Uganda in Transition Two Years of The NRA-NRM by Mahmood Mamdani
Uganda in Transition Two Years of The NRA-NRM by Mahmood Mamdani
Uganda in Transition Two Years of The NRA-NRM by Mahmood Mamdani
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Taylor & Francis, Ltd. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Third World Quarterly
1156
Security
1157
From the Amin coup of 1971 to the fall of Lutwa in 1986, we can trace
two major negative developments that account for the degeneration of
this army. The first was a shift in recruitment from peasants to lumpen
(bayaye) and semi-lumpen elements; in other words, to those removed
from the world of labour and central to the world of plunder. Second
was a factional division of the army into increasingly independent armed
gangs. In turn, these two developments reflected a wider failure to forge
a programme around which to unite a majority of Ugandans. These
developments can be traced from regime to regime.
The first significant change in the social character of this army
followed the coup of 1971. Then, in the teeth of sharp internal factional
rivalry, Amin turned to the urban poor as the easiest and quickest
available source of manpower for recruitment into the army. The most
dramatic public example of this was in 1973 when about 7,000
unemployed were gathered in City Square in Kampala, applauded by
Amin as 'volunteers' who had registered to go and fight alongside their
'brothers' in the Middle East and in South Africa, and immediately
recruited into the army!
The 'liberation' war of 1979 accelerated the tendency to recruit
soldiers from the residue of society for the following reasons: despite its
name, the 'liberation' war was really an inter-state war between the
Tanzanian army and Amin's soldiers; contending middle-class factions
rushed into the political vacuum created by Amin's defeat at the hands
of a foreign army. (The majority of these factions were hastily brought
together through a conference at Moshi in March 1979 and immodestly
baptised the Uganda National Liberation Front (UNLF), an arrangement
which disintegrated just as hastily and indecently following Amin's
defeat. The subsequent rivalry between these factions focused mainly on
recruitment for and control over the new Uganda National Liberation
Army (UNLA), and as each contending faction tried to recruit to the
maximum to outstrip rival factions, it turned to the one group readily
available for an armed venture, the bayaye.
The failure to organise an internal struggle against the Amin regime
was at the root of the failure in the post-Amin period to gel together a
coalition of forces around a programme that could inspire and sustain
popular support. A string of regimes followed-four in under two
years-one on the heels of another, signifying successive attempts by
diverse middle-class political factions to seek a wider and stable base of
support from a population which they only succeeded in dividing and
1158
1159
1160
Economy
1161
of glory. This attempted repetition has taken two forms: on the one
hand, every regime has re-appropriated the properties that were
confiscated from the expelled Asian owners and redistributed them to its
narrow circle of supporters at the summit; on the other hand, every
regime has organised an expulsion of opponents and an appropriation of
their properties-usually land and cattle and household effects, as in
1979 (of Muslims) in Bushenyi, 1980 in West Nile or 1982-83 in
Bushenyi and Mbarara and Rakai-for distribution to a broader circle
of supporters at the base.
The tragic legacy of the Amin era has thus come to haunt Ugandans
with every new regime. As a result, not only those with property, but also
those without it, have come to experience and thus to believe that you get
rich not through investments that create new wealth but through a
transfer of already created wealth; in a word, that the quickest way to
wealth is through political power. The zero-sum character of political
competition, that loss of political office is akin to a total loss, has given
political struggles a life-and-death character; in turn, the recognition of
the ephemeral nature of political power has turned extreme plunder into
not only the quickest but also the most rational way of acquiring wealth.
With each succeeding round of transfers, internal division and violence
have intensified as Ugandan society seems to have turned in on itself.
It is this legacy, in addition to the distortions that normally
characterise neo-colonies, that President Yoweri Museveni must
contend with. His determination to establish law and order and
bourgeois legality is nothing but an attempt to bring to a close the Amin
era. And this attempt is bound to have a contradictory outcome. On the
positive side, but in the medium-term, it will create the necessary legal
environment for a functioning economic system where property titles
have legal validity and can be the basis for acquiring mortgages for
investments; this long-run security for property, no longer limited to the
lifespan of individual regimes, will also create the basis for relative
political stability within the propertied class.
But on the negative side, and in the short-term, this same reform will
appear to the popular classes-but especially to that mass of small
proprietors in and around urban centres-as a setback, a closing of the
great opening created by the Amin regime with the 1972 expulsion and
kept open-however clumsily-by every subsequent regime. The
thousand-and-one ways in which men and women of substance in high
positions could avail themselves of an opportunity for advancement to a
distant relative or clansmate will have been closed. To them, the reform
1162
1164
these lands are occupied and cultivated by tenants. The result has been a
marked spread of insecurity amongst tenants in the region that is the
leading producer of export and food crops in the country.
