2008 Volkov
2008 Volkov
2008 Volkov
VADIM VOLKOV
Abstract: The author compares two conflicts between large businesses and the state in the
United States and Russia. Although almost one hundred years apart, the Standard Oil and
Yukos cases are comparable in so far as they erupted in the context of early capitalism in
a weak institutional environment. Both conflicts were shaped by the state’s increasingly
strong authority.
Keywords: early capitalism, large business, Standard Oil, the state, Yukos
I n January 1906, Missouri State Attorney General Herbert S. Hadley began court hearings
to prove that the Standard Oil Company of Indiana, the Waters-Pierce Oil Company, and
the Republic Oil Company were parts of a single monopolistic conspiracy. He issued one
of his thirty-four subpoenas to John D. Rockefeller, the most powerful business tycoon
in the United States and the founder of Standard Oil. Rockefeller ignored the subpoena,
leaving the agitated press to speculate about his whereabouts. In June, David Watson, the
Attorney General of Ohio, announced his resolve to prosecute Standard Oil for violating
the state’s antitrust law. In November, U.S. Attorney General Charles J. Bonaparte began
prosecution of Standard Oil of New Jersey under the Sherman Antitrust Act. In the same
month, the Circuit Court of Missouri opened a lawsuit against Rockefeller and his clos-
est associates to dissolve Standard Oil of New Jersey, the holding company controlling
more than sixty other companies. Thus began a massive attack against America’s largest
Vadim Volkov is associate professor of sociology at the Political Science and Sociology Depart-
ment at the European University in St. Petersburg. In 2005–6, he was the European Commission
at Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin’s Marie-Curie Fellow. In 2001–5, he was Sociology Department
chair at the Higher School of Economics, St. Petersburg Branch; in 1999–2001, he was Social Sci-
ence Research Council/MacArthur Foundation Postdoctoral Fellow for the International Peace and
Security Program. Dr. Volkov received his PhD in sociology from the University of Cambridge in
1995 and Higher Education Degree from Leningrad State University’s Faculty of Economics in
1987. He is the author of Violent Entrepreneurs: The Use of Force in the Making of Russian Capi-
talism (Cornell University Press, 2002) and of articles in Social Research, Politics and Society,
and Europe-Asia Studies. His research interests include economic sociology, problems of the state
and violence, public and private security, comparative mafia, and the sociology of everyday life.
Copyright © 2008 Heldref Publications
240
Standard Oil and Yukos 241
oil company and its owners. From November 18 to 20, 1908, Rockefeller gave three days
of court testimony. In November 1909, the first court announced its decision to dissolve
Standard Oil of New Jersey, which Standard Oil immediately appealed to the U.S. Supreme
Court. On May 15, 1911, Chief Justice Edward Douglas White announced the final verdict:
the Court required Standard Oil to divest itself of all its subsidiaries within six months.
It took the federal government, first under President Theodore Roosevelt, and then under
President William Howard Taft, more than five years to disassemble what was then the
world’s biggest oil company.1
On July 2, 2003, Russian law-enforcement authorities arrested billionaire Platon Leb-
edev, chairman of the Board of Directors of Menatep, the oil giant Yukos’s financial center.
The General Procuracy charged Lebedev with financial fraud dating back to the 1993–94
privatization of the phosphate-producing plant Apatit, and with tax evasion by Menatep
subsidiaries in Tomsk Oblast. On October 25, Mikhail Khodorkovsky, the head of Yukos
and one of Russia’s leading tycoons, was arrested and charged with fraud, tax evasion, and
theft. In October 2003, the General Procuracy froze 44 percent of Yukos stock (a major
part of it belonging to Khodorkovsky and his closest associates). During 2004, Russia’s
Federal Taxation Ministry filed $27.5 billion in tax claims against Yukos for unpaid taxes
and fines. On December 19, to meet the claim on Yukos’s main assets, the oil mining
company Yuganskneftegaz was auctioned and purchased for $9.35 billion by an unknown
company that was later bought by the state oil company Rosneft for less than $30,000.
