IBT - Lesson 1
IBT - Lesson 1
IBT - Lesson 1
H
A
1
P
T
E
Why people R
trade?
Topics:
International Trade through Ages
Why do nations trade?
Classical Theories of International Trade
Modern Theories of International Trade
Why do nations import?
Why do nations export?
Trade Barriers
Objectives:
After studying this chapter, you should:
Explain the nature and history of international trade, and be able to identify key
characteristics of and players in international trade today.
Compare and contrast the types of economic decisions made by individuals and
governments and their differing impacts.
Discuss the theories of comparative and absolute advantage and their role in economic
decision-making.
Demonstrate an understanding of the roles that efficiency, specialization, and
opportunity costs play in defining comparative advantage.
T he tremendous growth of international trade over the past several decades has
been both a primary cause and effect of globalization. The volume of world trade increased
twenty-seven fold from $296 billion in 1950 to $8 trillion in 2005 (WTO, 2007). In recent years
world trade has declined in volume and was down in 2012 and is expected to remain sluggish
through 2013. This is a result of the struggling economies of Europe and doubt over the Euro
(WTO, 2013). The continued decline of world trade was evidenced by a decrease of 0.3 percent
in May, with forecasters cutting their prediction for global growth (Hannon, 2013).
As a
result
of
international trade, consumers around the world enjoy a broader selection of products than
they would if they only had access to domestically made products. Also, in response to the
ever-growing flow of goods, services and capital, a whole host of U.S. government agencies and
international institutions has been established to help manage these rapidly-developing trends.
Although increased international trade has spurred tremendous economic growth
across the globe —- raising incomes, creating jobs, reducing prices, and increasing workers’
earning power — trade can also bring about economic, political, and social disruption.
Since the global economy is so interconnected, when large economies suffer recessions,
the effects are felt around the world. When trade decreases, jobs and businesses are lost. In the
same way that globalization can be a boon for international trade; it can also have devastating
effects.
Given these diversities, no country has the potential to produce all the commodities in
the most efficient manner or at the least cost. For instance, India can produce textiles at the
lower cost while Japan can produce electronic goods and automobiles cheaply. Just as there is
division of labor in the case of individuals, the countries also adopt this principle at the
international level.
WHY DO NATIONS EXPORT?
The term “export” is derived from the conceptual meaning as to ship the goods and
services out of the port of a country. The seller of such goods and services is referred to as an
“exporter” who is based in the country of export whereas the overseas based buyer is referred
to as an “importer”.
In International Trade, “exports” refers to selling goods and services produced in home
country to other markets.
sufficient
production capacity a good marketing
an effective
and capability, information and effective market
national export
product superiority communication research
and competitive policy
system
pricing
Selection of Exporting Method
Clearly the nature, size and structure of the market will be significant in determining the
method adopted.
Many other factors will affect the cost/benefit analysis of maintaining the company’s
own staff in foreign markets, such as whether the market is likely to be attractive in the long
term as well as the short term and whether the high cost of installing a member of the firm’s
own staff will be offset by the improvements in the quality of contacts, market expertise and
communications. The alternative, and usually the first stage in exporting, is to appoint an agent
or distributor.
Agents
Agents provide the most common form of low cost direct involvement in foreign
markets and are independent individuals or firms who are contracted to act on behalf of
exporters to obtain orders on a commission basis. They typically represent a number of
manufacturers and will handle non-competitive ranges. As part of their contract they would be
expected to agree sales targets and contribute substantially to the preparation of forecasts,
development of strategies and tactics using their knowledge of the local market.
The selection of suitable agents or distributors can be a problematic process. The selection
criteria might include:
Distributors
Agents do not take ownership of the goods but work instead on Direct Marketing
commission, sometimes as low as 2-3 per cent on large volume and orders.
Distributors buy the product from the manufacturer and so take the market risk
on unsold products as well as the profit. For this reason, they usually expect to take
a higher percentage to cover their costs and risk.
