Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

FDI, Trade Openness, Capital Formation, and Economic Growth in Bangladesh: A Linkage Analysis

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No.

1; January 2011

FDI, Trade Openness, Capital Formation, and Economic Growth in


Bangladesh: A Linkage Analysis

Bishnu Kumar ADHIKARY


College of International Management, Ritsumeikan Asia Pacific University
1-1, Jumonjibaru, Beppu-shi, Oita-ken, Japan
Tel: 81-977-781-034 E-mail: adhikary@apu.ac.jp
Abstract
This paper examines the linkage between FDI, trade openness, capital formation, and economic growth rates in
Bangladesh over a period 1986 to 2008 using time series analysis. All variables are found stationary at first
differencing both at constant and constant plus trend level under the ADF and PP stationary tests. The
Johansen-Juselius procedure is applied to test the cointegrating relation between variables followed by a vector
error correction model. The empirical results trace a strong long-run equilibrium relationship between GDP
growth rates and the explanatory variables with unidirectional casual flows. The volume of FDI and level of
capital formation are found to have significant positive effect on changes in real GDP. The degree of trade
openness unleashes negative but diminishing influence on GDP growth rates. We conclude that Bangladesh
should formulate FDI-led polices and ensure higher degree of capital formation to enhance her economic growth
rates at large.
Keywords: FDI, Capital formation, Trade openness, GDP growth, VECM and Bangladesh
1. Introduction
Theoretically, the linkage between foreign direct investment (FDI), trade openness, capital formation, and
economic growth tends to be positive. A number of reasons can be outlined in favor of this assertion. First, the
neoclassical and endogenous growth theories underline that FDI promotes economic growth in a capital scarce
economy by increasing volume as well as efficiency of physical investment (Romer 1986, Lucas 1988, Grosman
& Helpman 1991, Baro & Salai-I-Martin 1995). In other words, FDI supplies long-term capital with new
technologies, managerial know-how and marketing capabilities which, in turn, augment economic growth by
creating employments, increasing managerial skills, diffusing technologies and fostering innovations (Asiedu
2002). FDI can also facilitate ‘agglomeration economies’ through industry clustering and networking, and
lowering costs for all producers in the market (Krugman 1991). Pugel (2007) reports that FDI increases
technological spillover benefits, widens the scope of international competition and strengthens the supply side
capabilities of a host country for producing and selling goods and services, which lead to higher economic
growth.
Second, the degree of trade openness is likely to influence the flows of international capital in terms of
risk-return relationship. In fact, no one feels interested in committing long-term investment in a country that
imposes tariff and non-tariff barriers on investment and creates problem in repatriating capitals as well as profits.
The level of trade openness also indicates the degree of comparative advantage of a country in undertaking
investment. This view basically rests on the ‘transaction cost theory’ (Coase 1937, Williamson 1975) that
postulates a low transaction cost environment generates financial incentives (higher return on investment) for
both the domestic and foreign players in supplying large irreversible investment like FDI. Moreover, the
endogenous growth theories stress that a more open trade policy framework promotes allocative efficiency of
investment by reorienting factors of production to sectors that have comparative advantages in trade; thereby
augmenting economic growth (Solow 1956, Balasubramanyam et al. 1996). Edwards (1992) also points out that
a country with a higher degree of economic openness can grow faster by absorbing new technologies at a faster
rate than a country with a lower degree of openness.
Third, the level of capital formation is likely to influence FDI and economic growth as well. Neo-classical
growth model postulates that developing economies that have a lower initial level of capital stock tend to have
higher marginal rate of returns (productivity) and growth rates if adequate capital stock is injected. In other
words, in a capital shortage economy, the marginal productivity of investment is increased in the short-run when
additional capital is injected in the form of long-term investment like FDI, and this increased productivity

