Welfarestate in Historical Perspective
Welfarestate in Historical Perspective
Welfarestate in Historical Perspective
http://journals.cambridge.org/EUR
Asa Briggs
ain but even more markedly in other parts of the world, a small
number of British historians and sociologists have begun to make
a more searching examination of the "background" and "benefits"
of the "welfare state". As a result of their continuing labours,
the significance of each of the great "turning points" of British
"welfare state" history is already being re-assessed. The stark
contrast between the nineteenth arid twentieth centuries has been
qualified. Landmark legislation such as the National Health Insur-
ance Act of 1911, which hitherto had been treated generally or
symbolically, has been re-interpreted in the light of newly discov-
ered or hitherto neglected evidence. The pressures have been
more carefully scrutinized, and the setbacks have been examined
as well as the successes. Many of the "reforms" were designed as
remedies for specific problems : they were certainly not thought
of as contributions to a "trend" or a "movement". The sources
of inspiration were multiple—socialism was only one of several
strands—and this very multiplicity added to later complications
and confusions. The old poor law, from which social services
emerged both directly and by reaction, was not so much broken
up, as its critics had wished, as eroded away by depression, war,
unemployment and the introduction piecemeal of remedial legisla-
tion. The social welfare legislation of the Labour government
of 1945-50, the climax of fifty years of social and political history,
has itself begun to be viewed historically. The pre-suppositions
which underlay it can now be seen to have been the products of
a particular set of circumstances, circumstances which have already
changed. Among those circumstances the experience of war seems
to have been as relevant as the appeal of socialism in determining
the practicability and the popularity of introducing comprehensive
welfare proposals.
So far, however, the re-interpretation and the rewriting have
largely been insular. Relatively little attention has been paid, in
consequence, to the comparative history of welfare legislation.
Specialists in social administration have collected comparative
data, but they have naturally enough used them more frequently
for practical than for historical purposes. The "uniqueness" of
Britain has been emphasized to the neglect of the study of trends
and tendencies in other countries.
In certain respects British experience has been unique, as
foreign writers as different as HaleVy and Schumpeter, have
recognized. The uniqueness can only be appreciated, however,
when the experience of several countries is taken into account.
223
ASA BRIGGS
(1) I.L.O., International Labour Confer- (2) I.L.O., Approaches to Social Security
ence, 34th Session, Objectives and Minimum (1942), P- i-; Objectives and Advanced
Standards of Social Security (1950), pp. 3-4. Standards of Social Security (1952);
See also "Survey of Post-War Trends in D. THOMSON, A. BRIGGS, E. MEYER,
Social Security" in International Labour Patterns of Peacemaking (1945), p. 340,
Review, June, July, August, September, ch. vn, appendix 11.
1949.
224
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
(3) R. M. TITMUSS, Problems of Social (5) A. V. DICEY, Law and Public Opinion
Policy (1950), p. 506. in England during the Nineteenth Century
(4) C. L. MOWAT, The Charity Organi- (1914 edn.), p. 1.
zation Society, 1869-1913 (1961), p. 75.
225
ASA BRIGGS
cessor. The statesmen who had passed the Education Act of 1870,
creating the first public-provided schools, would probably have
been quite unwilling to have passed the 1891 Act relieving parents
of the necessity for paying for any part of their children's elemen-
tary education. The people who passed the 1891 Act would in
their turn have baulked at the School Meals Act of 1906. Dicey
was right in implying that the men of 1906 would certainly have
stopped far short of the "school meals revolution" of the Second
World War. A Board of Education circular of 1941 completely
abandoned old precepts that cheap school meals should be pro-
vided only to children who were both "necessitous" and "under-
nourished". Already during the previous year the number of
school meals provided had doubled. By 1945 1,650,000 dinners
were taken on every school day in England and Wales, about
fourteen per cent being free and the rest costing the parents a
nominal sum. This figure compared with 130,000 in 1940 and
143,000 in the depressed conditions of the mid-i93os. In round
figures one child in three was fed at school in 1945 in place of one
child in thirty in 1940.
The distribution of milk, fruit juice and "welfare foods" was
regulated on social grounds throughout the Second World War.