Direct Marketing
Direct marketing is concerned with marketing and selling activities which do not depend
for success on direct face-to-face contact and include mail order, telephone marketing,
television marketing, media marketing, direct mail and electronic commerce using the Internet.
The critical success factors for direct marketing are in the standardisation of the product
coupled with the personalisation of the communication.International direct marketing,
therefore, poses considerable challenges, such as the need to build and maintain upto-date
databases, use sophisticated multilingual data processing and personalisation software
programs, develop reliable credit control and secure payment systems.
Reasons for exports
At least since the beginning of the industrial era almost three centuries ago, countries exported
goods and services because:
Individuals and firms have been able to produce more goods and services than can be
consumed at home. This prompted a search for foreign opportunities to sell the
“excess” production;
Individuals and firms have been able to sell goods or services to other countries at prices
higher than the prices they can obtain domestically.
In today’s global economy, exporting serves somewhat different purposes for developing and
industrial countries.
Developing Countries
Although the economies of developing countries
are typically not as productive as the economies of
industrial countries, developing countries nonetheless
produce some goods and services in amounts they are
unable to use or consume at home. This is called a
production surplus.
For example, some developing countries produce
vast quantities of agricultural products, like cocoa in Cote
d’Ivoire and coffee in Latin America, which their own
populations are not large enough to consume. Other
developing countries produce quantities of industrially
valuable minerals, like oil or iron ore, that their own economies are too small or not yet
industrialized enough to use.
For many developing countries, exports also serve the
purpose of earning foreign currency with which they can buy
essential imports—foreign products that they are not able to
manufacture, mine, or grow at home. Developing countries, in
other words, sell exports, in part, so that they can import.
Exporting goods and services can also further advance
developing nations’ domestic economies.
Industrial Countries
Exports are also more than just an outlet for “excess” production for industrial
countries. Because their economies are more diverse, industrial countries tend to:
The exchange rate is a key determinant of international trade. When a company in one
country wants to import goods from a company in another country, it typically must pay for the
exporting either in that country’s currency or in the currency of one of the world’s major
economies. These currencies– the United States dollar, the European euro, the British pound
sterling, the Japanese yen, and the Swiss franc–are collectively known as hard currencies. Most
countries do not use a hard currency in their domestic economy; you could not use them to buy
a Big Mac in Thailand or a soda in Russia. In order to participate in the international economy,
however, countries must have some stock of a hard currency.
WHY DO NATIONS IMPORT?
The motivation for a country to import goods and services
from other countries is perhaps less obvious than its motivation
for selling exports (making a profit on goods not consumed by the
domestic market). As with exports, the purposes served by
imports vary from country to country. Let’s explore these various
purposes by starting with asking why a country like the United
States, with its massive and extraordinarily diverse economy,
would need to import anything from other countries.
In fact, there are only a handful of goods or services that the United States absolutely
must import from other countries. With a land area spanning several climatic zones, immense
natural resources, and a dynamic workforce, the United States is able to produce, mine, or
grow almost every item its citizens need to lead reasonably prosperous lives.
Yet no country today, including the United States, can be totally self-sufficient without
suffering a high cost. All countries need to—or choose to—import at least some goods and
services for the following reasons:
Goods or services that are essential to economic well-being
Goods or services that are highly attractive to consumers but are not available in the
domestic market
Goods or services that satisfy domestic needs or wants can be produced more
inexpensively or efficiently by other countries, and therefore sold at lower prices.
The United States cannot meet its oil consumption needs exclusively through domestically
produced oil; in 2012 the US consumption of oil dropped to a 16 year low, a total of 18.56 million bpd, as
a result of a weak economy (Reuters, 2013). Meanwhile, the domestic production of oil rose sharply in
2012, with 6.4 million bpd being produced in the U.S. (Fowler, 2013). This means that the U.S. will need
to import less and steadily become more self-reliant, with projections stating that U.S. output will
overtake Saudi Arabia by 2020, making it the largest producer for about five years (Nguyen, 2012).