16 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

influences economic growth in the long-run. The new endogenous growth theories further postulate that the
increased efficiency of investment brought by FDI provides a comparative advantage to the capital scarce
economies to catch-up or to converge with the richer economies in the long-run (Romer 1986). Finally, FDI
channels much needed capital for investment and provides support to capital formation; trade openness
facilitates the flows of international capital and redirects factor endowments to more productive sectors; a high
level of capital formation ensures needed finance for the industries growth and development; and all of them
jointly promote economic growth at large. From this perspective, the linkage between FDI, trade openness, and
economic growth ought to be positive. Not only this, this nexus should be co-integrated in the long-run. However,
a question arises whether this nexus works equally for all developing countries, particularly in Bangladesh.
Bangladesh, in fact, opened her economy in the late 1980s to reap the benefits of FDI in order to accelerate
economic growth. The government set up Board of Investment (BOI) in 1989 to promote and facilitate private
investment both from domestic and overseas sources. The government also lifted restrictions on capital and
profit repatriation gradually and opened up almost all industrial sectors for foreigners to invest either
independently or jointly with the local partners. Further, the government introduced various financial and
non-financial incentives like tax exemptions for power generations, import duty exemptions for export
processing industries, tax holiday schemes for undertaking investment in priority sectors and low development
areas, zero duty rate for the import of capital machinery and spare parts for 100 percent export oriented
industries, almost no restrictions on the entry and exit mode, and reduction of bureaucratic hassles in getting
faster approvals of foreign projects. Together with all these incentives followed by a low labor cost structure,
Bangladesh has been an attractive destination for FDI in the South Asian region since the late 1980s.
Figure 1 (in appendix) illustrates the flows of FDI (as a percentage of GDP), degree of trade openness, level of
capital formation over GDP, and GDP growth rate in Bangladesh for a period 1986 to 2008. Figure 1 portrays
that Bangladesh has significantly opened her economy during the previous two decades from 17.57% in 1986 to
49.09% in 2008 in order to encourage cross- border transactions. Likewise, the gross capital formation as a
percentage of GDP increased consistently from 16.70% in 1986 to 24.08% in 2008. However, FDI inflow as a
percentage of GDP provides a heterogenic trend that mainly increased from 1995 (0.24%), but dropped in
1999(0.69%), reached a peak in 2005 (1.46%) and leveled off 1.39% in 2008. Similarly, with respect to GDP
growth rates, the country exhibits a heterogenic trend that varies between 2.15% to 6.62% over the period
1986-2008. This creates an interest for us to investigate empirically the long-term equilibrium relationship
among FDI, Trade openness, capital formation and GDP growth rates in Bangladesh with a view to assisting
policy making institutions. We like to note that there exists a growing body of literature that examines
individually the FDI, openness and capital led growth hypothesis in a cross-country analysis, however, a few
studies has examined economic growth led FDI, trade openness and capital formation jointly in a single study
either in the context of cross countries or an individual country.
Thus, the study contributes to the existing FDI, economic and finance literature in the following ways. First, the
study deals with one of the emerging economies in South Asia that practices democracy and market oriented
policies to enhance economic growth. Second, a country specific study removes the country specific problem
and skepticism about the robustness of economic results that are often linked with cross-section and panel
analysis. Third, the study utilizes annual time series data from 1986 to 2008 which covers recent data as well as a
period of extensive economic and financial liberalization measures undertaken by the government to attract FDI.
Fourth, it investigates the linkage between FDI, trade openness, capital formation, and economic growth which is
rarely studied in the context of Bangladesh. Finally, the study employs a new estimation technique like Vector
Autoregressive (VAR) approach to examine whether the linkage between variables is long-term, unidirectional
or bi-directional. We like to note that the data point covers 23 observations for this study which may raise small
sample bias in long-run growth analysis. However, we used here yearly observation which is considered
effective when it covers more than two decades.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 provides theoretical underpinnings and surveys the
related literature of the linkage between FDI, trade openness, capital formation, and economic growth. Section 3
describes our data and statistical model. Section 4 reports the empirical results, and finally, section 5 concludes
with some policy remarks.
2. Theoretical underpinnings and survey of related literature
The neoclassical and endogenous growth models can be considered as a theoretical foundation for FDI led
economic growth hypothesis of a country. The neoclassical growth theories assume that FDI can channel
required funds to the productive sectors of a capital shortage economy which, in turn, help increase the economic

Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education 17


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

growth rate by increasing the marginal productivity of capital. In other words, the neoclassical perspective is
based on a basic principle in economics that outlines economic growth demands capital investment in the form
of long-term commitment (Adams 2009). The neoclassical economists also view FDI as more reliable and less
volatile sources of capital for the developing economies that can augment economic growth (Blomstorm et al.
1994, Borenzstein et al. 1995, Balasubramanyam et al. 1996, Lipsey 1999, Moosa 2002, Moosa & Cardak 2006).
On the other hand, the endogenous growth theories state that the long-run growth of a country is not only
influenced by the volume of physical investment but also depends on the efficiency of utilizing investment.
Therefore, endogenous growth model focuses on incorporating organizational, managerial, technical and human
skills, innovation and technological progress, and accumulation of knowledge endogenously in the growth
theories that are often brought by FDI (Romer 1986, Lucas 1988, Mankiw et al. 1992, Pugel 2007). Precisely, in
the endogenous growth model, the long-run economic growth is viewed as a function of technological progress
deriving from technology transfers and knowledge spillovers (Grossman and Helpman 1991, Romer 1994, Nair
–Reichert and Weinhold 2001). A growing body of empirical literature also supports this FDI led endogenous
growth hypothesis. For example, Saint-Paul (1992) and Obstfeld (1994) argue that a higher volume of
cross-border transaction increases the productivity of capital by diversifying the risk of investment. Not only that,
a greater risk diversification further encourages domestic investment in innovation activities that, in turn,
influences economic growth in the long-run. This is also revealed by a study of the United Nations Conference
on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) in 1992 that examines the FDI led growth hypothesis in developing
economies. The study unearths that FDI creates a positive effect on employment, human skills and international
trade, beside the economic growth rates, for China and Taiwan. By the same token, Acemoglu and Zilibotti
(1997) explain that greater openness in international transactions helps direct financial flows from
capital-abundant towards capital-scarce countries. Such a movement of capital flows helps in accelerating the
convergence process - a system to catch the developed economies by the developing economies - of a developing
country. Zhang (2001) reports that FDI tends to promote economic growth in the Asian economies than in Latin
Americas. He further argues that FDI is likely to influence economic growth when a host country adopts
liberalized trade policies, improves education and maintains macroeconomic stability. McLean & Shrestha
(2002) also report that FDI exerts significant influence on economic growth in developing economies than in the
developed economies. They document that in developing economies, a 1 per cent increase in FDI can increase
GDP per capita growth rates by approximately 0.5 percentage point on an average (Adhikary & Mengistu 2008).
Recently, Nath (2009) reports that economic growth calls for investing sufficient capital where FDI plays a
two-fold function: (1) contributes to capital accumulation and (2) increases the total productivity of investment.
Despite this positive link between FDI and economic growth, empirical evidence also reveals negative
association between them. This view goes to the dependency theorists who argue that dependence on foreign
investment tends to create a negative impact on economic growth and income distribution. The underlying
assumption behind the dependency theory is that an economy controlled by foreigners does not develop
organically rather grows in a disarticulated manner (Amin 1974). This happens because of the multiplier effect
which shows that the demand elasticity between two sectors is less than unitary, thereby directing to stagnant
growth rates in the developing countries (Adams 2009). The dependency theories also argue that foreign gigantic
players may create negative effect on the growth and development of domestic firms’ of a host country in the
long-run as they have large volume of capital, superior technologies, higher market access, advanced marketing
networks and better managerial and human relation skills (Marksun & Venables 1997, Agosin & Mayer 2000,
Kumar & Pradhan 2002). This situation could be even dismal for the limited capital young growing firms as they
may be unable to compete with the Multinational Corporations (MNCs). Further, this imbalanced competition
may possibly lead to the extinction of such small local firms. In this tune, Bornschier & Chase–Dunn (1985)
claim that FDI tends to create a monopoly industrial structure which may lead to ‘underutilization of productive
forces’. The dependency theories further argue that FDI can have an adverse impact on employment, income
distribution, national sovereignty and autonomy of a country (Musila and Sigue 2006). FDI can also influence
negatively the balance-of-payment position of a country if the inputs of production need to be imported (Musila
and Sigue 2006). Moreover, financial stability of a country may reduce by shrinking foreign exchange reserves
when profits and capitals are repatriated. Thus, dependency theories argue that FDI is not an aid to the
development rather it undermines the process of development (Razin et al. 1999). This confounding theoretical
and empirical evidence on FDI and economic growth leads us to conclude that FDI is country specific, and can
be positive, negative or insignificant, depending on the economic, technological and institutional conditions of a
host country.
With respect to the link between trade openness and economic growth, the endogenous growth theory (Romer
1986, Lucas 1988), transaction cost theory (Coase 1937, Williamson 1981) and international product life cycle

