manufacturing sector, while
primary agricultural production accounted for less than 10 percent between 2006
and 2008 (FAO, 2012a). Nonetheless, this statement might need some qualification,
as FDI in the primary agricultural sector is difficult to track back (ibid.).
The recognition that private sector investment is needed to leverage addi-
tional funds, expertise and other resources for agricultural growth has pushed public
policy to provide an enabling environment for private investments in agribusiness.
Over the years, developing countries have adopted a wide range of economic
prescriptions for creating enabling environments and “getting markets right” (FAO
and UNIDO, 2009; p. 136). These prescriptions include a variety of agricultural and
macroeconomic policies that have a direct impact on the agricultural sector. Cases in
point are the deregulation of the economy, the opening up of domestic markets to
world markets, the privatization of state-owned enterprises, increased investments
in research and development, the provision of rural credit, and minimum guaranteed
producer prices (FAO and UNIDO, 2009; FAO, 2012a). The resulting improved
business climate is expected to attract capital to invest in specific firm strategies and
general market-based solutions that contribute to both development and economic
growth goals (FAO and UNIDO, 2009).
More recently, developing country governments have become keen on fostering
collaborative and inclusive business models, by which investors seek to promote
the involvement of smallholders and local investors. This practice is seen as a means
to “pre-empt local conflict and international criticism through building up local
participation from the start” (FAO, 2012a; p. 80). Consequently, host countries are
striving to put in place appropriate policy and regulatory frameworks to ensure
that the developmental benefits of agriculture FDI are maximized, by inter alia,
employment generation, transfer of expertise and technology, and infrastructure
development. They also try to minimize risks, such as the potential exclusion of
small farmers and firms, land tenure conflicts and negative environmental impacts
(UNCTAD, 2009a; FAO, 2012a).
These efforts to enhance the business climate have translated into improved
institutional frameworks for agribusiness investment promotion, i.e. setting up or
strengthening institutions responsible for disseminating information, or attempting
to create an image of the investment site. These institutions also provide investment
services for prospective investors in the agriculture and agribusiness sectors (Wells
and Wint, 2000).
The increased attention given by governments to investment promotion can be
illustrated by the more than fourfold increase in the number of investment promo-
tion agencies (IPAs) set up from 1980 to 2004 in developing countries. Current
estimates place the number of regional and city-level IPAs at 8 000 worldwide (VCC
and WAIPA, 2010). Another institutional option for investment promotion found in
Chapter 2 – Framing the discussion: concepts, theoretical foundations [...] 23
Chapter 3
Overview of the corridor profiles
Policy and institutional framework. Corridors repeatedly appear in the main Afri-
can policies and programmes. Table 5 captures how the main institutions operating
TABLE 4
Corridors identified in Africa
Corridor name Countries involved Cases selected
in the region at three levels (continental scale, regional trade blocs and in the context
of global and regional partnership platforms)26 imagine the role of economic and
transport corridors in the continent.
TABLE 5
Policy and institutional framework informing the development of African corridors
Institutions Regional policies and programmes
Level Institutions
WEF’s New Vision for Agriculture WEF aligns with the African-led CAADP
Multinational partnership platform and supports the above corridors as part
of its global programme
G8’s New Alliance for Food Security The New Alliance also aligns with CAADP
and Nutrition and uses Grow Africa’s approach, which is
Multinational partnership platform based on WEF’s New Vision for Agriculture
framework
26
A partnership or multistakeholder platform engages multiple partners across government,
companies, farmers, civil society and others.
28 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
27
For further information about the AU, see: www.au.int [last accessed July 2013].
28
WEF is “an independent international organization committed to improving the state of the world
by engaging business, political, academic and other leaders of society to shape global, regional and
industry agendas”. www.weforum.org [last accessed August 2013].
29
The 28 global companies that champion the initiative at the global level are AGCO Corporation,
A.P. Møller-Maersk, BASF, Bayer CropScience, Bunge, Cargill, CF Industries Holdings, The
Coca-Cola Company, Diageo, DuPont, General Mills, Heineken, METRO Group, Mondelez
International, Monsanto Company, The Mosaic Company, Nestlé, Novozymes, PepsiCo, Rabobank
International, Royal DSM, SABMiller, Sinar Mas Agribusiness and Food, Swiss Reinsurance
Company, Syngenta International, Unilever, Wal-Mart and Yara International (WEF, 2013).
Chapter 3 – Overview of the corridor profiles 29
initiative has engaged business leaders, governments, academia, civil society, and the
donor and investor community to implement two country-level agricultural cor-
ridor partnerships: SAGCOT in the United Republic of Tanzania and the BAGC
Initiative (BAGCI) in Mozambique (WEF, 2012; Jenkins, 2012). Other agricultural
development models identified by New Vision include a breadbasket30 project in
Ghana; a horticultural value chain intervention in Honduras; and a transforma-
tion plan for the agricultural sector in Morocco (ibid.). Currently, WEF supports
multistakeholder partnerships in 11 countries across Africa, Asia and Latin America
(WEF, 2013).
Another multilateral partnership aligned with CAADP and developed in col-
laboration with WEF and Grow Africa is G8’s New Alliance for Food Security
and Nutrition. This alliance is formed by African and G8 governments that commit
public sector funding and action to enable agriculture investments, and by multi-
national and African private companies that have committed to invest over US$3
billion to boost African food security. The United Republic of Tanzania was one of
the original countries participating in the alliance, and Mozambique followed suit.
A similar approach is shared by the Tripartite, an umbrella institution
that gathers together three sub-Saharan African trading blocs: the Common
Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA), the East African Com-
munity (EAC) and the Southern African Development Community (SADC).
The Tripartite has devised a regional growth strategy also based on the design
and implementation of infrastructure and trade interventions along corridors in
eastern and southern Africa.31
Policy and institutional framework. Regional trade blocs in LAC (see Table 7) are
becoming involved in the application of the corridor approach. A case in point is
the Union of South American Nations (UNASUR),32 which is responsible for the
30
See Glossary.
31
www.comesa-eac-sadc-tripartite.org [last accessed May 2013].
32
UNASUR, established in 2008, encompasses all 12 South American countries. For further
information see: www.unasursg.org
30 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
TABLE 6
Corridors identified in Latin America and the Caribbean
Corridor name Countries involved Cases selected
TABLE 7
Policy and institutional framework informing the development of LAC corridors
Regional policy Latin America and the Caribbean
Regional development bank Inter-American Development Bank (IaDB) bases its current
regional integration strategy on the economic corridor model
33
www.iirsa.org [last accessed December 2012].
34
Emerging corridors in the Zonapaz region (Huehuetenango, Quiché, Alta Verapaz, Baja Verapaz,
Chimaltenango and the Peten).
35
Two corridors on the Atlantic coast and the south of Honduras (in Spanish the Corredor Atlántico
and the Corredor del Sur).
32 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 2
IIRSA integration corridors or hubs
Andean hub
Amazon hub
Peru-Brazil-Bolivia hub
MERCOSUR-Chile hub
Capricorn hub
Paraguay-Panama
Waterway hub
Southern hub
that have replicated the pioneer experience of the United States Agency for Interna-
tional Development (USAID) in Peru in the late 1990s, known as the PRA Project.
These corridors are serviced by Economic Services Centres (ESCs) located in the main
intermediate cities. These centres provide BDS to players in the agricultural and other
sectors with the goal of promoting economic growth and generating employment.
A second category of economic corridors emerging in Latin America is the
commodity-extraction corridor. This corridor is mostly driven by private players
in an effort to increase the efficiency of strategic agricultural value chains, such as
soybeans and sugar-cane ethanol. It is most commonly found in the Southern Com-
mon Market (Mercosur) countries, particularly in Argentina and Brazil (Fergie and
Satz, 2007). Regrettably, these private-led corridors fail to make it to the list for in-
depth study in spite of their interest because they lack programmatic frameworks,
by their very own nature. Moreover, private efforts are rarely documented and are
less accessible than public or public-private initiatives.
Chapter 3 – Overview of the corridor profiles 33
TABLE 8
Economic corridors identified in Asia
Corridor name Countries involved Cases selected
TABLE 9
Policy and institutional framework informing the development of Asian corridors
Regional policy Asia
Regional The Asian Development Bank (ADB) has pushed the economic corridor
development bank model as the basis for the region’s integration strategy
Regional trade blocs Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN): AFTA and AEC
Eurasian Economic Community (EurAsEC)
South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC)
Regional GMS subregion: Core Agriculture Support Programme (CASP, Phase II:
agricultural policy 2011–2015)
The regional trade blocs, and in particular the Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN),36 with its ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) are increasingly
recognizing the importance of economic corridors. Such corridors are seen as a
stepping-stone towards establishing the ASEAN Economic Community (AEC)
by 2015 (Shrestha and Chongvilaivan, 2013). Moreover, the Economic Ministers of
ASEAN+637 endorsed the idea of an East Asia Industrial Corridor (EAIC) connect-
ing the Mekong Region to India, as the model project for the integration of East
Asia (ERIA, 2008).
Another important integration initiative in the GMS is the Ayeyawady-Chao
Phraya-Mekong Economic Cooperation Strategy (ACMECS) among the GMS
five. This political, economic, and cultural organization was set up by Thailand in
2003 to increase agricultural and manufacturing development, competitiveness and
employment creation in the subregion (Cochrane, 2012).
Using this typology, Table 10 provides a bird’s eye view of the economic corridor
initiatives that have been selected for in-depth analysis in the coming chapters.
Finally, it is desirable to provide a reminder of why some corridors have been
eliminated in the course of this selection process. The corridors excluded belong to
one of the following categories.
36
ASEAN member countries are Brunei Darussalam, Cambodia, Indonesia, Lao PDR, Malaysia,
Myanmar, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Viet Nam.
37
ASEAN countries plus six countries, namely China, India, Japan, the Republic of Korea, Australia
and New Zealand.
36 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
TABLE 10
Summary of corridor profiles
Type Region Name Countries Key driver Year Estimated budget
involved of start
Asia CAREC Afghanistan, ADB, the European Bank (1996) US$46 billion +
Corridor Azerbaijan, for Reconstruction and 2001 US$1 270 million
programme China (Xinjiang), Development (EBRD), in TA
Kazakhstan, the International Monetary
Kyrgyz Republic, Fund (IMF), Islamic
Mongolia, Development Bank
Pakistan, (IDB), the United Nations
Tajikistan, Development Programme
Turkmenistan (UNDP) and
and Uzbekistan the World Bank
Africa SAGCOT United Republic WEF’s New Vision May US$1.3 billion,
of Tanzania for Agriculture 2010 of which US$650
million (backbone
infrastructure) +
US$570 million
(last-mile
infrastructure41)
+ US$50 million
(Catalytic Fund)
38
The NDF is the joint multilateral development finance institution of Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway
and Sweden. It has specialized in the provision of finance to climate change related investments since 2009.
39
OFID is the development finance institution established by the Member States of the Organization of the
Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) in 1976 as a collective channel of aid to developing countries.
40
The Catalytic Fund provides start-up finance for agriculture businesses incorporating smallholder
farmers. The loans awarded by the Fund are either low-cost or interest-free, and repayable as soon
as the investee firm attracts private finance (SAGCOT, 2010).
41
See Glossary.
Chapter 3 – Overview of the corridor profiles 37
1. Transport or logistic corridors that have still not evolved into economic corridors.
2. Urban corridors have not been selected because of the relative irrelevance of
the agricultural sector in the corridor action plan.
3. Private sector-led corridors have been excluded owing to the absence of a
programmatic framework.
figure 3
A framework for economic corridors
Delivery at scale
Delivery &
implementation
mechanisms
Strategy
Soft interventions
& targeted
Effective direction sectors in the agricultural sector
Hard & soft Cross-sectoral
interventions
soft interventions
Hard interventions
Corridor
Leadership
development & aligment
matrix
Finance
& risk
management
Strategy deployed and targeting of sectors, industries and firms. The final goal is
to have a corridor roadmap agreed upon by all the key stakeholders.
Corridor development matrix. The roadmap is materialized in a matrix that lists
the corridor projects, classifying them according to their priority, the funding
source and their nature, e.g. investments and TA projects.
The second cluster groups three building blocks for delivering the corridor pro-
gramme to scale. These are the following:
Finance and risk management. The lead convener(s) should mobilize resources to
be able to implement the corridor programme. Resource mobilization obviously
comes before implementation, but for the sake of clarity the detailed budget
and sources of funding will be described after the scope of the soft and hard
interventions has been defined.
Although soft and hard corridor interventions are clustered together in Figure
3, in the next chapters they will be split into two sections. The first section
will deal with soft interventions in the agricultural sector and in cross-sectoral
links. Within this section, special attention will be given to the specialization
of the corridor in terms of agricultural value chains and market orientation.
The second part deals with infrastructure interventions and their interface with
agricultural commodities.
Delivery and implementation mechanisms, with a focus on the institutional
arrangements established among the corridor’s stakeholders.
Chapter 4
Introduction to the corridor cases
This chapter presents six corridor experiences that take place in developing regions:
one in Latin America, two in Africa and three in Asia. They are promoted by four
players that have left an indelible mark on the way the corridor programmes are
structured. These players are a regional bank (ADB), a bilateral government agency
(USAID), an international multistakeholder partnership (WEF’s New Vision for
Agriculture) and the Government of Indonesia (GoI). Each brings its own agenda,
background and distinctive modus operandi to the corridor programme it leads.
TABLE 11
Summary of corridors analysed
Surface GDP
Year of No. of No. of Population Investments Targeted
(million (US$
gestation corridors countries (million) (US$ million) sectors
km2) billion)
the private sector. These commonalities and differences will be brought out and
explored during the course of this and following chapters.
A typology of economic corridors was presented towards the end of Chapter 3
(Figure 3), where corridors can be classified into different categories in relation to
the geopolitical unit involved, the nature of the corridor champion and the sectoral
focus adopted. In Table 12 this typology has been applied to the six corridor experi-
ences considered.
A brief glance at Table 12 reveals that most corridor programmes appraised have
a national focus, whereas two – those promoted by ADB – incorporate a regional
dimension. The specific countries participating in both mono and multicountry
corridors analysed are listed in Table 13.
Each programme supports a variable number of corridors that range from one to
ten, as shown in Table 14.
Two programmes are monosectoral, meaning that they tie together infrastructure
(transport, energy and telecommunications) and agricultural development. Accord-
ingly, they receive the name of “agricultural growth corridors”. The other four
TABLE 12
Types of corridors analysed
Geopolitical focus Sectoral focus Promoter
BAGCI ¾ ¾ ¾
CAREC ¾ ¾ ¾
GMS ¾ ¾ ¾
MP3EI ¾ ¾ ¾
PRA ¾ ¾ ¾
SAGCOT ¾ ¾ ¾
TABLE 13
Countries involved in each initiative
Corridor initiative Countries involved
BAGCI Mozambique
GMS Cambodia, Lao PDR, Myanmar, Thailand, Viet Nam and China
(Yunan and Guangxi Zhuang provinces)
MP3EI Indonesia
PRA Peru
Sources: www.adb.org; www.proyectopra.com; AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010; SAGCOT, 2011; CMEA, 2011.
Chapter 4 – Introduction to the corridor cases 41
TABLE 14
Number of corridors in each initiative
Corridor initiative Corridors supported
GMS North-South Economic Corridor, NSEC, which targets the ecologically and
culturally sensitive area linking southern China, Lao PDR, Myanmar and Thailand
East-West Economic Corridor (EWEC), encompassing Lao PDR, Myanmar, Thailand
and Viet Nam, which represents the only direct and continuous land route
between the Andaman Sea and the South China Sea
Southern Economic Corridor (SEC), which includes Cambodia, Thailand
and Viet Nam
MP3EI Sumatra
Java
Kalimantan
Sulawesi
Bali-Nusa Tenggara
Papua-Kepulauan Maluku
Sources: www.adb.org; www.proyectopra.com; AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010; SAGCOT, 2011; CMEA, 2011.
Putting the corridors on the map. One of the most ambitious economic corridor
initiatives worldwide takes place in Asia, in the Greater Mekong Subregion. The
GMS corridor programme is the result of an economic cooperation and integration
agreement signed in 1992 by Cambodia, the Lao People’s Democratic Republic,
Myanmar, Thailand, Viet Nam (these five countries are thence referred to as GMS5)
and southern China (Yunan province and the Guangxi Zhuang Autonomous
Region), under the aegis of ADB.
As of December 2011, the programme had almost US$15 billion worth of
investment projects completed or under implementation.42 As seen earlier, the
figure 4
The three GMS corridors
North-South
Kunming
Guangxi
Yunnan
R
NMA
Nanning
MYA
Hanoi
Mandalay
LAO
PEOPLE’S
Naypyitaw DEM. REP.
East-West
Chiang Mai
Vientiane
Southern
D
ILAN
THA
VIET
Bangkok CA
MB
(Krung Thep) OD
IA
NAM
Phnom Penh
Ho Chi
Minh City
National capital
Major city
Corridor
42
As at the end of 2011, 56 GMS priority projects worth around US$15 billion were either completed
or being implemented (ADB, 2012d).
Chapter 4 – Introduction to the corridor cases 43
programme comprises three corridors and nine subcorridors running across six
Southeast Asian nations (Figure 4).
Already in its third decade, the GMS initiative has become ADB’s flagship
exercise in regional economic cooperation, and has spawned a number of spin-offs,
with CAREC being the main one.
The CAREC programme, also supported by ADB, capitalizes on the success of
its predecessor. It is a partnership of ten countries (Afghanistan, Azerbaijan, the
Xinjiang province of China, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, Mongolia, Pakistan,
Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan) and six multilateral institutions – ADB,
the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), the International
Monetary Fund (IMF), the Islamic Development Bank (IDB), the United Nations
Development Programme (UNDP) and the World Bank – working together to
promote development through regional cooperation, leading to accelerated growth
and poverty reduction (CAREC, 2010; ADB, 2011f).
Spanning nearly 4 000 km across Central Asia, CAREC promotes six corridors
that extend inland along historic trade routes in Central Asia, linking western China
to the Caspian Sea. These corridors connect mostly landlocked members with each
other and to markets beyond by providing the finance and expertise to increase
mobility of people and goods across Central Asia, as seen in Figure 5.
figure 5
Corridors of the CAREC programme
CAREC 1a,c
CAREC 1b
CAREC 6b,c
KAZAKHSTAN
Qyzylorda
CAREC 3
Aqtau Shu
Almaty
Türkistan
Taraz Bishkek
Nukus
Uchquduq Shymkent
KYRGYZSTAN
Baky
CAREC 2 UZBEKISTAN Tashkent Chust
Türkmenbashi Osh CAREC 1,2,5
Balkanabat Jizzakh Khujand
TURKMENISTAN Bukhoro Nawoiy Bekabad Kashgar
Türkmenabat Samarqand
Qarshi
TAJIKISTAN
Ashgabat Dushanbe
Mary
Termez
National capital Kunduz
Serakhs Mazari
Major city Sharif
Corridor
Hirat
Kabul
Source: author’s elaboration (UN Map No. 3763 Rev. 7, December 2011, Department of Field Support - Cartographic Section).
44 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
43
Peru is divided into 25 regions or departments and one province.
44
See Glossary for a definition of subsistence, emergent and commercial farmers.
Chapter 4 – Introduction to the corridor cases 45
figure 6
Economic corridors currently supported by the PRA Project
Quito COLOMBIA
ECUADOR
Tumbes
Iquitos
PERU
Piura
Moyobamba
Chachapoyas
P
Chiclayo BRAZIL
Cajamarca
A
Trujillo Pucallpa
C
I
Huaraz Huánuco
F
Cerro
I
de Pasco
C
Huancayo
Major city Callao
Lima
National capital
Puerto
Sierra La Libertad Huancavelica Maldonado
Ayacucho
O
Ancash Cusco
Abancay
Sierra Norte Lima-Huánuco
C
Ica
Pasco Junín
E
BOLIVIA
Huancavelica A
Ayacucho-VRAE
N Puno
Cusco
Arequipa
La Paz
Arequipa
Puno Moquegua
CHILE
Source: author’s elaboration (UN Map No. 3838 Rev. 3, May 2004, Department of Peacekeeping Operations - Cartographic
Section).
figure 7
The Beira Agricultural Growth Corridor
DEMOCRATIC
REPUBLIC
OF THE CONGO
UNITED
REPUBLIC
OF TANZANIA
I
MALAW
MOZAMBIQUE
Lilongwe
ZAMBIA
Lusaka Blantyre
Tete
Harare
Beira agricultural
Beira growth corridor
ZIMBABWE Rail and road link
Bulawayo
Road
National capital
Major city
BOTSWANA
Source: author’s elaboration (UN Map No. 4045 Rev. 7, November 2011, Department of Field Support - Cartographic Section).
SOUTH AFRICA
through an area with some of the richest farmland in Africa, running from the
Republic’s coastal plains and the valleys of Kilombero and Ruaha, to the hills and
valleys of the Southern Highlands and the Usangu flats (Figure 8). This area could
become the country’s breadbasket, and beyond, a globally significant agricultural
and livestock producer. Regionally, the corridor reaches mining industries in Zam-
bia and Malawi, as well as Katanga province in the DRC (SAGCOT, 2010).
Members of the SAGCOT partnership incorporate government, multina-
tional companies, the Tanzanian private sector, farmers and development partners.
It strives to attract investments into Tanzania’s Southern Corridor to tap on its agri-
cultural potential. As of today, this potential could be qualified as dormant, leaving
a large fraction of the rural population poor and food insecure. The corridor’s action
plan seeks to triple its agricultural output by bringing 350 000 ha into commercial
production – most of them under irrigation – by 2030 (ibid.).
In Indonesia, the MP3EI is an example of a government-led programme to
accelerate national growth using the corridor approach. This does not mean that
Indonesia’s is the “average” national corridor programme. First, the nation is a
major international player in terms of population and GDP and it is growing at such
Chapter 4 – Introduction to the corridor cases 47
figure 8
SAGCOT map
Dodoma
Kinonko
Morogoro Kibaha
Dar es Salaam
Mlandizi
Sumbawanga
Iringa
Mbeya
Makambako
Tunduma
UNITED
REPUBLIC
OF TANZANIA
ZAMBIA
MALAWI
MOZAMBIQUE
Source: author’s elaboration (UN Map No. 4045 Rev. 7, November 2011, Department of Field Support - Cartographic Section).
high rates45 that by 2025 it may become one of the top ten global economic powers
(Kuncoro, 2013). Few emerging and developing countries have that many economic
and human resources to devote to this type of development initiative: Indonesia has
allocated nearly US$400 billion to its corridor programme.
Second, Indonesia is the largest archipelagic country in the world. This translates
into a programme in which each one of the six corridors selected cover one island,
with the additional challenge of improving inter-island connectivity.
Third, the geography of the country (17 000 islands stretching for 5 200 km
east to west and 1 870 km north to south) determines a high spatial concentration
in the western regions, e.g. the islands of Java and Sumatra where population and
economic activity (particularly manufacturing and services) tend to agglomerate,
45
As of 2012, Indonesia was the fourth most populous country in the world. The country’s real GDP
growth has been growing at an average of 6 percent, 2010–2013, year on year (Kuncoro, 2013).
48 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 9
Indonesia economic corridors
Kalimantan EC
Sulawesi EC
Papua – Kepulauan
Maluku EC
Sumatra EC
Java EC
Bali – Nusa
Tenggara EC
Economic Center
Mega Economic Center
creating a wealth gap with the relatively less advanced eastern regions (ibid.). This
explains why the Indonesian corridor programme focuses not only on accelerating
growth but also on reducing regional inequality – and especially reducing disparities
in post-conflict areas.
In spite of these peculiarities, the case of Indonesia provides useful insights into a
national corridor programme driven by the government (both central and regional),
without any donor support but in partnership with the private sector (Figure 9).
figure 10
Timeline of the selected corridor programmes
GMS corridor CAREC corridor PRA corridor BAGCI & Indonesian corridor
programme programme programme SAGCOT programme
Sister
projects
figure 11
Phases of the CAREC programme
Set-up of CAREC
Strategic
RETA initiatives institutional Comprehensive
Framework 2020
framework Action Plan
Phase I. Groundwork Phase II. Trust-building Phase III. Strategic Phase IV. Towards
and awareness raising direction and focus economic corridors
Similarly, the CAREC programme went through an inception phase from 1996 to
2001, and in 2002 its institutional framework was finally established (Figure 11).
In the same way, the official date of commencement of the PRA corridor
programme was 1998, but only in 2000 did it become fully operational with the
establishment of the first corridor centres, as shown in Figure 12.
Corridor programmes can evolve remarkably over time. New components can
be added or phased out. Corridors and subcorridors can be modified. New stake-
holders can get involved and governance mechanisms may change. A good example
of such fluid transition is illustrated in Box 6.
50 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 6
Evolution of the PRA corridors: a moving target
The PRA Project was put in motion in 1998 by USAID. The Project envisaged three compo-
nents: business development, infrastructure and policy dialogue – all of which started at differ-
ent times and with different implementers. The first component began with the establishment
of ESCs in the corridors during 1999 and 2000. Its implementation was initially the responsibil-
ity of the National Confederation of Private Business Institutions (CONFIEP) of Peru, but it was
later entrusted to an international consulting firm. The infrastructure PPP component came
into being into 2003 and was active until 2007. It was implemented in close collaboration
with the Ministries of Transport and Finance, and with ProInversión, the Peruvian investment
promotion agency in charge of implementing infrastructure concessions. The infrastructure
component facilitated the concession of the port of Callao and the IIRSA North highway, and
accomplished the transaction design phase46 for the IIRSA Central highway. Policy dialogue
only became a fully fledged component in the second phase (2009 to present).
The number of corridors supported by the Project have not remained stable over time. In
the first phase, it worked in 13 economic corridors in the Peruvian jungle and highlands: the
ten original corridors were established in 2000 and three other corridors were added later
on: Huancavelica (2002), Piura (2005) and Ancash (2007). In 2004, three ESCs (Cajamarca,
Puno and Huaylas) closed down.
The opening and closure of ESCs happened for reasons both internal and external to the
Project’s management. The internal reasons were a shift in strategic priorities of USAID/Peru’s
Mission,47 which resulted in changes in intervention areas in 2003; and resource limitations,
which compounded by the diversion of funds to the new and intensified corridors, provoked
the closure in 2004 of the three ESCs already mentioned. Such shifting budget priorities,
midway through the life of the Project, dictated that higher priority be given to:
alternative development zones (i.e. areas making the transition from coca to licit eco-
nomic activities), which translated into an intensification of activities in some segments of
the economic corridors of Ayacucho, Huánuco, Pucallpa and Tarapoto; and
border areas between Peru and Ecuador, namely, Jaén – one of the original PRA cor-
ridors – and Piura, where an ESC started up in 2005. These two corridors were financed
by USAID’s Peru-Ecuador Border Programme, and were associated with the Ecuador-Peru
Binational Commission.48
The external motivation derived from the interest expressed by private companies and public
agencies in the project model, and their subsequent decision to co-fund the opening of
new ESCs. The private sector made the first move. In 2002, a mining company located in
Huancavelica, Minas Buenaventura, decided to finance an ESC in that corridor – the first PPP
46
This encompasses the technical, financial and legal design of the concession transaction, which
typically includes prequalification and evaluation criteria, cost recovery and affordability.
47
http://peru.usaid.gov [last accessed August 2013].
48
http://www.planbinacional.org.pe [last accessed August 2013].
Chapter 4 – Introduction to the corridor cases 51
BOX 6 (Continued)
anywhere in the world under USAID’s then-new Global Development Alliance (GDA).49 In
2007, another mining company, Antamina, followed suit, investing in the establishment of
a new ESC in Ancash. In November 2008, the Clinton-Giustra Sustainable Growth Initiative
(CGSGI)50 signed a cooperation agreement with the Antamina Mining Fund to extend the
term of operation and scope of the ESC in Ancash.
From the public sector side, the Sierra Exportadora (SIEX) programme51 – in operation since
2006 to encourage exports from the Peruvian highlands – also became interested in the PRA
model. Peru and the United States of America had just signed a Free Trade Agreement (FTA),52
and the Peruvian Government saw in the PRA methodology and its good export record (US$54
million of additional exports to the United States of America in the first phase) an excellent
post-FTA initiative. Rather than attempting to replicate it on its own, SIEX decided to collabo-
rate formally with the Project and its private partners at the time (Minas Buenaventura and
Antamina) through a PPP agreement (the PRA Alliance) signed in March 2007 (USAID, 2008a).