The same principles were carried from nutritional policy to social
security policy. "In a matter so fundamental", a government
White Paper of 1944 stated, "it is right for all citizens to stand in
together, without exclusion based on differences of status, func-
tion or wealth" (7). The argument was not simply that admin-
istrative problems would be simplified if structures were "com-
prehensive" or "universal" but that through "universal schemes"
"concrete expression" would be given to the "solidarity and unity
of the nation, which in war has been its bulwark against aggression
and in peace will be its guarantee of success in the fight against
individual want and mischance".
This White Paper, like the equally significant White Paper
of 1944 (Cd. 6527) accepting the need for social action to prevent
unemployment, was the product of a coalition government, pledged
to national unity. The strains and stresses of total war forced
politicians to consider the "community" as a whole : the hopes
of "re-construction" (the term was used with particular fervour
(6) TITMOSS, op. cit. pp. 509-10. Services" in The British Economy, 1945-50,
(7) Cd. 6550 (1944) § 8, § 33. See also (ed. G.D.N. WORSWICK and P. ADY, 1952),
Cd. 6404 (1942) and A. BRIGGS, "The Social pp. 365-80.
226
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
during the First World War) were held out to inspire the public
in years of trial. There was thus a close association between war-
fare and welfare. Moreover, the knowledge that large sums of
money, raised through taxation at a level without precedent, were
being used to wage war led without difficulty to the conclusion that
smaller sums of money could produce a "welfare state" in times
of peace. All parties were interested in this line of argument.
The Conservative partner in the war-time coalition, the predomi-
nant political partner, published as late as 1949 a pamphlet, The
Right Road for Britain, which stated unequivocally that "the social
services are no longer even in theory a form of poor relief. They
are a cooperative system of mutual aid and self-help provided by
the whole nation and designed to give to all the basic minimum
of security, of housing, of opportunity, of employment and of
living standards below which our duty to one another forbids us
to permit any one to fall".
By 1949, when this pamphlet was published, the legislation
introduced by the Labour government of 1945 to 1950, particu-
larly the health service legislation, was freely talked of as "welfare
state" legislation. Much of it went beyond the ideas of "com-
prenhensiveness" or "cooperation" as such and reflected socialist
philosophies of "equality". Attempts had been made to raise the
standards of service to meet the claims of "equal citizenship".
"Homes, health, education and social security, these are your
birthright", exclaimed Aneurin Bevan. Sociologists as well as
socialists explained the new policies in terms of the fabric of citizen-
ship. Hitherto, they suggested, social service policy had been
thought of as a remedial policy to deal with the basement of
society, not with its upper floors. Now the purpose was extended.
"It has begun to re-model the whole building, T. H. Marshall
wrote in 1949, and it might even end by converting a skyscraper
into a bungalow" or at least into a " bungalow surmounted by an
architecturally insignificant turret" (8).
The changes in mood since 1949 have already been noted :
they can be explained in narrowly fiscal or broadly socio-political
terms and they constitute the background of current controversies.
The object of this paper is to go back beyond the current contro-
versies, beyond the relatively recent experience of total war, to
the historical matrix within which the idea of a "welfare state"
has taken form. Before going back in time, however, it is neces-
(8) T. H. MARSHALL, Citizenship and Social Class (1949), pp. 47 and 48.
227
ASA BRIGGS
II
228
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
229
ASA BRIGGS
(9) J. BENTHAM, Works (ed. J. BOWRING, view of the "agenda" of the state in The
1843), vol. I l l , p. 35. Cf. J. M. Keynes's End of Laissez Faire (1926).
230
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
Ill
232
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
233
ASA BRIGGS
234
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
ideal state was what he called the "social state". This state
would seek "to secure the prosperity and happiness of every class
of society" but it would be particularly concerned with "the pro-
tection of the poor and needy, because they require the shelter
of the constitution and the laws more than other classes". The
"social state" was the true state of history : it was the political
economists who were the revolutionaries. Because, however, the
actual state in the early nineteenth century was deviating further
and further from the ideal (and historic) state, the defence of
social rights would have to take the form, if need be, of rebellion.