The United States could, in theory, abandon foreign oil imports, but it would be a costly
decision because:
1. It is not clear that domestic reserves of oil, both those that are known and those that
have yet to be discovered, could satisfy current domestic demand.
2. Even if U.S. oil reserves were adequate, generating the extra oil necessary to fill the gap
now filled by imported oil would be extremely costly. Many foreign countries are able to
produce oil much more cheaply. Besides, accessing the additional U.S. reserves would
require many years of research and development.
3. Other energy sources—for example, coal, nuclear power, or hydro-electric power—
could conceivably be substituted for oil imports, but complying with the respective
environmental regulations, along with the cost of producing additional energy from
these sources, would be very expensive.
Of course, energy conservation measures could also reduce the need for oil imports by
decreasing the energy consumption of the average American citizen. Energy conservation
would be prudent, regardless of which energy supply the United States favors in the future;
however, foreign producers would still be able to produce the oil more cheaply, regardless of
the level of production. In addition, the scale of energy-saving measures needed to
substantially reduce U.S. imports of oil would require dramatic changes in economic activity
and lifestyles and have thus far have not been politically viable.
Electricity produced by hydropower plants built
into dams is another example of an essential resource
that the United States does not produce in sufficient
quantity to meet its consumption needs. The United
States imports large quantities of hydropower from
Canada.
The same logic applies to any resource or product whose domestic supply is limited
although the domestic demand is high. The United States—-though not most other countries—-
can often find ways to increase the production of a commodity, reduce domestic consumption,
or identify domestic substitutes. These alternatives often prove more costly than continuing to
import from other countries, though.
It is worth noting that the country where a good is produced need not be the same as
the country where the corporation that manufactures and sells the good is established. Several
American clothing companies, such as The Gap, manufacture most of their clothes in
developing countries.
Trade Specialization
Two broad categories of goods
and services
A large number of other goods and services imported by the United States and many
other countries would probably fit into two additional categories:
Mercantilism became popular in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries in
Western Europe and was based on the notion that governments (not individuals who were
deemed untrustworthy) should become involved in the transfer of goods between nations in
order to increase the wealth of each national entity. Wealth was defined, however, as an
accumulation of previous metals, especially gold.
The concept of mercantilism incorporates two fallacies. The first was the incorrect belief
that old or precious metals have intrinsic value, when actually they cannot be used for either
production or consumption. Thus, nations subscribing the mercantilism notion exchanged the
products of their manufacturing or agricultural capacity for this non-productive wealth. The
second fallacy is that the theory of mercantilism ignores the concept of production efficiency
through specialisation. Instead of emphasizing cost-effective production of goods, mercantilism
emphasises sheet amassing of wealth with acquisition of power.
Theory of Economic Development
The trade structure is also sought to be explained in terms of scale economies.
According to this theory, there is a relationship between the size of the internal market and
average unit cost of production and export competitiveness. A firm operating in a country
where the domestic market is large will be able to reach a high output level thereby reaping the
advantage of largescale production. The lower cost of production will increase its
competitiveness enabling the firm to make an easy entry to the export market. While prima-
facie this logic appears to be valid, this hypothesis cannot be generalized because it is possible
that the pull of the domestic market will be so strong that the export would not be promoted,
as is the case with India in certain products.
The Age of
Mass
The Drive to Consumption
Maturity
Takeoff
Preconditions
for takeoff
Traditional
Society
As you can see from the example above, a country can have a comparative advantage in
producing a good even if it is absolutely less efficient at producing that good. To understand
this more clearly, think of an example of a doctor in private practice:
A young doctor opens her own practice, working by herself, and within a few months
has developed a substantial clientele. At first, she was performing all her clerical work—filing,
typing and answering the phone—by herself. With an ever-busier schedule, however, she
realizes that she could spend more time seeing patients, and thus see a greater number of
patients, if she hired an assistant.
As it turns out, the young professional is not only a brilliant doctor, but is also lightning-
fast at typing and filing. She is, in fact, better at doing both jobs than the clerical assistant she
hires. In other words, she has an absolute advantage at both tasks: medical diagnosis and
clerical work.