PRA I ended in 2008, but USAID soon launched the second phase (September 2009),
convening public and private actors to join this effort. The successful alliances with Minas
Buenaventura, Antamina and CGSGI presented the private sector as a powerful ally in the
country strategy to combat poverty. For the second phase of the PRA, USAID renewed its
strategic alliance with PRA I partners, added six new private ones, expanded the partnership
with SIEX and built a new one with Lima’s regional government (ibid.).
The second and current phase (PRA II) has tried a new approach. Instead of preselecting eco-
nomic corridors, it has focused on engaging strategic partners (public sector agencies and local
private firms) to co-finance the operation of the ESCs. This strategy materialized in 2010 into a
partnership between USAID/Peru, the Government of Peru (GoP) through its SIEX programme,
the government of the Lima region and nine private sector organizations. PRA II operates
ESCs in ten trade corridors to connect SMEs to new markets, and identifies critical regulatory
reforms to ease trade and investment, and facilitates meaningful PPPs (USAID, 2008a; 2008b).
In January 2012, USAID/Lima and SIEX signed a Memorandum of Understanding (MOU)
to facilitate USAID’s transfer of the Peru PRA model into Peruvian hands as official economic
development policy. The signing of this MOU sought to merge further the capacities and
funding from the Governments of Peru and the United States of America, as well as private
sector companies to help the citizens of the highlands region overcome poverty.53
49
The Global Development Alliance (GDA) is a market-based business model for partnerships
between the public and private sectors to address jointly defined business and development
objectives. Alliances are co-designed, co-funded, and co-managed by partners so that the risks,
responsibilities and rewards of partnership are equally shared. Private actors include private
businesses, financial institutions, entrepreneurs, venture capitalists and investors; foundations
and philanthropists; and other for-profit and not-for-profit non-governmental entities. Further
information is available at: http://idea.usaid.gov/gp/about-gda-model [last accessed August 2013].
50
http://www.clintonfoundation.org/main/our-work/by-initiative/clinton-giustra-enterprise-
partnership/programs/peru.html [last accessed August 2013].
51
www.sierraexportadora.gob.pe [last accessed August 2013].
52
The Peru-United States Trade Promotion Agreement was signed in 2006 and entered into force in
February 2009.
53
www.chemonics.com [last accessed July 2014].
52 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 12
PRA project timeline
This contagion also takes place at the national level. Box 6 illustrated the case of
Peru, where the GoP has institutionalized the PRA model of economic corridors.
Similarly, the Ministry of Agriculture of Mozambique (2010) sees the Beira Cor-
ridor as the pilot for several similar agricultural corridors that it is planning to
develop through its Centro de Promoção da Agricultura (CEPAGRI). The focus
on agricultural corridors offers Mozambique an opportunity to fast track the
development of its agricultural sector and to ensure food security, by building
on existing infrastructure networks and encouraging clusters of agricultural busi-
nesses to develop.
All the experiences analysed are, at least conceptually, in the “economic cor-
ridor” stage. However, many initiatives still devote most of their resources to
developing transportation infrastructure. For instance, as of 2012, 63 percent of
GMS programmed investments had gone to infrastructure development; in the case
of CAREC, this figure reaches nearly 80 percent of the overall budget. It is only
natural that in the process of evolving from transport to economic corridors, the
focus on infrastructure development still prevails for some time, to the detriment
Chapter 4 – Introduction to the corridor cases 53
figure 13
Timelines of BAGCI and SAGCOT
[…] [...]
[…]
of the implementation of soft components. In fact, although the vision and politi-
cal will to become economic corridors are manifested in strategic documents and
masterplans, the corresponding budget allocations take time to follow. Moreover, a
nuanced treatment of these budgetary figures is needed, because soft interventions
require much lighter investments than hard or infrastructure ones.
In this evolutionary process towards economic or growth corridors, support to
agriculture is sometimes added years after the commencement of the initial corridor
operations. In 2006, the GMS corridor initiative started its agricultural flagship
programme, and the CAREC programme added agriculture as a second-tier area
of work, i.e. 14 and ten years, respectively, after their launch. In the case of GMS,
the programme enlargement to nine sectors was the result of an increased emphasis
54 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 14
Timeline of the Greater Mekong Subregion programme
2002 GMS Strategic Framework 2002–2012 adopted at the first GMS summit
2007 Endorsement of CASP I (2006–2010) at the 1st GMS Agriculture Ministers’ Meeting
2011 Endorsement of CASP II (2011–2015) at the 16th GMS Agriculture Ministers’ Meeting
GMS Economic Cooperation Programme Strategic Framework 2012–2022
Source: author’s elaboration based on ADB, 2004; 2006; 2007a; 2010e; 2011a; 2011c; 2012a; and 2012b.
Chapter 5
Effective direction
This chapter is dedicated to analysing the cluster of actions aiming to steer the
economic corridor programme in the most effective direction, as noted in the study
framework illustrated in Figure 3. The cluster is composed of three building blocks,
namely the development of a shared goal and vision of the corridor programme;
the definition of the corridor strategy and targeting modalities; and the selection of
subprojects and instruments arranged in a development matrix.
TABLE 15
Visions and goals of the corridor programmes
Corridor initiative Visions and goals of the corridor programmes
CAREC “Good neighbours, good partners and good prospects” through long-term, efficient
and effective regional economic cooperation in Central Asia
MP3EI Accelerate growth and reduce regional inequalities in Indonesia through joint
public-private investments in corridors, improved connectivity and better skilled
human resources
PRA Contribute to poverty reduction via sustainable job and revenue creation through
the mobilization of private-sector investment in selected economic corridors of Peru
SAGCOT Accelerate agricultural green growth in the Southern Corridor of Tanzania by attracting
strategic private sector partners with environmentally responsible business models
to enhance linkages with smallholders and fix critical links in the value chains
Sources: www.adb.org; www.proyectopra.com; AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010; SAGCOT, 2011; CMEA, 2011.
56 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 7
Vision alignment among corridor stakeholders in the BAGC and SAGCOT
The idea of supporting the development of agrocorridors in Mozambique and the United
Republic of Tanzania has been the result of various parallel processes gathering steam across
the globe.
One such process started in 2008 at the General Assembly of the United Nations (UN)
in New York. During the event, a UN Private Sector Forum was held to join efforts to pro-
mote agricultural growth in developing and emerging countries. It was at the Forum that
the concept of an agricultural growth corridor was first discussed, following the proposal of
Yara – an international fertilizer company – to pilot an agricultural corridor programme. The
idea was well received by private sector leaders and representatives of development agencies,
including FAO, the International Finance Corporation (IFC) and the Alliance for a Green Revo-
lution in Africa (AGRA). Some Mozambican government representatives who attended the
presentation became interested in participating in the initiative (WEF, 2010). From there, a
process unfolded that would see the concept launched on the Mozambican side of the Beira
Corridor (BAGCI). Soon afterwards, the United Republic of Tanzania followed suit (SAGCOT).
The proposal to foster agricultural growth corridors was formally endorsed in the context of
WEF’s “New Vision for Agriculture” initiative, launched in Davos in January 2009. New Vision
found a perfect match in the vision of the Mozambican Government. Planning for and invest-
ments in the Beira Transport Corridor have been going on since the 1960s, although much of
the progress made vanished during the Mozambican civil war (1977–1992) (Meeuws, 2004). In
the 2000s, with the help of donors and the private sector, the corridor reached a point where
key infrastructure investments were again operational.54 Conditions then became right for the
GoM to move forward to an economic corridor approach. The strong interest of multinational
investors in the corridor was instrumental in building momentum (World Bank, 2010). Further
to embracing the corridor approach, the GoM developed an agricultural strategy (Plano Estra-
tégico para o Desenvolvimento do Sector Agrário, PEDSA) entirely in line with the New Vision,
and directly made or promoted major investments in irrigation and transportation infrastructure
(port and railway enhancements) along the Beira Corridor.
Mozambican-based private firms were also receptive to BAGCI. National corporations
were already making large investments in the mining and agriculture sectors (through com-
mercial farms and smallholder aggregation), and the port of Beira.55 These investments were
geared towards increasing the volume of goods transported, and catalysing agricultural out-
put in the corridor, as a result of an improved freight network and expanded cargo handling
capacity (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010).
54
Including rehabilitation work carried out with funds from a World Bank post-conflict project
to rebuild the Beira Transport Corridor in the 1990s. See: http://www.worldbank.org/projects/
P001770/beira-transport-corridor-project?lang=en [last accessed July 2013].
55
The port of Beira is the natural freight port for Zimbabwe, but can also play a significant role for Malawi,
Zambia, Botswana and the Congo.
58 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 7 (Continued)
The agrocorridor model was further concretized during 2009 through contributions from
international consulting firms such as Prorustica (specialized in supporting PPP development),
InfraCo (specialized in infrastructure services such as irrigation) and AgDevCo (agricultural
development).56 Ultimately, this shared vision translated into the establishment of BAGCI,
marked by an inaugural meeting on 20 January 2010 in Maputo. A few days later, BAGCI
was internationally launched and the Beira Investment Blueprint57 presented at the 2010
WEF Annual Meeting in Davos (Kaarhus et al., 2010).
In January 2009, the Minister of Agriculture of the United Republic of Tanzania attended
the WEF in Davos and expressed the interest of the country, together with Mozambique, in
taking a lead role in developing agricultural growth corridors (SAGCOT, 2010). In October of
that year, with efforts in Mozambique gathering steam, key players in Tanzanian agriculture
met to discuss the possibility of launching a pilot agricultural growth corridor in the country.
The meeting convened representatives of the Tanzanian Prime Minister’s Office (PMO), the
Tanzania Agriculture Partnership (TAP), the Tanzania Investment Centre (TIC), Yara, the Nor-
wegian Embassy, Norfund, the AfDB and the World Bank. Following the meeting, a working
group under TAP developed a concept note, exploring the establishment of an agricultural
corridor linking the fertile southern highlands to the port of Dar es Salaam, with support from
national and international stakeholders. The concept note of SAGCOT, as the corridor was
labelled, was presented and approved at the African WEF in Dar es Salaam in May 2010. The
initiative is personally driven by the Tanzanian President and counts on the support of G20
countries (DFID, 2012).
With the SAGCOT initiative formally launched, the first step was to prepare an Investment
Blueprint (presented in January 2011, exactly one year after the approval of that of BAGC),
which would identify public and private sector investment opportunities and propose an
investment promotion strategy for the corridor (SAGCOT, 2011). In 2012, SAGCOT launched
its Investment Greenprint,58 which lays out a strategy for implementing “Agriculture Green
Growth” in the corridor to intensify agriculture sustainably for both smallholder and com-
mercial agriculture, while conserving the natural resource base. In May 2011, the two main
institutions of the partnership – the SAGCOT Centre and the SAGCOT Catalytic Trust Fund
– were established.
56
InfraCo is a project development company founded in 2005 to provide infrastructure development
services. It is donor-funded (e.g. British, Netherlands and Swedish cooperation) but privately
managed (Kaarhus et al., 2010). AgDevCo is a not-for-profit company operating in sub-Saharan
Africa that invests “social venture capital” to create commercially viable agribusiness investment
opportunities. Source: www.agdevco.com [last accessed July 2013].
57
This type of blueprint is an investment roadmap for the corridor that comprises an indicative
long-term financing plan and a short-term project portfolio, with both “fast-track” and “ready to
go” investment opportunities (Kaarhus et al., 2010).
58
See Glossary.
Chapter 5 – Effective direction 59
BOX 7 (Continued)
As a result, the Beira and SAGCOT corridors have several common traits. They started
only months apart, driven by the same champions. They both have a focus on the selected
sector (agriculture) and geographic areas (growth poles and clusters), coupled with enabling
infrastructure improvements. Essentially, agribusiness and mining are the two sectors driving
growth and competing somewhat over the same resources and services (e.g. logistics). The
emphasis of both corridors on agriculture is hence not surprising, especially considering that
they have plenty of fertile arable land available, yet a low level of commercial agriculture.
In addition, these corridor initiatives have a similar organizational arrangement consisting of
multilateral partnerships that include the public and private sectors, development partners
and civil society. They also utilize the same tools to pilot innovative economic development
models: investment blueprints, Catalytic Funds59 and the implementation of agricultural sub-
projects grouped in selected agrobased clusters. Last but not least, they are both aligned with
their respective national agricultural strategies, PEDSA in Mozambique and Kilimo Kwanza or
“Agriculture First” in the United Republic of Tanzania.
59
See Glossary.
60 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
assess the competitiveness of sectors or industries. This means that if these studies
were adequately conducted, there should not be much difference between the tar-
geting in the first (star sectors and industries) and second (star firms’) options. The
difference, as already explained, would be the possibility to discover out-of-the-box
business opportunities using the star firms’ model, which relies on the natural
selection of products/value chains/sectors, as opposed to an ex ante targeting. For
further information on the PRA strategy see Box 8.
Regardless of the path taken in the previous point, the subsequent step consists
of steering both public and private investment into the corridor areas targeted for
development. The key is to ensure that limited public resources are not distributed
so widely – something that might happen for political reasons, e.g. to reach a wider
base of citizens – that they fail to have the intended impacts. On the contrary, these
resources should rather be focused on helping the corridor to achieve its maximum
economic potential (Thomas, 2009). Finally, countries could move sequentially,
learning from successful corridors in one region or (sub)sector before spreading
investments to others.
Sectoral targeting. The corridor programmes studied have selected a variable num-
ber of sectors, as noted in Table 16. The exception was the PRA Project that decided
to support star connecting firms, as already mentioned, but ended up supporting
mostly agribusiness companies.
Table 16 shows that BAGCI and SAGCOT focus primarily on the agriculture
sector, coupled with infrastructure improvement. Agribusiness is also the primary
recipient of support from the PRA Project. The GMS cooperation programme
involves coordinated efforts in agriculture and eight other targeted sectors in order
to reduce business costs and facilitate the start-up and operation of business ventures.
TABLE 16
Sectors prioritized by the corridor programmes
BAGCI CAREC GMS MP3EI PRA SAGCOT
Agriculture ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Infrastructure ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Transport ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Energy ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Telecommunications ¾ ¾
Other sectors
Trade ¾ ¾
Environment ¾ ¾ ¾
Tourism ¾ ¾ ¾
Others ¾ ¾
BOX 8
The development of a corridor strategy: the case of the PRA Project
The PRA Project is markedly business oriented but, paradoxically, its origin can be traced
back to Peru’s mid-1990s food security strategy. The Peruvian Government worked closely
with USAID between 1994 and 1997 to develop and implement a national food security
and anti-poverty strategy, with poverty being the main cause of food insecurity. The strategy
developers concluded that Peru’s rising poverty levels at the time called for a radically differ-
ent approach, and hence departed from conventional anti-poverty or food security strategies
in four ways (Riordan et al., 2003).
1. The point of departure was the explicit recognition of the link between intermedi-
ate cities, growth and poverty reduction (USAID, 2008a). The strategy developers
maintained that the solution to the problem (poverty) did not necessarily lie close to
the place where the problem was (rural areas). They believed that growth radiates
from intermediate cities or regional centres and extends to the economic corridors
between these centres, which in turn are linked to large cities or megacities (Lima).
Consequently, they recommended spatial prioritization to channel scant public
resources into selected economic corridors (linking intermediate cities) that were
stricken by poverty but that had economic potential (ibid.).
2. The second element was the perception that the Peruvian Government could not do
it all, and that market forces could significantly contribute to poverty reduction. From
this premise, the strategy traced out a number of directions for public policy to part-
ner with the private sector in order to take advantage of its ability to link poor people
with markets and create job opportunities (ibid.).
3. The third innovative feature was the combination of two types of interventions (social
and productive) that work in tandem, despite having different goals (equity versus
efficiency concerns), approaches and implementers. The social interventions envis-
aged required targeted investments in social infrastructure across the entire country,
using poverty maps and related tools. On the contrary, productive interventions were
to be exclusively carried out in selected economic corridors. This latter category includ-
ed both hard investments in supporting public infrastructure (roads, energy and ports)
and soft investments such as publicly financed (or donor-financed) but privately run
business promotion centres to reduce transaction costs in economic corridors (ibid.).
4. Finally, the strategy recommended considering an outsourcing model to provide busi-
ness services in the corridors and improve productive infrastructure, expanding the
use of concessions and competitive performance contracting (ibid.).
Such an unconventional, rather controversial approach was put in motion in 1998 by USAID
in the PRA Project. To achieve the objective of poverty reduction, the Project envisaged an
interrelated set of interventions concerning the provision of BDS, infrastructure development
and policy dialogue.
62 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 8 (Continued)
To implement the business development component, the first step was to establish both
functional and geographic limits. As per design, the PRA Project became organized geo-
graphically in economic corridors. All of Peru was mapped into 24 economic corridors that
were ranked according to two criteria: economic potential, and the prevalence of extreme
and moderate poverty. Given budgetary and design conditions, the project team decided to
work in the top ten ranked corridors, namely Ayacucho, Cajamarca, Cusco, Huancayo, Huá-
nuco, Huaylas, Jaén, Pucallpa, Puno and Tarapoto (USAID, 2008a; 2008b).
Within these corridors, the PRA Project favoured a transaction-focused approach based
on “star connector firms”. The Project intentionally runs counter to mainstream development
approaches that are based on “star products” or “star sectors” (i.e. product or sectoral/
industrial targeting). Therefore, within the corridors, the Project was open in principle to all
licit economic sectors and industries. However, an ex post analysis shows that it is primarily
an agricultural value-chain project.
Once the geographic scope had been delineated, it was time for functional targeting.
The decision fell on business and infrastructure development. The first function was to be
achieved through the provision of non-financial BDS (facilitating access to information, com-
mercial brokering and policy dialogue) to reduce market transaction costs. To provide these
services, the project established regional ESCs that assisted individual client firms to overcome
specific impediments to business expansion. Through these ESCs, the project linked buyers
with proven demand to local suppliers and lifted producer bottlenecks in meeting buyer
requests. By doing this, it generated rural income and employment.
The second function was based on the facilitation of public investment with the highest
economic return, such as roads and electricity. These investments were selected according
to their capacity to stimulate private sector economic activity, and consequently employment
generation. The infrastructure component, rather than directly funding and implementing
the development of such infrastructure, provided comprehensive TA to the GoP in order to
develop and implement a PPP model for innovative infrastructure concession in the corridors.
The above process determined a corridor strategy defined by the following elements:
the combination of business services offered by privately managed centres that provide
non-financial BDS to potential investors and existing enterprises in economic corridors,
and the provision of TA for developing high-impact infrastructure improvements (high-
ways and ports) through PPPs;
strict compliance with the Project’s “orders first” mantra – which encapsulates a practical
market-pull approach – that subsequently triggers its engagement in supply-push activities;
continuous performance monitoring that zeroes in on three indicators (additional sales,
employment and productive investments) with monetary incentives for staff linked to
the achievement of targeted sales and investment values (employment is calculated as a
function of additional sales);
adoption of an outsourcing model for the overall implementation contractor (USAID) and
the ESC operators (mostly NGOs, but also consulting companies and universities), thus
allowing a high degree of flexibility.
Chapter 5 – Effective direction 63
The priority sectors envisaged are agriculture, energy, environment, human resourc-
es development, investment, tourism, telecommunications, transport infrastructure
and transport and trade facilitation. Specific long-term plans have been developed
for most of the sectors, as will be explained in section 5.3. CAREC has four priority
sectors: transport, trade facilitation, trade policy and energy.60 From 2001 to 2012,
CAREC invested more than US$21 billion in almost 140 CAREC-related projects
in these core sectors (ADB, 2011f). The Indonesian corridor programme has
identified eight sectors as the focus of national development, inter alia, agriculture,
mining, energy, industrial, marine and telecommunications. Within these sectors,
the programme encourages large-scale investment in 22 primary activities, of which
seven belong to extended agriculture, namely food and beverages, palm oil, rubber,
cocoa, animal husbandry, timber and fisheries (Strategic Asia, 2012).
Whether by design or not, all of them support agribusiness development but
they do so in three different ways. The first is to have agriculture as priority or core
sector – either the “only one” (i.e. agriculture plus infrastructure) or one of many.
Examples of the former type of corridor are BAGCI and SAGCOT, given that
they target agriculture, together with the transport and energy sectors. Cases in
point of multisectoral corridors targeting agriculture are the GMS and Indonesian
corridors programme.
The second approach is that employed by the CAREC programme, in which
agriculture is a second-tier sector, as shown in Figure 15. Being a second-tier area
implies that corridor interventions in agriculture are the following:
Unlike first-tier initiatives, they are not sector wide. Rather, they are limited to
highly focused projects, which are smaller, less sensitive, but quick yielding and
conducive to building confidence and mutual trust among CAREC countries.
The focus on project implementation is accompanied by additional ADB support
to capacity development of national and regional institutions in defining regional
cooperation projects, mobilizing funds and catalysing stronger coordination
across CAREC ministries of agriculture. Agricultural interventions in this
scheme are principally designed to support efforts in core or first-tier areas and
notably (agricultural) trade facilitation.
These areas are subject to fund availability, principally from other support-
ers, as opposed to core areas of work that are funded by the champions of
the corridor programme. In fact, second-tier activities usually involve new
development partners.
These interventions are subject to different governance mechanisms from those
regulating core areas of work. For example, CAREC coordinating committees
required for priority sectors are not necessary for second-tier activities; instead,
the CAREC Secretariat should monitor and report on them. Furthermore,
the dominant mode of cooperation in agriculture has so far been building on
knowledge and information exchange through the CAREC Institute.61 This
60
http://www.carecprogram.org/index.php?page=carec2020-strategic-framework [last accessed July
2013]; investments as of December 2012. The accumulated estimated investment is expected to
amount to US$46 billion by 2014.
61
www.carecinstitute.org [last accessed July 2013].
64 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
The third approach is a de facto targeting of the agribusiness sector, as in the PRA
corridors. The PRA Project favoured the principle of “star connector firms” instead
of targeting core or star prioritized sectors, value chains or products. However, this
selection process ended up by pointing at firms operating mainly in the agricultural
sector, as predicted by the initial feasibility studies that identified agriculture as one
of the sectors with greatest economic potential in the corridors.
When following the first approach, interventions to promote agricultural growth
within the boundaries of a corridor are planned comprehensively and bundle up
together to generate synergies and maximize impacts. The hallmark of an agrocor-
ridor – and, by the same token, of the agricultural component of an economic
corridor initiative – is the concentration and cross-linking of resources62 around
a long-term plan to promote sustainable growth throughout the corridor (Milder
et al. 2012; Kuroiwa, 2012). For example, the blueprint of the SAGCOT corridor
(SAGCOT, 2011) states that the objective of the corridor initiative is to “establish
southern Tanzania as a regional food exporter [...] by concentrating and linking agri-
cultural investment from the public sector, development partners, and Tanzanian
and international investors [...] (around) a targeted strategy and realistic action plan
to deploy resources, engage partners, and coordinate activities and investments”
(Milder et al., 2012; p. ii).
figure 15
First- and second-tier system of the CAREC programme
62
These resources should be enough to facilitate a critical mass in a physical and economic sense.
Chapter 5 – Effective direction 65
Pillars of the corridor programmes. The six corridor programmes have a varying
number of pillars, as shown in Table 17, but they all have three in common: infra-
structure development, investment promotion and business development.
Apart from these common elements, each corridor programme has a different
number of pillars and nuances in the way the pillars are approached. It is worth
examining the various programmes in detail (Box 9). The GMS programme, for
example, has five pillars concerning: (i) the strengthening of infrastructure linkages
through a multisectoral approach; (ii) facilitation of cross-border trade, investment
and tourism; (iii) enhancement of private sector participation and competitiveness;
(iv) development of human resources and required skill competencies; (v) protection
of the environment and promotion of the sustainable use of shared natural resources
(ADB, 2011a).
The CAREC programme has four pillars, as shown in Figure 16. The first pillar
refers to regional infrastructure networks, and notably the development of a seam-
less network of six transport corridors – the programme’s backbone – including
some 3 600 km of road building and improvements, almost 2 000 km of railway
track, the upgrading of ports and border crossings, and also better energy security,
efficiency and distribution (ADB, 2011f). The second pillar provides an integrated
framework for fostering trade, investment and business development, laying the
ground for subsequently building economic corridors. It would be the equivalent of
merging pillars two and three of the GMS programme. The third pillar is knowledge
transfer and capacity building to increase the capacity of member countries for
designing and implementing mutually beneficial regional initiatives, as well as to
form a cadre of officials skilled in regional cooperation processes. The fourth pillar
pertains to the provision of regional public goods to address transboundary issues,
TABLE 17
Sectors prioritized by the corridor programmes
BAGCI CAREC GMS MP3EI PRA SAGCOT
Infrastructure linkages/connectivity ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Trade facilitation ¾ ¾
Investment promotion ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Policy dialogue ¾ ¾ ¾
Environmental management ¾
Capacity building/organizational
¾ ¾
strengthening
Source: author’s elaboration, based on www.adb.org; www.proyectopra.com; AgDevCo & InfraCo, 2010;
SAGCOT, 2011; CMEA, 2011.
66 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 16
Pillars of the CAREC programme
BOX 9
Rationale behind the design of the corridor programme pillars
The four pillars of the CAREC programme facilitate the transformation from transport
to economic corridors across the region. This transformation is measured under the
CAREC programme according to the evolution of “nodes” along the corridor. The
programme distinguishes three distinct phases consistent with the progress achieved
in and among the nodes.
The development of connective infrastructure among the nodes, i.e. transport cor-
ridors. The second pillar is instrumental in doing this.
The economic development of corridor nodes through soft and hard infrastructural
support. These nodes can be: (i) commercial nodes (i.e. where major business activ-
ity is carried out); (ii) border nodes, where cross-border movements of goods and
services occur; (iii) gateway nodes, where a corridor ends, and the entry and exit
points to the corridor are located; and (iv) interchange nodes, where two or more
corridors intersect.
The establishment of soft links among nodes. It is through the spatial interaction
among corridor nodes that new opportunities for trade and investment are cre-
ated, making the corridor function as an economic space. The third and fourth
pillars of the CAREC programme contribute to improving interaction among cor-
ridor nodes.
figure 17
Components of the Beira Corridor programme
63
See Glossary.
64
See Glossary.
65
BAGC has a partnership with the Provincial Directorate of Agriculture in Manica of the
Mozambican Ministry of Agriculture to support monitoring the incidence of fruit fly.
68 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
the United Republic of Tanzania (GoT). Special task forces have been established
to address specific investor issues regarding land leasing (through regional land
banks), export regulations, taxation and imports of seeds, other inputs and agri-
cultural machinery. Private sector participation in this dialogue is ensured by the
SAGCOT Centre, which coordinates with the Tanzania Private Sector Foundation,
the Agricultural Council of Tanzania and other private sector organizations that
bring together local and international investors to guarantee that priority issues for
the corridor are addressed at the highest levels.
MP3EI unfolds a development strategy with three interrelated pillars. The first
pillar regards the development of existing and new growth centres along economic
corridors through the promotion of clusters and SEZs, conforming to the core
competencies of each region. This component seeks to optimize agglomeration
advantages, explore regional strengths and reduce the spatial imbalance of economic
development throughout the country. The GoI provides incentives to SEZ firms,
such as favourable taxation and customs policies, labour regulations and licensing
developed in consultation with the private sector. The second pillar refers to the
improvement of connectivity between the centres of economic growth (major cities)
and main clusters supported by improved infrastructures including roads, seaports,
airports, power, water and other related infrastructures. Connectivity is understood
in a triple sense: intracorridor (or intra-island) connectivity, inter-economic-cor-
ridor connectivity and international trade logistics or global connectivity, notably
with other ASEAN countries. The last pillar points at the investment in human
resources – through training, research and development (R&D) and technology
transfer – to strengthen the capacities required to support the development of cor-
ridor initiatives (CMEA, 2011).
BOX 10
The GMS Strategic Framework 2012–2022
The GMS Strategic Framework 2012–2022 strives to adopt fully the regional economic corri-
dor approach, which implies promoting “multisector investments to foster economic corridor
development, stronger cross-sectoral linkages, more local stakeholder involvement [...]”, as
well as more effective monitoring and evaluation (ADB and ADBI, 2013; p. 58).
The framework proposes widening and deepening the GMS corridors in three ways.