It took the Russian federal authorities one and a half years to assert state control over
Yuganskneftegaz, a company that produced 62 percent of all Yukos’s oil. Khodorkovsky
and Lebedev were sentenced to eight years in prison.2
Formally, in both cases, the state attacked the country’s largest oil company. The two
cases have similar sets of principal players and similar conflicts between the wealthiest and
the most powerful; or, more accurately, the conflicts themselves determined who would
ultimately become the most powerful (and perhaps also the most wealthy). The events
previously outlined are separated by some one hundred years and took place in different
countries with dissimilar histories and cultures. Are they comparable? If so, what should
be compared? The analogies applicable to the two cases, I argue, derive from the similar
political and economic conditions in which they emerged. The comparison highlights
structural conditions and historical situations that produced the cases against Standard
Oil and Yukos. I refer to these conditions as “early capitalism,” a somewhat more neutral
substitute for normatively charged terms, such as “wild capitalism” or “primitive capitalist
accumulation.”3
The comparison is intended to highlight a sociohistorical condition in which individual
actors are stronger than institutions. In such a condition, institutions do not have sufficient
authority to significantly constrain the actors’ pursuit of their private goals or to limit the choice
of means to reach these goals. Actors are able to use institutions instrumentally, to create or
bend them—and thus adapt them—to serve their own interests. These interests and goals are
essentially the accumulation of wealth and power. What is extraordinary about early capitalism
is the speed with which actors gain wealth and power and the resulting inequalities.
Early capitalism is an environment in which there are no constraints sufficient to pre-
vent a plurality of strong actors emerging. There also is not one dominant actor that can
create a lasting hierarchy. Domination either by force or by law is impossible. In such an
environment, anarchic competition will prevail: actors employ all possible means to ensure
242 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
included: high but unstable growth; sharp inequalities and disproportions; the domination
of acquisitive interest; weak constraints on the means of advancing this interest; no insti-
tutional divide between economic and political undertakings; and economic and political
spheres driven by “strong actors.”
inspired.9 Both men compared contemporary big-business leaders, especially railroad and
oil magnates, to the aggressive nobility of the medieval Rhine, who robbed travelers pass-
ing through their land. The comparison implied that the business leaders knew no limits
or constraints in their acquisitive practices.10
In the early 1900s, Progressive journalists published renewed criticisms of the robber
barons, generating public support for state policies that would undercut the trusts’ power.
Matthew Josephson’s 1934 book The Robber Barons, published during the Great Depres-
sion, firmly established the term and with it the general attitude toward the Gilded Age and
its main actors. In the preface, Josephson characterized the book’s subjects:
They were aggressive men, as were the
first feudal barons; sometimes they were “[The robber barons’] entrepreneur-
lawless; in important crises, nearly all of ial style, which intertwined predatory
them tended to act without those estab-
lished moral principles which fixed more
activities with large-scale construction
or less the conduct of the common people efforts, became the hallmark of the
of the community. At the same time, it Gilded Age.”
has been noted, many of them showed
volcanic energy and qualities of courage
which, under another economic clime,
might have fitted them for immensely
useful social constructions, and rendered
them glorious rather than hateful to their
people. These men were robber barons as
were their medieval counterparts, the dominating figures of an aggressive economic age.11
Chester Destler classified and ranked the robber barons’ dominant incentives. The
acquisitive drive’s preeminence came as no surprise; the “monopoly profit” motive occu-
pied first place for twenty-five of his forty-three leading entrepreneurs. The second most
significant motive, clearly present in nineteen cases, was imperialism—that is, expanding
one’s power domain, which, according to Destler, was meaningfully distinguishable from
mere acquisition. The promoters’ profits ranked third with fifteen seekers, and manufac-
turing, transportation, and speculative profits tied for fourth place, each of the three traits
representing a significant motive for twelve entrepreneurs. A combination of easy profi-
teering, such as looting corporations or railroad machinations, completes the list. Destler
concluded that “profits from the routine production and services for consumption held a
decidedly tertiary place.”12
The capacity to move goods fast, far, and inexpensively from production sites to markets
was one of the key factors in explosive capitalist growth. The first cohort of robber barons
emerged as a result of multiple speculations, stock manipulations, and hostile takeovers
accompanying new post–Civil War railway construction projects.13 Their entrepreneurial