18 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

theory (Vernon 1966) can be put into place. According to the endogenous growth theory, a more open trade
regime allows a country to reorient factors of production in sectors that have comparative advantages. As
factor endowments are better utilized due to trade openness, the endogenous theory also underlines that a higher
equilibrium growth rate can be achieved in the long-run through increasing specialization and lowering cost of
inputs (Romer 1989). Solow (1957) reports that trade openness can create a room for technological progress and
efficiency in allocating inputs by eliminating protection for import substitution industries which, in turn,
influences economic growth. Grossman & Helpman (1991), and Barro & Sala-I-Martin (1995) mention that a
country with a higher degree of openness has a greater ability to absorb technological developments generated in
the leading nations, and this absorption capability leads them to grow more rapidly than a country with a lower
degree of openness. However, Edwards (1998) argues that the equilibrium rate of growth in the poorer countries
does not solely depend on openness rather on its initial stock of knowledge and the cost of imitations. Edwards
(1998) also argues that if the imitation cost of innovation in the poorer countries becomes lower than the cost of
innovation in technologically advanced economies, the poorer countries will grow faster than the advanced one,
and there will be a tendency towards convergence. This hypothesis basically complements the transaction cost
theory that postulates market for intermediary products are usually imperfect, and firms, as an economic agent,
need to incur certain costs to complete a transaction. Importantly, this transaction cost can be minimized when
markets are integrated both at the national and international levels through greater openness, or in particular,
through free trade. In addition, a reduction in the transaction cost provides opportunity for the developing
economies to gain larger access to the international markets, and this helps them to increase foreign exchange
reserves through increasing exports. Clearly, a higher degree of openness reduces transaction cost of investment
and influences economic growth by increasing investment and exports. This hypothesis can also be extended to
the international product life cycle theory proposed by Vernon in 1966. According to the product life cycle
theory, a high-income elastic product is usually used as a symbol of fashion and prestige by the upper class
people of a developing economy. This product becomes a middle class product when it enjoys economies of
scale. As products become standardized, firms tend to relocate their production in less capital intensive and low
transaction cost economies with a view to exporting them to richer countries. In other words, the product life
cycle theory explains that, other things being equal, the faster the rate of innovation in advanced economies, the
higher the scope of growth via imitation for laggard economies. Precisely, the higher the technology flows from
the leader to the follower via trade openness (international trade), ceteris paribus, the faster the diffusion process
is likely to be (Baumol et al. 1994). Obviously, a faster rate of technology absorptions and diffusions helps
accumulate technical and human skills that ultimately contribute to growth in the long-run. To this end, World
Bank (1993) studies 51 countries over a period 1960-89 and concludes that economic openness has a statistically
positive impact on the total factor productivity (TFP) growth. World Bank (2001) in its global development
finance edition also reports the importance of absorptive capacities for the success of FDI in Malaysia and
Taiwan. Likewise, Acemoglu & Zilibotti (1997) explain that the economically backward countries can accelerate
convergence process to catch richer economies by opening up their capital markets as capital usually moves
from capital-abundant towards capital-scarce economies. In effect, economic growth rates are enhanced in the
long-run.
However, counter arguments of the positive link between trade openness and economic growth can also be found
in empirical literature. For instance, Rodrik (1992) reports that economic openness may bring macroeconomic
instability by increasing inflation, depreciating exchange rates and inviting balance of payment crisis. Similarly,
Levine & Renelt (1992), and Andriamananjara & Nash (1997) report that a high degree of trade openness may
increase inflation and lower the real exchange rates which may create negative impact on domestic investment.
In other words, a liberalized trade regime may lead to a greater exchange rate depreciation which may reduce
aggregate supply of inputs by increasing prices of the imported inputs used in the production. As a result, the
volume of domestic output tends to be decreased. By the same token, Krugman (1994) argues that the effect of
openness on economic growth could be, at best, very tenuous, and at worst, doubtful. The argument in this case
is that the degree of trade openness, particularly the magnitude of tariff and non-tariff barriers, only can affect
the volume of trade, not necessarily the link between exports, imports, and economic growth. However, we
would like to note that these conflicting findings basically rest on different measurement of trade openness used
by researchers in a cross-country analysis. A country specific data analysis thus deserves attention to capture the
impact of specific problems and policies of a particular country in order to enrich our FDI literature with new
evidence.
Although empirical literature does not have consensus in tracing the link between trade openness and the
economic growth, a more conclusive views is found with respect to the capital accumulation and economic
growth. Both the classical and neo-classical growth model postulates that capital is nucleus to economic growth.

Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education 19


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Simply, if there is no capital, there is no investment and no growth. The rationale to this argument is that capital
accumulation helps expand productive capacity of different economic sectors by increasing number of firms.
When a number of firms engage into production or business activities, internal resources of a country are better
utilized through increasing competition and efficiency. As a result, the productivity of factor endowments is
increased and a low production cost can be achieved through greater economies of scale as well as
standardization of products. Precisely, capital accumulation helps increase investment, investment creates
employment through expanding production bases, additional employment generates higher savings which
provide confidence in undertaking larger investment, and this chain effect ultimately influences economic
returns positively. In tune with this, the proponents of endogenous growth theories argue that FDI can play a
substantial role in building capital formation by increasing funds and supplying of needed technology and skills,
which, in general, promote economic growth. In empirical analysis, Kormendi & Meguire (1985), Barro (1991),
Levine and Renalt (1992) conclude that the rate of physical capital formation influences the rate of a country’s
economic growth. In contrast, Kendrick (1993) notes that the formation of capital alone does not lead to
economic prosperity, rather the efficiency in allocating capital from less productive to more productive sectors
influences economic growth. Blomstorm et al. (1996) also note a one way causal relationship between fixed
investment and economic growth. They conclude that changes in capital formation rates do not have any
significant influence on future growth rates. On the other hand, Ghali & Al-Mutawa (1999) apply time series
analysis on G-7 countries and report that the causality between fixed investment (capital formation) and
economic growth is country specific and may run in both directions.
In summary, the empirical literature on the linkage between FDI, trade openness, capital formation, and
economic growth does not provide a consensus with its theoretical relationship as many authors document
positive relationship between them while others do not trace it, or at best, report very week relationship. These
wide differences basically result from authors’ perspectives, sample selection, methodologies and analytical
tools applied in their study (Chakrabarti 2001). Besides, the country specific characteristics with respect to the
economical, technological, infrastructural and institutional developments indeed matter a lot to gauze empirical
relationship. The present study thus extends a country specific analysis to add knowledge in our empirical
literature.
3. Data descriptions and empirical designs
In this paper, we seek to trace the relationship between FDI, trade openness, capital formation, and economic
growth in the context of Bangladesh over a period 1986-2008. In doing so, we consider changes in real GDP as
an indicator of economic growth. FDI is standardized by GDP to remove the problem associated with absolute
measurement. Trade openness is measured by export and import over GDP following Gries et al. (2009) and
Yanikkaya (2003). Capital formation is expressed as a percentage of gross fixed capital formation over GDP.
This measure is also adopted by Ghali & Al-Mutawa (1999), Levine & Renelt (1992), and Barro (1991). Data
have been gleaned from World Development Indicators published by World Bank.
As part of the empirical design, our base estimating equation in log-linear form is specified as follows:
lnYt =  +  lnFDIGt +  lnGFCGt + lnTGDPt + t --------------------(1)
Where, Y = changes in real GDP, FDIG = foreign direct investment as a percentage of GDP, GFCG = gross
fixed capital formation over GDP, and TGDP = trade over GDP. There are two reasons why variables are
converted into natural logs. First, the coefficients of the cointegrating vector can be interpreted as long-term
elasticities if the variables are in logs. Second, if the variables are in logs, the first difference can be interpreted
as growth rates. The expected signs of the parameters are: >0, >0, >0 and >0. The error-term () is
assumed to be independently and identically distributed. The subscript (t) indexes time.
For execution of the empirical design, we proceed as follows. First, the nature of the data distribution is
examined by using the standard descriptive statistics (mean, median, standard deviation, skewness and kurtosis).
Normality of data distribution is also ascertained by invoking the Jarque–Bera test. Second, the time series
property of each variable is investigated under a univariate analysis by implementing the ADF (Augmented
Dickey- Fuller) test for the unit root (nonstationarity) (following Dickey and Fuller 1981, Fuller 1996). Likewise,
the PP (Phillips-Perron) test is also implemented (following Phillips 1986, Phillips & Perron 1988, Perron 1989).
Third, if these tests confirm stationarity in time series data of each variable, equation (1) is estimated
appropriately by the Ordinary Least Square (OLS) method. Otherwise, its application leads to misleading
inferences in the presence of spurious correlation (Granger & Newbold 1974). These tests are conducted with
and without a deterministic trend (t) for each of the series. The general form of ADF test is estimated by the
following regression:

20 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Yt = 0 + 1Yt-1 + Yi + t --------------------------------------------(2)


Yt = 0 + 1Yt-1 + Yi + t + t -------------------------------------(3)
Where, Y is a time series, t is a linear time trend,  is first difference operator, 0 is a constant, n is the optimum
number of lags in the dependent variable and  is a random error term. The Philip-Perron (PP) equation is thus:
Yt = 0 + 1Yt-1 + t ---------------------------------------------(4)
Fourth, in the event of the nonstationarity of each variable, the cointegrating relationship among variables
(tendency for variables to move together in the long-run) is studied by the Johansen-Juselius procedure
(Johansen 1988, Johansen-Juselius 1992, 1999) to overcome the associated problem of spurious correlation and
misleading inferences. The basic idea behind cointegration is that if two or more series move together in the
long-run, even though the series themselves are trended, the difference between them is stationary, and it is
possible to regard these series to have a long-run equilibrium relationship. For cointegration, however, all the
variables must be in the same order of integration or depiction of I(d) behavior. To implement, the Vector
Autoregressive (VAR) approach is invoked as outlined in Granger (1988).The appropriate lag-length (p) is
selected with the aid of the FPE (Final Prediction Error) criterion (Akaike 1969) to ensure that errors are white
noise. This helps overcome the problem of over/under parameterization that may induce bias and inefficiency in
the estimates. The analysis commences with a congruent statistical system of unrestricted reduced forms as
follows:
Yt = D + Yt-i + t; t ~ IN (0,
), i=1, 2, 3, ----T _------------------(5)
Where, Yt is an (n u 1) vector of I (1) and /or 1(0) variables, and D is an (n u 1) vector of constraints.
Letting Yt = Yt - Yt-1, a convenient reparameterization of equation (5) is placed below:
Yt = D+ Yt-i + Y t-i + t -----------------------------------------------(6)
Since t is stationary, the rank, r, of the long–run matrix
determines how many linear combinations of Yt are
stationary. If r = n, all Yt’s are stationary, while r = 0 so that
=0, Yt is stationary, as are all linear
combinations if Yt ~ I (1). For 0<1<n, there exist r cointegrating vectors meaning r stationary linear combinations
of Yt. If this is the case,
= D  , where both D and  are n u r matrices. The cointegrating vectors of  are
/

the error-correction mechanisms in the system, while D contains the adjustment parameters. The
cointegrating rank, r, can be formally tested with maximum eigenvalue test ( O max) and the trace test ( O trace).
These are computed as follows: š
O max = --T ln(1- O r+1) ------------------------------(7)
Where, the appropriate null is r = g cointegrating vectors with (g = 0,1,2,3,---) against the alternative that r
g+1.
O trace = --T i) ----------------------(8)

Where, the null is r =g against the more general alternative r 1.