Adding “area development plans” through a variety of measures, namely: promoting
agribusiness investments; developing market and storage infrastructure; providing incen-
tives to industrial development; enhancing business climate and capacities for SMEs;
increasing rural-urban linkages by developing “green” value chains; enhancing resilience
of investments by using climate friendly technologies; and investing in tourism infrastruc-
ture. The emphasis of these measures is on facilitating environmentally and socially sound
trade and investment initiatives in the newly connected areas, as a means to generate
income, employment and more intraregional trade.
Finalizing incomplete infrastructural linkages and funding multimodal transport initiatives
with regional impact (railways, water and air transportation). Extending the network of
feeder roads linked to the main road arteries is also contemplated.
Enhancing regional transport and trade facilitation to reduce national barriers. This
includes the development and strengthening of logistics companies and the standardiza-
tion of custom procedures in the corridors. This strategy recognizes the critical role that
the private sector, and particularly logistics firms, can have in reducing costs and increas-
ing the flow of intermodal exchange of goods and services across the corridors (ADB,
2010e; 2011a; 2011c; 2012a; 2012b).
To underpin such economic corridor development, the new SF introduces two innovative
elements. The first element is a second-generation project pipeline with increased TA to
implement the action plan in agriculture and other targeted sectors. The second element is
a revamped approach on coordination and capacity development, based on the understand-
ing that a “business as usual” path is not an option for going forward. The new generation
of corridor development undertakings foreseen in the SF includes complex and integrated
multisector initiatives that encompass both hard and soft aspects. Such interventions entail
greater need for knowledge generation and management, institutional adaptation and, more
specifically, a stronger engagement with local authorities and private firms in the corridor
areas (ADB, 2010e).
corridor(s) that can be utilized to persuade other actors to co-finance specific areas
of work or activities detailed in the plan.
The SFs of both GMS and CAREC are operationalized through medium-term
action plans. They have also developed specific long-term plans for each flagship
programme or priority sector, which are well aligned with the overall framework
contained in the medium- and long-term plans. For instance, the GMS programme
70 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
has five-year plans for the agricultural sector, i.e. CASP I and II, and strategies for
other prioritized sectors, as noted in Table 18.
According to Sanghvi, Simons and Uchoa (2011), governments of developing
countries should make their corridor-based plans to foster agricultural growth as
targeted and explicit as possible. PRA designers disagree with this premise, hence
their attitude to the planning instrument described is slightly different. The PRA
Project has a project document that maps out the strategy, sets targets (results
framework) and indicates the components available, but keeps a flexible approach
on how to deliver targets. An essential ingredient of such flexibility is the absence
of selected sectors, industries and beneficiaries.
The blueprints or masterplans usually include a results framework and develop-
ment matrix for planning corridor subprojects. The matrix contains a list of priority
investments and TA corridor projects. The main purpose of the matrix is to serve as
a basis for corridor planning, programming and monitoring (Table 19). In addition,
it is of use for mapping the different funding sources, classifying the subprojects
into the various supported sectors, and differentiating which projects are funded
through loans, grants and/or TA funds. This matrix underlines the existing areas of
work with funding gaps and can be used as a platform for donor cooperation, i.e.
for negotiating with potential financiers and donors.
The preparation of the masterplan can be carried out in a participatory man-
ner through corridor working groups and stakeholder meetings. Opening up the
TABLE 18
Sectors targeted by the GMS cooperation programme and their corresponding plans
Targeted sector Support strategy or programme Flagship project(s)
1. Agriculture Core Agriculture Support Programme Flood control and water resource
(CASP) management
4. Human resources Phnom Penh Plan for Development Development of human resources
development Management (of human resources) and skill competencies
Long-term plan Ten-year Strategic Frameworks, Initial framework: Project Investment Investment Blueprint MP3EI
e.g. SF 2002–2012 and SF SF for a Comprehensive document Blueprint and Greenprint
2012–2022 Action Plan (2006) with results
and SF 2012–2022 framework
Monitoring and Monitoring of overall corridor CAREC Development PRA M&E M&E The SAGCOT A full-time
evaluation (M&E) development and sectoral plans, Effectiveness Review system framework Secretariat monitors dedicated
system e.g. M&E of the progress made outsourced to and processes daily activities, but Secretariat is
in implementation of the CEP- a private firm for assessing has outsourced the responsible for
BCI 2012–2016 the impact of design and operation developing an
investments in of an M&E system to M&E system
the corridor assess the impacts of for MP3EI
the partnership
71
72 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
66
The analysis excluded the fixed costs of the ESCs or the Lima office and the indirect costs of the
implementation contractor (USAID, 2008a).
Chapter 5 – Effective direction 73
subdivision of the three GMS corridors into nine subcorridors, and the possible
extension to India. Again, in the PRA Project, the number of corridors varied
repeatedly as a result of various internal and external dynamics. Furthermore, new
components can be added (e.g. the addition of agriculture development and other
areas of work in the GMS and CAREC programmes), and governance mechanisms
can be introduced or enhanced when the institutions concerned are ripe and ready
for greater involvement.
The M&E system of the PRA Project detected some vulnerability in the first
phase, and so PRA II made a conscious effort to fix this by mainstreaming gender
equity, compliance with labour standards, environmental protection, biodiversity
preservation and the inclusion of vulnerable groups in ESC activities. This main-
streaming effort has encompassed the redesign of business plan formats and the
M&E system to incorporate these dimensions, as well as the provision of training
and mentoring to comply with good agricultural and livestock practices, the Pes-
ticide Evaluation Report and Safe Use Action Plan (PERSUAP), and labour and
environmental standards (USAID, 2010).
75
Chapter 6
Delivery at scale: budget and
modalities of interventions
This chapter discusses two of the building blocks that form the “delivery at scale”
triangle represented in Figure 3. The third building block deals with corridor gov-
ernance, which will be examined in Chapter 7.
TABLE 20
Budget and sources of funding of the corridor experiences studied
Induced public
Induced PPPs
Co-financing
US$ million
investment
investment
convener
Induced
private
Main
Total
%
%
%
Sources: author’s elaboration, based on www.adb.org; www.proyectopra.com; AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010;
SAGCOT, 2011; CMEA, 2011.
Note1) The GoI is the main convener of the Indonesian corridors, so the induced public investment is considered
null to avoid duplication.
76 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
national governments and the private sector. For example, in the CAREC, GMS and
Indonesian cases, the corridor countries contribute to the programme with over a
quarter of the total budget, i.e. 26, 27 and 28 percent, respectively.
In all the cases, the contribution of the private sector to the development of the
corridor – registered either as induced PPPs or induced private investment – is note-
worthy. The exceptions are the corridors following the ADB model, but basically
because these data are not available.
Table 21 tries to put things into perspective and allow cross-comparison by
detailing the estimated accumulated investments per corridor and per country.
Another piece of data worth highlighting is the percentage of the corridor’s
budget that goes into the agricultural sector (Table 22). This ratio range is extremely
variable since it depends on the number of economic sectors and industries targeted,
but also on the fraction of the budget dedicated to the development of backbone
infrastructure, which can be very high. For instance, in the GMS corridor pro-
TABLE 21
Estimated accumulated investments per corridor and per country
Number of Accumulated investments Accumulated investments
corridors per corridor (US$ million) per country (US$ million)
TABLE 22
Percentage of corridor budget dedicated to agriculture
Corridor budget allocated to the agricultural sector (%)1)
BAGCI 35.0
CAREC n.a.
GMS 5.0
Indonesia 7.7
PRA 80.0
SAGCOT 49.0
TABLE 23
Contribution of corridor investments to the corridor GDP
1)
US$ million Contribution of corridor direct and induced investments to annual GDP (%)
BAGCI 0.8
CAREC 1.1
GMS 0.12
Indonesia 3.0
PRA 0.16
SAGCOT 0.9
TABLE 24
Estimated investments in GMS corridors
ADB Governments Co-financing Total
US$ million
TA 2012–2014 7 – 28 35
TABLE 25
Regional technical assistance projects financed by ADB under GMS CASP I and II and related fields
Project
Title Amount (US$)
number
CASP I
Subtotal 4 250 000
CASP II
Subtotal 14 300 000
Total 18 550 000
the process of implementing 456 investment projects, with a total project cost of
US$15 billion,67 mostly in the form of loans, but also with a certain grant compo-
nent. These projects dealt with the improvement of infrastructure (e.g. subregional
roads, airports, railways, hydropower for cross-border power supply, and tourism
infrastructure) as well as investments in agriculture. In addition, ADB and other co-
financiers supported nearly 180 RETA projects with a total cost of US$286 million
(subtotal 1992–2011) for economic and sector work, project preparation, capacity
67
www.adb.org [last accessed August 2013].
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 79
development, and coordination and secretariat assistance (ADB, 2012c). For the
current planning period (2012–2014), total estimated investments amount to US$2.8
billion in loans and grants, in addition to US$35 million of RETA projects.
Of the total ADB financial envelope for the GMS programme, only a relatively
small fraction is associated with agriculture. For the period 2012–2014, this alloca-
tion is US$111.5 million, i.e. 5 percent of the total financing estimated in US$2.2
billion. The major share still goes to the transport sector, amounting to 63 percent.68
Table 25 gives some examples of RETA projects and investments, both ongoing and
in the pipeline, that are targeting – one way or another – agricultural sector develop-
ment in the GMS corridors.
On some occasions, the budget allocation to the agricultural sector goes into
great detail. For example, a large part of the total MP3EI budget in Indonesia
(7.7 percent or US$30.66 billion) is dedicated to creating and improving supporting
infrastructure for specific value chains, including palm oil, rubber, cocoa, timber and
other food crops, as shown in Table 26.
The majority of the corridor programmes are requiring more and more financial
resources over time. Accordingly, resource mobilization efforts will need to be
stepped up to meet these financing needs. In addition to continued support from
the main champions (donors and IFIs) and countries themselves, the corridor
programmes should liaise with other development partners for greater financial sup-
port. The importance of accessing some of the newer and specialized global funds,
including those concerned with climate change and food security, is progressively
being recognized.
TABLE 26
Investments in agricultural value chains in the Indonesian economic corridors
Investments Sumatra Java Kalimantan Sulawesi Bali-NT Papua-KM Subtotal
US$ billion
68
www.adb.org [last accessed August 2013].
80 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Corridor programmes also need to tap private sources of financing more effec-
tively, and review various possible mechanisms, including guarantees and PPPs. The
latter modality is already being developed in some of the concerned countries, and
may be viable during the next decade in the rest of the developing world.
Soft interventions require fewer financial resources than infrastructure ones, but the
former investments improve capacities and institutions so that it is possible to raise
returns to hard investments. Most corridor subprojects or components (e.g. area
development plans, value-chain initiatives, clusters and SEZs) combine both soft
and hard features.
Another way to classify corridor interventions is according to their impact on two
corridor dimensions: broadness and national and/or regional scope (ADB, 2011c).
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 81
figure 18
Making economic corridors broader and regionally integrated
Broad
ZONE IV
National Regional
ZONE II
+ broad + broad
last-mile cross-border
infrastructure agroparks & SEZs
area contract
development farming
value chain
National Regional
ZONE III
ZONE I
+ narrow + narrow
ports
x
Regional
infrastructure, notably last-mile infrastructure that feeds into the major infrastruc-
ture supported under the first quadrant.
The movement from Zone I to Zone III symbolizes the adoption of measures
to support integration in a regional corridor. Figure 19 is a snapshot of a regional
corridor in Zone III that links three (narrow) national corridors crossing countries
A, B and C.
Rather than interpreting the regional corridor as an extension beyond national
boundaries of three different corridors, it is more usefully viewed as the subsequent
stage of reducing national barriers through transport and trade facilitation measures.
Figure 19 shows an example of complementary national interventions to increase
regionality on two levels: among the participating countries and complementarity
between integration hardware and software initiatives. The focus of Zone III is on
transport and trade facilitation, i.e. moving goods and people easily and cost effi-
ciently from place to place, which in Figure 19 is a port in Country A and another
in Country C.
Developing Zone III requires facilitating regional cooperation through several
coordination mechanisms, such as regional blocs or dedicated corridor bodies that
pursue regional integration. Zone III is relatively investment light, with the focus
being on creating or strengthening the software for the physical infrastructure
already in place (e.g. within the border policies, transport facilitation and trade and
investment promotion).
Zone IV marks the last stage of development of a regional corridor, which
becomes a broad and seamless regional entity. Movement towards Zone IV cor-
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 83
figure 19
Example of a narrow, regional corridor (Zone III)
Investment
Policy Policy loans, Policy
interventions interventions guarantees interventions
and grants
ridors may require joint regional plans, or joint plans for cross-border area develop-
ment (clusters, SEZs, etc.) by the concerned countries or, at the least, coordination
of national plans. The alternative, of coordinating national plans (including private
sector investment and activities), is often the most viable option.
This framework shows a sequence across the four zones, with Zone I preceding
Zones II and III, which in turn pave the way for Zone IV development. The next
sections detail the types of measures that are characteristic of each zone and those
needed to broaden and deepen or “regionalize” a corridor, i.e. to move from one
quadrant to another.
to address these bottlenecks. In these cases, the magnitude of the resources pooled
together may be substantial - especially when confronted with demand for large
infrastructural investments. Therefore, the participation of both the public and
private sectors is required. Should the infrastructure gap be considerable, incentives
and other support measures may be provided for greenfield developments, as noted
in the African agricultural growth corridors.
When analysing infrastructure interventions (Zone I) of the six corridor initia-
tives appraised, four issues emerge as worth highlighting. The first is the prioritiza-
tion of high-impact infrastructure, namely roads, railways, ports and energy. The
second refers to the sequencing of interventions: what comes first, infrastructure
development or interventions in agriculture and other selected economic sectors?
Third, three different ways of approaching the infrastructure component in an
economic corridor programme have been observed. Finally, there is a discussion on
the increasingly important role of the private sector in the financing, development
and management of corridor infrastructure projects through PPPs.
The corridor programmes studied have favoured high-impact infrastructure
improvements, particularly highways and ports. Within this high-impact category,
two main types of infrastructure can be distinguished. The first is physical con-
nectivity to reduce transportation costs, and travel and border crossing time. The
second encompasses telecommunications and energy to reduce business costs.
Many corridor programmes also enhance last-mile infrastructure, but this type of
intervention belongs to the second quadrant and, hence, will be analysed in section
6.4. Box 11 provides an overview of the way in which BAGCI and SAGCOT tackle
infrastructure development in their respective corridors.
Removing infrastructure bottlenecks is often the main budget ticket of the cor-
ridor programme. This is the experience of GMS and CAREC to date. As of 2011,
priority infrastructure projects worth approximately US$10 billion were completed
or about to be completed in the GMS area, with road networks representing the
largest share (ADB, 2012a). CAREC had invested over US$21 billion in major
infrastructure by the end of 2012. In both cases, the lion’s share of this figure went
to the development of road and railway networks: an indicative 63 percent of the
total budget for the GMS, and 79 percent for the CAREC programme.
At present, road infrastructure projects are almost complete in the GMS.
However, certain gaps remain, regarding multimodalism (particularly inclusion of
rail and inland water navigation), the improvement of logistics and other software
elements (e.g. road safety, enhanced competition in the transport sector and climate
proofing of transportation infrastructure) and the development of some corridor
sections in Myanmar (ADB, 2010f). CAREC has also built and improved some
3 600 km of road and almost 2 000 km of railway track (ADB, 2011f), but important
expansions and enhancements are still required. The current emphasis is on final-
izing the road and rail networks and on enhancing the software partnering with
transporters and other private actors. The approach to building and rehabilitating
these roads and railway lines has mostly been national, in the sense that each coun-
try has taken responsibility for the sections of the transportation backbone of the
three corridors and nine subcorridors that fall within its territory. Yet, put together,
all these projects form the puzzle of regional road and railway networks ensuring
intra- and intercorridor transport connectivity.
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 85
BOX 11
How BAGCI and SAGCOT approach infrastructure development
BAGCI distinguishes between major connective infrastructure (e.g. roads, railways and ports)
and last-mile infrastructure (AdDevCo and InfraCo, 2010). The latter infrastructure is clearly
lacking, whereas overall transport infrastructure is fair along the corridor (ibid.). The Beira
Blueprint has provisions only for improving last-mile infrastructure, whereas the Mozam-
bican Government undertakes investments in major transport infrastructure with funds from
its regular budget, donors, loans from international financial institutions and PPPs. SAGCOT
follows the same approach.
The Beira Corridor has a multimodal, mostly functional, transport backbone com-
posed of a road network among urban centres that is considered adequate: the Sena and
Machipanda railway lines69 and the port of Beira70. The railway lines and the port have
attracted private firms to take care of their management and invest in their expansion
(Domínguez-Torres and Briceño-Garmendia, 2011). The port of Beira has been privately
operated since 1998, when its general cargo and terminals management and operation
were conceded to a Netherlands company (ibid.). Similarly, the two railway lines serving the
corridor were given in concession to Indian consortia in December 2004.71 BAGCI’s road net-
work has recently seen a revamp in investment and rehabilitation, with a second-generation
road fund set in place (Domínguez-Torres and Briceño-Garmendia, 2011). Likewise, the
Sena railway line has recently been rehabilitated and the port of Beira is undergoing a major
upgrade, with channels being dredged to allow the transit of larger vessels, and handling
capacity being doubled from five to ten million tonnes (ibid.). Funding for the port upgrade
comes from several development agencies, multilateral banks and private investors. The
Danish International Development Agency (DANIDA)72 is funding the rehabilitation of some
parts of Beira airport.
In the SAGCOT case, there are several relevant ongoing investments in backbone infra-
structure by the GoT, development institutions and private companies, as summarized in
Table 27. Furthermore, in the 2010–2015 period, public investments of US$445 million are
required to improve the rural road network, mostly coming through the national budget
(SAGCOT, 2010).
Under current conditions in SAGCOT, much of the immediate upfront expenditure
required for new farming projects and farm improvement is in the last-mile infrastructure
connections, with an estimated budget envelope of US$570 million. With access to patient
capital, private players can manage the implementation of these investments, which should
provide a financial return over the long term (WEF, 2012).
69
The 680 km-long Sena line linking the port of Beira to the coal-mining town of Moatize and the
Malawian border, and the Machipanda railway line between Beira and Harare, Zimbabwe.
70
As explained earlier, the port of Beira acts as an international gateway, not only for Mozambique,
but also for the region’s landlocked countries – Malawi, Zambia and Zimbabwe.
71
Rail India Technical and Economic Services (RITES) Ltd and IRCON International.
72
http://um.dk/en/danida-en/ [last accessed July 2013].
86 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 11 (Continued)
Among other things, the ongoing upgrade of major infrastructure in both corridors offers
a great potential for strengthening channels to markets for agricultural producers. For this
potential to be realized, the charges for use of these facilities should be affordable for agri-
cultural players, particularly in the early years of corridor development (AgDevCo and InfraCo,
2010). The expected decrease in transport costs will likely have a favourable impact on the
competitiveness of Mozambican and Tanzanian agricultural production and agro-exports.
Besides the anticipated investments in transport and last-mile infrastructure, major
anchor investments in the mining sector, proposed and under way in BAGC, will probably
impact the corridor infrastructure. On the one hand, mining activities – among them, two
very large mining projects in construction near Tete, with a combined potential to produce
approximately 13 million tonnes of coal by 2015 – are expected to drive marked improve-
ments in transport, power and water infrastructure (ibid.). The agricultural sector will pos-
sibly be one of the most important beneficiaries of these infrastructure enhancements (ibid.).
On the other hand, the rising demand for transport of the mining sector poses an enormous
hurdle both institutionally and financially, as the size of the road and rail network seems to
overshadow the national capacity to fund its rapid expansion and maintenance. The com-
bined transport demand of the mining and agricultural sectors in the corridor will require
additional sustained and massive investments over decades, with the participation of the pri-
vate sector and non-traditional financiers (Domínguez-Torres and Briceño-Garmendia, 2011).
TABLE 27
Investments in backbone infrastructure along SAGCOT
Backbone
Donor and budget in US$ million Item financed
infrastructure
In Peru, the infrastructure component of the project did not fund the develop-
ment of transport infrastructure through loans and grants, but assisted the GoP to
develop an infrastructure PPP scheme to tap private investments and manage the
existing stock more efficiently. This assistance also prepared the GoP to programme
and manage key infrastructural projects of corridors through a national project and
negotiate their insertion as priority in the IIRSA pipeline.
Indonesia plans to invest over US$177 billion in general infrastructure serving the
six economic corridors. This represents an annual investment of over 1.25 percent of
the country’s GDP. Most of this investment goes to road and railway infrastructure
followed, inter alia, by energy, ports and airports (CMEA, 2011).
In Mozambique and the United Republic of Tanzania, the main roads and
railway lines of the corridors were in fair condition, but needed some upgrading
and/or expansion. In these corridors, infrastructure projects have been linked to
the extraction of agricultural commodities from producing areas or agrobased
clusters to ports and large consumer centres (Beira and Dar es Salaam). These
two experiences can offer useful policy lessons about best practices and pitfalls
of commodity-led infrastructure development in Africa and its potential to pay
growth dividends.
Ports are as strategically important for corridor growth as roads and railway
lines. Most economic corridors are anchored by ports, which are essential for
intraregional trade (GMS) and exports to distant markets. For example, GMS
transport corridors end at large port complexes that are located near dynamic
agricultural and industrial areas. Some corridors even take their name from the port
that serves as the main gateway, as in the case of BAGC, which ends at the port of
Beira. Interventions related to port development belong to Zone I because, even if
the port serves as the gateway for a regional corridor, responsibility for developing
or upgrading the port and managing it falls within the national sphere.
The corridor programmes studied often encompass the development or upgrad-
ing of sea and river ports. For example, Table 28 gives a list of the major river and
sea ports along the GMS corridors. However, these ports work as secondary ports
that then feed two major hub ports in Asia: Hong Kong and Singapore.
Other examples of ports that have been upgraded as part of the corridor action
plan are the port of Dar es Salaam (United Republic of Tanzania), and the port of
Callao (Peru), which are the principal international gateways for agricultural goods
produced in the SAGCOT and PRA corridors, respectively. An example of the
development of a new port is the project for developing a deep seaport in Dawei,
Myanmar, which is at the western end of the SEC. This port is essential for China
and the rest of the Mekong countries to reach the Indian Ocean.
Secondary or feeder ports serving hub ports are also important for intracorridor
connectivity. Cases in point are the inland ports on Lakes Tanganyika and Nyasa in
the SAGCOT corridor. Other examples are the seaport of Paita and the river port
of Yurimaguas in the Peruvian corridors analysed, and the ports of Da Nang and
Hai Phong in Viet Nam, which are part of the EWEC. CAREC has also upgraded
some river ports (ADB, 2011f). Indonesia, as an archipelago nation, has allocated
US$11.4 billion of the overall MP3EI budget envelope to developing new ports
(international hub, regional hub and feeder ports) and upgrading existing ones
(CMEA, 2011).
88 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
TABLE 28
Major river and sea ports along the GMS corridors
Country Port Location
figure 20
Insertion of SEZs in Indonesian corridors
Supporting
Main roads linking infrastructure: ports,
economic centres airports, power supply
Economic growth
centres: commercial
centres of trading hubs
Suggested
SEZ connectors
Supporting infrastructure
linking economic activities Main economic activities
prioritized in the corridor
lowed by a lateral movement along the y-axis to Zone II or along the x-axis to Zone
III. This was a clear generalization. A glance at the experiences appraised shows that
the “normal” sequencing (from Zone I to II or III) has been followed in five out of
the six corridor cases.
The Peruvian case has been the exception to the rule. As already explained,
the Peruvian corridor programme did not start with interventions in Zone I, but
focused on measures typical of Zone II. Consequently, the PRA Project launched
interventions to widen the existing transport corridor (operational but underper-
forming), before a single cent was invested in upgrading and rehabilitating the
transport backbone of the corridors. This implies that there is room to invert the
sequencing of corridor progress among the quadrants and zones as long as there is
a minimum degree of connectivity. Such connectivity can be improved in parallel or
with some delay with respect to activities performed in Zone II, but businesses will
face higher transaction costs in the meantime.
The case studies have revealed the existence of three approaches to infrastruc-
ture components in the framework of an economic corridor initiative, as elucidated
in Figure 21.
90 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 21
Degrees of IFI/donor support for developing corridor infrastructure
GMS BAGCI
BOX 12
The infrastructure component of the PRA Project
Two features distinguish the PRA corridor intervention from the GMS and CAREC pro-
grammes: the inversion of the sequential interventions (which component goes first, soft
or hard); and how infrastructure development is financed (i.e. direct financing through
loans from IFIs and government budgets or facilitation of infrastructure PPP design and
implementation). Unlike GMS and CAREC, the PRA Project did not wait to have improved
infrastructure in place to launch soft components seeking to capitalize on the economic
impacts of the enhanced connectivity. It started providing BDS in the selected corridors to
promote business growth, even before launching the infrastructure PPP component, making
the most of the existing, albeit limited, transport infrastructure.
In 2001, as a first step, the PRA Project conducted a study to quantify the economic
losses that socio-economic agents in the economic corridors were incurring because of
poor transport and energy infrastructure. Up to 24 infrastructure projects were assessed
to determine which ones would potentially yield the highest direct economic benefits. The
rehabilitation of the Tarapoto-Aucayacu stretch of the Fernando Belaúnde Terry (FBT) high-
way, in the San Martín region, was deemed the project with the highest estimated impact.
The Project held a series of meetings to inform Peruvian members of Congress and senior
government officials on the study findings. However, it soon became apparent that the GoP
had neither the necessary financial resources nor the capacity to borrow beyond the estab-
lished public debt ceiling, already capped.73 Eventually, the Project adopted a two-pronged
strategy. First, it joined forces with the Tocache Group – a lobby group formed by a broad
cross-section of public officials, private firms and NGOs in the department of San Martín
– to promote the rehabilitation of the FBT highway. The Tocache Group considered out-of-
the-box financing solutions, such as relinquishing the tax exonerations that the department
enjoyed at the time and earmarking the resulting revenues for the highway. The idea gained
traction and became law in 2005.
The second prong of the strategy drew inspiration from the active involvement of busi-
ness people in the Tocache Group, and more broadly from corporate participation in trans-
port infrastructure development and management – a fairly widespread phenomenon across
OECD countries. USAID provided additional funding to formalize the infrastructure PPP
component “to explore the potential of concessions as a way to leverage capital investment
in transportation by the private sector, both domestically and abroad” (USAID, 2008a). The
PRA Project provided TA to ProInversión, the Peruvian agency in charge of implementing the
national infrastructure concessions programme, from the onset of each concession project
design through to transaction closure. Between 2003 and 2007, the Project and ProInversión
worked together with the Ministry of Transport and other public entities in designing and
implementing five projects: three highways, the expansion of the main Peruvian port and
one energy project, summarized in Table 29.
73
GoP and PRA/USAID noted that current and projected government budgets – even when
supplemented with donor infrastructure loans – fell far short of meeting the country’s infrastructural
requirements.
92 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 12 (Continued)
TABLE 29
PRA-facilitated infrastructure developments
Item Cost (US$ million) Corridors involved
Callao port
(Southern Container Terminal)
Phase I 364 Serves all corridors
Phase II 253
As mentioned earlier, the PRA Project neither directly financed nor built roads and
ports, but supported the GoP in designing, structuring and implementing innovative PPP-
concession business schemes and transactions to attract private investment and expertise
to finance, build, operate and maintain in the long term highways, ports and energy
infrastructure projects. Its PPP work resulted in US$584 million in private capital investment
commitments to build and rehabilitate roads (IIRSA North highway) and port infrastructures
(state-of-the art container terminal and improvements to overall Callao port facilities) during
the life of PRA I (USAID, 2008a), and an additional US$115 million in road infrastructure
investment commitments (IIRSA Central highway) proposed for the national five-year infra-
structure investment plan from 2012 to 2016 (BNamericas, 2012).
The hallmarks of the PRA Project intervention in infrastructure were:
innovative PPP design and financing schemes to engage private sectors in otherwise not
so attractive concessions;
intense promotional campaigns to ensure the participation of both national and inter-
national bidders;
the vocation to transcend the corridor programme and propose a PPP scheme for coun-
trywide and multisectoral application.
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 93
BOX 12 (Continued)
When the Project’s infrastructure component started operations, there were already some
ongoing infrastructure concessions in Peru. However, Peru’s complicated geography makes
corridor infrastructure projects expensive, and thin domestic markets prevent many con-
cessions from meeting the private sector’s expectations in terms of revenue generation.
Furthermore, concessions frequently encountered problems pertaining to crossing fibre
optic networks and legal and social issues regarding land acquisition and expropriation
(BNamericas, 2012).