If governments are established in this land for the sole purpose of hoarding up
large masses of gold and stamping down individual wretchedness, if that is the-
sole interest and sole object of our government, I declare myself a traitor to it*
if I die tomorrow for using the word (15).
(15) The Fleet Papers (1842), p. 58; (16) Deutsche Allgemeine Zeitung, 6 Ju-
(1841), p. 39 ; Leeds Intelligencer, 10 Au- ly 1843 ; C. DRIVER, Tory Radical (1946).
gust 1833.
235
ASA BRIGGS
(17) The phrase is taken from his Stones July 1874. The term "fair day's wages
of Venice (1851). {Works, ed. Cook and for a fair day's work" was older.
Wedderburn, vol. XI, p. 263). The term (18) H. S. FOXWELL, The Claims of
"living wage" was first used by the English Labour (1886), p. 249.
Cooperator, Lloyd James, in the Beehive,
236
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
(19) Quoted in S. E. FINER, The Life not see that "deference" was as much a
and Times of Sir Edwin Chadwick (1952), feature of nineteenth-century England,
p. 477. Estimates of the likely effect of the extension
(20) N. SENIOR, Journals Kept in France of suffrage on popular demands for a new
and Italy (1843), pp. 150-2. In this journal political economy were influenced by esti-
Senior compared England with Switzer- mates of the power of "deference". See
land. The "pure democracies" of small W. BAGEHOT, The English Constitution
Swiss cantons, he claimed, resisted the (1872 edn.); A. BRIGGS, The A ge of Improve-
spell of "the political economy of the poor" ment (1959), ch. x.
because all their adult males "venerated (21) "Much of that tact which dreads
their clergy, their men of birth and of the ballot is a dread of the loss of aristo-
wealth and their institutions". He did cratical influence which prevails by gold,
237
ASA BRIGGS
and of the gain of the influence which rian Origins of the British Welfare State
prevails by popularity" (Letter of 14 Oc- (i960), esp. pp. 152-244.
tober 1852, quoted in Finer, op. cit. p. 478). (23) MCGREGOR, op. tit. p. 54.
(22) For details, see D. ROBERTS, Victo-
238
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
(24) J. B. BREBNER, "Laissez faire and tions", see also MACDONAGH, "The Nine-
State Intervention in Nineteenth-century teenth-century Revolution in Government :
Britain" in Tasks of Economic History, a Re-appraisal" in the Historical Journal
Supplement VIII (1948) to the Journal (1958).
of Economic History. For the dangers of (25) BLAND, loc. cit. p. 195, p. 200.
explaining in terms of Dkey's "abstrar-
239
ASA BRIGGS
(the Marxists with their concern for the forms of economic power
did not agree), the state against whose interference "the popular
party" waged "such bitter war" in the first decades of the nineteenth
century [...] was "an altogether different thing" from the state
whose assistance "the new democracy" was continually invoking
and whose power it was bent on increasing. Bland recognized
also that if labour parties put forward "welfare" objectives in
their electoral programmes, other parties working within a democ-
racy would be forced themselves to put forward policies which
would attempt to meet some at least of the labour demands.
Tories had advanced social policies earlier in the nineteenth century
in the name of "traditionalism" or sometimes of "paternalism" :
Liberals, some of whom were developing a positive theory of
"welfare" of their own, would similarly be forced to advance
"welfare" policies, if only in the name of political realism.
"The Liberals" he held (and he had a clear anti-Liberal bias) were "traditionally
squeezable folk" and "like all absorbent bodies" they would be "forced to make
concessions and to offer compromises [...] Such concessions and compromises
will grow in number and importance with each successive appeal to the electorate,
until at last the game is won" (26).
24O
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
24I
ASA BRIGGS
(30) Yet Beatrice Webb herself said of straight out of the nobler aspect of the
her poor law scheme in 1907 : "The whole medieval manor" ; Our Partnership (1948),
theory of the mutual obligation between p. 385.
the individual and the State [...] is taken
242
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
243
ASA BRIGGS
244
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
(37) W. PEMBER REEVES, State Exper- the Fabians in these lectures, delivered to
iments in Australia and New Zealand (1902), working-men in the early 1880s, by con-
vol. II, p. 244. For more recent appraisals, trasting the age of capitalist anarchy with
see W. B. SUTCH, The Quest for Security the age of regulation which had preceded
in New Zealand (1942); R. MENDELSOHN, it. For movements in liberal political
Social Security in the British Commonwealth economy at this time, see T. W. HUTCHISON,
(1954). A Review of Economic Doctrines, 1870-1929
(38) J. A. HOBSON, The Evolution of (1953), ch. 1.