The question of appropriate land tenure policies is central, not simply
because production in our country. is predominantly agricultural, but
more so because it is carried out mainly by small peasants. Even in those
countries that are today put forward as show-cases by the IMF, such as
South Korea in Asia or Ivory Coast in Africa, vital institutional changes
were necessary for the economy to grow. In South Korea, a land reform
gave 'land to the tiller'; in Ivory Coast, state policy declared that 'land
belongs to the person who brought it under productive use' at a stroke
dealing a death blow to both absentee and clan tenure. Without the
institutional reform that will give security of tenure to peasants in this
area, the price reform so fondly championed by the IMF cannot have the
desired effect.
Second, in the historical labour-reserve areas of the 'North', where
land is still relatively plentiful but where the capacity to bring it under
cultivation is limited, both because of the dearth of numbers and of
implements, co-operation in labour has been customary. But its further
development has been stunted because state policy has generally tended
to favour individual initiatives by 'progressive farmers'; at the same
time, it has tended to ignore indigenous forms of production-based
co-operation while promoting colonial-style marketing co-operatives
controlled by these same 'progressive farmers and traders'. It is no
exaggeration to say that state agricultural policy has concentrated on
chanelling small peasant surpluses to large proprietors through the
import and subsidised sale of tractors and exotic cattle; and yet, unlike
neighbouring Kenya, capitalist farmers and ranchers are really marginal
to agricultural production in Uganda, and more so today than twenty
years ago, since it is small peasant crops (coffee) and not plantation
crops (tea) that survived the intervening economic crisis.
What is needed in these areas of peasant production which are free of
landlordism is a reversal of existing agricultural policy. State financial
subsidy, legal protection and institutional encouragement need to take
into account the fact that the solid base of agricultural production in
these areas is the small peasant, the middle and poor peasant, not the
so-called progressive farmer. State policy thus needs to encourage the
development of small peasant-based co-operatives, not simply in
marketing but in production proper and not as a negation but as a
development of conventional forms of co-operation.
1165
Third, there is the necessity for structural reform in the state sector in
general, and the parastatal sector in particular. Uganda historically had
one of the most efficient parastatal sectors, its centre-piece being the
Uganda Development Corporation. Following the Asian expulsion of
1972, however, a rapid and haphazard expansion was forced on this
sector, leading to disorganisation and ultimately gross financial
irresponsibility. We now seem to have reached the point at which Zaire
found itself in 1977, when President Mobutu characterised corruption as
'a Zairois sickness'. Today, it is almost the official view that corruption is
as Ugandan as matoke or millet, and that therefore the only way to solve
the problem is to look beyond Uganda towards foreigners for a solution.
The President openly complains of a lack of honest and trusted cadres,
and the people have come to view the entire official machinery of
implementation-the civil service-with suspicion and derision. What is
the way out?
Once again, as with every key issue, there is an alternative. The answer
of the IMF is, in a word, 'privatisation': trim the state sector by selling off
loss-making, corrupt parastatals to profit-conscious private
entrepreneurs, as is supposed to be done with Custodian Board
properties. It is an answer deceptively simple and therefore attractive.
But 'privatisation' will simply deliver state-controlled resources
primarily into the hands of foreign capital and secondarily into those of
local capital whose orientation is primarily speculative. What is the
alternative?
In my view, the alternative is two-fold. First, it is necessary to admit
that the remuneration system in effect in the public service today, the
system of payment of wages and salaries, is totally counter-productive.
Instead of encouraging hard work and dedication, it discourages it. Even
the government has now evolved two reward systems for the same work:
a realistic system of payment for foreigners, but a nominal system for
locals. Never before in our history have state employees been penalised
so severely for being Ugandans!
We need to beware of, the consequences. While most people still
manage to make ends meet, the form of income of government
employees is predominantly either illegal or anti-social. My point is that
the government has made it literally impossible for its employees to live
with any degree of self-respect. For the system of official renumeration
has the consequence of putting on sale public employees to the highest
bidder. And yet, it is the same government which then turns around and
blames the people for being corrunt!
1166
National unity
1167
1168
1169
1170
Popular support for the HSM came from two areas: Acholiland and
Teso. In the latter, too, the initial conditions for this support were sown
by mistakes made by the NRA. In the absence of previous political work
reflecting an organised political base, the NRA fell back on a 'natural'
base-migrants from western Uganda-thereby deepening instead of
healing divisions within Teso society. As these divisions led to
recrimination, including the confiscation of cattle, large sectors of the
population began to look elsewhere for political guidance and
leadership.
Lakwena's temporary success in organising peasant support, in spite
of a series of crushing military defeats at the hands of the NRA, iS
explained by two factors: it reflected a vote of no confidence by the
peasantry in its conventional leadership; and it illustrated the failure of
the NRA/NRM to arrive at a viable programme for the 'North'.