The Project’s main contribution was the introduction of innovative transaction design
features to the existing Peruvian infrastructure concession model, in order to improve not
only the bankability and attractiveness of the concessions, but also to protect the public
interest by providing mechanisms to share larger than expected revenues. For example,
the Project introduced state-of-the-art financial engineering schemes to make the projects
more enticing for private investment. One such scheme was developed for the IIRSA Central
highway concession. To make up for the expected insufficient stream of toll revenues on
this highway, the GoP agreed to provide a minimum revenue guarantee (determined at the
bidding stage). A safeguard mechanism was also introduced – should revenues be higher
than expected, a public-private revenue-sharing mechanism would be deployed. Another
example is the case of the IIRSA North highway concession. The GoP introduced annual
payments for construction (i.e. securitization of construction progress certificates prorated
to the advancement of work), and payments for operation and maintenance of up to US$15
million, with collections from tolls deducted from the yearly payment. The transaction was
further enhanced by a partial credit guarantee from IaDB to cover the GoP’s payment obli-
gations for an amount up to US$60 million74 (USAID, 2008a). Moreover, a revolving US$60
million bridge loan was negotiated with the Andean Development Corporation to avoid
delays on the commencement of construction works, while the winning concessionaire
managed to secure long-term financing (USAID, 2006).
In the case of the FBT highway, one of the key features of the financing scheme was the
creation of a trust fund specifically earmarked for the completion of the highway, fed by the
proceeds of the value-added tax (US$14 million annually for 50 years) upon the elimination
of the fiscal exoneration (upon request of local, provincial and regional governments of the
corridor) that the department of San Martin had up to then enjoyed (ibid.). The enhanced
model also emphasized the adoption of good design practices to minimize the need to make
substantial modifications during contract execution, e.g. completing the appropriate techni-
cal prefeasibility, feasibility and environmental studies, as well as studies on land acquisition
before awarding the concession.
The PRA Project conducted an aggressive local, regional and international project pro-
motion campaign to ensure competitive and transparent bidding processes. It also prepared
promotional brochures, sent information bulletins to over a hundred firms and conducted
road shows targeting high-level government officials in South America (USAID, 2008a).
74
www.proinversion.gob.pe [last accessed May 2013].
94 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 12 (Continued)
Eventually, these promotional efforts to foster the participation of international bidders for
the concession contracts yielded fruit. The IIRSA North highway concession contract was
granted to a consortium of Brazilian and Peruvian firms, and that of the new container ter-
minal in the port of Callao to a Dubai-Peruvian consortium. These concessionaries brought
with them not only ample financial resources but also first-class technical expertise and
managerial expertise (ibid.).
The infrastructure component transcended the mandate and lifetime of the project. In
2006, the Peruvian Ministry of Transport and Communications approved the Transport Sec-
tor Policy, which specified that transport infrastructure was “[...] not an end in itself, but
an appropriate means to foster safe, efficient and quality transport services”75 that help in
improving the competitiveness of economic corridors, thus mainstreaming the PRA model.
Furthermore, in 2007, the Ministry created the “Project Peru programme”,76 designed to
improve road infrastructure to connect and integrate economic corridors better, forming a
sustainable development axis in order to raise the competitiveness of rural areas. The Peru-
vian concession programme for transport infrastructure under the PRA-designed PPP model
has kept the momentum going. The regulations of this model were published in 2008 and,
as of March 2012, there were 26 transport infrastructure contracts, 14 of which involved
highways, amounting to an investment of US$3.5 billion (BNamericas, 2012).
Efforts to improve the competitiveness of Peruvian economic corridors through infra-
structural improvements have been further developed under IIRSA, the UNASUR umbrella
programme mentioned in Chapter 3. This programme has taken the IIRSA North highway
and transformed it into a multimodal transport corridor connecting the Pacific (from the
port of Paita on the north coast of Peru) and Atlantic Oceans, through the Brazilian State
of Amazonas via three PRA corridors (Sierra La Libertad, Jaén and Tarapoto). The main
infrastructural works in the multimodal corridor are the concession of the port of Paita
(granted in March 2009 for US$227.8 million), and a logistics platform in Paita; the IIRSA
North highway between Paita and the city of Yurimaguas in the Tarapoto corridor; a port,
airport and logistics centre in Yurimaguas; and other facilities in the inland water transport
corridor formed by the Huallaga, Marañón and Amazon rivers between Yurimaguas and the
industrial pole of Manaus, capital of Amazonas State.77
The African agricultural growth corridors use PPPs intensively in various fields,
including infrastructure PPPs such as the one mentioned regarding the management
of the main ports and railway lines. In particular, they pay attention to ensuring the
correct supervision and monitoring of infrastructure PPPs.
75
Ministerial Resolution 817/2006-MTC/09, dated 7 November 2006.
76
Ministerial Resolution 223/2007-MTC-02, as amended by Ministerial Resolution 408/2007-MTC/02.
77
www.iirsa.org [last accessed July 2013].
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 95
78
http://www.yara.com/sustainability/how_we_engage/africa_engagement/growth_corridors/
index.aspx [last accessed August 2013].
96 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 13
Examples of last-mile infrastructure development in economic corridors
The BAGC and SAGCOT initiatives emphasize the importance of developing last-mile infra-
structure to alleviate critical constraints hindering commercial agriculture in their respective
corridors. Specifically, investments are needed to overcome the low accessibility in rural
areas to all-weather feeder roads79 and power networks, and the lack of adequate irriga-
tion infrastructure.
BAGCI plans to upgrade sections of rural roads and critically expand coverage in strips
of high agricultural potential land in the northern part of Tete, southwestern Manica and
east of Dombe in Mozambique (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010). It also envisages enhancing
the coverage of power networks in the Beira Corridor which, although reasonable, leaves
many areas of fertile agricultural land unattended. Likewise, the current irrigation area
will be expanded significantly to take advantage of the country’s generous endowment of
water resources (Domínguez-Torres and Briceño-Garmendia, 2011). Out of BAGCI’s target
of US$1.7 billion of private investment, the majority of investment costs pertain to last-mile
infrastructure, including on-farm (irrigation) and off-farm infrastructure, which includes the
costs of bringing road access, power and water to the farmgate. Estimated investment costs
are distributed as shown in Table 30.
Similarly, the SAGCOT blueprint calculates that US$108 million will be needed for mar-
keting, storage and processing infrastructure along the corridor, including processing/milling
facilities, warehouses and cold storage, and a network of wholesale markets and collection
points. Some of these facilities and infrastructure are likely to be funded publicly (e.g. whole-
sale markets), and others commercially (agroprocessing plants). However, patient capital will
probably be needed to help the private sector to achieve economies of scale and ensure
strong farmer-firm linkages in the initial years of the corridor programme (WEF, 2012).
The GMS programme has also developed agriculture-specific last-mile infrastructure,
such as agrifood wholesale markets, warehouses, logistics and trading centres and feeder
roads linking priority agricultural and agro-industrial hotspots in the corridor with major
transport links (ADB, 2008b; 2011a). For instance, fresh primary and wholesale markets
have been constructed, at a cost of US$150 000 each, in certain segments of the GMS cor-
ridors, particularly in the Lao People’s Democratic Republic, to facilitate the participation of
smallholder farmers in agricultural marketing chains (Zola, 2009).
The CAREC programme finances and develops different types of infrastructure in a
sequencing manner. In the first phase, the focus is on developing the transport backbone
of the corridors. Then comes the turn of last-mile infrastructure, including: (i) infrastructure
of corridor towns, such as agricultural collection points, wholesale markets and agricultural
warehouses; (ii) agrobased cluster infrastructure; and (iii) infrastructure and facilities that
contribute to ensuring that the agricultural products originating from different areas along
the corridor meet the standards required by domestic or foreign markets (ADB, 2012e).
79
The countrywide rural accessibility level is only 24 percent, and over 40 percent of rural roads are in
poor condition (Domínguez-Torres and Briceño-Garmendia, 2011).
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 97
BOX 13 (Continued)
TABLE 30
Estimated investment costs in the Beira Agricultural Growth Corridor
US$ million Percentage
80
Other farm capex 516.3 30
These interventions appear in the GMS, CAREC, Indonesian and African expe-
riences, but it is in the BAGCI and SAGCOT cases that they are given paramount
importance. The targets set for last-mile infrastructure in these two corridors are
so significant that, in order to be able to achieve them, the corridor supporters
provide financial support and foster an innovative scheme where infrastructure
service companies (ISCs) play an important role in financing and developing last-
mile infrastructure. An ISC is a private firm that secures patient capital to build
agriculture-supporting infrastructure that it then leases to medium-size commercial
farms and producer organizations.
An action plan to broaden and deepen an economic corridor by fostering
agricultural growth is likely to include a complex set of soft investments. These
software interventions can be delivered by using different mechanisms, can have
various entry points and can encompass a long list of thematic areas, as illustrated
in Figure 22.
Corridor delivery mechanisms. Indonesia and the GMS and CAREC programmes
have followed the first approach shown in Figure 22 of mainstreaming these inter-
ventions into their regular activities.
Other programmes, given the complexity and variety of soft interventions
planned for promoting agricultural growth, have decided to establish corridor
centres with dedicated staff and facilities to roll out all or some of the planned soft
interventions. This has been the choice of the PRA Project, BAGCI and SAGCOT
80
Other capital spending or money spent to acquire or upgrade physical assets such as buildings and
machinery.
98 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 22
Soft interventions to promote agricultural growth along an economic corridor
– see examples in Box 14. The main functions of these centres involve coordination,
investment promotion and the provision of BDS.
Similarly, some programmes have adopted corridor specific instruments such as
the catalytic finance funds deployed by BAGCI and SAGCOT.
As depicted in Figure 23, BAGCI has put in place dedicated financial facilities to
support socially responsible agribusiness companies (Catalytic Fund) and farmers
located in the corridor. Support to farmers is provided through the Smallholder
Support Facility, which awards grants for implementing innovative models for the
delivery of public goods and services to smallholder farmers.
SAGCOT has set up a sister fund of the BAGC Catalytic Fund: the SAGCOT
Catalytic Trust Fund (CTF). See Box 15 for further information about these
corridor-bound funds.
Entry points. The soft interventions planned can have one or more entry points
in the agricultural sector. They can target agribusiness firms and farmer organiza-
tions along the corridor involved in collaborative arrangements (linked through
contract farming and outgrower arrangements) to help them improve day-to-day
operations and find medium- and long-term solutions (adapted from UNCTAD,
2004; 2008; 2009b). This reflects the idea of sustainable, inclusive business models
contained in the blueprints of BAGCI and SAGCOT, as will be further analysed
in section 7.2.
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 99
BOX 14
Corridor centres
As seen in Box 8, the PRA Project set up an ESC in each corridor to provide BDS to targeted
farmers and client firms.
BAGCI has set up two Agri-Services Centres in Chimoio and Beira to provide agribusiness
support services to investors, farmers and other users. These centres play a key role in promot-
ing both greenfield and brownfield investments. One of their main activities is to collaborate
in the development of a database of current and planned agribusiness initiatives within the
corridor, with a view to improving coordination (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010).
The Tanzanian agrocorridor also uses this delivery mechanism. The SAGCOT Centre was
created in May 2011 as an independent institution with the functions of coordinating and
mobilizing investment and partnerships in the corridor; commissioning research; monitoring
and improving the business enabling environment; and conducting impact assessment of the
initiative over time (SAGCOT, n.d.; WEF, 2012; 2013). It concentrates these efforts in priority
agrobased clusters and value chains. One key aspect of the operation of the SAGCOT Centre
is to assist investors with start-up aspects, including site identification, company registration,
available incentives and social and environmental safeguards. The Centre plays a subsidiary role,
helping the members of the partnership to do their jobs in a more targeted and effective way.
The GMS programme does not have corridor centres as such. However, the programme
and, in particular, CASP II, places great emphasis on cross-border agriculture resource centres
and investment one-stop centres (i.e. centres for approving investment applications and
facilitating the approval of business licences and other permits) to use more effectively exist-
ing and future infrastructure through progress in areas related to investment promotion in
agriculture and the development of agro-industries in the corridors (ADB, 2007a).
figure 23
Tools to support brown and greenfield agribusiness developments in BAGC
Working
capital Working capital
facility to support
Information Small farm organizations increased production
Agri-centre and other services
Venture
capital “Social” venture capital
Contract Public
facility to promote
farming/ goods
outgrower and services pioneer investments
BOX 15
Corridor financial facilities
The BAGC blueprint considered three types of financial facilities, as illustrated in Figure 23: a
working capital facility, a social venture capital facility and a patient capital facility.81 So far,
only the social venture facility has been put in place under the name of the Beira Catalytic
Fund (BCF). The fund was set up in 2010 with an initial endowment of US$20 million with
support from the governments of Mozambique, Norway, the Netherlands and the United
Kingdom.82 AgDevCo manages the fund.83 This facility invests “social” venture capital in
early-stage agribusiness projects, taking out many of the front-end costs and risks that deter
private investment in the corridor. More specifically, the fund makes debt and equity invest-
ments on attractive terms to support the capital structure in the development of both exist-
ing and greenfield agribusinesses (on-farm operations, value addition and services). It also
provides entrepreneurs with managerial and technical support through the full project devel-
opment cycle, from design to implementation (e.g. helping to secure access to land respon-
sibly), as seen in Figure 24. In particular, it helps to leverage domestic and foreign capital
in support of the business, including local credit facilities and guarantees, as well as patient
capital from the international community to fund irrigation and other last-mile infrastructure.
FIGURE 24
Support to entrepreneurs provided by the Beira Catalytic Fund
1 2 3 4 5
Source: author’s elaboration based on AgDevCo, 2012.
The venture capital provided is tied to the recipient’s commitment to supply affordable
goods, services and end-markets to smallholder farmers. Amounts invested by the BCF
are typically in the range US$50 000 to US$500 000 per business (AgDevCo, 2012). BCF
operates as a competitive,84 revolving facility85 that seeks to recover its capital and make a
financial return (in the range of 5–10 percent overall) where available from incoming com-
mercial investors.
81
See Glossary.
82
http://www.agdevco.com/userfiles/file/AgDevCo %20Brochure %20June %202013 %20low
%20res.pdf [last accessed July 2013].
83
http://www.agdevco.com [last accessed July 2013].
84
Calls for proposals are regularly published.
85
All returns are recycled into funding new agribusiness opportunities.
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 101
BOX 15 (Continued)
As of February 2013, BCF had invested over US$3 million in 12 projects, directly ben-
efiting over 10 000 smallholder farmers.86 The large majority of the supported projects
fund commercial and outgrower production of crops (e.g. citrus, banana, litchis and other
fruit, organic sugar, maize and seeds) and livestock (goat products and broiler chickens)
(AgDevCo, 2012). The portfolio of the BCF is expected to reach approximately 25 projects
in a way that optimizes the achievement of direct impact at scale for smallholders while at
the same time recognizes the need to build agribusinesses across the extended value chain
(DFID, 2013). BCF’s performance is measured in terms of the income and capital generated
from the facility, as well as the business turnover, profit and formal jobs generated by the
fund portfolio (i.e. investee businesses) (ibid.).
Over time, other finance and insurance mechanisms are expected to complement this
facility. Examples of these mechanisms are working capital and patient capital facilities, and
weather-index insurance products for agriculture. An example of the latter type of tool is a
pilot index-based weather microinsurance product for maize, soybeans and sesame farmers
in the Chimoio region of Manica province, recently launched by BAGCI, in partnership with
AgDevCo and a local agricultural training college, Instituto Superior Politécnico de Manica
(ISPM), a technical university.87
The Smallholder Support Facility is a matching-grant facility88 managed by the BAGC
Partnership (see Chapter 7) that finances the provision of public goods and services89 to
smallholder farmers in the framework of a wide range of sustainable and replicable initia-
tives geared to integrating smallholder farmers into markets. These initiatives can be divided
into two main categories: private sector-driven outgrower and contract farming schemes in
priority value chains, and innovative models for supplying agricultural support services (e.g.
technology development and transfer, farmer organization, training and credit) to small-
scale producers.
Such grants are extended to up to US$100 000 per annum, for a maximum of two years.
Eligible applicants are farmers’ organizations, private firms, research institutions and NGOs
that are able to demonstrate that a “one-off” investment can result in a sustainable increase
in smallholder income, without the need for an ongoing subsidy. It is seen as a “smart
subsidy”90 to support the non-commercial components of smallholder support programmes
and induce earlier adoption of improved farming technologies. Examples include demon-
stration plots (e.g. Phoenix Seeds has established over 58 demonstration sites of maize and
86
http://www.agdevco.com/userfiles/file/BAGC %20press %20release_photosv3.pdf [last accessed
July 2013].
87
http://seedinvestors.blogspot.com.es/2012/12/beira-agricultural-growth-corridor-bagc.html [last
accessed July 2013]
88
See Glossary.
89
See Glossary.
90
See Glossary.
102 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 15 (Continued)
soya in the corridor); extension and training programmes (e.g. the establishment of ISPM’s
agricultural mechanization centre to provide short-term courses to tractor and machinery
operators); capacity building for farmers’ organizations; and last-mile infrastructure to serve
smallholder farmers, and particularly irrigation (e.g. RDI’s “hub and spoke” irrigation scheme
for avocados) (DFID, 2013).
As in the case of the Beira Corridor, the SAGCOT CTF is the mechanism by which sub-
projects are appraised and implemented in the corridor. The CTF has two windows. The first
is a Matching Grant Facility (MGF) for established commercial agribusinesses working with
smallholder farmers to build or extend competitive supply chains in a way that generates
income and creates employment for smallholders. The second is a Social Venture Capital
Fund (SVCF) to encourage the development and expansion of smaller and younger agri-
business firms (provided with start-up finance), also linked to smallholders (Government of
Tanzania, 2012). The CTF is expected to be at least US$50 million in size, although proposed
contributions are much higher: US$73.75 million (see breakdown of this figure in Table 31).
The CTF counts on financial backing from the Tanzanian Government and development
partners (DFID, 2012).
TABLE 31
Estimated contributions to the SAGCOT Catalytic Trust Fund
SAGCOT Catalytic Trust Fund
presence of interrelated elements such as active links for farmers to markets, support
to farmer aggregation and broad-based access to finance. Given the importance of
value-chain targeting in corridor programmes, this issue is studied in section 6.6.
Another option is to support the development of agrobased clusters by selecting
areas with potential for improving economies of scale and reducing transaction costs
for the acquisition of inputs and services specific to the agribusiness activities that are
to be promoted, such as agricultural inputs, machinery, or logistics-related services
(UNCTAD, 2004; 2008; 2009b). This strategy favours the appearance and clustering
of service providers, wholesalers, retailers, exporters and other agricultural traders,
and their associations (World Bank, 2009b). Clustering efforts are often coupled
with the promotion of SEZs and agro-industrial parks along the corridor, according
to the advantages of the specific region. The objective is to generate a diversified
agro-industrial base, in the sense of covering a wide range of agroprocessing activi-
ties (notably transitioning towards higher-value processed commodities), but also in
terms of mixing small-, medium- and large-scale agroprocessing companies.
BAGCI is one of the corridor programmes that promotes the concentration of
agricultural activity in selected clusters or locations where processors, agricultural
support service providers (e.g. extension and finance), specialized suppliers and
associated institutions are also present. SAGCOT shares the clustering approach of
the Beira model, as described in Box 16.
In Indonesia, the development of growth centres on the establishment of clusters
and SEZs is one of the three MP3EI pillars. The location of agrobased clusters and
SEZs responds to the logic of maximizing the efficiency of agricultural crop move-
ment patterns to processing zones and ports (CMEA, 2011). The Indonesian mas-
terplan foresees a sequencing of agrobased cluster development in support of the
six economic corridors in three phases: 2011–2014, 2015–2019 and 2020–2030. The
nature of the interventions outlined in each phase depends on the level of perfor-
mance and existing critical mass of firms and supporting/connective infrastructure
in each corridor. In particular, the type and size of infrastructure improvements are
dictated by the economic activities carried out in the clusters.
These SEZs are multisectoral platforms (agriculture and other sectors) linked
to agricultural clusters and plantation nodes to stimulate value addition in the
corridors (ibid.). One example of agribusiness SEZs is Sei Mangke in the northern
part of the Sumatra Corridor. This SEZ has been earmarked as the centre for palm
oil-based industries (Presidential Decree 32/2012). The public sector has made
commitments to fund infrastructure developments to improve the connectivity of
the SEZ – primarily a 30-km railway line and the development of the nearby ports
of Dumai and Belawan. The private sector reacted positively to this initiative: many
multinational companies submitted plans to the tune of US$1 billion to establish
themselves within the SEZ. However, land acquisition issues were encountered
because of the refusal of the head of the district or bupati, empowered under
regional autonomy laws, to approve the land transfer.91 This is a reflection of the
91
http://www.accessmylibrary.com/article-1G1-301373032/mp3ei-infrastructure-projects-flounder.
html [last accessed July 2013].
104 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 16
Clustering in SAGCOT
SAGCOT has planned to focus initially on six agrobased clusters. These clusters have been
selected on the basis of the presence of large commercial farms, land availability, transport
and productive infrastructure, along with the potential for profitable groupings of farming
and processing to emerge over time. Building on existing operations and planned invest-
ments, these clusters are intended to bring together nucleus farms and outgrower schemes,
irrigated block farming operations, processing and storage facilities, transport and logistics
hubs, agricultural research stations and related service providers (SAGCOT, 2011).
Each cluster requires investments along the entire agricultural value chain, and particu-
larly those needed to improve last-mile infrastructure to farms and local communities. Some
investments are public goods, for example rural infrastructure, and as such will be provided
by the GoT and its development partners – US$1.3 billion according to the SAGCOT blue-
print. Others, with potential to generate financial returns will likely come from the private
sector – estimated at US$2.1 billion – such as professionally managed irrigated farm blocks
(SAGCOT, 2010; 2011).
Six priority sites have been selected, communities consulted, and environmental and
social impact assessments performed. Firms interested in investing in the clusters can obtain
land leases through the National Land Allocation Committee. Land leases are bid out to
investors ranked according to scoring criteria, which included the extent of outgrower sup-
port, value addition, community integration and protection of natural resources.
These clusters have been divided into three categories depending on the relative ease or
difficulty involved in developing agribusiness ventures. Accordingly, “Type 1” clusters incor-
porate most of the “quick win” projects, where significant development of medium- and
large-scale commercial farming, public irrigation schemes and backbone infrastructure are
already in place. Examples of Type 1 clusters are the Ihemi (Figure 25) and Kilombero clusters.
“Type 2” and “Type 3” require further investment in backbone infrastructure and careful
assessment of social and environmental impacts.
The initial focus on Type 1 clusters is critical to establish the momentum needed for SAG-
COT’s long-term success. For example, in the Ihemi and Kilombero clusters, over a dozen new
or expanded nucleus farms can be established in the first five years – in livestock, sugar, rice
and other cereals, and high-value horticulture – all with associated outgrower/service block
schemes to extend the benefits to smallholder farmers in the vicinity.
Agribusiness SEZs will also be deployed along key locations of SAGCOT. These SEZs will
give preferential treatment to all agricultural production businesses, including – in addition
to agroprocessing – distribution of agricultural inputs, manufacturing and hiring of agroma-
chinery, and packing and transportation of agricultural products (OECD, 2013).
lack of coordination among line ministries, agencies and local governments, which
may hinder the implementation of MP3EI.
Most corridor models opt for a combination of all the above entry points. For
instance, the agricultural plan of the GMS programme (CASP II) underscores that
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 105
BOX 16 (Continued)
FIGURE 25
Ihemi: example of an agricultural cluster in the SAGCOT corridor
Mpwapwa
District
Kilosa
Ruaha District
National
Park
Kiwere Nyanzwa
dam dam
Mtanga Farm
Kisolanza
Horticulture
Project Kisolanza
Mufindi Kilombero
District District
Source: author’s elaboration (UN Map No. 4045 Rev. 7, November 2011,
Department of Field Support - Cartographic Section).
Thematic coverage. The range of topics covered by the different corridors varies
greatly. However, seven broad clusters of soft agrobound interventions used to
develop agrocorridors, either individually or concomitantly, can be individualized.
Most corridors have taken the approach of addressing issues of policy and creating an
enabling environment, as these issues arise in the course of programme implementa-
tion. For example, the dialogue between the PRA Project and the GoP led to stream-
lining and strengthening the national policies for forest concessions and food safety
standards. An alternative to this approach is to address multiple agricultural policies
through a coordinated set of actions. Mozambique, the United Republic of Tanzania
and other Grow Africa countries participating in G8’s New Alliance for Food Security
and Nutrition Country Cooperation Frameworks have made upfront commitments
to improve policy and create an enabling environment for agribusiness development as
part of a joint agreement with development partners and donors (WEF, 2013).
2. Non-financial BDS to develop potential business opportunities in the agri-
cultural sector. The provision of non-financial BDS is key to improving the
corridor’s domestic sales and exports, mobilizing investments and generating
employment in the corridor. These services include: brokering of market link-
ages and promotion of contract farming in the interior areas of corridor coun-
tries; investment promotion; SME-support services; information services; and
other technical and entrepreneurial assistance as required. More specifically,
these services include the following:
Brokering of advantageous market linkages and promotion of contract
farming and outgrower arrangements. This issue is the cornerstone of
almost all the corridors analysed. However, they have approached the
topic from various angles and hence have arrived at different strategies. For
example, one of the main functions of the PRA ESCs is to act as brokers,
advisors and moral guarantors of contract farming deals between buyers
and local farmers. Other corridors take a less direct but equally important
engagement in contract farming via other means of promotion, such as
innovative financial models for offering incentives and support services
to agribusiness farmers and producer organizations engaged in contract
farming and outgrower deals, as found in BAGCI and SAGCOT; facilitating
information; and offering incentives, among other mechanisms.
Investment promotion. Agricultural corridors are means to reduce critical
constraints that limit investments required to enhance the competitiveness
and inclusiveness of the agricultural and agro-industrial sectors, by providing,
inter alia, critical infrastructure (waterbound transport and railway and road
systems, including farm-to-market roads and provincial road networks to
108 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
3. Financial and risk management tools. These include catalytic finance and
finance to promote market access and the provision of embedded services,
such as agricultural extension. The African corridor programmes studied have
rolled out dedicated financial facilities to support greenfield investments by
companies with socially responsible business models, as well as innovative
models for delivering public goods and services to organized smallholder
farmers located in the corridor. These corridors have also devised risk man-
agement tools, such as loan guarantees and currency risk instruments to help
leverage capital from national banks into agribusiness firms operating in the
corridor. Another option they have explored is to pilot index-based weather
microinsurance for selected corridor crops, as done by BAGCI (Box 15).
Another example pertains to the collaboration in SAGCOT and the Sulawesi
Corridor in Indonesia between corridor managers and local banks to develop
warehouse receipts systems for key corridor crops.
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 109
TABLE 32
Various types of plans for economic corridor development
BAGCI CAREC GMS MP3EI PRA SAGCOT
Mainstreaming in national
¾ ¾ ¾
programmes and institutions
Value chains ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Financial facilities ¾ ¾
92
US$22.5 million in a 40-year concession.
112 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 17
Engaging the private sector in regional corridor programmes:
the case of GMS
To ensure that private sector perspectives were well reflected in the deliberations of all the
GMS sector fora and working groups, the GMS programme launched the GMS Business
Forum in 2000, with support from ADB and the United Nations Economic and Social Com-
mission for Asia and the Pacific (UN ESCAP). This forum brings together the business com-
munity throughout the subregion via the national Chambers of Commerce and Industry.93
It provides a channel for public-private dialogue on policy issues; promotes networking
among enterprises, business chambers and IPAs in the context of GMS-related activities;
fosters the expansion of PPPs for infrastructure development and encourages the develop-
ment of SMEs; and plays a vital role in the capacity building of the private sector and its
associations in the GMS.94 In particular, the forum supports the implementation of CASP
and CBTA, especially the development of business networking along the corridors and the
development of quality standards for services. For example, in 2010, the forum established
a private sector-led Trade and Transport Facilitation Task Force (TTF-TAF) to review the busi-
ness environment and facilitate the implementation of customs and transit systems in all
the corridors. In 2011, the forum set up a unified platform for trade, transport, and logistics
companies, called the GMS Freight Transport Association (FRETA) to support TTF-TAF and
work together with GMS governments.