Does it make sense then for the doctor and her assistant to share both tasks, each
spending part of the day diagnosing patients and doing clerical work? The answer is no. By
having the assistant perform all the clerical work, the doctor is able to maximize her
specialization and see more patients. The patients are undoubtedly better off too.
In other words, even though the assistant is worse at performing both tasks, an
economist would say that he nonetheless has a comparative advantage at clerical work. As you
can see, by working together – trading their services – the doctor and the assistant are able to
maximize their skills, making both better off.
As these examples show, trade allows countries to specialize in the production of what
they do best and make the most efficient use of their resources, thereby decreasing the price of
both goods. No matter how inefficiently a country produces every kind of good, it can always be
said to have a comparative advantage in at least one of those goods.
That is the theory of comparative and absolute advantage. It helps explain what
happens in the real world of international trade, and it offers broad guidance to countries as
they decide which goods and services to produce and subsequently export, and which, in turn,
to import.
The Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin theory of factor endowment addressed the question
of the basis of cost differentials in the production of trading nations. They posited that each
country allocates its production according to the relative allocates proportions of all its
production factor endowments – land, labour and capital on a basic level, and, on a more
complex level, such factors as management and technological skills, specialized production
facilities, and established distribution networks.
Thus, the range of products made or grown for export would depend on the relative
availability of different factors in each country.
Agricultural production or cattle grazing would be emphasized in such countries as Canada, and
Australia, which are generously endowed with land. Conversely, in small land mass countries with high
populations, export products would center or labor-intensive articles. Similarly, rich nations might center
their export base on capital-intensive production.
In this way, countries would be expected to produce goods that require large amounts
of the factors they hold in relative abundance. Because of the availability and low costs of these
factors, each country should also be able to sell its products on foreign markets at less than
international price levels. Although this theory holds in general, it does not explain export
production that arises from taste differences rather than factor differentials. Some of these
situations can be seen in sales of luxury-imported goods, such as Italian leather products,
deluxe automobiles and French wine, which are values for their quality, prestige, or panache.
Like Classical theory, the Heckscher-Ohlin theory does not account for transportation costs in its
computation, nor does it account for differences among nations in the availability of
technology.
Economist Paul Samuelson extended the factor endowment theory to look at the effect
of trade upon national welfare and the prices of production factors: Samuelson posited that the
effect of free trade among nations would be to increase overall welfare by equalizing not only
the prices of the goods exchanged in trade, but also of all involved factors. Thus, according to
his theory, the returns generated by use of the factors would be the same in all countries.
Trade in Theory and Practice
In reality, of course, trade specialization does not work precisely the way the theory of
comparative advantage might suggest, for a number of reasons:
Generally, countries with a relative abundance of low-skilled labor will tend to specialize
in the production and export of items for which low-skilled labor is the predominant cost
component. Countries with a relative abundance of capital will tend to specialize in the
production and export of items for which capital is the predominant component of cost.
Finally, international trade brings several other benefits to the average consumer.
Competition from imports can enhance the efficiency and quality of domestically produced
goods and services. In addition, competition from imports has historically tended to restrain
increases in domestic prices.
Modern Theories of International Trade
Human Capital Approach Theory
This theory, which is also sometimes known as Skills Theory of International Trade, has
been advocated by a number of economists, especially Becker, Kennen and Kessing. Whereas
the Factor Proportions Theory considers labor as a homogenous factor, however, it is not so in
the real world. In fact, for export of manufactured goods, the skill level of labor is very
important determinant. Labor can be basically divided into skilled and unskilled labor. On the
basis of empirical testing Kessing concluded that patterns of international trade and location
were predetermined for a broad group of manufacturers by the relative abundance of skilled
and unskilled labor.
USA and Japan are highly industrialized; both have similar demand characteristics viz. computers,
software, air-conditioners, internet, fashion garments etc. Firms in both the countries are highly export
competitive because they have already grown big by first catering to the domestic demand that is why
the trade between the USA and Japan is so substantial. This theory explains how an industrialized
country grows rapidly in its economic growth.