In the Johansen-Juselius procedure, O max and O trace tests are conducted. For any conflict between these tests,
the final selection lies with the discretion of the researchers in view of their trade offs for bias, efficiency and
sample size.
Finally, on the evidence of cointegrating relationship, a vector error-correction model (VECM) is estimated to
model the long-run causality and short-term dynamics. The purpose of VECM model is to indicate the speed of
adjustment from the short-run equilibrium to the long-run equilibrium state. The greater the coefficient of the
parameter, the higher is the speed of adjustment of the model from the short-run to the long-run. Considering our
base equation (1), The VECM model is specified as follows:
lnYt = D + et-1+ lnYt-i + lnFDIGt-i +
lnGFCGt-i + lnTGDPt-i + t -------------------------------------------------(9)

In this specification, the variables are cointegrated if the parameter ( ) of the error correction term is negative
and statistically significant in terms of its associated-t value. This indicates unidirectional long-run causal flows
from changes in FDI, capital formation and openness to real GDP changes in Bangladesh as well as long-run
convergence. Changes in FDI, capital formation and trade openness Granger cause the changes in economic
growth rates when ci’s, di’s and ei’s are significant in terms of the F- test (Bahmani & Payesteh, 1993). In case of
O being positive and statistically significant, still there exists a long-run causality but with a divergence.
Besides, impulse response analysis is performed in this study by giving a shock of one standard deviation ( r 2
S.E. innovations) to FDI, capital formation and trade openness to visualize the duration of their effects on the

Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education 21


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

GDP growth rates of Bangladesh. In the end, a variance decomposition analysis is conducted to gain additional
insights.
4. Empirical Results and Main Findings
According to our empirical design outlined in section four, we document the following results:
4.1 Descriptive Statistics
The variables under study are found to be normally distributed (appendix, table 1). The mean-to-median ratio of
each variable is approximately one. The standard deviation is also low compared to the mean, showing a small
coefficient of variation. The range of variation between maximum and minimum is also reasonable. The numeric
of skewness of each variable is low and is mildly negatively skewed. The figure for kurtosis in each variable,
except the LnGDPG, is below 3 which confirms near normality. The Jarque-Bera test statistics also accept the
null hypothesis of normal distribution of each variable, except the LnGDPG, with varying probabilities.
However, the histogram normality test supports normality of the distribution within 10% level (Jarque-Bera
4.8541 with associated P-value 0.08829). The Breusch–Pagan-Godfrey test reveals homoskedasticity
(Obs*R-squared 5.04122 with associated P-value 0.1688) of the distribution. Likewise, Breusch–Godfrey serial
correlation test reveals no autocorrelation among the variables (Obs*R-squared 1.5931 with associated P-value
0.4509). Thus, the normality of the distribution is ensured in the study.
4.2 Stationarity results
All the variables under ADF and PP tests (except LnY that is found stationary at constant and trend) are found
nonstationary in levels (appendix, table 2&3). This is ensured by comparing the calculated ADF and PP statistics
at the 1 per cent and 5 per cent significance levels with their respective critical values. As a result, all the
variables have been differenced once to check their stationarity. At first differencing, the calculated ADF and PP
tests statistics clearly reject the null hypothesis of unit root both at the 1 per cent and 5 per cent significance
levels when compared with their corresponding critical values. Clearly, the ADF and PP tests decisively confirm
stationarity of each variable at first differencing under both constant and constant plus trend level, and depict the
same order of integration, i.e. I (1) behavior. Consequently, the Johansen-Juselius procedure is implemented as
outlined in equation (5) to detect the cointegrating relationship among variables.
4.3 Co-integration results
Table 4 (in appendix) presents the result of Johansen co-integration test both at the trace and maximum eigenvalue
levels. Accordingly, both the trace and maximum eigenvalue statistics detect one cointegrating relationship at the
5% level ((panel 4(a) and 4(b)). In other words, these tests indicate the presence of a long-run equilibrium
relationship among variables. As a result, the vector error correction model (9) is estimated.
4.4 Vector error correction model (VECM)
The vector error correction model confirms a long-run equilibrium relationship among the variables where a
unidirectional long-term causal flow runs from changes in FDI, capital formation and trade openness to the GDP
growth rates of Bangladesh (appendix, Table 5). This is revealed by the estimated coefficient ( ) of the error
correction term (e^t-1) which is negative, as expected and statistically significant in terms of its associated t-value.
The changes in lagged FDI and capital formation have positive significant effects on real GDP growth. However,
trade openness exerts significant negative, but diminishing effect on the economic growth rates. This is revealed
from the negative sum of the coefficients of subsequent lagged trade openness values. The reason behind the
negative relationship between trade openness and economic growth rates is probably due to high imports and
depreciating exchange rates of Bangladesh which has created negative trade balance position in almost all the
years covered in the study. The numeric of adjusted R2 at 0.8244 shows a very high explanatory power of the
model. The F statistics at 10.915 suggest that a moderate interactive feedback effect exists within the system.
The significance of F statistics further indicates Granger causality among variables. The optimum number of lags
is determined by the AIC criterion, as stated earlier.
4.5 Impulse response and variance decomposition
Figure 2 (in appendix) reports impulse responses. It shows how a one-time positive shock of one standard
deviation (± 2 S. E. innovations) to the FDI, capital formation and trade openness endures on the economic
growth rates of Bangladesh. A cursory examination of Figure 2 (a) in appendix shows that the impulse response
of trade openness on GDP growth rates is positive and mildly increases as time passes on. Likewise, figure 2(b)
in appendix reveals that the initial positive shock given to the capital formation raises economic growth rates
from the second year and peaks at approximately 0.25% somewhere between the sixth and seventh years.