A fairly recent development in the GMS programme governance is the establishment of an
umbrella structure at the corridors, known as the Economic Corridors Forum (ECF). This forum
is the main advocate and promoter of multisector coordination in the GMS corridors by rais-
ing awareness of needs and priorities, and increasing the involvement of local authorities and
private actors in corridor affairs (ADB, 2011a). The first ECF took place in Kunming, China,
in June 2008, followed by the ECF-2 in 2009, the ECF-3 in 2011 and the ECF-4 in 2012.95
93
www.gmsbizforum.com [last accessed July 2013].
94
Ibid.
95
ECF-2, held in Phnom Penh, Cambodia in September 2009, “GMS Economic Corridors: Pathways
to an Integrated, Harmonious and Prosperous Subregion”, discussed and generally agreed with the
directions set forth in the corridor strategy and action plans. ECF-3, “Strengthening Pathways for
Sustained Progress in the GMS”, took place in Vientiane, Lao People’s Democratic Republic, in June
2011. ECF-4, “Towards Implementing the New GMS Strategic Framework (2012–2022): Expanding,
Widening, and Deepening Economic Corridors in the GMS”, which took place in Mandalay,
Myanmar in June 2012, sought to promote strong country and sector ownership further, as a critical
requirement for effective delivery of an investment framework aligned with the development of
inclusive economic corridors in the GMS.
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 113
to apply agricultural trade facilitation initiatives (e.g. to pilot the proposed inte-
grated package for automating the licence and permit system) and to expand growth
through the creation and expansion of industrial estates, one-stop services centres,
border SEZs, and other infrastructure and facilities (ibid.).
Some examples of cross-border SEZs include those established along the new
corridor roads linking Viet Nam with Cambodia and the Lao People’s Democratic
Republic (Table 33). One example on the Lao PDR-Viet Nam border is the Lao Bao
Special Economic and Commercial Area, which includes coffee and fruit processing
(canned and bottled juice beverages) (ADB, 2010c). Along the East-West Economic
Corridor (EWEC), agro-industry is growing fast in several segments. These include
the Nghe An Economic Zone, Viet Nam, with major new private and foreign invest-
ments in beer, sugar and milk factories over the last few years;96 the Hoi An and Chu
Lai Open Economic Zone in Tam Ky, Viet Nam, with the presence of some agrifood
processing firms such as PepsiCo (beverages) and Uni-President China food produc-
tion company (Ishida, 2012). Nonetheless, given the rapid development in Southeast
Asia, SEZ and cluster initiatives could be applied more widely (Menon, 2009).
Nonetheless, Bafoil et al. (n.d.) maintain that GMS SEZs (based on the analysis
of three SEZs in Cambodia and the Lao People’s Democratic Republic) have failed
to harmonize incentives, cross-border rules, cross-border cooperation objectives,
regional governance and multilevel structures of governance. They do not present
social, economic, political or cultural structures across the region nor is the subsys-
tem conducive to regional integration from infrastructure-driven regional integra-
TABLE 33
SEZs proposed at border areas in the framework of the GMS corridor programme
SEZs located on the borders of the Name of SEZ
countries below
96
These include a sugar processing joint venture with the United Kingdom-based multinational Tate
& Lyle, the Sai Gon beer factory in Nam Dan, the Hanoi beer factory in Nghi Loc and the TH True
Milk fresh milk processing plant in Nghia Dan.
114 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
tion. There is also a gap between regional market integration; the SEZ cases do not
reflect any horizontal relations between them, not even at a national level. To sum
up, there are systemic problems in the approach to hard and soft aspects of trade
facilitation towards regional integration.
Another key intervention in Zone IV is the promotion of cross-border contract
farming, for instance, through the operation of cross-border agriculture resource
centres and the passing of enabling legislation. Consequently, Chinese and Thai
firms are increasingly engaging in cross-border contract farming with farmers from
Cambodia, the Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Myanmar and Viet Nam. Thai-
land has been actively pursuing contract farming as a tool for regional economic
integration, building upon the Declaration of the 2005 ACMECS Summit. In the
declaration, Thailand pledged tariff-free imports of all approved agricultural prod-
ucts produced under contract farming in ACMECS (GMS5) countries.
The declaration included an agreement to accelerate cooperation on contract
farming, including the conclusion of MOUs on the topic and the establishment of
joint bilateral working committees. For instance, in keeping with this agreement, the
Governments of Thailand and Myanmar signed an MOU to facilitate Thai invest-
ments in crops for which local demand is not met in Thailand. Myanmar provides
Thai agribusiness firms with access to 7 million ha of arable land. In return, the Thai
firms provide seeds, technology and equipment for the farmers and purchase all the
products from contract farms (ADBI, 2008a).
Thailand also has bilateral projects with the Lao People’s Democratic Republic,
especially through the Sister Cities project under ACMECS. The Laotian Govern-
ment has taken a proactive stance as well, with regard to cross-border contract
farming, by promoting the so-called “2+3” policy to ensure that all the parties
involved obtain benefits. This policy implies that under a contract farming arrange-
ment, producers contribute land and labour (two elements), while investors provide
inputs, technical advice and access to markets (three elements) (Fullbrook, 2007).
This arrangement takes advantage of lower labour costs and land availability on one
side of the border, and more advanced entrepreneurship and technology, and greater
availability of capital and management skills, on the other. Buyers sometimes offer
more than the three factors mentioned; for instance, Chinese agricultural scientists
have been able to develop a special variety of rubber tree suited to conditions in
northern Lao PDR. Several examples can be found of the 2+3 business model in the
Laotian section of GMS corridors.
Table 34 lists subsectors and value chains in GMS corridors where cross-border
contract farming agreements abound.
Another important area of regional corridor cooperation is the improvement of
regional regulatory systems for agricultural and food products, and the harmoniza-
tion of the different national systems, notably the following.
Modernize sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) measures to facilitate trade in
agricultural and food products in the CAREC corridors (ADB, 2012e); and
improve SPS handling in GMS for Cambodia, the Lao People’s Democratic
Republic and Viet Nam.97
97
www.adb.org
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 115
TABLE 34
Contract farming experiences in GMS agrifood chains
Corridor Participating countries Subsectors and value chains
NSEC Lao PDR, Myanmar, Rubber, tea and maize (northern Lao PDR/China)
China and Thailand
Cassava and sugar (Guangxi/Viet Nam)
Sugar cane, maize, watermelons, bananas, cabbages, tamarind
and other horticultural products (northern Lao PDR/Thailand)
Forest products
Agricultural machinery and equipment
Biofuel production
-- Biofuel from cassava, jatropha and sugar cane (China)
-- Biodiesel from jatropha and oil palm (Thailand)
-- Bioethanol from maize, cassava and sweet sorghum
(Myanmar)
EWEC Lao PDR, Myanmar, Beer, sugar, beverages and milk production (Viet Nam)
Thailand and Viet Nam
Pinewood oil, beer and sugar (Lao PDR)
Rice (Thailand and Viet Nam)
Organic food
Sources: ADB (2007a; 2009; 2010b; 2010c); ADBI (2008a; 2008b); Nguyen and Ha-Duong, 2009; Malik et al., 2009;
Shepley et al., 2009; USAID, 2009; Manorom et al., 2010.
figure 26
Examples of corridor soft-side interventions aiming to promote regional integration
Environmental management
• Regional cooperation in research and development
on climate friendly agriculture
• Climate change mitigation and adaptation in agriculture
• Flood and drought management
Coordination mechanisms
• Development of corridor coordination institution and mechanisms
involving public and private stakeholders and other corridor supporters
• Creation of corridor institutes to create and share knowledge on key issues
Logistics
• Promotion and deregulation of cross-border logistics investments
• Corridor-based associations of logistics firms
BOX 18
Corridor specialization in agricultural value chains
Each economic corridor has different factor endowments, strengths, constraints and com-
plementarities. Therefore, each corridor tries to develop economic activities for which they
enjoy competitive advantages. This also applies to agriculture and its different subsectors
and value chains.
The GMS corridors, for example, are all different. NSEC provides good opportunities for
investing in agriculture and agro-industry, including food processing, non-food agrobased
industries (e.g. forest products and bioenergy industries), agricultural machinery and equip-
ment, and cottage industries linked to community tourism (ADB, 2010b). SEC offers good
potential for investing in the production and processing of commercial and industrial food
crops, as well as ethanol production from cassava and sugar cane (ADB, 2010c). Similarly,
EWEC prioritizes support to agriculture-based processing activities through cross-border con-
tract farming in Savannakhet (Lao PDR), and rice processing in Viet Nam and Thailand. More
important, EWEC tries to position itself as the organic belt of the GMS.
Even within a corridor, each route tends to specialize in certain sectors in order to make
the most of underlying comparative advantages and complementarities. For instance, in
NSEC, the central subcorridor focuses on agro-industry and other labour-intensive industries;
while the eastern subcorridor capitalizes on primary agriculture, agro-industry, trade and
logistics (ADB, 2010c). Similarly, each GMS corridor naturally favours the development of dif-
ferent agricultural value chains. For instance, the central subcorridor of SEC is well endowed
for developing industrial crop value chains such as rubber and sugar cane, and some com-
mercial crops (particularly cassava, rice and pulses). SEC’s southern coastal subcorridor, on
the other hand, has advantages for the development of rice, fisheries, renewable energy
production (e.g. biodiesel from palm oil and ethanol from sugar cane), durian, pepper and
other fruit and vegetables (ibid.).
Two factors in particular influence the specialization of GMS corridors in one agricultural
value chain/subsector or another. The first factor is the expansion of biofuel production across
the GMS area, notably in China, Thailand and Viet Nam and, more recently, in Myanmar.
The second refers to the promotion of contract farming for commercial and industrial crops
across the subregion, and particularly by Sino-Thai investors in border areas of Cambodia,
Lao PDR and Viet Nam.
Supply-side factors (available farm land and workforce, favourable soil and
weather conditions) are also conducive to the surge of biofuel production in the
GMS corridors. The production of both ethanol and biodiesel98 could help farmers
located in the corridors diversify their activities and earn additional income while
concomitantly offsetting projected demand using energy produced locally and with
fewer environmental impacts (Malik et al., 2009).
98
See Glossary.
118 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
TABLE 35
Corridor specialization in biofuel crops
Ethanol Ethanol Ethanol Biodiesel Palm oil/ Soybeans/ Sugar/
from from from from biodiesel biodiesel ethanol
cassava maize sorghum jatropha
BAGCI ¾
GMS ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
MP3EI ¾
PRA ¾
SAGCOT ¾ ¾
Source: author’s elaboration, based on www.adb.org; www.proyectopra.com; AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010;
SAGCOT, 2011; CMEA, 2011.
Note: ¾ core; ¾ secondary.
Biofuel production is uneven across the GMS corridors, in terms of the crops
used, production levels and scale of operations. The two Chinese provinces
belonging to the eastern branch of NSEC, Yunnan and Guangxi, are important
producers of bioethanol. In Guangxi, the state-run COFCO – China’s largest
grain trader and processor – operates a cassava-based ethanol plant (one of
China’s five largest bioethanol plants) that produces 200 000 tonnes per year,
plus 30 000 tonnes per year of second-generation biofuel99 from cassava residues
and stalks (ADB, 2009; Malik et al., 2009). Furthermore, a subsidiary of the state
energy company, the China National Offshore Oil Corporation (CNOOC),
is planning to set up first- and second-generation facilities in the province of
Guangxi to process 180 000 tonnes of ethanol per year from cassava. Yunnan has
specialized in jatropha biodiesel production; in fact, it has been designated as the
demonstration province to roll out the national jatropha programme (Malik et
al., 2009). The provincial government has proposed 14 biodiesel refining plants
with an aggregated annual production capacity of 3.2 million tonnes of biodiesel.
Additionally, Yunnan and Guangxi have great potential for producing bioethanol
from sugar cane.
Viet Nam produces bioethanol from sugar cane, sweet sorghum and cassava, and
biodiesel from jatropha and catfish oil. Its estimated annual capacity is approxi-
mately 320 million litres of bioethanol from cassava and 53 million litres from sugar
cane (Nguyen and Ha-Duong, 2009). The Thai segment of the NSEC corridor
produces biodiesel from oil palm and jatropha in large- and small-scale operations,
respectively. In Myanmar, sugar cane is the main source of bioethanol followed by
maize, cassava and sweet sorghum; in contrast, biodiesel production (mainly from
jatropha) is still at the demonstration phase, in spite of the ambitious three-year
government plan (2006–2008) that attracted much interest initially but created some
land conflicts (ADB, 2007a).
99
See Glossary, under biofuel.
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 119
TABLE 36
Corridor specialization in grains and other crops key to ensuring food security
Cassava Maize Rice Sorghum Wheat
BAGCI ¾ ¾
GMS ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
MP3EI ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
PRA ¾
SAGCOT ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
100
http://beiracorridor.com/ [last accessed July 2013].
120 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
TABLE 37
Corridor specialization in animal and fish protein production
Dairy products Fisheries/ Livestock Poultry
aquaculture
BAGCI ¾
GMS ¾
MP3EI ¾ ¾ ¾
PRA ¾ (trout) ¾ ¾
SAGCOT ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
TABLE 38
Corridor specialization in fruit and vegetables
Artichokes Bananas Citrus Litchis Mangoes Misc. fruit Misc.
vegetables
BAGCI ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
GMS ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
(tamarind)
MP3EI ¾ ¾
PRA ¾ ¾ ¾
(proc. fruit) (proc. potatoes)
SAGCOT ¾ ¾
on the other hand, are cultivated for the export market, for example, artichokes and
other non-traditional export crops in the Peruvian corridors.
The penchant of the corridors reviewed for high-value agricultural products
goes beyond the production of biofuel, horticultural, animal and fisheries products.
Other high-value crops produced are detailed in Table 39.
A large fraction of these products are cultivated with the export market in mind.
In the case of GMS, there is particular emphasis on producing for the subregion, as
shown in the rising intraregional trade statistics.
The exception is CAREC. Given that agriculture is a second-tier area in the
CAREC corridor programme, efforts are ad hoc and highly focused, not sectoral
or even value-chain-wide. Therefore, there is no use talking about specialization in
these corridors. With regard to market orientation, the main destination markets for
agricultural production have traditionally been Europe for Central Asian countries
and eastern China (Xinjiang province) (ADB, 2012e). Partially because of this, there
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 121
TABLE 39
Corridor specialization in other high-value agricultural products
Proc. Cocoa Coffee Cut Forest Miscellaneous Rubber Tea
beans flowers products
BAGCI
GMS ¾ ¾
MP3EI ¾ ¾ ¾
PRA ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
(certified) (bixin, tara)
SAGCOT ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾ ¾
Source: author’s elaboration, based on www.adb.org; www.proyectopra.com; AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010;
SAGCOT, 2011; CMEA, 2011.
Note: ¾ core; ¾ secondary.
is ample room for improving intra-CAREC agriculture trade, whose volume is far
less than that of interregional trade, possibly in a proportion of 1 to 15 (ibid.).
The PRA Project experience is also unique when it comes to value-chain target-
ing. In focusing on increasing sales by firms working in the corridors, the project
has in fact addressed value-chain issues through a great deal of firm-based work
(USAID, 2008a). It has encouraged businesses for over 400 products, with a large
preponderance of agricultural and food products. Rice, trout, palm oil, fruit, beans
and legumes, coffee, flowers and plants, certified wood and wooden flooring,
artichokes, tara (a small leguminous shrub whose subproducts are used in leather
manufacturing and in a number of food applications), cocoa, poultry, dairy products,
cotton and processed potatoes are among the most successful products supported,
listed in descending order in terms of contribution to new sales.101 This makes the
PRA Project primarily an agro-industrial programme, with the raw material coming
from the countryside and the processing taking place in intermediate cities belong-
ing to the same corridor as suppliers, but also in Lima and other large cities.
The PRA Project choice of working with clients, instead of preselected products,
sectors or industries, has operated as a natural selection process that has brought
to light products and market opportunities that otherwise would have been over-
looked. Examples of products that might likely have slipped under the radar in a
preselection exercise abound in the list of the Project’s top businesses: flowers, bixin
(a natural colourant for food and nutraceutical uses), tara, processed fruit, palm oil
and certified wood.
Thanks to fluid information channels, market expertise on a specific product
or value chain and the trust established with client connector firms attained by
a specific corridor and the Project’s central office could be easily transferred to
other corridors. For example, the experience of Huaylas in the cut flower export
business catalysed the development of similar business deals in the Huancayo and
101
http://www.proyectopramonitoreo.com [last accessed July 2013].
122 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
102
http://www.siicex.gob.pe [last accessed May 2013].
Chapter 6 – Delivery at scale: budget and modalities of interventions 123
ers, the Project helped achieve new deals for 680 tonnes of trout products worth
US$5.8 million by identifying small-scale trout farmers in Huancayo, Huancavelica
and Puno interested in and able to supply the processing firm. It also facilitated
consultancies and TA to help the company transfer trout farming technology to its
suppliers to comply with technical standards for exports to the EU, United States
of America and other markets (ibid.).
In May 2006, USAID added forestry certification to the PRA Project’s BDS com-
ponent. The target was to achieve Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) certification of
400 000 ha of forestland in the Cusco, Pucallpa and San Martín corridors through
the application of a PRA business approach. Such certification does not necessarily
translate into higher prices, but is instrumental for accessing international markets.
The Project helped to forge alliances between private enterprises and native com-
munities, and provided training and TA to help them achieve the FSC certification,
improve their forest management standards and market their forestry products bet-
ter. In addition, it worked closely with the forest certification office of the national
Natural Resources Institute to expedite administrative procedures – the time to pro-
cess certifications was cut by as much as 60 percent. The Project contributed to the
certification of 394 115 ha of forest, with 70 percent of this certification occurring
in collaboration with native communities and 30 percent on forestry concessions
(USAID, 2006; 2008a; 2008b).
125
Chapter 7
Delivery at scale:
corridor governance
126
Main stakeholders involved in the corridor programmes analysed
BAGCI CAREC GMS MP3EI PRA SAGCOT
Spain China
Switzerland Republic of
Korea
UK
Spain
USA
Sweden
Others
Switzerland
UK
USA
TABLE 40 (Continued)
127
128 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
partners, given its middle-income country status.103 Other countries lend assistance
to the corridor programmes analysed in accordance with their “good neighbour”
policy. For example, South Africa supports BAGCI, whereas Australia, China and
Japan support the GMS corridor programme. Australia has invested around US$150
million in transport and energy projects in the GMS corridor programme under
co-financing arrangements with ADB and the World Bank (AusAID, 2009). China
and Japan are essential donors and supporters of the GMS corridor programme,
both within and outside the framework of the programme.104 For both Japan and
China, maintaining strong ties with GMS countries is strategically important, given
the trade and FDI flows established between them and the GMS5 economies.
Moreover, for China, cooperation with Southeast Asian nations is a crucial test of
its “good neighbour” policy, particularly for Yunnan province. There seems to be a
geographic division of tasks between the two countries. Japan is keen on supporting
the development of the EWEC corridor, given the strategic importance of Viet Nam
and Thailand for Japanese interests (Cochrane, 2012; Reilly, 2013). For China, on
the other hand, NSEC is vital to link land-locked areas of southern China to areas
where deep seaports can be constructed in Southeast Asia. In particular, China per-
ceives NSEC’s potential as a “landbridge” between Shanghai and Singapore (ibid.).
Some bilateral agencies support corridors where multinational corporations
originating in their countries have strategic interests, such as in the African cor-
ridors. These circumstances may create some unease within civil society.
An essential actor in this picture is the government of the host countries, either
as promoter or supporter of the corridor initiative or, in some cases, as aid recipi-
ents. The involvement of the public sector is heterogeneous, but can encompass
line ministries (e.g. agriculture, transport, energy and trade), regional and provin-
cial governments, and state-owned enterprises or parastatals, depending on the
case. Regional and provincial governments and agencies are indispensable for the
successful realization of corridor plans. Examples are the contributions of the Vale
do Zambeze agency to BAGCI, the Chinese provinces of Guangxi, Xinjiang and
Yunan to the CAREC and GMS programmes, the regional government of Lima to
the PRA corridor project and the Indonesian states to MP3EI. The relationships
between central and decentralized governments and among central agencies are
not always without problems. Some coordination issues were found, for example,
between federal and regional authorities in Indonesia and Ethiopia, creating prob-
lems to deploy or implement the economic corridor programmes.
The level of ownership of the programme by the national/local govern-
ments varies from one country to another. The strongest involvement is
obviously that of the Government of Indonesia, in its role as main promoter.
SAGCOT also has high-level buy-in from the government, with the Tanzanian
President showing a strong personal commitment to the initiative (GMF, 2013).
103
http://data.worldbank.org/income-level/MIC [last accessed July 2013].
104
Japan and China are two of the largest subscribers to ADB, holding 15.65 and 6.46 percent
shares in the Bank’s capital, respectively; their respective voting rights are 12.82 and 5.47 percent
(Brahmawong and Sukhraromana, 2013). These countries have also made significant investments in the
GMS corridors through their official development assistance and through private corporations.
Chapter 7 – Delivery at scale: corridor governance 129
BOX 19
Coordination problems between central and decentralized public authorities
The Government of Indonesia acts as a regulator, facilitator and catalyst to support national
growth through the development of economic corridors. In its role of regulator, the govern-
ment plans to amend or remove (debottlenecking) regulations that inhibit investments. As a
facilitator and catalyst, it provides fiscal and non-fiscal incentives, and promotes the partici-
pation of the private sector and other key stakeholders in the implementation of the mas-
terplan. The central government is responsible for deregulating certain regulations that hold
back investments and for allocating a central budget for implementing major infrastructure
works. Provincial and regional governments, on the other hand, are responsible for the
development of key sectors and the intra-island or intracorridor infrastructure established
in their territory. Both central and regional/provincial authorities ought to make the cor-
responding provisions in their regular budgets to implement the masterplan. However, the
dialogue between central and local counterparts is not always as it should be, and resource
allocation is also not always well aligned.
In order to overcome this, a task team has been set up at corridor level, formed by rel-
evant stakeholders from the central and local government and businesses. At the regional
level, the governor plays a key role in the implementation of regional development pro-
grammes in each economic corridor. Governors are expected to establish and enhance their
fora to create unity and harmony in inter- or intra-economic corridors.105
Ethiopia is another country that has encountered difficulties in implementing corridor
initiatives because of central-local imbalances. In the mid-2000s, the Government of Ethio-
pia formulated an economic corridor strategy to accelerate economic growth and optimize
investment. However, problems soon surfaced. The central and regional governments106
failed to develop a shared vision of corridor development, giving rise to significant confusion
about the concept itself and implementation modalities, including potential implications for
regional investment plans and cross-border coordination (UNDP, 2011). In 2007, in light of
the above, the Ethiopian Government asked three United Nations agencies107 for support
to develop a national corridor strategy, called the “National Framework and Strategy for
Identification, Establishment and Operation of Economic Growth Corridors” (ibid.). As part
of this support, several policy fora were organized to clarify policy direction. Learning mis-
sions were set up in Southeast Asia to gain from more advanced experiences in economic
growth corridors, and a study was commissioned to establish a standardized definition of
economic corridors suitable for the Ethiopian reality, set up criteria for selecting corridors,
propose organizational and coordination arrangements for establishing and operating cor-
ridors at the federal and regional levels, and identify financing and investment alternatives
and mechanisms (ibid.).
105
www.kp3ei.go.id [last accessed July 2013].
106
Ethiopia is a federal country where each regional state has a high degree of autonomy.
107
FAO, UNDP and the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO).
130 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
In the case of Peru, the Peruvian Government has gradually increased its commit-
ment to the PRA Corridor Project. Initially, its involvement was limited to ProIn-
versión, the SIEX programme and Project Peru,108 but eventually the GoP became
the recipient of the PRA model, officially transferred in 2012. Something similar has
occurred in the CAREC and GMS programmes where ADB insisted in transferring
increased responsibilities to national counterparts and focal points, including the
function of resource mobilization.
Multinational and domestic corporations also support corridor programmes,
either through multistakeholder partnerships such as those in Africa or through
private-donor collaborations (as in Peru). For example, multinational agribusiness
firms and some local firms have been pivotal in the realization of the corridor
partnerships in Mozambique and the United Republic of Tanzania. A sign of their
importance is that Unilever (United Kingdom/Netherlands) and the Norwegian-
based Yara International are on the Executive Committee of SAGCOT. Moreover,
the Chief Executive Officer of Yara was the one who put forward the idea of
piloting an agrocorridor experience in Africa, which eventually gave way to the
SAGCOT and BAGC partnerships.
Another alternative is the involvement of private actors in corridor programmes
as part of their corporate social responsibility strategy. In Peru, eight private firms
signed a partnership agreement with the donor (USAID) to co-finance the establish-
ment of corridor centres in their regions. These firms, mostly mining companies,
were not involved in agribusiness operations, but saw an opportunity in the corridor
programme to contribute to the development of their territories and communities.
International consulting firms play a pivotal role in corridors, particularly in the
prefeasibility and design phases, but also as managers or technical leaders of the
corridor implementing bodies. Cases in point are Chemonics International in the
Peruvian corridors, and AgDevCo, InfraCo and Prorustica in the African corridors.
Two important categories of private sector actors involved in corridor operations
are companies specialized in infrastructure development that enter into partnership
with the public sector to build, co-finance and operate infrastructure works. These
companies may develop and/or manage either large connective infrastructure (e.g.
ports and roads) or last-mile infrastructure, as in the ISCs mentioned in the BAGCI
case. The second category is logistics and trade companies that are key partners in
the design and deployment of transport and trade facilitation activities, which are a
core area of work in regional corridor programmes.
From the discussions so far, it might seem that private actors play only a second-
ary role in corridor programmes, accompanying initiatives championed by national
governments alone or supported by the international community. However, in
many parts of the world, private actors are leading corridor efforts, as in the
Mercosur soybean corridors or the Maputo-Gauteng Corridor in southern Africa.
The rule of thumb is that in countries and regions where the private sector is quite
developed, the evolution from transport to economic corridor is mostly left to the
108
ProInversión is the Peruvian IPA. The SIEX programme promotes exports from the Peruvian
highlands and Project Peru seeks to enhance intra- and intercorridor connectivity.
Chapter 7 – Delivery at scale: corridor governance 131
initiative of private actors. But even in the cases analysed where the private sector is
not particularly thriving, private investments constitute a large proportion, ranging
from a third to half of the overall estimated investments induced by the corridor
programmes (see discussion in section 6.1.) In fact, the corridor initiatives studied
have been primarily conceived as catalysers of private investment and entrepre-
neurial glue. This is an expression of the most common pro-corridor argument,
which postulates that the attraction of private sector investments in growth nodes
along corridors may alleviate coordination failures and the scarcity of capital in
developing countries (World Bank, 2010).
Obviously, the extent to which a corridor development initiative is championed
by the private or public sectors influences the type of policies promoted and the
impacts generated. The Maputo-Gauteng experience in southern Africa shows that,
when corridor development is led by the private sector, it may be more difficult for
governments to impose people-centred policies. In contrast, expectations in BAGCI
– which is largely in the hands of public authorities – are that the corridor benefits
be more equitably distributed.
In any case, multilevel governance systems are in place in the majority of inter-
ventions, including public and private sector actors, IFIs, donors and civil service
actors, among others. Such systems should in theory balance the interest of the
various stakeholders and contribute to a more equitable distribution of the value
added through corridor interventions.
TABLE 41
Use of land in BAGC and SAGCOT
BAGC SAGCOT
… rainfed 80 000 –
109
See Glossary.
Chapter 7 – Delivery at scale: corridor governance 133
figure 27
Nucleus farm hub, outgrower model and smallholder block farming
Serviced
outgrower
plots
Outgrower irrigated farm blocks
connected to water and power supply
Commercial
farm hub with
packing house
Small dam/ and storage
storage reservoir facilities
Feeder road
Electricity Local village
Water supply
110
http://www.yara.com/sustainability/how_we_engage/africa_engagement/growth_corridors/index.
aspx [last accessed July 2013].
134 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
TABLE 42
Corridor institutional settings
Type of model Main organizational traits
BOX 20
Institutional arrangements and delivery mechanisms of the GMS corridor
programme
The GMS programme has opted for a model of functional corridor-led institutions for tech-
nical cooperation. It is managed by a multilevel institutional mechanism dating from 1995
that involves both political and operational authorities of the GMS participating countries,
as evidenced in Figure 28.