During this period, several of the commanders and leaders from the
cliques into which the old regimes disintegrated-such as
Lieutenant-Colonel Kilama or Professor Ojok-joined forces with
Lakwena. This was a result of the failure of these cliques to rally popular
support, in contrast to the success of the HSM in that same endeavour.
The joining of forces was in most instances opportunistic, as individual
commanders or leaders hoped to join the only movement with popular
support, and use it later to realise their own ambitions. From all
accounts, though, every time these individuals tried to assert their
independent leadership, they failed.
Lakwena lost not because she was finally outwitted militarily by the
NRA; her forces never did have military superiority over those of the NRA.
Lakwena lost when she lost political superiority over the NRA; and this
happened the minute her forces stepped into territory where they had no
political support. Without the peasants behind her, the disintegration of
her forces was just a matter of time.
The duration-however short-of the Holy Spirit Movement should
really be seen as a failure on the part of the NRA to provide political
leadership to the 'Northern' peasantry at a time of deep internal social
crisis when it had lost faith in its conventional leaders and was
desperately looking for an alternative. At that time, for the NRA to
confront the manifestation of this crisis and this failure-the HSM-as
nothing but a military challenge was surely the sign of a political failure.
For residents in Kampala, the most graphic illustration of this lapse was
the series of reports that appeared in the government-owned press about
repeated confrontations between ill-armed and ill-trained cadres of the
1171
HSM and well-armed and well-trained soldiers of the NRA, leading to the
death of the former in hundreds, and on an almost daily basis. The
resulting military victory of the NRA must be considered a political
failure for the policy of constructing a broad, nation-wide base.
This issue has an even more far-reaching significance. For, given the
extremely uneven development of the political economy of Uganda in
this century, the formation of classes has also tended to have a
regionally-specific character. Propertied interests are concentrated in the
'South' which was historically the focus of export production, school
education, administrative and commercial development. It is these
southern propertied interests that dominate the leadership of the DP and
predominate in the NRM'S current broad base. But it is these very
interests that can be expected to counter in the most vigorous manner
any attempt at fundamental change.
In contrast, the 'North' has at most individual occupants of office with
individual interests to protect; it has yet to develop a class of large
proprietors. Any movement wanting to reform the inherited structures
of Ugandan society is far less likely to find organised resistance to such a
change in the 'North'. And yet, given the relatively backward
development of commodity relations and therefore the relatively strong
grip of clan ties in the 'North', no movement can expect to organise the
'Northern peasantry' except through the mediation of a cadre base
recruited from the educated middle strata of the 'North'! But it is
precisely this group that the NRM has shunned by substituting the offer of
a few jobs for sustained political work.
The third type of opposition to the NRA-organised broad base came
from small groups of intellectuals looking for a better deal from the
NRM-led government. The best known of these are the remnants of the
UNLF, now organised in London as the Uganda National Liberation
Front: Anti-Dictatorship (UNLF-AD). First organised on the eve of the
Moshi Conference of 1979, an event that catapulted them straight into
the post-Amin regime in Kampala, the UNLF-AD has never outgrown its
political baptism. It continues to hope for a political miracle, a repetition
of the Moshi Conference whereby it may step into yet another political
vacuum in Kampala. Hence its call for a 'roundtable conference' of all
organised groups to decide on the future government for the country.
But 1986 was not 1979. The political vacuum of 1979 was created by
the presence of a foreign army on Ugandan soil. In 1986, there were no
foreign soldiers in Uganda; instead, there was a new army forged in the
course of an internal struggle against the Obote regime and its
1172
Democracy
When the NRA came to power in early 1986, it ushered in what it believed
was a new and revolutionary concept of democracy: participatory, grass
root and popular as opposed to representative, elitist and parliamentary.
Against the conventional practice of democracy which was limited to
holding elections at the summit, the national parliament, it upheld the
alternative of organising every village community into a Resistance
Council and creating on this base a hierarchy of Resistance Committees
(RCs) right up to the National Resistance Council. This alternative, it
claimed, was far more democratic; it extended democracy from the elite
to the mass of working people, while allowing them to hold officials
accountable at all times.
The institution of RCS was born in the course of the guerrilla war. In
order to draw on popular support to counter and to survive state
repression, every movement has historically had to broaden the extent of
popular participation. The introduction of RCS by the NRA was no
exception. The RCS were the first attempt to crack the regime of
dictatorship introduced by the colonial power into village society at the
turn of the century. This was the regime which had created out of the
traditional chieftainship an absolute institution, without any check or
balance from countervailing institutions, as provided, for example, by
1173
1174
and beneficiaries of the new regime, was that the most opportun
lumpen elements were among those attracted to it.