The theory also assumed that each country had as its objective full production efficiency. It
neglected such other motives as traditional employment and production history, self-sufficiency
or political objectives.
In addition, the theory is overly simplistic in that it deals only with two commodities and
two countries. In reality, given the full range of production by many countries and interplay of
many motives and factors, the trade situation is actually an ongoing dynamic process in which
there is interplay of forces and products. The largest area of weakness in classical theory is that
while we considered all resource units used in production, the only costs considered by classical
economists were those associated with labor. The theorists did not account for other resources
used in the production of commodity or manufactured goods for export such as transportation
cost, the use of land, and capital. This failing was addressed by subsequent trade theories,
which in modern theories include all factors of production in looking at theories of comparative
advantage.
Most of the models of strategic trade are motivated by the attempt to relax (and explore
systematically the implications of) the seemingly restrictive assumptions of the Ricardian and H-
O models, such as those relating to perfectly competitive markets, constant or decreasing
returns to scale, product homogeneity, per factor mobility, no externalities or spillover effects,
and so forth.
The essence of almost all the new models of trade is the recognition that industries are
characterized by any or all of the following features: scale, economies (both dynamic and
static), product differentiation, imperfect competition, externalities and spillover and, in cases,
irreversible investments. Some of the main insights from this literature are as follows:
1. Increasing returns to scale provide a justification for trade for reasons other than
comparative advantage, since firms will have the incentive to produce and export in
order to lower costs by attaining greater scale economies; an example of a industry
where this is an important issue is the commercial airframes industry.
2. Product differentiation can result in intra industry trade, since, within the same
industry, the same product can have different brand identities; for example, the US will
export certain types of automobiles (Ford Escort) and it will import other types of
automobiles (BMWs).
3. Imperfect competition creates rents, and trade policy could shift rents from the foreign
country to the home country. For example, the imposition of quotas will increase
domestic prices and thus can create rents for foreign producers; the home-country
government may Notes try to counterbalance it with a subsidy to domestic producers,
so as to put price pressure on foreign producers.
4. Externalities and spillover effects (particularly in innovation and R & D) may sometimes
provide a justification for industry protection for reasons other than industry infancy or
national security.
5. Irreversible investments induce an asymmetry between entry and exit costs, and can
therefore lead to “hysteretic” responses to price or quantity shifts.
Thus, the impetus for a firm to go abroad may come from a wish to expand for internal
reasons to use existing competitive advantages in additional spheres of operations, to take
advantage of technology, or to use raw materials available in other locations. Alternatively, the
motive might arise from external forces, such as competitive actions, customer requests or
government incentives. The final determinant however, is based in a cost benefit analysis. The
firm will move abroad if it can use its own particular advantages to provide benefits that
outweigh the costs of exporting or production abroad and provide a profit.
A trade deficit also occurs when companies manufacture goods in other countries. The raw materials for
manufacturing that are shipped overseas for factory production count as an export. The finished
manufactured goods are counted as imports when they're shipped back to the country. The imports are
subtracted from the country's gross domestic product even though the earnings may benefit
the company's stock price, and the taxes may increase the country's revenue stream.
Causes
Effect
Initially, a trade deficit is not necessarily a bad thing. It can raise a country's standard of living because
residents can access a wider variety of goods and services for a more competitive price. It can also
reduce the threat of inflation since it creates lower prices.
Over time, a trade deficit can cause more outsourcing of jobs to other countries. As a country imports
more goods than it buys domestically, then the home country may create fewer jobs in certain industries.
At the same time, foreign companies will likely hire new workers to keep up with the demand for their
exports.
They believe that trade deficits are harmful for a number of reasons:
Trade deficits are often interpreted as a sign of a nation’s economic weakness. They are
said to reflect an excessive reliance on products made by others, and to result from
deficiencies in the home country’s economic output. In the eyes of many labor
supporters, an excess of imports over exports comes at the expense of domestic
production and jobs.