The GMS Summit is the maximum decision body of the GMS programme, where the
Prime Ministers of the six countries gather together with ministers and country delegations,
representatives of the private sector, ADB and other development partners. The Summit is
held every three years and is hosted by GMS countries on a rotational basis.111 They serve as
an important venue for GMS leaders to provide high-level political commitment, discuss and
agree on priority actions in the GMS programme, and endorse important documents, such
as the ten-year GMS Strategic Frameworks, specific corridor strategies and sectoral action
plans, including those in agriculture (ADB, 2012a).
FIGURE 28
GMS programme institutional structure
GMS Summit
(triennal)
National
ADB GMS Ministerial-level Conference Coordinating
Secretariat (annual) Committee
in each
country
WG on Agriculture WG on tourism
111
The first Summit was held in Phnom Penh (Cambodia) in 2002; the second in Kunming (Yunnan
Province, China) in 2005; the third in Vientiane (Lao PDR) in 2008; and the fourth and last in
Naypyidaw (Myanmar) in 2011 (ADB, 2012a).
136 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 20 (Continued)
The GMS Ministerial Conferences are yearly meetings involving GMS Ministers, accompa-
nied by GMS senior officials, headed by the GMS National Coordinators, together with ADB,
other development partners and representatives from the private sector. The Conference
reviews the overall progress of key deliverables for the GMS programme; gives broad direc-
tions to the programme and prepares action plans; dialogues with development partners
and the private sector to determine ways of increasing their participation; and undertakes
preparatory work for the GMS Leaders’ Summits. Senior Officials’ meetings, for example of
senior agricultural civil servants, are held periodically to discuss and agree on the programme
and activities, and conduct other preparatory work for the Ministerial Conferences (ibid.).
Each country has set up a national GMS Secretariat that acts as the government focal
point to assist in the implementation and coordination of the GMS programme. The Secre-
tariat implements, evaluates and follows up the working plan on GMS economic coopera-
tion, and reports to the respective line ministries and working sectors. It also coordinates
with other stakeholders such as NGOs, local and provincial governments, and the private
sector at the regional (GMS Business Forum), national and provincial levels. As shown in
Figure 28, the ADB GMS Secretariat provides central technical, administrative, facilitation
and financing support to GMS meetings and subprojects (ibid.).
The implementation of the GMS programme has been supported by sector fora and
working groups in the nine sectors of cooperation, as shown. There is a specific Working
Group on Agriculture (WGA), whose core mandate is to support the design and implemen-
tation of priority projects under CASP “to promote agriculture trade, food security, and
sustainable livelihoods”.112 WGA was proposed as a mechanism for agricultural cooperation
in the GMS at the Tenth GMS Ministerial Conference in November 2001, and was eventu-
ally established in 2002. It has a national Secretariat in each country composed of a WGA
national coordinator and support staff.
Under the current strategic framework, the GMS WGA continues to monitor the overall
implementation of CASP II and ensures that it is well coordinated with other sector programmes.
However, new elements have been introduced to improve WGA’s performance, as follows:
WGA is expected to seek a broader range of financing sources, including multilateral and
bilateral development partners, private enterprises and national government financing.
Actions are being taken to strengthen WGA’s linkages with FAO, IFAD, CIRAD, CGIAR,
SEARCA and others involved in agriculture in the subregion (ADB, 2007a).
Plans for further strengthening the WGA Secretariat with full-time technical and adminis-
trative in-country staff are under way. Furthermore, a more effective institutional mecha-
nism for WGA is being defined to improve its performance and engage GMS member
countries in a more systematic and sustained manner. Following the endorsement of
the new strategic framework, GMS countries undertook a fine-tuning of GMS fora and
working groups, including WGA, to sharpen their focus and make them more effective
(ADB, 2012a).
112
www.adb.org/countries/gms/sector-activities [last accessed July 2013].
Chapter 7 – Delivery at scale: corridor governance 137
BOX 20 (Continued)
To ensure that private sector perspectives are well reflected in the deliberations of all
the GMS sector fora and working groups, the GMS programme launched the GMS Busi-
ness Forum in 2000, with support from ADB and UN ESCAP. This forum brings together the
business community throughout the subregion via the national Chambers of Commerce and
Industry.113 It provides a channel for public-private dialogue on policy issues; promotes net-
working among enterprises, business chambers and investment promotion agencies in the
context of GMS-related activities; fosters the expansion of PPPs for infrastructure develop-
ment and encourages the development of SMEs; and plays a vital role in the capacity build-
ing of the private sector and its associations in GMS.114 In particular, the Business Forum
supports the implementation of CASP and CBTA, especially the development of business
networking along the corridors and the development of quality standards for services. For
example, the forum established in 2010 the private sector-led TTF-TAF to review the business
environment and facilitate the implementation of customs and transit system in all the cor-
ridors. In 2011, the forum set up a unified platform for trade, transport, and logistics com-
panies, known as FRETA, to support TTF-TAF and work together with GMS governments.
A fairly recent development in the GMS programme governance is the establishment of
an umbrella structure at the corridors, known as the ECF.115 This forum is the main advocate
and promoter of multisector coordination in the GMS corridors, raising awareness of needs
and priorities, and increasing the involvement of local authorities and private actors in cor-
ridor affairs (ADB, 2011a).116
The current Strategic Framework 2012–2022 has introduced three new elements related
to corridor and overall programme governance.
The creation of a knowledge platform to address second-generation issues where high-
quality analytical work, effective discussion and consensus building around its results will
be critical, such as the interlinkages between energy, agriculture, food security and the
environment (ADB, 2011a; 2012a).
113
www.gmsbizforum.com [last accessed July 2013].
114
Ibid.
115
www.gmsec.org [last accessed July 2013].
116
The first ECF took place in Kunming, China, in June 2008, followed by ECF-2 in 2009, ECF-3 in
2011 and ECF-4 in 2012.
138 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 20 (Continued)
A renewed commitment to develop stronger linkages with other regional initiatives and
organizations working in the GMS, such as CAREC and ASEAN, among others.117
The formation of a high-level board of advisors to review the programme periodically and
advise member countries on areas for improvement (ADB, 2011a; 2012a).
One of the main differences between the GMS and CAREC programmes so far
as this study is concerned is the treatment of agriculture as a core sector in the first
programme and as a second-tier sector in the latter. This implies that the GMS has a
regional coordination committee in place for the agricultural sector that interacts with
sectoral focal points nominated by each GMS country. On the other hand, CAREC
collaboration in agricultural issues is ad hoc, and therefore there is no specific commit-
tee for agriculture or other specific governance mechanism. It is the CAREC Secre-
tariat that coordinates activities in this field as part of its general coordinating functions.
At a country level, national coordination committees have been established to
liaise with the different ministries and local agencies concerned with the imple-
mentation of specific corridor activities at the national level. Bafoil and Ruiwen
(2010; p. 80) point out that GMS “economic corridors are a mix of formal (because
they are signed by heads of state) and informal mechanisms (they tend to involve
local actors) for regional cooperation” – and the same could be said of CAREC.
The important point is that implementation of the corridor interventions is not
undertaken through a parallel structure at the national level, but through already
established channels involving national and local public agencies.
The PRA corridors, on the contrary, have created corridor-specific structures
using an outsourcing model where private companies, NGOs or consortia of
various organizations are contracted out to run the corridor centres or ESCs. These
centres are the direct providers of BDS and promoters of investment along the cor-
ridor. The overall management and coordination of the corridor programme have
been entrusted to a company, together with M&E. Evidently, the corridor centres
liaise with national and local authorities and other actors that would like to pursue
some kind of collaboration with the programme. As a result of this opening to other
stakeholders, the PRA Project has succeeded in creating market-based business
models for PPPs, for the funding/operation of the corridor strategy and in creating
interest to mainstreaming the PRA model to the point that it has become a national
programme. See Box 21 for further information.
117
ASEAN and ASEAN+3 focused on the integration process and formation of an ASEAN economic
community; the Mekong River Commission (on water transport infrastructure development and
management, and other aspects of water resource management of the Mekong River; CAREC and
ACMECS (on the transport and trade agenda); the Bay of Bengal Initiative for Multi-Sectoral Technical
and Economic Cooperation; the Indonesia-Malaysia-Thailand Growth Triangle (on broader connectivity
issues); and the Southeast Asian Ministers of Education Organization (on human resources development).
Chapter 7 – Delivery at scale: corridor governance 139
BOX 21
Institutional arrangements and delivery mechanisms of the PRA Project
118
These partnerships took place under the umbrella of USAID’s GDA programme. As explained,
GDA develops partnerships across the globe with private sector organizations to leverage resources and
explore innovative approaches that amplify the impact of socio-economic development initiatives. Private
companies engage in this initiative as part of their corporate social responsibility (CSR) programmes.
140 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 21 (Continued)
119
Source: personal communication.
Chapter 7 – Delivery at scale: corridor governance 141
BOX 22
BAGCI’s institutional arrangements and delivery mechanisms
FIGURE 29
BAGCI institutional framework
Private sector
BAGCI
Government BAGC Partnership Partnership Board
Secretariat
Donors Secretariat supports
and promotes the CF
The Board serves as a coordinating platform that brings together stakeholders to discuss
specific issues and share information. It facilitates operational support for the partnership
and implements specific programmes funded by development partners in the framework of
BAGC. It advises the Catalytic Fund (CF) on the use of grants and concessional funding121
for smallholder farmer development programmes. Additionally, it lobbies government and
development partners to address key constraints to agricultural growth, and also monitors
and assesses the impacts of BAGCI.
120
www.beiracorridor.com [last accessed July 2013].
121
This is an alternative term for “soft loan” or financing below market rate of interest.
142 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
BOX 22 (Continued)
The BAGC CF, as mentioned earlier, invests in early-stage farming and agroprocessing
businesses that integrate smallholder and emergent farmers.122 It has a board of four direc-
tors: a representative from AgDevCo, the fund manager, and three directors appointed
by the BAGCP Board (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010). It also has an Investment Committee
responsible for making allocation decisions in accordance with the recommendations of the
fund manager. A Mozambican company (BAGC Investment Company) is being established
to inherit the work from AgDevCo. There are challenges ahead to operationalize the new
governance structures and ways of working between BACG and the local fund manager in
an effective and efficient manner (DFID, 2013).
122
See Glossary for a definition of emergent farmer.
123
TAP is an informal PPP platform that works towards improving the production and marketing of
agricultural crops (mainly maize and rice) using a value-chain approach in 25 districts of the United
Republic of Tanzania. TAP’s members include development partners, central and local government
agencies, agribusiness multinational companies, local private companies and international and domestic
NGOs. For further information, see: www.tap.or.tz [last accessed July 2013].
Chapter 7 – Delivery at scale: corridor governance 143
TABLE 43
Types of public-private collaboration present in (agro)corridor programmes
Type Actors Description
These partnerships have two main benefits. First, at the country level they
broaden stakeholder engagement to farmers’ associations, civil society organiza-
tions, local private sector firms, multiple ministries and local governments. Second,
the partnership becomes a vehicle for coordinating and reinforcing global support
for on-the-ground corridor activity. This support is not just financial, but also
includes expertise, and knowledge about efficient new approaches to agricultural
and local development (WEF, 2013).
Despite their importance, all the above partnerships are fairly new in terms of
their application not only to corridor programmes, but countrywide. This newness
implies a need to transform country-level institutional mindsets and mechanisms.
For instance, in order to work properly, these partnerships may require a transfor-
mation of the legal, regulatory and policy framework in which they are embedded.
Consequently, one of the roles of economic corridors is to test new concepts such
as those of PPPs and multistakeholder partnerships, which can then be upscaled to
the entire country or other fields of work.
145
Chapter 8
Gains and pitfalls
of agrocorridor initiatives
TABLE 44
Economic performance indicators
GDP gain (%) Incremental jobs Private investment (US$ million)
1)
BAGCI 12.9 350 000 1 356
CAREC – – –
GMS 1.1–8.3 – –
Sources: AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010; CAREC, 2010; 2012; ADBI, 2010; CMEA, 2011; USAID, 2008a; 2008b;
Milder et al., 2012.
Notes: 1) These data are estimates that include both direct and indirect jobs. 2) This figure reflects the
actual generation of direct jobs created; it does not account for the creation of indirect new jobs.
from 2006 (baseline year) to 2010, with a GDP per capita growth rate of 17 percent
(CAREC, 2010). Some countries such as Afghanistan, Azerbaijan, Turkmenistan
and Uzbekistan have experienced increases of 30–48 percent in GDP per capita
(ibid.). Nonetheless, in the absence of specific data, it is impossible to quantify the
exact contribution of the CAREC corridors to this growth.
PRA I had a sizeable effect on the GDP of some corridors: 1.65 percent in
Pucallpa, 1.90 in San Martín and 2.35 in Ayacucho (ibid.). However, its impact was
more visible on the corridor agricultural GDP, notably in Ayacucho, Cajamarca,
Pucallpa and San Martín, where PRA activities ranged from 4.5 to 8.7 percent of the
agricultural GDP.
For the remaining corridor programmes, Table 44 records the estimated GDP
gains. Indonesia estimates that by applying MP3EI, the annual national GDP
growth will be approximately 12.7 percent nationally, versus a 10.3 percent growth
in a business-as-usual (non-MP3EI) scenario. This signifies a 2.4 percent GDP gain
associated with the corridor programme. Internal growth within the corridor is
estimated at 12.9 percent, while growth in the areas outside the corridors would also
increase by 12.1 percent as a result of the spillover effects of corridor development
(CMEA, 2011).
Finally, BAGCI and SAGCOT plan to generate total incremental revenues per
annum worth US$1 875 and US$1 300 million, respectively. These increases repre-
sent GDP gains estimated at 12.9 percent in the case of Mozambique and 5.2 percent
in the Tanzanian corridor. More specifically, the BAGCI programme is projected
to generate US$1 billion of farming revenue annually, plus additional supply-chain
revenues in the order of US$0.5 billion (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010). The distribu-
tion of these direct benefits is consistent with the corridor business model that puts
smallholder farmers at centre stage. BAGCI is also expected to have major indirect
benefits for a broad section of the corridor population by inducing growth in other
sectors (e.g. construction, services and retail), which generate a multiplier effect.
Table 45 sets out order-of-magnitude estimates of the incremental direct and indirect
benefits, assuming that the Investment Blueprint is fully implemented by 2030.
Chapter 8 – Gains and pitfalls of agrocorridor initiatives 147
TABLE 45
Estimated benefits of BAGCI
Estimated benefits US$ million per annum
124
www.proyectopra.com [last accessed August 2013].
148 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
figure 30
Employment opportunities generated by SAGCOT
people
impacted
on-farm employment through
employment opportunities employment
opportunities in the wider opportunities
(including agricultural as direct or indirect
smallholder value chain beneficiaries
farmers)
140
thousands
+ 120
thousands
+ 160
thousands
+ 1.9
million
= 2.3
million
employment additional
opportunities beneficiaries
in agricultural from employment
processing in a household
corridors have increased significantly (Fujimura and Edmonds, 2008). For example,
FDI as a percentage of GDP grew from 2.5 percent in 2006 to 4.2 percent in 2010 in
the CAREC region, with Mongolia, the Kyrgyz Republic and Turkmenistan being
the most successful FDI destinations among CAREC countries.
The investments made in transport and trade facilitation and in the business
environment have resulted in a considerable reduction in business costs. The GMS
corridors have seen their transport efficiency improved, and their cross-border
delays reduced, together with informal payments at the border. These factors have
indirectly fostered the development of food and other manufacturing industries (e.g.
cement and mining) as well as tourism along the corridors. Several studies show that
average travel time on the corridors has been reduced by 40–50 percent, and so has
border-crossing time (ADB, 2008b; 2010a; 2010b; 2010c; 2010d). Average transport
and trade costs, understood as the aggregate cost of transport, transhipment, cus-
tom clearances and other border-crossing and transit fees, have notably declined,
although there is no overall estimate for all the GMS corridors. This cost reduction
benefits especially intra-GMS trade of agricultural products, and particularly of
vegetables, pulses, maize, rice, sugar, rubber and fresh fruit (ADB, 2008b).
TABLE 46
Estimated new employment generated by BAGCI
Total new employment Number of new jobs
TABLE 47
Actual and estimated new investments triggered by the corridors
Budget of the corridor Private investments Ratio of private investments per US$
initiative (US$ million) (US$ million) invested in the corridor programme
CAREC 25 136 – –
GMS 7 428 – –
PRA 62 28 1:0.45
Sources: AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010; CAREC, 2010; 2012a; ADBI, 2010; CMEA, 2011; USAID, 2008a;
2008b; Milder et al., 2012.
Note: data registered in the Table exclude investments brought in by the private sector via PPPs.
Similarly, in the CAREC corridors in 2011 almost one hour was shaved off
border-crossing time, and costs to clear the border decreased by an average 16 per-
cent (CAREC, 2012). Furthermore, the average time required to start a business and
the cost of business start-up procedures have been cut in half from 2006 (31 days
and 26.6 percent of gross national income per capita, respectively) through 2010
(15 days and 10.8 percent) (ibid.).
Although it is too soon to assess the broader economic impacts of the PRA
Project’s PPP infrastructure component, some of the PRA-supported highway con-
cessions completed offer significant savings in terms of transport time and costs. For
example, in the Tarapoto-Yurimaguas segment of the IIRSA North highway, trans-
port costs have decreased by 44 percent, and transport time by 70 percent (USAID,
2008a; 2008b). Moreover, the estimated benefits of the port of Callao concession
could easily surpass US$2 billion in the initial three years of operation (ibid.).
An underlying objective of BAGCI is to improve trade and transportation
linkages (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010). Although no specific trade targets have
been set out in the blueprint, BAGCI intends to build further on the combination
of multimodal transport infrastructure and recently improved trade logistics that
have been increasingly positioning Mozambique as one of the sub-Saharan coun-
tries with the lowest costs of trading across borders. More precisely, according to
Domínguez-Torres and Briceño-Garmendia (2011) the costs of export and import
in Mozambique are about 60 percent of the sub-Saharan average, and the time
required to export and import is around 70 percent of the regional average.
Moreover, the corridors described have had a significant impact on regional
and international trade and on domestic sales. For instance, cumulative sales of
goods and services generated by the PRA Project are worth US$397 million (PRA
I: US$307 million and PRA II: US$90 million). About 47.8 percent of the addi-
tional sales generated in the first phase – US$146.8 million – were exports, while the
remaining 52.2 percent was channelled to the domestic market.
The GMS and CAREC corridors are also becoming a platform for boosting
trade flows, because of the growth and strengthening of regional institutions, and
150 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
the development of shared experiences and sense of community that increases trust,
as well as their ability to deliver jointly regional public goods and services. Total
GMS exports and imports grew 17.4 and 16.6 percent, respectively, from 2000 to
2009. Intraregional trade among the GMS countries in value terms has been dou-
bling almost every three to four years since 2000, with China seizing the lion’s share,
followed at a distance by Thailand and Viet Nam (ADB, 2012c). Intra-GMS trade is
now estimated at 30–50 percent of the area’s total trade (Shrestha and Chongvilai-
van, 2013). The size of intra-GMS trade increased at an average annual growth rate
of 21.7 percent between 2000 and 2009, from US$13.9 to US$81.2 billion (ADB,
2012f). However, this estimate excludes informal trade, which appears to account
for a significant share of intra-GMS trade, perhaps in the order of 20–30 percent of
total trade (ADB, 2007b). The composition of GMS5 exports varied. Cambodia, the
Lao People’s Democratic Republic and Myanmar increased their share of exports of
primary products, while Thailand and Viet Nam exported manufacturing products
(ibid.). Extra-GMS trade (i.e. GMS trade with the rest of Asia and the world) has
also augmented at double-digit rates since 2000 (ibid.).
Agricultural trade is growing among the GMS countries, through the GMS coun-
tries (especially for the landlocked Lao PDR), and with the rest of the world (mainly
Japan, EU and the United States of America) (ADB, 2012f). The exact amount of
intra-GMS agricultural trade is difficult to estimate, in part because of the high level
of informality enabled by the porous borders and the relatively small volumes of
agricultural products traded (ibid.). Similarly, there are no studies that document the
exact percentage of trade growth attributable to corridor development.
Even in the absence of exact data, the significant reductions in transport and
border crossing time and costs resulting from the GMS programme’s infrastructural
improvements and trade facilitation measures have definitely improved trade perfor-
mance. In particular, the increase in cross-border and intra-GMS agricultural trade is
expected to lead to greater cross-border investment, complementing trading activities
and involving cross-border production, agroprocessing and marketing tie-ups that
relieve raw material supply constraints, upgrade technology and improve capacity
utilization. The expansion in extra-GMS trade can also enable agribusiness com-
panies in the GMS corridors to link up with regional supply chains and networks.
Investments in agriculture and other anchor industries, and labour mobility among
the Mekong countries are also experiencing a wave of dynamism (ADB, 2012c).
In Central Asia, the establishment and upgrading of a network of six multi-
modal transport corridors of more than 80 000 km are providing greater access
to major external markets for trade to and from the region. The corridors are
expected to have a regional multiplier effect that could triple trade flows by 2017,
compared with 2006 (CAREC, 2010). For example, the Southern Transport Cor-
ridor Road Rehabilitation Project in the Kyrgyz Republic (part of CAREC Cor-
ridors 2, 3, and 5) has spurred trade between the Xinjiang Autonomous Region of
China and the Kyrgyz Republic, which grew annually by 13 percent from 2003 to
2010 (CAREC, 2012).
Most corridors have significant economic impacts on smallholder farmers. An
evaluation carried out in 2008 documented improvements in the GMS corridors
with regard to farmers’ incomes and diversification of income-generating activi-
ties, access to markets and credit, land ownership patterns and other issues (ADB,
Chapter 8 – Gains and pitfalls of agrocorridor initiatives 151
2008b). For instance, surveys show that the income of farmers living along EWEC
rose by 20 percent because of the increase in selling volumes and prices received
after road completion (ADB, 2008a).
By assisting its clients, PRA I helped to improve the productivity and income
generation of more than 42 000 small producers and firms (beneficiaries) via the
long-term commercial linkages established. An estimated 43 percent of these ben-
eficiaries were very poor, i.e. earned less than US$1 per day (USAID, 2008a) and
37 percent were women (USAID, 2008b). Evidence of the PRA Project’s impact on
beneficiaries is available for some value chains and corridors. Artichoke producers
in the Mantaro Valley, for example, experienced an average net income increase of
30 percent; and in the Ayacucho corridor the PRA-assisted replacement of potatoes
by snow peas resulted in an additional US$351 in sales and 269 person-days of
employment per ha (USAID, 2008a; 2008b).
Finally, in the African corridors, growth of commercial agriculture on the
scale and in the manner inclusively and sustainably envisaged in the BAGCI and
SAGCOT blueprints would have a positive transformational impact on smallholder
farmers and rural communities. Consequently, BAGCI plans to generate US$1
billion of gross on-farm income (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010). Its main direct
benefits are higher and more predictable incomes for farmers and other chain actors
and increased employment opportunities for on-farm and off-farm labour, but also
capital income generated from investment and fiscal revenue accruing to the Mozam-
bican Government. Equally, the SAGCOT plan to mobilize US$3.4 billion of public
and private investment to “kick start” the region’s latent potential for commercial
agriculture is expected to contribute to the transformation of several thousand small-
holders into commercial farmers, with access to irrigation and weather insurance. As
a result, an annual value of additional farming revenues of US$1.2–1.3 billion will be
generated by 2030 (SAGCOT, 2011; Milder et al., 2012). Impacts on regional food
security are also anticipated thanks to some new 350 000 ha of land in profitable
production, serving regional and international markets. The resulting surge in cor-
ridor production is estimated at 630 000 tonnes of rice and 680 000 tonnes of other
grains, 4.4 million tonnes of sugar cane, 3 500 tonnes of red meat, and 32 000 tonnes
of fruit and vegetables (ibid.).
The corridor programmes have had other long-term impacts. For example, one
of the PRA Project’s most significant contributions – which goes even beyond
the actual and potential impacts highlighted above – lies in the development
of a second-generation PPP infrastructure model adapted to the Peruvian con-
text. This model includes state-of-the-art concession contracts, environmental
management tools and financial engineering. The importance of the model is its
applicability beyond PRA. For instance, after developing the concession scheme
for the port of Callao with PRA Project support, ProInversión decided to prepare
bidding documents to attract private companies to invest and operate in another
five Peruvian ports.125 The model is also being applied to numerous IIRSA infra-
structure initiatives.
125
www.proinversion.gob.pe [last accessed May 2013].
152 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
The PRA Project impacted not only on people but also on institutions. The
demonstration effect on the agribusiness sector and on governmental and develop-
ment initiatives was evident from the first phase. As of September 2008, 25 instances
of producer associations and firms had invested, following in the wake of PRA
pioneer clients, but without Project support. Similarly, at that time, 38 development
projects and NGOs, and 32 public instances had adapted the Project’s market-pull
methodology (USAID, 2008a; 2008b).
In the private sphere, the demonstration effect has been very important in vari-
ous agricultural value chains. For example, the Project introduced the production
of artichokes in the Junín corridor in 2002. The total artichoke production area in
the corridor went from none to almost 700 ha by the end of Phase I, of which only
half were PRA-supported. More growers, alerted by the attractive returns of fellow
farmers, decided to plant artichokes, without the assistance of the Project but taking
advantage of the presence of new buyers in the area. A similar pattern was observed
in the black-eye pea chain in the Piura corridor, where 400 ha were planted without
Project support out of 2 200 additional ha, and the number of processors increased
from one to seven, forming a regional bean cluster. Another example is the Ama-
ranth Road (amaranth or kiwicha is an Andean grain), linking Cusco, Abancay and
Andahuaylas. Only in Andahuaylas, 80 additional ha were planted without PRA
Project support, of a total of 340 ha in the zone (USAID, 2008a).
As discussed in previous sections, institutional instability and the changing
business and public environment introduced continuous modifications in the
PRA Project’s original format. However, the results achieved seem to indicate
that the programme has managed to weather the storms without slowing down
performance. The potential institutional risk involved in collaborating with mining
and other sector companies has not yet materialized. On the contrary, the private
partners have shared the PRA model and have proactively engaged in the promotion
of agribusiness development in their corridors. PRA II faces many challenges ahead
and particularly how to transfer the programme’s philosophy, methodologies and
tools to SIEX successfully. Being a privately managed initiative worked for the PRA
Project, but it is still to be seen whether the PRA model can be as highly performing
when managed by a public entity (ibid.).
The WEF model, although still at an early stage of development, also has poten-
tial to be adapted in other countries and applied to other sectors. In 2011, a number
of African leaders agreed to launch Grow Africa to support CAADP. Building on
SAGCOT, BAGCI and other models piloted by the New Vision for Agriculture,
Grow Africa can play a catalytic role in accelerating private sector investment and
expanding knowledge of best practices across Africa (Jenkins, 2012).
As important as economic sustainability is environmental sustainability. A
typical step in the design of corridors is an environmental assessment to gauge
environmental impacts and develop alternatives and mitigation options to guide
interventions and set priorities. For example, the GMS programme conducted a
transboundary, cross-sectoral strategic environmental assessment to support gov-
ernments in ensuring that economic corridors have the best possible impact on the
environment. Spatial modelling tools have been used to help locate and quantify the
environmental impacts geographically (both in terms of opportunities and risks) of
corridor development (Ramachandran and Linde, 2011).
Chapter 8 – Gains and pitfalls of agrocorridor initiatives 153
SAGCOT went one step forward with its agricultural green growth strategy.
From 2010 to 2030, the implementation of this strategy will result in a net reduc-
tion of GHG emissions totalling nearly 30 million tonnes of CO2-equivalent,
worth almost US$300 million.126 More than 90 percent of these reductions are
associated with avoided deforestation, while the remainder results from increased
soil carbon127 and avoided emissions from agricultural practices. Avoided GHGs
associated with sustainable intensification of rice and livestock production were
not included in the model, because of data uncertainties, but could significantly
increase these estimates. The anticipated emissions reductions from the green
strategy could open the door to significant new financing from international carbon
markets and REDD+128 financing mechanisms (Milder et al., 2012). The SAGCOT
agricultural green growth strategy will also generate annual water savings of about
940 million m3 per year on irrigated land (Milder et al., 2012).
126
At recent carbon prices of US$10 per tonne of CO2-equivalent (Milder et al., 2012).
127
See Glossary.
128
REDD is the UN Collaborative Programme on Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and
Forest Degradation (REDD) in developing countries. REDD+ goes beyond deforestation and forest
degradation, by incorporating the role of conservation, sustainable management of forests and
enhancement of forest carbon stocks. The REDD/REDD+ programme offers several financing options,
including market mechanisms, fund-based systems and their combination. For further information, see:
http://www.un-redd.org/AboutREDD/tabid/102614/Default.aspx [last accessed July 2013].