style, which intertwined predatory activities with large-scale construction efforts, became
the hallmark of the Gilded Age. By 1867, Cornelius Vanderbilt had consolidated the
railway system around New York City, issuing watered stock for his merged New York
Central and Hudson River Railroad. He was determined to build new routes to connect
the East Coast with the industrial and agricultural production around the Great Lakes. He
sought control over the existing Erie Railroad system, a large share of which belonged to
James “Big Jim” Fisk, Daniel Drew, and Jay Gould. The trio issued new stock to extend
Standard Oil and Yukos 245
the railway eastward and secure the strategic route for themselves. Having learned about
the rival plan, Vanderbilt attempted a hostile takeover, secretly purchasing Erie bonds
and securing a decision from a New York court prohibiting any additional issuing of Erie
stock. Fisk, Drew, and Gould, the “Erie ring,” learned about Vanderbilt’s actions and struck
back. First, they sold large numbers of Erie bonds at a high market price, which Vanderbilt
quickly bought, pushing the price up. Then, just when Vanderbilt thought he had acquired
enough to take over the railroad, the Erie ring, in defiance of the court prohibition, printed
5 million additional bonds, flooding the market and dramatically reducing both the price
of bonds and Vanderbilt’s share of them. This led to a typical early-capitalist corporate
conflict, the 1867–68 “Erie War.” Vanderbilt responded by having the court issue arrest
warrants for his competitors. To escape arrest, the Erie ring hired armed guards and fled
to New Jersey. The warring parties spent huge sums on attorneys and bribes to New York
judicial authorities, while different courts issued conflicting decisions forbidding and
legalizing the Erie railroad bonds. The outcome was determined by the price the parties
were prepared to pay to judicial authorities, and when Vanderbilt was no longer prepared
for further expenditure he suggested a settlement. He agreed to sell much of his Erie stock
to Fisk and his partners at a favorable price, and in so doing secured two seats on the Erie
railroad system’s board of directors.
When strong agents enter into property conflict in conditions of high autonomy
and weak constraints on the choice of means, the outcome may be decided through
violence. Control over transportation networks and financial flows that connected min-
ing enterprises to markets provided an opportunity to control these enterprises without
owning them; this became a common stratagem later employed by Rockefeller. The
war over the Pennsylvania route between Fisk-Gould and rivals Joseph Ramsey and J.
P. Morgan similarly manifested the anarchy characteristic of early capitalism.14 Mor-
gan emerged triumphant in this corporate war, established his business reputation, and
began his rise to economic leadership. Railroad construction was the main breeding
ground for robber barons, although they were for the most part financial manipulators,
not track builders.15
In contrast to these early speculators and promoters, who amassed large fortunes but cre-
ated little value, the cohort of robber barons who came of age in the 1880s and 1890s was
more socially productive—they developed large-scale manufacturing and introduced techni-
cal innovations. Even though monopoly profits and imperialism were their major incentives,
the inevitable by-products of these pursuits were economic growth and industrial moderniza-
tion. Werner Sombart regarded American robber barons (alongside people like Cecil Rhodes)
as models of a new type of capitalist actor whose chief obsession was “to see their business
thriving,” and, “as for acquisitiveness, it was forced upon them, even though they may never
have set out with that as their goal.”16 This preoccupation with business development is what
Destler identified as the imperialist motive distinguishable from mere profiteering—that is,
when expansion of the enterprise rather than personal enrichment becomes the chief goal.
The leaders of this cohort were Andrew Carnegie, Morgan, and Rockefeller. But their con-
structive role was acknowledged only later, during the period of American revisionist histo-
riography in the 1950s. Before then, they were widely seen as proponents of fraudulent and
conspiratorial business methods and engines of corruption.17 The reason may have been that
whereas successors judged the results, contemporaries focused on their methods of accumu-
lating wealth—the means by which “empires” were built—and their lifestyles.
246 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
Party machines and congressmen exercised far more real power than did presidents. The
executive branch not only did not have an administration to carry out independent policies,
but also did not have any assistants. Until the end of the nineteenth century, the central state’s
efforts to regulate business were irresolute and inconsequential. Stephen Skowronek referred
to state activity as “patchwork.”23 American politicians limited themselves to a few federal
regulations and commissions, such as the 1887 Interstate Commerce Act and the Interstate
Commerce Commission and the 1890 Sherman Act, to respond to concrete problems and the
public pressure to address them. These measures were generally ineffectual.