In time, this fact became clear and a change of policy ensued.
Realising that the short duration of the guerrilla war had not given the
NRM the opportunity to create an independent machinery of
implementation, and that it was forced to rely on the old and corrup
civil service, the NRM proceeded to draft layer upon layer of state
functionaries into the cadre school. For those who care to draw lessons
from history, there was an uncanny resemblance with the cadre school
established during the days of Kwame Nkrumah in Ghana.
The point is that, with this change, the NRM cadre school ceased to be a
cadre school in all but name. Its purpose was no longer to train political
combatants for a political struggle; its objective now was far more
modest, to give a touch of political consciousness to state functionaries!
Cadres, on the other hand, cannot be created as if in a laboratory; a
cadre school must function as an adjunct to real struggles in real life, not
as a substitute for it. To function as such, however, a cadre school would
have to draw its personnel from the arena of democratic struggle in
society-workers' and students' strikes, movements of peasants and
women, and so on-and not from state functionaries. And these
products of the cadre school would then need to return to the mass
movements in order to build a movement in touch with reality.
Yet the NRM fears that if it organises an active body of cadres, spread
through the various segments of Ugandan society, organised by and
responding to a single centre, it will simply be turned into one amongst
several political parties, a development which will only serve to intensify
the internal division of Ugandan society. Thus, instead of welcoming
open political competition, it has put a ban on all political party activity.
What is the practical significance of this ban? Those who aim to
conserve the existing structure of society have no need to create new
institutions in order to do so; that need only exists for those who wish to
transform that structure. Kampala and other urban centres, after all, are
daily the site of religious rallies organised by fast proliferating
foreign-financed and even foreign-staffed evangelical groups. Are these
not political rallies under another name? The ban on political activity
surely, then, applies only to the NRM-or, more specifically, to those who
wish to bring basic change to Ugandan society. It does not apply to
existing political parties, nor to those who wish to conserve the basic
institutions of society.
1175
1176
country-then the NRM may simply become a camouflage for the best
organised party within the broad base-today, none other than the DP.
Could we then not have a parallel with the Kenyan situation where the
old Kenya African Democratic Union (KADU) today reigns supreme, but
under the banner of the Kenya African National Union (KANu)?
The third tendency sees neither the NRM nor the RCS as the institutional
leadership of the new Uganda; rather, this role falls on the shoulders of
the army, the NRA. Such a point of view reflects a vote of no confidence in
civilian society and its institutions; it indicates both a sense of despair
about creating new civilian institutions to organise new civilian forces in
the interest of transforming society, and a failure to do so.
But if the army is to dominate and direct civil society, shall we not
perpetuate the crisis of Ugandan society, where rulers are tempted to
deal with opponents militarily and not politically, where opposition has
become synonymous with sabotage and criticism with treason, and
where each successive regime has simply consolidated the official
machinery of repression in the name of guarding the national interest
and thereby further intensified the crisis of civil society?
A serious consideration of Ugandan history, in my view, would
conclude that the salvation of Ugandan society lies in the opposite
direction, in the strengthening of civil society vis-ac-vis state institutions
For this to happen, it is necessary to implement a comprehensive
programme of democratisation that goes far beyond the multi-party
democracy at the summit championed by the legal opposition to Obote,
the DP. This would mean a democratisation of the base, by transforming
chiefs into civil servants accountable to RCS as organs of the people, and
by introducing forms of workplace democracy. It would mean
upholding the right of organisation, thereby guaranteeing the existence
of autonomous mass organisations independent of the state. It would
also mean a consolidation rather than a trimming of the free press that
Uganda enjoys today. Finally, it would mean the freedom of political
organisation, thereby removing the ban on party political activity, and
calling for open political activity by all parties, including the NRM.
I believe the NRM is today caught in a contradiction: on the one hand,
it wants to be a home for the reconciliation of all tendencies in Ugandan
society, but on the other hand, it also wants to change that society. But
you cannot do both. Not all political tendencies are reconcilable; if you
try to move in all directions at the same time, the only result will be
paralysis.
1177
1178
Conclusion
1179
1180
Bibliographical Note
There is very little published material on the Museveni regime, either in the form of
books or scholarly articles. The commentary on the Museveni government is far more
conjectural, and is found by and large within the pages of magazines and newspapers.
Within Uganda, the most critical and informative of the material could be found
within the pages of Weekly Topic (Kampala) and Foward (Kampala). I have tried to put
together some of this material in a single article entitled 'Background to the capture of
state power by NRA' and published in Forward 8 (1-2), 1986.
Of the comments published outside the country, probably one of the most insightful
was a short piece entitled 'Year of Peace' by Yusuf Hassan in Africa Events (London),
January/February 1987, upon his return from Uganda.
1181