154 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
i.e. viable in areas with untapped growth potential. Conversely, blind support
to backward regions with little potential for economic growth and where eve-
rything needs to be developed is plainly objectionable.
3. Misaligning hard and soft interventions in the corridors. Corridor initiatives
do not always pay equal attention to hard and soft components – there is a
tendency to invest first in hard infrastructure, thinking that soft interventions
will logically follow. However, this is not the case since such alignment has to
be planned and prepared. Failure to do this (i.e. developing lacking connective
infrastructure without improving the business environment and investing in
transport and trade facilitation) gives way to a scenario in which returns on
investments are not maximized, and economies of scale are more difficult to
attain. The long experience of the GMS and CAREC programmes indicates
how long it takes in the real world to introduce soft interventions in a corridor
initiative. The design and planning of an effective hard-soft mix is challenging
because it requires intense capacity building and coordination skills to orches-
trate the participation of various actors, each with a vested interest in its own
part of the agenda.
4. Mistargeting is another common mistake. The selection of sectors, value chains,
crops and geographic areas ought to be guided by criteria of economic perfor-
mance and social and environmental sustainability. Sometimes, the wrong
areas, sectors and industries are selected on political grounds or dictated by
lobby and pressure groups. In other cases, the mistargeting is caused by inad-
equate appraisals based on wrong assumptions and insufficient evidence. The
targeting or selection process in the design of the corridor programme should
be carried out on the grounds of economic and technical feasibility studies
and preferably through some kind of multilevel and multistakeholder checks-
and-balances mechanism. For instance, Ambrosio-Albalá and Bastiaensen
(2010) suggest that there is a high risk of local governments being captured
by local groups and elites, which can lead to a failure to identify economies of
scale for delivering public services or a failure to deal with corridor spillovers.
This risk could be minimized by ensuring the active involvement of central
governments in the design, regulation and coordination of corridor initiatives.
In other cases, multinational agribusiness companies can exert excessive pres-
sure on governments and development partners to the point where they can
hijack the design of the corridor programme. A good measure to avoid this is
to invite domestic firms, producer federations and civil society to engage in the
corridor and counterbalance the influence of multinationals.
The right selection of growth centres, usually large urban areas, can do much to
stimulate regional development and integration. However, because of sheer dyna-
mism, there is a risk that these novel urban configurations do not necessarily feature
high on policy agendas. Recognizing the role of these urban centres, as the PRA
Project did with its “intermediate cities” theory, is key to spreading the economic,
spatial and infrastructural synergies of large cities geographically over an area within
the corridor vastly exceeding their current municipal boundaries.
Chapter 8 – Gains and pitfalls of agrocorridor initiatives 155
5. Disregarding issues that, although vital for the success of the agricorridor,
require unpopular actions(s) that will not produce political gains, such as land
reform or corruption. For example, if the lack of security in land tenure dis-
courages potential investors and the design of the agricorridor programme fails
to tackle this critical issue, the corridor investment strategy will be unlikely to
be successful.
6. Neglecting the introduction of environmental, social and food security safe-
guards. The quest for sustainable spatial development entails ecological and
social aspects being harmonized with economic objectives. Therefore, cor-
ridor developers should ascertain whether the strategy to develop agribusiness
within the corridor contributes to maximizing the economic, social and envi-
ronmental benefits of the corridor for local communities.
that they are able to engage in international promotional campaigns to ensure the
participation of both national and international bidders. Finally, PPPs, being a fairly
new model, require changes in mindsets. For example, officials at the ministries
most relevant to the corridor system – agriculture, transport, energy, finance – are
unlikely ever to have dealt with a mechanism as complex as these partnerships. To
respond, they will need new skills and a more business-like approach.
Governance issues. Concerns of a social nature such as land tenure issues, exclusion
of economic actors and lack of equity or fairness, and an environmental nature – land
degradation, inadequate management of water resources and agro-industrial waste
– may emerge during the implementation of the corridor programme. Accordingly,
governance issues pertaining to inclusiveness, fairness and environmental concerns
stemming from agricultural corridor interventions need to be assessed.
The potential environmental problems derived from both infrastructure and
agro-industrial developments undertaken in economic corridors first need to be
established. Infrastructure projects of the magnitude and scope implemented in
the corridors, and the resulting increased mobility of people and goods, may trig-
ger faster exploitation of natural resources (land, water and soils). For example,
in the GMS corridors road upgrading and expansion led to deforestation and
biodiversity loss in some areas, because of the involuntary facilitation of logging
and transporting of timber. Similarly, augmented agro-industrial activity along the
economic corridors could lead to pollution and waste disposal issues. Land clearing
for agro-industrial and commercial purposes could also result in deforestation and
biodiversity loss (ADB, 2008a; ADB, 2011b). Intensifying agricultural production
for markets because of amplified demand and economic opportunities along the
corridors, may lead to undesirable environmental consequences if the required
increase in chemical and water use is poorly managed (Pingali, 2001).
Ensuring the social sustainability of corridors is equally vital. However, eco-
nomic corridor programmes can trigger up to four types of negative social impacts
on communities and vulnerable groups. These are: displacement of local communi-
ties and ethnic minorities, and poorly managed resettlement schemes; emergence of
vulnerabilities in the labour market of corridors; land grabbing; and exclusion from
value chains, and agriculture in general, of small-scale actors, such as farmers and
agribusiness SMEs.
For example, some GMS infrastructure projects have required the relocation and
resettlement of local inhabitants, causing changes in their socio-economic environ-
ment. The impact of this displacement can be particularly severe for marginalized
groups, such as small, remote rural communities and ethnic minorities. While
resettlement and compensation schemes usually complement major infrastructure
projects, they need to be better planned and implemented (ADB, 2010b). Further-
more, land prices around road construction sites tend to rise because of speculation
and expected increase in demand. This may cause small landowners to sell their
properties prematurely or they may be dispossessed of them, particularly in areas
where land rights are not properly defined or enforced (ibid.).
The dynamism of economic corridors can cause problems in the labour market.
For instance, the rapid growth experienced in the Mekong countries, partially
driven by the GMS corridor programme, has spawned vulnerabilities in the local
158 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
129
See Glossary.
130
See Glossary.
Chapter 8 – Gains and pitfalls of agrocorridor initiatives 159
surplus land, which could be upscaled across the GMS corridors. However, experi-
ence from the region and elsewhere has shown that, if deployed unsustainably,
biofuel developments can be associated with numerous risks, particularly in terms
of food security, impacts on soil, water quality and availability, and biodiversity
(USAID, 2009).
The current investment pattern in the GMS corridors appears to favour large
plantations, which may lead to smallholder exclusion (ADB, 2007a). For example,
farmers engaged in small-scale jatropha developments in Yunnan, and corridor areas
in Myanmar and Viet Nam, are vulnerable to uncertainties and high-transaction
costs in processing and marketing (ADB, 2007a; Shepley et al., 2009). Similarly, the
predominant model in Cambodia and the Lao People’s Democratic Republic is a
concession that utilizes farmers only as daily wage labour and therefore may limit
inclusive growth in the long term (Malik et al., 2009).
161
Chapter 9
Guidance for making
economic corridors work
for the agricultural sector
3. Design for scale and mobilize the right “change agent”. Corridors are good
vehicles for piloting and testing new business and governance approaches but,
beyond that, they should be designed for scaling up to a transformative level.
Only interventions that incorporate a smart mix of strategic elements (pro-
ducer aggregation, market linkages and finance) and have clearly identified a
change agent (i.e. the entity that can act as a key driver in scaling the initiative
and establishing links to smallholders) are really upscalable (WEF, 2013).
Successfully designing for scale often involves identifying critical barriers in
the value chain, and discovering the change agent that is best placed to over-
come them. Based on this diagnosis, the corridor strategy will focus support
on these change agents.
Change agents can be found in different parts of the value chain. They
could be government extension agents or farmer groups. Nonetheless, in most
cases, they are what the PRA Project refers to as “star connecting firms”. They
can be, for example, large investors that have set up nucleus farms and receive
some corridor support in return for aggregating the produce of smallholder
farmers in their area/cluster and providing them with extension services and
inputs, as seen in SAGCOT. Change agents can also be seen on the off-take
and processing side of the agrifood chain, where agroprocessors, traders,
supermarkets and other entrepreneurs with networks of small-scale suppliers
manage to aggregate production and add value.
Scaling up can be undertaken in phases by, for example, leveraging exten-
sion workers in one agrobased cluster or agrifood chain at a time or on one
particular practice or issue. Another possibility is to launch a multiphase plan
that prioritizes support to different agrifood chains in consecutive waves, as
SAGCOT is set to do.
5. Identify the most appropriate model for corridor governance and delivery
mechanism(s) to manage and implement the corridor programme and offer the
planned corridor services. Again, the aptness or otherwise of a given corridor
institutional model is very context specific: in some cases the establishment
of corridor centres presents itself as the optimal solution, while in others it
is more suitable to build upon existing structures and complement them with
coordinating mechanisms such as liaison officers, focal points or high-level
ministerial committees, depending on the circumstances. The model for cor-
ridor authority can be selected from various options. For example, the govern-
ance of the GMS corridor relies on a system formed by summits, conferences
and technical meetings, combined with a centralized corridor secretariat and
national focal points. In the PRA Project, the corridor authority is held by a
central manager, an outsourced private firm, which coordinates the various
corridor centres, whose management is equally outsourced to private firms,
NGOs and consortia. In addition, there could be several delivery mechanisms
operating concomitantly, each with a different function. For example, there
could be an overall corridor authority responsible for providing strategic
guidance and monitoring the delivery of the programme; Corridor Centres
in charge of delivering corridor services, as in the corridors of the United
Republic of Tanzania, Mozambique and Peru; Corridor Funds, either managed
internally or by an external entity, which provide financing and guarantees
to corridor beneficiaries (SAGCOT and BAGCI funds); and finally, Cor-
ridor Institutes and Observatories responsible for developing and dissemi-
nating information and studies on key corridor topics, such as the CAREC
Institute,131 the GMS Environment Operations Center132 or transport and
131
http://www.carecprogram.org/index.php?page=carec-institute [last accessed September 2013].
132
www.gms-eoc.org [last accessed September 2013].
Chapter 9 – Guidance for making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector 165
trade observatories to monitor progress against trade and logistics targets and
perform the corresponding studies and surveys.
9. Take measures to avoid land grabbing and other land tenure problems. Cor-
ridor authorities are often in a position to influence and provide high-quality,
practical inputs to national land reform processes. However, more corridor-
specific actions to encourage ethical behaviour in (trans)national land deals
are often required. These include the adoption of responsible investment
guidelines and the establishment of land banks. SAGCOT has pushed for this
twin-track approach. The SAGCOT partners and G8 members involved in the
New Alliance for Food Security and Nutrition have confirmed their intention
to take account of the Voluntary Guidelines on the Responsible Governance
of Tenure of Land [...] adopted by the Committee on World Food Security
(FAO, 2012c), as well as the Principles for Responsible Agricultural Invest-
ment (PRAI) produced by FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD and the World Bank
133
www.wbginvestmentclimate.org [last accessed September 2013].
Chapter 9 – Guidance for making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector 167
(FAO et al., 2010). In addition, they intend to develop joint pilot implementa-
tion programmes for the Voluntary Guidelines and the PRAI in the United
Republic of Tanzania (G8, 2012).
As seen previously, a land bank might be established to link investors to
suitable sites in the corridor in an efficient, transparent and equitable manner.
Land banks seem to operate best when professionally maintained. This way,
investors do not need to search for land as part of the business development
process, thus reducing their financial risk and costs. Situations in which plan-
ners face conflicts of interest and communities in planning and negotiation pro-
cesses – some of which are coercive – can also be averted (Milder et al., 2012).
10. Devise green growth or environmental strategies for the corridor. Corridor
plans are increasingly based on the belief that environmental sustainability
and economic growth are not only compatible, but should be integrated. The
Southern Corridor of Tanzania has made an explicit commitment to advance
the practice of green growth; the GMS corridors are also progressively
embracing this model.
The first step towards green growth is to conduct an environmental assessment
in order to identify effective approaches to maintain the quality of ecosystems,
mitigate climate change and ensure access to clean energy and water in the cor-
ridors, among other issues. One essential element in the pursuit of green growth
corridors is the inclusion in the masterplan of measures to ensure that major
investments in transport and agriculture are realized sustainably (Ramachandran
and Linde, 2011). Accordingly, the corridor investment programme should
incorporate agriculture green growth practices to position the corridor as a place
that attracts “best in class” investors and innovators willing to integrate environ-
mental sustainability into their business plans (Milder et al., 2012).
Agrocorridors can use a variety of approaches to measure and track pro-
gress on green growth. One option is to embed in the masterplan explicit
guidelines and smart targets for environmental sustainability in activities and
investments, and scrupulously adhere to them. This can be done for the corri-
dor programme as a whole, and for each individual agrifood chain, cluster/SEZ
and investment project. The corridor plan can develop its own framework or
make use of well-tested, groundbreaking initiatives such as the Field to Market
or the Sustainable Agriculture Initiative Platform.134
134
www.fieldtomarket.org; www.saiplatform.org [last accessed September 2013].
168 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Ensure that corridor initiatives have top political support, and are monitored
directly from the office of the president, highly influential ministers or
high-level coordinating committees.
Verify that the design of the corridor programme guards against “ownership
gaps” at either the local, national or regional levels.
Incorporate good practices such as inclusive business models that empower
smallholder farmers, good investment and land tenure principles, innovative
financing and green growth practices.
Adopt an explicit focus on engaging and working closely with small-scale
farmers and firms, women and youth, and ensure that they are actively
involved in decision-making to shape projects and new business models.
-- Consider offering definitions of each vulnerable group identified in the
inclusion policy.
-- Make sure that corridor resources are deployed to maximize inclusion
outcomes.
-- Foster a community-driven, decision-making process involving all stake-
holders to ensure that the rights of these vulnerable groups are protected.
Make sure that the corridor masterplan reflects the policy framework
within the corridor and identify key issues for policy dialogue and action.
135
These round tables include the Better Sugar Cane Initiative (Bonsucro – www.bettersugar.org);
the Round Table on Responsible Soy (www.responsiblesoy.org); the Global Roundtable for
Sustainable Beef (www.sustainablelivestock.org); and the Roundtable on Sustainable Biomaterials
(http://rsb.epfl.ch) [last accessed May 2013].
172 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Identify and engage the right organizations to deliver the above financial
products. If the path chosen is to set up a corridor body responsible for this
delivery, choose the most appropriate model and initiate its establishment.
Establish investment guidelines to help steer investors towards socially
responsible and agriculture green growth practices with broad social and
environmental benefits. These investment guidelines would enhance, but
not duplicate, environmental and social safeguards put in place through
other mechanisms (e.g. SAGCOT).
Accelerate the availability and adoption of agricultural index insurance in
the corridor, in order to mitigate risks to farmers, especially smallholders
and women farmers, and increase income and nutritional security.
Complete corridor agricultural risk assessment strategies, with the mandate
of identifying key risks to food and nutrition security and agribusiness
development and recommending options for managing these risks.
Ensure that there is adequate fiscal margin for the public investments
required and place emphasis on the due diligence work of the Central Bank.
Minimize the risk of major infrastructure projects by selecting partners for
joint ventures with proven expertise and a solid financial background.
Strengthen social and environmental safeguards management, including
bolstering the capacity of the staff of the corridor authority and corridor
partners (particularly the public sector) to conduct better environmental
impact assessments.
Implement a single coherent process for identifying lands suitable for
agriculture or forestry investment, for example, by establishing land
banks and voluntary guidelines.
Devise strategies to minimize risks involved in the concentration of
resources in the corridor (as a typical megaproject). For example, it is
important to monitor and enhance the health of the adjacent landscape,
upon which the long-term value of corridors depends.
7. Hard-side interventions
Execute planned infrastructure investments along the corridor using the
preferred governance models (e.g. direct implementation and infrastructure
PPPs), and applying international best practices for developing and
managing transport and trade corridors. See, for example, Arnold, Olivier
and Arvis (2005) and Arnold (2006).
Ensure that the development of the corridor transport axis is complemented
with adequate rural infrastructure development to support access to
markets and corridor widening.
Enhance the environmental and social regulatory framework applicable to
connective, energy and last-mile infrastructure and strengthen the national/
corridor capacity to enforce compliance and apply sanctions for non-
compliance.
Implement logistics programmes, with active industry participation through
platforms and fora.
Strengthen existing mechanisms for modelling road toll and port revenues
based on applicable fiscal provisions; for the collection and auditing of such
revenues; and for interagency coordination.
Implement mechanisms for information sharing, transparency and
accountability, including eventual publication of revenues and possibly
infrastructure PPP/concession contracts.
Chapter 10
Conclusions
This chapter has been kept purposely short because comprehensive and detailed
conclusions and recommendations have already been presented in Chapter 9.
cesses are ongoing and extremely important in developing regions, so the interaction
between central and federal or regional governments within each country has to
be added to the formula. Without mutual support between national and regional
organizations, it would be difficult to face the complexity of inter-institutional
implementation and the need for standardized and harmonized, and yet innovative
corridor execution and financing models.
Motivated by these reasons, some of the actors mentioned have teamed up to
promote agribusiness development through six economic corridors, as shown
throughout these pages. These corridors have been fostered by different lead con-
veners or actors that have shaped four distinct corridor models. As could not be
otherwise, the four models analysed have diverse strategies, stakeholders, objectives,
engagement and governance models, as well as corridor programme components.
Nevertheless, they also have much in common for they share the basic principles of
agrocorridor development.
The approach used in characterizing these agrocorridor models has been to
deconstruct them along the lines of the core factors that have been defined in theory
as key to the contribution of corridor performance. These factors are, inter alia,
public policy, investment incentives, infrastructure, labour performance (through
human resources development) and regional and global integration. This decon-
struction has been captured through the establishment of monographs of corridor
characteristics, understanding the (core) developer, the development phases of the
corridors and the nature of corridor institutions such as corridor authorities, centres
and funds. A tailor-made framework for analysis has been applied to ensure the
systematic, coherent comparison across the cases. The framework looks at the com-
parative advantage of each corridor, the extent of its connectivity and infrastructure,
its composition of firms and farmers, the soft interventions deployed to develop the
agribusiness opportunities, its supported agrifood chains, and the specific processes
and tools used for planning and implementing the corridor programme. This analy-
sis has culminated in implications on governance, impacts on local, national and
regional development, and finally the sustainability of these corridors.
The study of the cases reveals that corridor programmes come in all shapes and sizes.
Some are multicountry, multicorridor and multisectoral, while others deal with a single
country, corridor and sector. Obviously, this wide variability is also observed in the
budget and target for induced investments attributable to each corridor intervention.
An important element of differentiation among the six cases studied is the way
they approach the agribusiness sector. Some corridor programmes have been cre-
ated with the sole purpose of contributing to agribusiness development; others have
agriculture as one of several core sectors they support. Finally, agribusiness can be
a second-tier sector that corridor programmes deal with in an ad hoc manner, when
specific initiatives for joint action are identified and agreed upon.
Each approach may yield a different outcome, but each has the potential to
impact the agribusiness sector in a substantial, positive manner. Long-lasting gains
in agricultural and total GDP have been observed, incremental jobs have been
created along the agrifood chain and ancillary industries and services, agricultural
exports have steadily increased and farmers’ income have risen. In particular, the
impacts of agrocorridors in terms of employment generation are noteworthy. As
highlighted in Chapter 9, incremental jobs are created not only on farm but also off
180 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
farm, mostly in the agroprocessing sector, but also in other stages of the agricul-
tural value chain. Indirect effects on employment in other sectors are also far from
being negligible. Furthermore, the emphasis of many agrocorridor programmes on
inclusive and socially responsible engagement models will likely have long-lasting
positive effects on the income levels of small-scale farmers and agribusiness firms.
The impressive positive impacts of agrocorridor programmes can blind us to the
existence of some negative effects, such as land tenure issues, environmental degra-
dation, overuse of water resources and the exclusion of small-scale actors. To avoid
the emergence of these issues, social and environmental safeguards can be built into
the corridor masterplan. Some of these safeguards might seek to reduce the market
asymmetry of information and bargaining power between the farmers and their
suppliers and buyers, which are often multinational agribusiness companies. Other
safeguards will try to address the potential negative externalities associated with
agricultural intensification. Further social safeguards are broader in scope, such as
enabling communities to sustain themselves, protect their land rights and create
favourable ecoenvironmental conditions in the corridor area where they live.
To shield the agrocorridor programme against the potential poor design, imple-
mentation and governance issues underscored in Chapter 9, guidance is provided for
those concerned with corridor/agribusiness development. A two-pronged approach
is followed: a best practices summary and a checklist are offered to be used in com-
bination. The main goal of these guidance elements is to maximize the potential of
the corridor plan to yield positive outcomes (triple bottom line of economic, social
and environmental effects) and minimize the likelihood of negative outcomes.
Annex 1
Glossary
Agribusiness
Agribusiness is a broad concept that covers input suppliers, agroprocessors, trad-
ers, exporters and retailers. Agro-industry broadly refers to the establishment
of enterprises and supply chains for developing, transforming and distributing
specific inputs and products in the agricultural sector. Agro-industry refers to
the establishment of enterprises and supply chains for developing, transforming
and distributing specific inputs and products in the agricultural sector. (Source:
FAOTERM.) For the sake of simplification, these two terms are considered
interchangeable in this document.
Agricultural extension
“Agricultural extension provides non-formal agriculturally related continuing
adult education for multiple audiences: farmers, spouses, youth, community, urban
horticulturalists (continuing agricultural education and community development)
and for various purposes (including agricultural development, community resource
development, group promotion and cooperative organizational development)”
(FAO, 2001; p. 9).
Block farming
Block farming is a farming system in which groups of smallholder farmers join
together to farm large tracts under the guidance of a technical supervisor in order
to minimize labour, input and extension costs (Milder et al., 2012). In this specific
case, the term refers to farm blocks under irrigation that are leased to commercial
and smallholder producers (AgDevCo and InfraCo, 2010).
Breadbasket (project/intervention)
A breadbasket project consists of the priority development of an area or region with
the potential for providing most of the food for a country. The Cerrado region of
Brazil and the northeast region of Thailand are two examples of successful bread-
basket corridor programmes in the developing world, carried out by two relatively
backward and landlocked agricultural regions in otherwise dynamic nations (World
Bank, 2009b). They have developed at a rapid pace and have become leading agricul-
tural exporters, through investing in large connective infrastructure and large dams,
agricultural research, and soil recuperation in well-defined corridor areas (World
Bank, 2009b).
Brownfield investments
Brownfield investments entail the expansion of existing ventures. Greenfield invest-
ments, on the other hand, are ventures that finance new physical facilities for a
business in a location where no existing facilities are currently present.
Catalytic financing
Catalytic financing is long-term capital to support companies and organizations to
undertake project development (in this case, of sustainable agriculture projects) that
can be taken to scale.
Contract farming
Contract farming is an agricultural production system carried out according to an
agreement between a buyer and farmers. The agreement establishes conditions for
the production and marketing of a farm product or products (FAO, 2012d). An out-
grower scheme is a system under which small-scale farmers (outgrowers) produce
crops for sale to a specific purchaser, usually an agricultural processing operation or
nearby large-scale farm. Frequently, the outgrowers receive training, extension and
input supplies to help improve product quantity and quality (Milder et al., 2012).
Dry port
A dry port is a facility that provides services for the handling and temporary storage
of containers, general and/or bulk cargoes that access the dry port by any mode
of transport such as road, railways, inland waterways or airports. (Source: www.
unescap.org [last accessed July 2013].)
Dutch disease
The Economist (1977, pp. 82–83) coined this term in relation to the role of natural
gas in the Dutch economy following the oil crisis of 1973. It referred to the fact that
the rise in natural resource exports (gas in the case of the Netherlands) can cause an
Annex 1 – Glossary 183
Economic integration
Economic integration is often defined as the abolition of the various restraints of
trade between nations. However, in this report economic integration refers not only
to the concept of free trade areas, but also to more advanced processes of integra-
tion that have more to do with economic convergence and catching-up processes.
There are several levels of economic integration: (i) free trade area with no tariffs
against members and individual tariffs against outsiders (e.g. the North American
Free Trade Area [NAFTA] and the European Free Trade Area [EFTA]); (ii) customs
union (no tariffs against members, common tariff against outsiders, e.g. the Andean
Group and Caribbean Community and Common Market [CARICOM]); (iii) com-
mon market (a customs union without limitations on factor mobility, such as the
European Union); and (iv) complete economic integration (unification of monetary,
fiscal, social and counter-cyclical policies).
Freight forwarding
Freight forwarding is a service used by firms that deal in international trade. Instead
of directly handling the transportation of their products, which can involve a
multitude of carriers, requirements and legalities, these firms can hire a “freight for-
warder” to act as an intermediary between them and various transportation services.
Global services
Global services are those necessary for companies competing on the world
market, such as easy access to global destinations for passengers and freight (in
particular airborne services), and the existence of advanced services supporting
international finance and market development. Other services include those in the
field of marketing and information and communication technology, and human
resources development to obtain a workforce with sufficient skills for meeting
international requirements.
Governance
The term “governance”is linked to the work of Williamson (1975; 1985) and other
new institutional economists, who state that institutions matter in many ways that
are pertinent for industrial organization, economic development and other fields
of social sciences. The institutional perspective encompasses two levels of analysis.
The first level is broader in scope and deals with the institutional environment or
“rules of the game” (or environment in which the institutional actors are embed-
ded). The second level is more focused on the microanalytic level pertaining to the
“institutions of governance”, which operate at the level of individual transactions,
and include markets, hybrids (mixed governance structure composed of hierarchic
and market elements) and hierarchies (i.e. a governance structure, with a ruling
body of clergy organized into orders or ranks each subordinate to the one above
it) (Williamson, 1973). Using this second, narrower sense, each mode of governance
has associated transaction costs; thus, taking the institutional environment as given,
economic agents align transactions with governance structures to effect economiz-
184 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Hardware (investment/interventions)
Hard components or investments refer to public spending aimed at developing
material infrastructure. “Hardware” concerns operations that enhance the connec-
tivity of national infrastructure investments (in transport, energy and communica-
tions) and associated regulatory frameworks to sustainable trade and investment
integration corridors, with the goal of reducing cross-border transaction costs,
boosting external competitiveness through productive integration, and promoting
balanced territorial development” (IaDB, 2011).
(Investment) greenprint
An investment “greenprint” can be defined as an investment framework to stimulate
“green growth”, i.e. growth that respects the environment and uses natural resources
adequately. Agriculture green growth is an approach for attracting and coordinating
investment in agricultural production, processing and distribution that is efficient,
profitable, sustainable and resilient to climate change (Milder et al., 2012).
Land bank
Land banks consist of general land available for investments, as determined by local
land-use plans, where investors can pick available areas in which to invest (Theting
and Brekke, 2010).
Land grabbing
Land grabbing is the transfer of rights to large areas (over 200 ha) of agricultural
land from local communities to foreign or domestic investors under false pretences
and questionable contracts, and occasionally with clear breaches of traditional rights
to land (Theting and Brekke, 2010; EC, 2013). Such land grabs typically involve
limited consultation with local communities, limited compensation, and a lack of
regard for environmental sustainability and equitable access to, or control over,
water resources.
Last-mile infrastructure
This concept refers to infrastructure that links smallholders and local communities into
the network, such as feeder roads, power and irrigation connections to the farmgate.
Market thickness
In agglomeration economics, “market thickness” refers to the effective number
of firms in a given market; thus, a thicker market indicates that more transactions
of a homogeneous good take place in a unit of time (Lippman and McCall, 1986).
Conversely, “thin markets” have a low number of buyers and sellers, and transac-
tions are scant; thus, they are less liquid and more volatile (since the few trades that
take place can affect prices significantly). The term “market thickness” has a long
history in the study of financial markets and commodity exchanges (Telser, 1981),
particularly in finance microstructure literature under the term “liquidity” (Lipp-
Annex 1 – Glossary 185
man and McCall, 1986), and in the transactions cost literature. See, for example, the
literature review in Hubbard (2001).
Matching grant
This type of grant encourages applicants to provide matching contributions in
cash or in kind, e.g. personnel time or assets. Consequently, the facility operates
on a co-investment basis, pairing up with national sponsors to create investment
opportunities to attract private investors.