By 1900, industrialization, large corporations’ consolidation of economic power,
and the formation of new national markets—the forces that determined the lives of
human communities—transcended rural community institutions, causing widespread
alienation. The incomprehensible methods used by corporations to control the economy,
politics perceived as unresponsive to the public interest, and growing class tensions
were the main reasons for the Progressive movement’s emergence.24 The new urban
middle class became the main force demanding that (1) politicians improve their moral
standards, (2) government free itself from the influence of special interest groups, and
(3) government increase public control over corporations. According to Robert Wiebe,
by 1900, “enough bitter conflict and blasted dreams had combined with a vague sense
of diminishing bounty to generate a strong demand for order.”25 As the federal govern-
ment began to meet the demands of the Progressive movement, the (re)construction of
the state became the central political process.
Throughout its early history, Standard Oil confronted episodic but fierce resistance from
independent companies, state courts, and federal commissions, nonetheless managing to
ward off the attacks in court or invent new organizational forms, such as front companies,
to escape prosecution. It remained impregnable against both state and federal governments
whose administrative capacity was minimal. Several states adopted antitrust acts, but these
failed to cause significant damage. Standard Oil had operated on a national scale and soon
expanded to become global, far exceeding the jurisdiction of state governments.
When New Jersey adopted a law permitting corporations to purchase shares of corpora-
tions in any other state, New Jersey–based holding companies developed elaborate owner-
ship structures uniting other companies across the country. Between 1898 and 1903, 183
New Jersey–based holding companies had total capitalization of $4 billion—one-twentieth
of the United States’ total wealth, nearly twice the amount of money in circulation in the
country, and more than four times all manufacturing combinations’ capitalization between
1860 and 1893.28
While business developed new forms of consolidation, the Sherman Act was, for a
decade, generally regarded as a failure. As Hans Thorelli concludes in his comprehensive
study of antitrust policy, “efforts to enforce the law were generally haphazard, sporadic
and uncoordinated in addition to the fact that they were frequently half-hearted.”29 The
executive branch did not provide leadership or coordination to enforce the law. Congress
believed laws should be self-enforced and did not allocate any funds for antitrust enforce-
ment. District courts and attorneys had no experience in applying the law to corporations,
no personnel, and no resources to collect the complex evidence needed to litigate against
corporations whose resources and scale were incomparably greater than the courts.30
By the early 1900s, reforms initiated in 1883 produced their intended effect—the
depoliticization of the civil service.31 After numerous media revelations of corruption
and monopoly policies, public opinion turned firmly against trusts. Several legal instru-
ments, including the Sherman Act, were available, but no potent political leadership yet
existed. In 1900, Roosevelt strongly stated that “nothing needs closer attention, nothing
deserves to be treated with more courage, caution, and sanity, than the relations of the
State to corporate wealth, and indeed to vast individual wealth.”32 When President Wil-
liam McKinley was assassinated in 1901 (the third presidential assassination during the
Gilded Age), Roosevelt ascended to the presidency and implemented antitrust policies.
To implement his agenda, Roosevelt had to break free from the Republican Party’s influ-
ence. Roosevelt rejected Senator George Clement Perkins’s and Senator Marcus Hanna’s
requests to downplay strong antitrust rhetoric in his first presidential address (both were
major brokers between the federal government and Wall Street) and positioned himself
as a national, rather than a party, leader. Roosevelt transferred political authority to the
executive branch and strengthened the organization, particularly the Department of Com-
merce and Industries and the Department of Commerce and Labor (the first new depart-
ment since the Civil War). Roosevelt also revived the Interstate Commerce Commission
and induced Congress to pass several important acts enhancing the powers of federal
offices and commissions.
The government inaugurated the era of trust-busting in February 1902, opening pro-
ceedings against the Northern Securities Company, a holding company for five major
railroads, jointly controlled by Harriman, Hill, and Morgan. The main reason for initiating
the case was to assert the federal government’s supremacy over corporations. Roosevelt
Standard Oil and Yukos 249
wrote in his 1913 memoirs: “When I became President . . . [t]he absolutely vital question
was whether the Government had power to control [interstate corporations] at all. . . . It
was useless to discuss methods of controlling big business by the National Government
until it was definitely settled that the National Government had the power to control it.”33
As the Northern Securities case gained momentum, Morgan visited the White House,
hoping to settle the issue, but Roosevelt insisted that the case be settled in court and alleg-
edly remarked that Morgan “could not help regarding me a big rival operator, who either
intended to ruin all his interests or else could be induced to come to an agreement to ruin
none.” In 1904, the Supreme Court ordered the dissolution of Northern Securities, estab-
lishing the Sherman Act’s first successfully applied precedent and tremendously boosting
Roosevelt’s popularity.