Modern Capitalism (1902), p. 321. (40) T. H. GREEN, Lectures on the
(39) A. MILNER, Introduction to A. TOYN- Principles of Political Obligation (1895 edn.)
BEE, Lectures on the Industrial Revolution pp. 206-209.
(1923 edn.), p. xxv. Toynbee anticipated
245
ASA BRIGGS
of chance of life with those among whom they live" (41). Even
old conservative principles of property were reinterpreted in radical
terms and in Hobhouse's arguments were converted into instruments
of social justice (42). Individualism itself was increasingly asso-
ciated with the freeing of the powers of "under-privileged" indi-
viduals. In 1909 Hobson commented that "the whole conception
of the state disclosed by the new issues, as an instrument for the
active adaptation of the economic and moral environment to the
new needs of individual and social life, by securing full opportunities
of self-development and social service for all citizens, was foreign
to the Liberalism of the last generation" (43).
The "welfare measures of the Liberal governments of 1905-14,
culminating in the bitterly controversial "budget against poverty"
of 1909 and Lloyd George's national insurance schemes against
ill health and unemployment in 1911, were in sharp contrast to
the Gladstonian liberalism of only thirty years before. "They
are so far removed from the old Liberal individualism", one Liberal
historian has written recently, "that they may be called social
democracy rather than pure liberalism" (44).
IV
246
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
(45) W. H. DAWSON, Bismarck and State manded all his uncritical devotion, but
Socialism (1890), p. ix. Wellington was no Bismarck" (DRIVER,
(46) S. B. FAY, "Bismarck's Welfare op. cit. p. 189).
State" in Current History, vol. XVIII (1950). (48) J. A. SCHUMPETER, History 0/
(47) " A British Bismarck", Professor Economic Analysis (1954), p. 765.
Driver has written, "would have com-
247
ASA BRIGGS
(49) The pre-history of this approach leads (50) A. WAGNER, Rede iiber die soziale
back to Sismondi who has important links Frage (1872), pp. 8-9. G. VON SCHMOLLER,
with Mill and the English utilitarians. He is Uber einige Grundfragen ties Rechts und
a seminal figure in the critique of industri- der Volkswirtschaft (1875), p. 92.
alism and the demand for welfare legislation.
248
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
(51) For the background of these at- in England in the Twentieth Century, pp. 3-
tempts, see M. GINSBERG, "The Growth of 26.
Social Responsibility" in Law and Opinion (52) See G. MAYER, Bismarck and"
Lassalle (1927).
249
ASA BRIGGS
(53) DAWSON, op. cit. p. 35. This taneously the positive advancement of
remark was made in 1884. Five years the welfare of the working classes", (quot-
earlier the Emperor, referring to the anti- ed ibid. p. n o ) .
socialist law of 1878, had said, "a remedy (54) J. H. CLAPHAM, An Economic His-
cannot alone be sought in the repression tory of Modern Britain, vol. Ill (1938),
of socialistic excesses ; there must be simul- p. 445.
250
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
251
ASA BRIGGS
252
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
(58) For Booth, see T. S. and M. B. SIMEY (60) See inter alia C. L. Mow AT, The
Charles Booth, Social Scientist (i960); for Charity Organisation Society; K. DE
Rowntree, see A. BRIGGS, Seebohm Rowntree SCHWEINITZ, England's Road to Social
(1961). See also B. S. ROWNTREE and Security (1943); C. W. PITKIN, Social
G. R. LAVERS, Poverty and the Welfare Politics and Modern Democracies, 2 vols.
State (1951). (1931), vol. II being concerned with France;
(59) "In intensity of feeling", Booth R. H. BREMNER, From the Depths; The
wrote, " and not in statistics, lies the Discovery of Poverty in the United States
power to move the world. But by sta- (1956).
tistics must this power be guided if it (6i) See M. ABRAMS, Social Surveys and
would move the world aright" {Life and Social Action (1951); P. V. YOUNG, Scien-
Labour, Final Volume, Notes on Social tific Social Surveys and Research (1950); D.