22 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Thereafter, it declines but remains positive. Figure 2(c), however, unearths positive but diminishing influence on
changes in real GDP over time. Overall, the impulse response function traces positive influence of the response
variables on the GDP growth rates of Bangladesh.
The variance decomposition outputs are reported in table 6 (appendix). We document that the variance of GDP
growth rates is always caused by 100 per cent by itself in the first year. In the second year, the GDP growth
variance is decomposed into its own variance (64.48%) followed by FDI (22.84%) and level of capital formation
(12.66%). However, in subsequent years, the share of GDP growth rates remains constant to approximately 56%
followed by the volume of FDI and degree of capital accumulation (26% and 12% respectively). On the other
hand, the share of trade openness in explaining the variation of real GDP increases gradually from the second
year, and remains constant to 7% from the fifth year onwards. In summary, the volatility of GDP growth rates is
mainly caused by its own variation, as it always accounts for major portion (above 50%) of the fluctuations.
5. Concluding remarks
This study investigates the linkage between FDI, trade openness, capital formation, and economic growth rates
empirically in the context of Bangladesh by analyzing time series data for a period 1986-2008. Based on the
evidence from the trace ( trace) and maximum eigenvalue ( max) statistics, the study reveals a strong long-run
equilibrium relationship among the variables. A strong unidirectional long-term causal flow is evidenced
stemming from changes in FDI, trade openness and capital formation to the economic growth rates of
Bangladesh. The significance of lagged response variables followed by F statistics further indicates joint
significance of the explanatory variables to cause Granger causality in the system. Precisely, the volume of FDI
and level of capital formation reveal significant positive effects on changes in real GDP. This result approves our
theoretical linkage between them, and favors international finance and neoclassical growth theories. The results
also support the study of Kormendi & Meguire (1985), Barro (1991), Levine & Renalt (1992) that report positive
influence between the rate of physical capital formation and the rate of a country’s economic growth. In contrast,
trade openness shows significant negative, but diminishing effect on the rates of economic growth. This result
contradicts our theoretical positive relationship hypothesis between them, but supports the study of Levine and
Renelt (1992), and Krugman (1994) that trace insignificant or negative relationship. In Bangladesh, the negative
association between the trade openness and economic growth rates perhaps due to the exchange rate depreciation,
large volume of imported materials and negative trade balance position. The impulse response function reveals a
mild positive influence of the response variables on the GDP growth rates of Bangladesh. Finally, the variance
decomposition analysis unearths that the variation in the GDP growth rates is predominantly feed on its own
variance followed by the volume of inward FDI and the level of capital formation as well. Trade openness,
however, provides less importance, as compared to FDI and degree of capital formation, in changing GDP
growth rates. The policy implications of this study are relatively simple. The volume of international capital and
the magnitude of capital formation, in general, being the robust determinants of economic growth, it is expected
that the government of Bangladesh should provide more emphasis of the above factors to increase its economic
growth. Side by side, the government should formulate export led fiscal and monetary policies to increase its
exports as well as rates of GDP growth.
References
Acemoglu, D., & Zilibotti, F. (1997). Was Prometheus unbound by chance? Risk, diversification and growth.
Journal of Political Economy, 105(4), 709–51.
Adams, S. (2009). Foreign direct investment, domestic investment, and economic growth in Sub-Saharan Africa.
Journal of Policy Modeling, 31, 939-949.
Adhikary, B.K., & Mengistu, A.A. (2008). Factors influencing foreign direct investment (FDI) in “South”
and“Southeast” economies. The Journal of World Investment and Trade, 9(5): 427-437.
Agosin, M.R., & Mayer, R. (2000). Foreign investment in developing countries: does it crowd in domestic
investment? UNCTAD Discussion Paper 146, Geneva, Switzerland.
Akaike, H. (1969). Fitting autoregression for prediction. Annals of the Institute of Mathematical Statistical, 21,
243-247.
Amin, S. (1974). Accumulation on a World Scale: A Critique of the Theory of Underdevelopment. New York,
Monthly Review Press.
Andriamananjara, S., & Nash, J. (1997). Have trade policy reforms led to greater openness in developing
countries? World Bank Working Paper Series, 1730.

Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education 23


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Asiedu, E. (2002). On the determinants of foreign direct investment developing counties: Is Africa different?
World Development, 30 (1), 107-119.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M. & Payesteh, S. (1993). Budget deficits and the value of the dollar: an application of
cointegration and error-correction modeling. Journal of Macro Economics, 15, 661-667.
Balasubramanyam, V.N., Salisu, M., & Sapsford, D.(1996). Foreign Direct Investment and Growth in EP and IS
Countries. The Economic Journal, 106 (434), 92-105.
Barro, R.J. (1991). Economic growth in cross section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106,
407-444.
Barro, R.J., & Sala-I-Martin, X. (1995). Capital mobility in neoclassical models of growth. American Economic
Review, 85,103-115.
Baumol, William. J., Nelson, R.R., & Wolf, E.N. (1994). Convergence of Productivity: Cross National Studies
and Historical Evidence. New York: Oxford University Press.
Blomstrom, M., Robert, E., Lipsey, R., & Mario, Z. (1994a). What explains the growth of developing countries?
In Baumol, J.William, R. R. Nelson, & W. N. Edward (Eds.), International Convergence of Productivity.
London: Oxford University Press. 243-259.
---------------------------- (1996b). Is fixed investment the key to economic growth? Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 111(1), 269-276.
Borensztein, E. J., Gregorio, & Lee, J. W. (1995). How does foreign direct investment affect economic growth?
NBER Working Paper 5057.
Bornschier, V., & Chase – Dunn, C. (1985) Transnational Corporations and Underdevelopment. Praeger: New
York.
Chakrabarti, A. (2001). The determinants of foreign direct investment: Sensitivity analysis of cross-country
regression, Kyklos, 54(1), 89-113.
Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Econometrica, 4, 386-405.
Dickey, D.A., & Fuller, W.A. (1981). Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root.
Econometrica, 49, 1057-1072.
Edwards, S. (1992a). Trade orientation, distortions and growth in developing countries. Journal of Development
Economies, 39, 31-57.
----------------(1998b). Openness, productivity and growth: What do we really know? Economic Journal,
108(447): 383-398.
Fuller, W.A. (1996). Introduction to Statistical Time Series. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Ghali, K.H., & Al-Mutawa, A. (1999). The intertemporal causal dynamics between fixed capital formation and
economic growth in the group of seven countries. International Economic Journal, 13(2), 31-37.
Granger, C.W.J. (1988). Some recent developments in a concept of causality. Journal of Econometrics, 39,
199-211.
Granger, C.W.J., and P, Newbold. (1974). Spurious regressions in econometrics. Journal of Econometrics, 2,
111-120.
Gries, T., Kraft, M., & Meierrieks, D. (2009). Linkages between financial deepening, trade openness and
economic development: causality evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 37(12), 1849-1860.
Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Johansen, S. (1988). Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12,
231-254.
Johansen, S., and K, Juselius (1992a). Testing structural hypothesis in multivariate cointegration analysis of the
PPP and VIP for U.K. Journal of Econometrics, 211-244.
------------------------(1999b). Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration with applications to
the demand for money. Oxford Bulletin of Statistics, 169-210.
Kendrick, J.W. (1993). How much does capital explain? In A. Szirmai, B. Van Ark & D. Pilat (Eds.), Explaining
Economic Growth. Essays in Honour of Angus Maddison. Amsterdam: North Holland. 129-146.

24 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Kormendi, R. C., & Meguire P. G. (1985). Macroeconomic determinants of growth: Cross-country evidence.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 16, 141-163.
Kumar, N., & Pradhan, J. P. (2002). Foreign direct investment, externalities and economic growth in developing
countries: some empirical explorations and implications for WTO negotiations on investment. RIS Discussion
Papers 27/2002, New Delhi.
Krugman, P. (1991a). Geography and Trade. Leuven University Press: Leuven.
--------------- (1994b). The myth of Asia’s miracle. Foreign Affairs, 62-78.
Levine, R., & Renelt, D. (1992). A sensitivity analysis of cross-country regressions. The American Economic
Review, 82(4), 942-963.
Lipsey, R. E. (1999). The role of FDI in international capital flows. In M. Feldstein (Eds.), International Capital
Flows. Chicago University Press: Chicago. 307–331.
Lucas, R.E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3-42.
Mankiw, N.G., David, R., & David, N.W.(1992). A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, CVII, 407-438.
Marksun, J.R., & Venables, A.J. (1997). Foreign direct investment as a catalyst for industrial development.
NBER Working Paper 624, Cambridge.
McLean, B., & Shrestha, S. (2002). International financial liberalization and economic growth. Research
Discussion Paper 03, Reserve Bank of Australia.
Moosa, I. A. (2002). Foreign Direct Investment: Theory, Evidence and Practice. Palgrave: London.
Moosa, I. A., & Cardak, B.A. (2006). The determinants of foreign direct investment: An extreme bound analysis.
Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 16, 199-211.
Musila, J.W., & Sigue, P.S. (2006). Accelerating foreign direct investment flow to Africa: from policy
statements to successful strategies. Managerial Finance, 32(7): 577-593.
Nair-Reichert, U., & Weinhold, D. (2001). Causality test for cross country panels: a new look at FDI and
economic growth in developing countries. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 63(2), 153-171.
Nath, H. K. (2009). Trade, foreign direct invest, and growth: evidence from transition economies. Comparative
Economic Studies, 51, 20-50.
Obstfeld, M. (1994). Evaluating risky consumption paths: the role of inter-temporal substitutability. European
Economic Review, 38 (7), 1471-1486.
Perron, P. (1989). The great crash, the oil price shock and the unit root hypothesis. Econometrics, LVII:
1361-1402.
Phillips, P.C.B. (1986). Understanding spurious regression in econometrics. Journal of Econometric, XXXIII,
311-40.
Philips, P.C.B., & Perron, P. (1988). Testing for a unit root in time series regressions. Biometrica, LXXV,
335-46.
Paugel, A. T. (2007). International Economics. McGraw-Hill Irwin: New York, USA.
Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Yuen, C. (1999). Excessive FDI under asymmetric information. NBER Working Paper
7400, Cambridge.
Rodrik, D. (1992). The limits of trade policy reforms in developing countries. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 6(1), 87-105.
Romer, P. M. (1986a). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 95(5), 1002-1037.
---------------- (1989b).What determines the rate of growth and technological change. World Bank Working Paper,
279.
----------------- (1994). The origin of endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1):3-22.
Sahoo, P. (2006). Foreign direct investment in South Asia: policy, trends, impact and determinants. ADB
Institute Discussion Paper, 56, ADB: Manila.
Saint-Paul, G. (1992). Technological choice, financial markets, and economic development. European Economic
Review, 36 (4), 763-781.

Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education 25


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Solow, R.M. (1956a). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70,
65-94.
------------------- (1957b). Technical change and the aggregate production. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39,
312-320.
UNCTAD. (1992). Transnational corporations as engines of growth. World Investment Report, New York:
United Nations.
Vernon, R. (1966). International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 80(2), 190-207.
Williamson, O.E. (1975a). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: The Free
Press.
----------------------- (1981b). The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach. The American
Journal of Sociology, 87(3), 548-577.
World Bank. (1993a). The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. Oxford University Press:
USA.
---------------- (2001b). Global Development Finance 2001: Building Coalitions for Effective Development
Finance. www.worldbank.org.
Yanikkya, H. (2003). Trade openness and economic growth: a cross country empirical investigation. Journal of
Development Economies, 72, 57-89.
Zhang, K. H. L. (2001). Does foreign direct investment promote economic growth? Evidence from East Asia and
Latin America. Contemporary Economic Policy, 19, 175-85.
Appendix
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics
LNGDPG LNFDIG LNGFCG LNTGDP
Mean 1.559156 4.108411 3.008771 3.336558
Median 1.617234 5.733730 3.031238 3.401585
Maximum 1.891505 6.990533 3.204802 3.893677
Minimum 0.769739 -1.386294 2.773604 2.849156
Std. Dev. 0.282751 2.676347 0.157778 0.332852
Skewness -1.289908 -0.579275 -0.153181 -0.043030
Kurtosis 4.284243 1.777516 1.397786 1.743775
Jarque-Bera 7.958695 2.718509 2.550074 1.519446
Probability 0.018698 0.256852 0.279421 0.467796
Table 2. ADF unit root test for stationarity
Level First Difference
Constant Constant and Trend Constant Constant and Trend
LnY -1.79788 -4.96125*** -7.07823*** -6.87831***
LnFDI -0.93837 -1.9294 -5.88046*** -5.73292***
LnGFCG -2.12551 -0.125224 -3.82921*** -4.06575**
LnTGDP 0.03210 -2.55446 -5.45606*** -5.31637***
Table 3. PP unit root test for stationarity
Level First Difference
Constant Constant and Trend Constant Constant and Trend
LnY -2.47665 -5.13399** -15.8572*** -15.1582***
LnFDI -0.83553 -1.95249 -5.86517*** -5.72174***
LnGCFG -0.53433 -1.67153 -3.80658*** -4.0657**
LnTGDP 0.185644 -2.57981 -5.46239*** -5.32052***
Note: The Mackinnon (1996) critical values are -3.699871 and -2.976263 at 1 per cent and 5 per cent levels of
significance, respectively. *** indicates significance at the 1% level while ** at the 5% level.

26 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Table 4. Johansen Multivariate Co-integration Test


Panel: 4(a)
Hypothesized No. of CE(s) Eigen Value Trace Statistic 5 Percent Critical P- Value
Value
None* 0.817067 57.08819 47.85613 0.0054
At most 1 0.525830 21.41690 29.79707 0.3322
At most 2 0.202818 5.746936 15.49471 0.7252
*denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 5% level
Trace test indicates one cointegrating equation at the 5% level.

Panel: 4(b)
Hypothesized No. of Eigen Value Max-Eigen 5 Percent Critical P- Value
CE(s) Statistic Value
None* 0.817067 35.67129 27.58434 0.0037
At most 1 0.525830 15.66996 21.13162 0.2447
At most 2 0.202818 4.760118 14.26460 0.7718
*denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 5% level
Max-eigenvalue test indicates one cointegrating equation at the 5% level.

Table 5. Estimates of VECM


Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-statistic Prob.
C -0.150284 0.068198 -2.203632 0.0334
^t-1 -0.182232 0.038935 -4.680459 0.0000
LnY(-1) -0.867117 0.262642 -3.301520 0.0020
LnY(-2) -0.495819 0.158338 -3.131394 0.0032
LnFDIG(-1) 0.198331 0.091388 2.170219 0.0360
LnFDIG(-2) 0.129342 0.052035 2.485652 0.0172
LnGFCG(-1) 15.89569 3.657879 4.345603 0.0001
LnGFCG(-2) 6.026766 2.553032 2.360630 0.0232
LnTGDP(-1) -3.861557 0.886831 -4.354331 0.0001
LnTGDP(-2) -2.502552 0.732334 -3.417226 0.0015
R-squared 0.907609 Mean dependent var 0.052822
Adjusted R-squared 0.824456 S.D. dependent var 0.272519
S.E. of regression 0.114180 Akaike AIC -1.19523
Sum squared resid 0.130370 Schwarz SC -0.69736
Log likelihood 21.95230 F-statistic 10.9150
Durbin-Watson stat 1.812184 Prob (F statistic) 0.01447

Table 6. Estimates of variance decomposition of GDP growth rates


Period S.E. LnGDPG LnFDIG LnGFCG LnTGDP
1 0.155968 100.0000 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000
2 0.194226 64.48479 22.84152 12.66434 0.009343
3 0.209479 55.66875 26.11899 12.96792 5.244346
4 0.212282 55.75105 25.64782 12.62782 5.973311
5 0.215623 55.24734 24.89778 12.47488 7.380003
6 0.218325 55.08025 24.99665 12.35383 7.569264
7 0.221545 55.17349 25.11277 12.04392 7.669815
8 0.224446 55.61204 25.01953 11.78260 7.585828
9 0.226923 56.05718 24.91642 11.59775 7.428651
10 0.229185 56.32750 24.74352 11.44226 7.486719

Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education 27


www.ccsenet.org/ijbm International Journal of Business and Management Vol. 6, No. 1; January 2011

Figure 1. FDI over GDP, trade openness, Gross capital formation over GDP and GDP
growth rate in Bangladesh (1986 -2008)
Response of LnTGDP to LnY Response of LnGFCG to LnY Response of LnFDI to LnY

.12 .07 1.2

.10 .06

.05 0.8
.08
.04
.06
0.4
.03
.04
.02
0.0
.02
.01
.00
.00 -0.4
-.02 -.01

-.04 -.02 -0.8


1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

(a) (b) (c)


Figure 2. Response to Cholesky one SD (± 2 S.E. innovations)

28 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119

You might also like