By the time the Bureau of Corporations opened investigations into Standard Oil in 1906,
Roosevelt’s overwhelming 1904 electoral victory and a record of successful trust-bust-
ing cases boosted his power and popularity tremendously. Public opinion was decisively
against Standard Oil after Lloyd and Ida Tarbell’s series of magazine articles and books
were published. Tarbell’s two volumes on the History of the Standard Oil Company (1904)
catalogued the company’s business practices and made its abuses known to the critical
public well before the Bureau of Corporations published the results of its own investiga-
tion. Roosevelt used the bureau’s report to justify railway regulation. Hoping to reach an
agreement and avoid further attacks, Standard Oil canceled most of the rates that the bureau
had condemned. However, the antitrust campaign reached its high point as several cases
against Standard Oil were initiated and the bureau launched a new investigation focused
on the oil industry. It soon produced another electrifying report describing price-cutting
practices, collusive agreements, public deception, and other practices. This report served
as the basis for the lawsuits that followed. By the summer of 1907, the federal government
had seven lawsuits pending against Standard Oil and its subsidiaries, in addition to the
cases that state attorneys initiated. The suit to dissolve Standard Oil under the Sherman
Act, filed in the Missouri Circuit Court, proved fatal for the corporation. In 1911, Standard
Oil was separated into thirty-eight independent companies, their stock divided among
shareholders, and management reorganized to divide control. Exxon Mobil, Chevron, and
Amoco—today’s largest oil companies—all subsequently emerged from this breakup after
many permutations.
Some scholars view Standard Oil’s dismemberment as purely political because, rather
than having a positive effect, it further benefited the owners and damaged consumers. In a
1912 speech, Roosevelt noted: “All companies are under the same control. . . . The Price
of stock has gone up over one hundred per cent. . . . At the same time, the price of oil
to the consumer has gone up by leaps and bounds.”34 It is now recognized that, from an
economic standpoint, the corporation’s division was meaningless—if not harmful—but the
government consistently pursued the policy, and the public faithfully supported it.
The rationale for antitrust policy comes from the context of Roosevelt’s state-building
efforts. Reviewing the application of the Sherman Act, Thorelli notes that, under condi-
tions of insufficient resources and inadequate experience, it “will be difficult for any
administration to steer clear of charges of being susceptible to undue political influence.”
Strengthened presidential powers enabled the systematic attack on the biggest corpora-
tions; Roosevelt’s efforts to create a strong administration and to act outside party politics
with overwhelming popular support made trust-busting possible. Trust-busting was itself
250 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
part of state-building, however. In this sense, trust-busting was not only a critical test of
state capacity but also a means of gaining and institutionalizing that capacity.
allowing them to exert influence nationally. These conditions emerged differently in Rus-
sia and the United States; the latter had no legacy of a heavily industrialized economy
and gigantic state apparatus. But by the mid-1990s, these legacies had been reduced to
institutional wreckage in Russia and no longer exerted any decisive structural influence.
By 1997, strong actors coalesced into competing political-economic groups, each con-
sisting of owners of large assets either in finance, industry, or the media. These actors
formed alliances with the central government officials and regional administrators. Once
the strong actors had gained control of power and resources in an environment with few,
if any, institutional constraints (moral, legal, or bureaucratic), their interaction inevitably
assumed the features of anarchic competition.
The Oligarchs
A new round of economic and political empowerment for a select group of private owners
took place in 1995–97. The “loans-for-shares” auctions, reportedly invented by Anatoly
Chubais and Vladimir Potanin, were designed to raise money for the state budget and Presi-
dent Boris Yeltsin’s electoral fund for the 1996 elections. The plan involved transferring
twenty-nine large state enterprises to private banks in exchange for “loans” that would not
be repaid. As a result, selected banks with connections to the government received valu-
able assets at a price far below market value (including Yukos and Sibneft). When Yeltsin
was reelected, the bankers who contributed to his campaign rushed to claim posts in the
government and further privatization opportunities. Boris Berezovsky’s famous interview
with the Financial Times on October 29, 1996, was the first public manifesto of the rising
oligarchs: “We hired Anatoly Chubais. We invested huge amounts of money in the election
campaign. We secured Yeltsin’s election victory. Now we have the right to assume posts in
the government and enjoy the fruits of our victory.”38 He named bankers who controlled
half of the Russian economy: Khodorkovsky, Potanin, Alexandr Smolensky, Vladimir
Gussinsky, Vladmir Vinogradov, Mikhail Friedman, and himself.