Trade deficits represent a sacrifice of future growth. Because a nation with a trade
deficit is purchasing more than it produces, investment in future growth is being traded
for consumption in the present.
What is the impact of the coronavirus pandemic on global trade?
In the beginning of 2020, the world was impacted by the spread of the COVID-19 virus, also
known as Coronavirus. While the initial impact has been primarily in China, the virus later
spread worldwide. International Trade was impacted in several ways:
Enrichment
Closet Check
Activity 1
Grab a pen and paper and go to your closet. Take out the items that you wear the most
and see what percentage is made in the Philippines and in other countries. How imports affect
our economic progress?
The growth over the last century opened up new opportunities for trade, by creating
new markets for new materials from new sources. This city was at the center of this
growth. The need for coal and iron to build trains, rails, and ships attracted investment
from this city’s banking industry. Cattle and corn from the center of the continent
passed through great port cities to feed the city and its neighbors. The city used
phosphate mined on distant island countries to support its weapons factories. Tea and
coffee were popular beverages, although grown in the far reaches of the globe. Cotton
from hundreds of miles away made residents more comfortable, just as furs from the
north made them more stylish. Advances in communication, such as the telegraph,
made it easier to meet schedules and make deals from across the country and across
the ocean.
This community was the capital of a colonial settlement. Its residents consumed food
they grew nearby and used locally cut wood for fuel. Most of the tools, clothing, and
other necessities were provided by community craftsmen. More expensive products and
luxury items were procured from the home country over the ocean, as the
transportation and banking systems favored close trade relations with the colonists’
original land. The community participated in a plantation economy, purchasing slaves
from overseas and providing tobacco and processed rum in exchange.
This was the leading city in a desert land, and was arguably one of the most important
cities along a trade route which stretched from one continent to another. This powerful
merchant community participated in a complex trading network, as merchants from
East and West would meet in its markets and trade for items unavailable in their own
countries. Silk and paper, the secret of whose production was kept for centuries by
Eastern traders, was traded for exquisite rugs and carpets produced near the market
city. In turn, these products were traded for gold (and other precious metals), raw
materials, and fine items made or mined in the West. Although this city was supplied
with its basic necessities from nearby river valleys, it rose to become one of the greatest
commercial centers the world has seen.
The explosive expansion of the world economy over the preceding three centuries
dramatically affected this community. Most of this community’s residents were only
slightly aware of the level of internationalism of the trade that brought them so much.
The plastic materials in computers, cars, clothing and entertainment devices were
formulated from petroleum purchased from dozens of sources. The community
consumes coffee, soda, fruit, meat, and vegetables as likely to come from the other side
of the world as from their own country, but least likely to come from their own
neighborhood. The strong flow of raw materials from resource-rich countries to their
community was matched by the flow outwards of new products, intangibles like
information and communication and services, that comprised an ever-increasing portion
of the world economy. The necessities and luxuries that made up the daily life of the
residents were rarely made in the community, and items made or services provided by
the community were just as likely to be in demand in other countries.
In this small, isolated village a community maintained a stable yet precarious existence,
with little change in population over the centuries. Food was provided through
agriculture and supplemented by hunting and gathering. Almost all clothing and tools
were made by community members from natural sources near the village. Every year
members of the village met with members of nearby villages and trade for a few
precious products, such as religious items or perhaps new and unique weapons or tools.
In return, they provided raw minerals or salt from sources near their community.
The members of this community practiced agriculture in the deserts and river valleys of
their homeland. They grew corn and beans to support their small communities. An
extensive network of villages and roads in a peaceful environment increased trade
opportunity. They used quetzal feathers from lands over 1,500 miles to the south in
their religious ceremonies, and traded for minerals and other items from across the
continental landscape.
Instruction: Using your knowledge in the theory of comparative advantage, work out your own
plan to increase the efficiency of the production of fish and wood of the tribes.
After the conversation, both chiefs still hesitated to follow David's plan.
Essay Writing Rubric