Influences and Conclusion (1903), p. 178). C. Caradog JONES, Social Surveys (1955).
253
ASA BRIGGS
(62) The British controversy is well (63) MENDELSOHN, op. cit. ch. in :
described in U. CORMACK, "The Welfare J. C. BROWN, Public Relief, 1929-39 (1940);
State", Loch Memorial Lecture (1953). For E. A. WILLIAMS, Federal Aid for Relief
Sweden, see The Royal Social Board, Social (1939); P. H. DOUGLAS, Social Security in
Work and Legislation in Sweden (1938). the United States (1939 edn.).
254
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
255
ASA BRIGGS
far apart. For the intellectuals and for the public the magnifica-
tion of governmental power—and the enormous increase in gov-
ernment expenditure financed from taxation—were taken for
granted.
The fourth and fifth factors are also related to each other.
In all advanced industrial countries in the twentieth century there
has been a movement towards "welfare" in industry—"industrial
betterment" it was originally called—which has been accompanied
by the emergence of philosophies of "human relations", "welfare
management" and industrial and labour psychology (66). The
movement has to be explained in terms of both economics and
politics. A "managerial revolution", limited though it may have
been in its economic effects, has accelerated the tendencies making
for "welfare capitalism". The need to find acceptable incentives
for workers, to avoid labour disputes and to secure continuous
production, to raise output in phases of technical change and (more
recently) to hold labour "permissively" in a period of full employ-
ment has often driven where "human relations" philosophies have
failed to inspire. "Welfare", a word which was often resented by
workers, when it was applied within the structure of the firm,
was, indeed, used in a business context before it began to be
applied to a new kind of state. Within state schemes of "welfare"
employers have made, and are expected to make sizeable contri-
butions. In France and Italy, in particular, obligatory social
charges as a percentage of assessable wages constituted the main
source of "welfare" expenditure (67). In the United States busi-
ness rather than the state was, and is expected, directly to provide
a network of "welfare" services. As in all such situations, the
provision of "welfare" varies immensely from one firm (giant busi-
nesses are at one end of the scale) to another.
In contrast to these countries, such as Great Britain, which appear to regard gov-
ernment (for reasons which have been stated above) merely as the most effective
of several possible institutions for the administration of income security programmes
or the provision of services, [...] a society like the United States that distrusts
(66) See A. BRIGGS, "The Social Back- E. T. KELLY (ed.), Welfare Work in In-
ground", in H. CLEGG and A. FLANDERS dustry (1925); P. E. P., "The Human
(eds.), Industrial Relations in Great Britain Factor in Industry" [Planning, March,
(*955); L. URWICK and E.F.L. BRECH, 1948).
The Human Factor in Management, 1795- (67) P. E. P., "Free Trade and Security"
1943 (i944); E. D. PROUD, Welfare Work, (Planning, July 1957); "A Comparative
Employers' Experiments for Improving Analysis of the Cost of Social Security"
Working Conditions in Factories (1916); in International Labour Review (1953).
256
THE WELFARE STATE IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
its government is likely to seek to organise its social security services in such a
way as to keep government activity to a minimum (68).
(68) E. M. BURNS, Social Security and For industrial relations, see CLEGG and
Public Policy (1956), p. 274. FLANDERS, op. cit.
(69) For the nature of the nineteenth- (70) R. M. TITMUSS, Essays on the Welfare
century pattern, see J. M. BAERNRBITHER, State, pp. 21-22.
English Associations of Working Men (1893). (71) Ibid. p. 19.
257
ASA BRIGGS
(72) See A. PEACOCK, "The Welfare Fabian Tracts (i960); J. SAVILLE, "The
Society", Unservile State Papers (i960); Welfare State" in The New Reasoner
R. M. TITMUSS. "The Irresponsible Society", No. 3, (1957).
258