Meta-trends
System-wide developments arising from the simultaneous occurrence of a number
of independent social, economic and technological trends.
One-stop shop
A one-stop shop relates to the ability of providing a comprehensive selection of goods
or services at a single location. The rationale of a one-stop shop or centre is to provide
a convenient, efficient and comprehensive selection of services to targeted clients.
Patient capital
Patient capital can be defined as equity funding with return requirements that are
delayed in time or lower in profitability than normal commercial thresholds (EC,
2004). In the context of the Beira Agricultural Growth Corridor (BAGC), it refers
to long-term, low-cost, subordinated capital to develop on-farm infrastructure,
mostly funded by development partners, such as bilateral donors, multilateral
development banks and large foundations (AgDevCo, 2010).
Public goods
Public goods are investments that deliver significant collective benefits but are not
profitable in their own right.
Smart subsidies
Smart subsidies are those characterized by being transparent (and designed to mini-
mize scope for political interference and administrative allocation), target-effective,
cost-effective, cost-efficient and non-distortionary (World Bank, 1998).
186 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Software (investment/interventions)
Investments in soft components (policy and regulatory coordination) mean public
or development funding that prepares the ground for “hard” investments (physical
integration), for example by improving governance, developing human resources and
business capacity, building a fostering enabling environment and strengthening rel-
evant organizations (Streeck and Mertens, 2011). Software refers to “operations that
support policy reforms, regulatory upgrades, institutional strengthening and capac-
ity development needed to facilitate the movement of goods, services, capital, people
and technology across borders, with the goal of promoting a better integration of
country systems and private operators into the global economy” (IaDB, 2011).
Transformative investment
A “transformative investment” is characterized by its catalytic nature and ability to
impact on markets and people, beyond its chronological and geographic scope (Katz
and Wagner, 2008).
Value-chain finance
Value-chain finance refers to “the financial flows to those actors from both within
the value chain and financial flows to those actors from the outside as a result of
their being linked within a value chain” (Miller and Jones, 2010; p. xv).
187
Annex 2
Economic corridors identified
10 Africa Greater Ibadan Lagos Accra (GILA) Corridor Benin, Ghana, Nigeria and Togo
15 Asia North-South Economic Corridor (Greater China, Myanmar, Lao People’s Democratic
Mekong Subregion [GMS programme]) Republic (Lao PDR) and Thailand
16 Asia East-West Economic Corridor Myanmar, Thailand, Lao PDR and Viet Nam
(GMS programme)
24 Latin The Initiative for the Integration of Argentina, Plurinational State of Bolivia,
America Regional Infrastructure in South America Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Guyana,
(IIRSA) Corridors: Paraguay, Peru, Suriname, Uruguay
and Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela
11) Andean Corridor
12) South Andean Corridor
13) Capricorn Corridor
14) Paraguay-Parana Waterway Corridor
15) Amazon Corridor
16) Guyanese Shield Corridor
17) Southern Corridor
18) Central Interoceanic Corridor
19) Mercosur-Chile Corridor
20) Peru-Brazil-Bolivia Corridor
Bibliography
ADB. 2004. The GMS Beyond Borders. Regional Cooperation Strategy and Program
(2004–2006). Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2006. The GMS Beyond Borders. Regional Cooperation Strategy and Program
(2007–2009). Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2007a. Strategic Framework for Subregional Cooperation in Agriculture 2006–
2010. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2007b. Trade Performance of GMS Countries. Trends, Patterns and Policy
Options, by P. Athukorala. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development
Bank. (unpublished)
ADB. 2008a. Accelerating the Implementation of the Core Agriculture Support Program
(Cofinanced by the Government of the People’s Republic of China). Technical
Assistance Report, Project 39542. Regional Policy and Advisory Technical Assistance
(R-PATA). December. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2008b. Transport and Trade Facilitation in the Greater Mekong Subregion. Time to
Shift Gears. Evaluation Study. SAP: REG 2008-86. Sector Assistance Program (SAP)
Evaluation. December. ADB Operations Evaluation Department. Mandaluyong City,
the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2008c. Lao People’s Democratic Republic and Socialist Republic of Viet Nam –
Greater Mekong Subregion: East-West Corridor Project. Performance Evaluation
Report. December. ADB Operations Evaluation Department. Mandaluyong City, the
Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2009. Status and Potential for the Development of Biofuels and Rural Renewable
Energy. The People’s Republic of China, by J. Huang, H. Qiu, J. Yang & Y. Zhang.
Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2010a. Toward sustainable and balanced development. Strategy and Action Plan
for the Greater Mekong Subregion East-West Economic Corridor. Mandaluyong City,
the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2010b. Toward Sustainable and Balanced Development. Strategy and Action Plan
for the Greater Mekong Subregion – North-South Economic Corridor. Mandaluyong
City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2010c. Toward Sustainable and Balanced Development. Strategy and Action Plan
for the Greater Mekong Subregion – Southern Economic Corridor. Mandaluyong
City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2010d. Seventh Meeting of the GMS Working Group on Agriculture (WGA-7).
Hanoi, 15–16 November. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2010e. Support for Implementing the Action Plan for Transport and Trade
Facilitation in the Greater Mekong Subregion. Technical Assistance Report. Project
44174–01. November. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
192 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
ADB. 2010f. Fourteenth Meeting of the GMS Subregional Transport Forum. Summary of
Proceedings. Nanning, China, 2–3 December. GMS Economic Cooperation Program.
Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2011a. The Greater Mekong Subregion Economic Cooperation Program Strategic
Framework 2012–2022. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2011b. Core Agriculture Support Program Phase II (2011–2015). Greater Mekong
Subregion Working Group on Agriculture. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian
Development Bank.
ADB. 2011c. Regional Corridors Development in Regional Cooperation, by P. Srivastava.
ADB Economics Working Paper Series 258. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines,
Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2011d. Cross-border Contract Farming Arrangement. Variations and Implications
in the Lao People’s Democratic Republic, by K. Manorom, D. Hall, X. Lu, S. Katima,
M.T. Medialdia, S. Siharath & P. Srisuphan. Greater Mekong Subregion-Phnom Penh
Plan for Development Management. Research Report Series 1(2). Mandaluyong City,
the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2011e. Trade and Investment in the Greater Mekong Subregion. Remaining
Challenges and the Unfinished Policy Agenda, by J. Menon & A.C. Melendez. ADB
Working Paper Series on Regional Economic Integration 78. Mandaluyong City, the
Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2011f. The New Silk Road. Ten Years of the Central Asia Regional Economic
Cooperation Program. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2012a. Greater Mekong Subregion Economic Cooperation Program. Overview.
Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2012b. Biofuels in the Greater Mekong Subregion. Energy Sufficiency, Food
Security and Environmental Management, by P. Tharakan, N. Crishna, J. Romero
& D. Morgado. ADB Southeast Asia Working Paper Series. Mandaluyong City, the
Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2012c. Trade and Trade Facilitation in the Greater Mekong Subregion. P.
Srivastava & U. Kumar, eds. August. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian
Development Bank. Available at: http://www.adb.org/sites/default/files/pub/2012/
trade-and-trade-facilitation-gms.pdf
ADB. 2012d. Asian Economic Integration Monitor. July. Mandaluyong City, the
Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2012e. A Strategic Framework for the Central Asia Regional Economic Cooperation
Program: 2011–2020. Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB. 2012f. Agricultural Trade Facilitation in the Greater Mekong Subregion.
Mandaluyong City, the Philippines, Asian Development Bank.
ADB & ADBI. 2013. Connecting South Asia and Southeast Asia. Interim Report. Tokyo,
Asian Development Bank and Asian Development Bank Institute.
ADBI. 2008a. Global Partnership in Poverty Reduction. Contract Farming and
Regional Cooperation, by S. Setboonsarng. ADBI Discussion Paper 89. Tokyo, Asian
Development Bank Institute.
ADBI. 2008b. Rice Contract Farming in Lao PDR. Moving from Subsistence to
Commercial Agriculture, by S. Setboonsarng, P.S. Leung & A. Stefan. ADBI
Discussion Paper 90. Tokyo, Asian Development Bank Institute.
Bibliography 193
Cochrane, G. 2012. The Greater Mekong Sub-Region at 20. Japan’s Role in the Region
and its Implications for Regional Integration. Centre for East and Southeast Asian
Studies. Lund, Sweden, Lund University.
Cohen, J.P. & Morrison Paul, C.J. 2007. Agglomeration, Productivity and Regional
Growth. Production Theory Approaches. Davis, California, United States of America,
University of Hartford and University of California. September 2008.
Collier, P. & O’Connell, S. 2007. Opportunities and choices. In The Political Economy
of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960–2000. Cambridge, United Kingdom, Cambridge
University Press.
De, P. 2013. Connectivity, Trade Facilitation and Regional Cooperation in South Asia.
New Delhi, Commonwealth Secretariat.
DFID. 2012. Business Case and Intervention Summary. Southern Agricultural Growth
Corridor in Tanzania (SAGCOT).London, Department for International Development.
DFID. 2013. Annual Review of the Beira Agricultural Growth Corridor (BAGC) Project.
Review undertaken on 30 April. London, Department for International Development.
Dicken, P., Peck, J. & Tickell, A. 1997. Unpacking the global, In R. Lee. & J. Wills,
eds. Geographies of Economies. London, Edward Arnold.
Domínguez-Torres, C. & Briceño-Garmendia, C. 2011. Mozambique’s Infrastructure.
A Continental Perspective. Washington, DC, International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development /World Bank. Available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/
MOZAMBIQUEEXTN/Resources/AICD-Mozambique_Country_Report.pdf
Du Pisanie, J.A. 2002. Competition versus Co-Operation the Case of SADC’s Regional
Development Corridors. South African J. Economics, 70(2): 145–154. March. Oxford,
United Kingdom, Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Durchslag, S. Rao, A. & Puri T. 1994. The promise of infrastructure privatization.
McKinsey Quarterly. February.
Easterly, W. & Levine, R. 1998. Troubles with the Neighbours. Africa’s Problem,
Africa’s Opportunity. J. African Economies, 7(1): 120–142.
Easterly, W. & Levine, R. 2001. What have we learned from a decade of empirical
research on growth? It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth
Models. The World Bank Economic Review, 15(2): 177–219.
EC. 1999. ESDP. European Spatial Development Perspective. Towards Balanced and
Sustainable Development of the Territory of the European Union. Committee on
Economic Development of the EC. Agreed at the Informal Council of Ministers
responsible for Spatial Planning in Potsdam, May.
EC. 2004. The Patient Capital Initiative. A Proposal for a Global Renewable Energy
Fund of Funds in the Context of the Johannesburg Renewable Energy Coalition.
Brussels, European Commission.
EC. 2013. European Commission (2/02/2013) Science for Environment Policy. Issue 318,
DG Environmental News Alert Service. Brussels, European Commission.
ECDPM. 2013. Corridors of power or plenty? Lessons from Tanzania and Mozambique
and implications for CAADP. Discussion Paper 138. Maastricht, the Netherlands,
European Centre for Development Policy Management.
ERIA. 2008. The Mekong-India Economic Corridor. Concept Paper. ERIA Research
Project Report 2008-4-2. Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia.
196 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Ernst & Young. 2011a. Eye on Africa: how to write yourself into the African growth
story. Special Issue, December/January 2011. Available at: http://www.ey.com/
Publication/vwLUAssets/Eye_special_ed_Africanm_Growth_Story/$FILE/Eye_
special_ed_African_Growth_Story.pdf
Ernst & Young. 2011b. An African dawn. Dynamics, 4: 30, September 2011. Available
at: http://www.ey.com/Publication/vwLUAssets/Dynamics_Growing_international_
development_Brick_by_brick/$FILE/Dynamics_Growing_international_
development_Brick_by_brick.pdf
FAO. 2001. Agricultural and Rural Extension Worldwide. Options for Institutional
Reform in the Developing Countries, by W.M. Rivera, M.K. Qamar & L.Van
Crowder. Rome. Available at: ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/004/y2709e/y2709e.pdf
FAO. 2006. Agro-industrial parks. Experience from India, by K. Laxminarayana Rao.
Agricultural and Food Engineering Working Document 3. Rome. Available at:
http://www.fao.org/ag/ags/publications/docs/AGST_WorkingDocuments/J7714_e.pdf
FAO. 2007. Guidelines for rapid appraisals of agrifood chain performance in developing
countries, by C.A. da Silva & H.M. de Souza Filho. Agricultural Management,
Marketing and Finance Occasional Paper 20. Rural Infrastructure and Agro-Industries
Division. Rome. Available at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/010/a1475e/a1475e00.htm
FAO. 2009a. High food prices and the food crisis – Experiences and lessons learned. The
State of Agricultural Commodity Markets 2009. Rome. Available at: ftp://ftp.fao.org/
docrep/fao/012/i0753e/i0753e00.pdf
FAO. 2009b. How to feed the world in 2050. Based on J. Schmidhuber, J. Bruinsma & G.
Baedeker. 2009. Capital requirements for agriculture in developing countries to 2050.
Presented at the Expert Meeting on “How to feed the world in 2050”. FAO, 24–26
June. Rome. Available at www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/wsfs/docs/expert_paper/
How_to_Feed_the_World_in_2050.pdf
FAO. 2010. Agro-based clusters in developing countries: staying competitive in a
globalized economy, by E. Gálvez-Nogales. Agricultural Management, Marketing
and Finance Occasional Paper 25. Rural Infrastructure and Agro-Industries Division.
Rome. Available at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/012/i1560e/i1560e.pdf
FAO. 2011. The rise of agrifood technopoles in the Middle East and North Africa, by
E. Gálvez-Nogales. Agricultural Management, Marketing and Finance Working
Document 30. Rural Infrastructure and Agro-Industries Division. Rome. Available
at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/016/ap292e/ap292e.pdf
FAO. 2012a. Trends and impacts of foreign investment in developing country agriculture.
Evidence from case studies. Rome. Available at: http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/user_
upload/newsroom/docs/Trends %20publication %2012 %20November %202012.pdf
FAO. 2012b. The State of Food and Agriculture 2012. Rome. Available at:
http://www.fao.org/docrep/017/i3028e/i3028e.pdf
FAO. 2012c. Voluntary Guidelines on the Responsible Governance of Tenure of Land,
Fisheries and Forests in the Context of National Food Security. Rome. Available at:
http://www.fao.org/nr/tenure/voluntary-guidelines/en/
FAO. 2012d. Guiding principles for responsible contract farming operations. Pultrone, C.,
Da Silva, C.A. & Shepherd, A. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations, FAO. Available at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/016/i2858e/i2858e.pdf
Bibliography 197
FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD & the World Bank. 2010. Principles for Responsible
Agricultural Investment that Respects Rights, Livelihoods and Resources. Rome,
FAO, International Fund for Agricultural Development, the UNCTAD Secretariat
and the World Bank Group. Available at: http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/
est/INTERNATIONAL-TRADE/FDIs/RAI_Principles_Synoptic.pdf
FAO & UNIDO. 2009. Agro-industries for development. C.A. Da Silva, D. Baker, A.
Shepherd & S. Miranda-da-Cruz, eds. Oxfordshire and Cambridge, The Food and
Agriculture Organization of the United Nations and The United Nations Industrial
Development Organization, by arrangement with CAB International. Available at:
http://www.fao.org/docrep/013/i0157e/i0157e00.pdf
Farooki, M. 2012. Policy Arena. The Infrastructure and Commodities Interface in Africa.
Time for Cautious Optimism? J. International Development, 24: 208–219. Development
Policy and Practice Group, Open University, Milton Keynes, United Kingdom.
Fergie J.A. & Satz, M. 2007. Harvesting Latin America’s agribusiness opportunity.
McKinsey Quarterly, March. Available at: https://www.mckinseyquarterly.com/
Harvesting_Latin_Americas_agribusiness_opportunity_1970
Fujimura, M. & Edmonds, C. 2008. Road Infrastructure and Regional Economic
Integration. Evidence from the Mekong. In D.H. Brooks & J. Menon, eds. Infrastructure
and Trade in Asia. Cheltenham, United Kingdom, Edward Elgar Publishing.
Fullbrook, D. 2007. Contract Farming in Lao PDR. Cases and Questions. Produced by
the Laos Extension for Agriculture Project (LEAP) for the Government-Donor Sub
Working Group on Farmers and Agribusiness. October.
G8. 2012. G8 Cooperation Framework to Support The “New Alliance for Food Security
and Nutrition” in Tanzania. Available at: http://www.usaid.gov/sites/default/files/
documents/1868/TanzaniaCooperationFramework.pdf
GAA. 2012. Growth Corridor Plans. Managing Melbourne’s Growth. Melbourne,
Australia, Growth Areas Authority.
Giordano, P. 2012. Investing in integration. Institute for the Integration of Latin
American and the Caribbean (INTAL), IaDB. Integration & Trade Journal, 34(16):
47–67. January–June. Available at: http://www.iadb.org/intal/intalcdi/integracion_
comercio/i_INTAL_IYT_34_2012_Giordano.pdf
GMF. 2013. The New Alliance for Food Security and Nutrition. Pushing the Frontier of
Enlightened Capitalism, by J.M. White. Washington, DC, German Marshall Fund of
the United States.
Government of Tanzania. 2012. Environmental and Social Management Framework
(ESMF) of the Southern Agricultural Growth Corridor of Tanzania (SAGCOT).
Report prepared by Environmental Resources Management Ltd. July. Available at:
http://letstalklandtanzania.com/s/download/reports/SAGCOT%20Environmental
%20and %20Social %20Management %20Framework.pdf
Hallam, D. 2011. International investment in developing country agriculture – issues
and challenges. Food Security J., 3 (Suppl. 1): 91–98.
Harrison, A. & Rodríguez-Clare, A. 2009. Trade, Foreign Investment, and Industrial
Policy for Developing Countries. NBER Working Paper 15261. Cambridge,
Massachusetts, United States of America, The National Bureau of Economic Research.
Healey, P. 2004. The Treatment of Space and Place in the New Strategic Spatial Planning
in Europe. International J. Urban and Regional Research, 28(1): 45–67. February.
198 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Hubbard, T.N. 2001. Contractual form and market thickness in trucking. RAND J.
Economics, 32(2): 369–86. Summer.
IaDB. 2011. Sector Strategy to Support Competitive Global and Regional Integration.
Vice-Presidency for Sectors and Knowledge, Integration and Trade Sector of IaDB.
Washington, DC, Inter-American Development Bank.
IDB. 2011. A study of international transport corridors in OIC member countries.
Jeddah, Saudi Arabia, Islamic Development Bank.
IIRSA. 2010. Agenda de Implementación Consensuada 2005–2010. Informe de
Evaluación. Initiative for the Integration of Regional Infrastructure in South
America. Buenos Aires, Institute for the Integration of Latin American and the
Caribbean (INTAL).
Infante, I. 2012. The Mesoamerican Integration Corridor. Integrating Mesoamerica
through the Pacific. Integration & Trade Journal, 34: 69–78. January–June. Institute
for the Integration of Latin America and the Caribbean (IDB-INTAL). Available at:
http://idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getdocument.aspx?docnum=36877594
Ishida, M. 2009. Special Economic Zones and Economic Corridors. ERIA Discussion
Paper Series 16/2009. Bangkok, IDE-JETRO.
Ishida, M. 2012. Emerging Economic Corridors in the Mekong Region. BRC Research
Report 8. Bangkok Research Center. Bangkok, IDE-JETRO.
Jenkins, B. 2012. Mobilizing the Southern Agricultural Growth Corridor of Tanzania.
A Case Study. The Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) Initiative at the Harvard
Kennedy School. Cambridge, Massachusetts, United States of America.
Kaarhus, R., Haug, R., Hella, J.P. & Makindara, J.R. 2010. Agro-investment in Africa
– Impact on land and livelihoods in Mozambique and Tanzania. Noragric Report
53. August. Department of International Environment and Development Studies
(Noragric), Norwegian University of Life Sciences.
Kaarhus, R. & Woodhouse, P. 2012. Development of National Producer Organizations
and Specialized Business Units in Mozambique. Noragric Report 63. January.
Department of International Environment and Development Studies (Noragric),
Norwegian University of Life Sciences.
Karlsson, C. 2008. Handbook of Research on Cluster Theory. Cheltenham, United
Kingdom, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
Katz, B. & Wagner, J. 2008. Transformative Investments. Remaking American Cities
for a New Century. ETHOS, World Cities Summit Issue, June. Singapore, Centre for
Governance and Leadership, Civil Service College.
Krugman, P. 1991. Increasing Returns and Economic Geography. J. Political Economy,
99(3): 483–499. June.
Kuncoro, M. 2013. Economic Geography of Indonesia. Can MP3EI Reduce Inter-
Regional Inequality? South East Asia Journal of Contemporary Business, Economics
and Law, 2(2). June.
Kuroiwa, I. 2012. Economic Integration and the Location of Industries. The Case of Less
Developed East Asian Countries. London, IDE-JETRO.
Lewis, O. 1969. The culture of poverty. In D.P. Moynihan, ed. On Understanding
Poverty: Perspectives from the Social Sciences, pp. 187–200. New York, Basic Books.
Lippman, S. & McCall, J. 1986. An operational measure of liquidity. American
Economic Review, 76(1): 43–55.
Bibliography 199
Luiz, J.M. 2003. The relevance, practicality and viability of spatial development
initiatives: a South African case study. Public Administration and Development, 23(5):
433–443. December.
Malik, U.S., Ahmed, M., Sombilla, M.A. & Cueno, S. L. 2009. Biofuels production for
smallholder producers in the Greater Mekong Sub-region. Applied Energy, 86: 58–68.
Manorom, K., Hall, D., Lu, X., Katima, S., Medialdia, M.T., Siharath, S. & Srisuphan,
P. 2010. Cross-border contract farming arrangements. Variations and implications in
the Lao People’s Democratic Republic. J. Greater Mekong Subregion Development
Studies, 5: 33–54. December. Manila.
Marín-Quemada, J.M., García-Verdugo, J. & Escribano, G. 2012. Energy Security for
the EU in the 21st Century. Markets, Geopolitics and Corridors. London and New
York, Routledge.
Marrian, B. 2001. Towards a general theory of corridor development in South Africa.
Paper presented at the 20th Annual South African Transport Congress, 16–20 July,
South Africa. Available at: ol.up.ac.za/upspace/bitstream/2263/8193/1/5b6.pdf
Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of Economics. London, MacMillan.
Mavrakis, D., Thomaidis, F. & Ntroukas, I. 2006. An assessment of the natural gas
supply potential of the south energy corridor from the Caspian Region to the EU.
Energy Policy 34(13): 1671-1680, February 2006.
McDonald, J. & McMillen, D. 2007. Urban Economics and Real Estate. Theory and
Practice. Hampshire, United Kingdom, Blackwell Press.
Meadowcroft, J. 2007. Who is in Charge here? Governance for Sustainable Development
in a Complex World. J. Environmental Policy & Planning, 9: 3–4.
Meeuws, R. 2004. Mozambique – Trade and Transport Facilitation Audit. Available
at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTTLF/Resources/Mozambique_Final_
Report.pdf
Menon, J. 2009. Regional efforts to create an attractive investment climate. Presentation
at the Second OECD-Southeast Asia Regional Forum “Enhancing Competitiveness
through Regional Integration”, 27–28 April, Bangkok.
Milder, J.C., Buck, L.E., Hart, A.K. & Scherr, S.J. 2012. The SAGCOT Greenprint. A
Green Growth Investment Framework for the Southern Agricultural Growth Corridor
of Tanzania. August. Dar es Salaam, United Republic of Tanzania, SAGCOT. (draft)
Miller, C. & Jones, L. 2010. Agricultural Value Chain Finance. Tools and Lessons.
Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations and Bourton on
Dunsmore, Rugby, Warwickshire, United Kingdom, Practical Action Publishing.
Ministry of Agriculture of Mozambique. 2010. Strategic Plan for Agricultural
Development. PEDSA 2010–2019. Available at: http://aec.msu.edu/fs2/mozambique//
caadp/PEDSA_FINAL-English_22_Nov.pdf
Morgan, K. 2008. Greening the Realm. Sustainable Food Chains and the Public Plate.
Regional Studies, 42(9): 1237–1250.
Myrdal, G. 1957. Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions. London, Duckworth.
Nguyen, T.N. & Ha-Duong, M. 2009. Economic potential of renewable energy in
Vietnam’s power sector. Energy Policy, 37(5): 1601–1613.
OECD. 2013. OECD Investment Policy Reviews. Tanzania. Working draft. Paris,
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
200 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
Ruben, R., Slingerland, M. & Nijhoff, H. 2006. Agro-food chains and networks for
development, 1–25. The Netherlands, Wageningen, Wageningen University and
Research Centre.
Sachs, J.D. & Warner, A.M. 1995. Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth.
Development Discussion Paper 517a. United States of America, Harvard Institute for
International Development.
Sachs, J.D. & Warner, A.M. 2001. The curse of natural resources. European Economic
Review, 45: 827–838.
SAGCOT. n.d. Southern Agricultural Growth Corridor of Tanzania. Membership
Principles and Obligations. Available at: www.sagcot.com/uploads/media/SAGCOT_
Partnership_principles.pdf
SAGCOT. 2010. Concept note. May. Available at: http://www.agdevco.com/sysimages/
sagcot_concept_note_rpt14.pdf
SAGCOT. 2011. Southern Agricultural Growth Corridor of Tanzania. Investment
Blueprint. January. Available at: http://www.sagcot.com/uploads/media/Invest-
Blueprint-SAGCOT_High_res.pdf
Sanghvi, S., Simons, R. & Uchoa, R. 2011. Four lessons for transforming African
agriculture. Mckinsey Quarterly, 1–11. April.
Shepley, S., Souksavat, O., Tola, P., Quang, T.L., Bajracharya, S.L., Sharma, S. &
Boswell, M. 2009. Developing Sustainable Pro-poor Biofuels in the Mekong Region
and Nepal. A holistic approach looking at smallholder benefits from an economic, social
and environmental point of view. SNV (Netherlands Development Organization) and
the World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF).
Shrestha, O.L. & Chongvilaivan, A. eds. 2013. Greater Mekong Subregion. From
Geographical to Socio-economic Integration. Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Singapore, ISEAS Publishing.
Sovacool, B.K. & Bulan, L.C. 2012. Energy security and hydropower development
in Malaysia. The drivers and challenges facing the Sarawak Corridor of Renewable
Energy (SCORE). Renewable Energy, 40(1): 113–129. April.
Strategic Asia. 2012. Implementing Indonesia’s Economic Master Plan (MP3EI).
Challenges, Limitations and Corridor Specific Differences. June.
Streeck, W. & Mertens, D. 2011, Fiscal Austerity and Public Investment. Is the Possible
the Enemy of the Necessary? MPIfG Discussion Paper. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/abstract=1894657
Teece, D.J. 1980. Economies of scope and the scope of the enterprise. J. Economic
Behavior and Organization 1(3): 223–247. September.
Telser, L.G. 1981. Why there are Organized Futures Markets. J. Law and Economics
XXIV(1): 1–22, April.
The Economist. 1977. “The Dutch Disease”, 26 November.
Theting, H. & Brekke, B. 2010. Land investments or land grab? A critical view from
Tanzania and Mozambique. Oslo, Spire.
Thomas, R.H. 2009. Development Corridors and Spatial Development Initiatives in
Africa. January.
Travers, R. 2008. Economic Corridor and Ecotourism. Whither Tourism in Laos? In J.
Cochrane, ed. Asian Tourism. Growth and Change. Oxford, United Kingdom, Elsevier.
202 Making economic corridors work for the agricultural sector
World Bank. 2009b. Awakening Africa’s Sleeping Giant. Prospects for Commercial
Agriculture in the Guinea Savannah Zone and Beyond. Washington, DC.
World Bank. 2010. Prospects for Growth Poles in Mozambique. The World Bank
Finance and Private Sector Development Africa Region. August. Washington, DC.
Wright, G. & Czelusca, J. 2004. The myth of the resource curse. Challenge, 47(2): 6–38.
March/April.
Yeung, H.W. 1998. Capital, State and Space. Contesting the Borderless World.
Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 23(3): 291–309.
Zola. 2009. A Preliminary Assessment of Contract Farming Arrangements and Plantations
in the Agriculture and Natural Resources Sector of Southern Lao PDR. Vientiane.
Agribusiness
and Food
Industries
Series
4
Making economic corridors work
for the agricultural sector
9 7 8 9 2 5 1 0 8 6 3 6 0
I4204E/1/11.14