In Russian, there are no terms equivalent to “robber baron” or “oligarch,” perhaps
because there has been no comparable group of economic actors in Russian history. The
term oligarkhi became popular in 1997 in publications by Alexander Solzhenitsyn, publi-
cist Alexander Privalov, and liberal government minister Boris Nemtsov. The first cohort of
oligarchs consisted of a few individuals who controlled large banks, enterprises, and media
resources in different combinations. Smolensky’s and Vinogradov’s assets were mainly
concentrated in the banking sector; Berezovsky’s and Gussinsky’s assets came from
banking, enterprise financial flows, and the media; Potanin and Khodorkovsky collected
natural-resource sector assets. Russia’s first cohort of oligarchs obtained their wealth
and influence by controlling financial and information flows. They relied on the political
influence that they either bought or acquired in exchange for lending their media power
to politicians to maintain their property and expand their power. At the same time, they
jealously watched one another and waged wars for political influence, natural resources,
and communications (e.g., the “wars” over Norilsk Nikel and Sviazinvest in 1997). The
1998 financial crisis ruined the oligarchs’ banking business and the groups that heavily
depended on it, such as SBS-Agro (Smolensky) and Inkombank (Vinogradov). The survi-
vors’ core assets—industrial, rather than financial (Gazprom, Interros-ONEKSIM, Yukos,
LUKOil)—grew stronger, as did the new financial-industrial business groups (Sibal, Alfa,
and Moskovsky Delovoi Mir [MDM]).
252 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
Hostile Takeovers
Scholars gave the massive redistribution and consolidation of property in 1999–2003 much
less attention than the previous era of ownership change.39 If the first wave of privatization
gave unconditional advantages to “insiders,” that is, former Soviet directors and workers,
the new round of competition for economic assets featured the aggressive advance of
“outsiders,” that is, new business groups that used all available means, including fraud
and violence, to change the management and achieve control over thousands of industrial
enterprises, including the largest ones. Large industry required a much greater degree of
concentration if it was to be restructured and efficiently managed. The ownership structure
changed within about four years. A dozen new business groups concentrated industrial
assets among themselves, leading to the appearance of a new cohort of business leaders.
The 1998–2002 transition was made possible by the Russian government’s laissez-
faire policies: Moscow focused on reducing the excessive regional sovereignty, leaving
the oligarchs to compete for assets. The ultraliberal 1998 bankruptcy law triggered a rise
in hostile takeovers, which reached nationwide proportions by 2001, involving thousands
of cases each year. It receded after 2003, when a revised bankruptcy law increased state
supervision.
Enterprise takeovers were typically framed as either bankruptcy proceedings, involving
the use of the 1998 “Law on Bankruptcy,” or as legal actions in defense of the minority
shareholders’ rights, using the “Law on Joint-Stock Companies.” Both laws enabled the
new oligarchs to quickly and creatively advance their interests. The 1998 law provided
a relatively easy way of changing an enterprise’s management—a procedure critical for
the success of any hostile takeover. It permitted arbitration courts to initiate bankruptcy
procedures against enterprises when their outstanding debts exceeded the equivalent of 500
minimum-wage payments—about 42,000 rubles in 1999 (about $15,000), and were not
repaid within three months of the due date.40 In the aftermath of the barter economy, many
companies, especially utilities, had large debts. After the August 1998 crisis, the extremely
low debt threshold carried enormous potential for seizing weaker owners’ major assets. By
the end of the 1990s, many enterprises were de facto bankrupt and used by their managers
for personal enrichment; after 1998, they were bankrupted de jure and expropriated by
more resourceful actors.
The practice became known as “contract bankruptcies” (zakaznye bankrotstva), imply-
ing a hidden economic agenda (other than improving economic performance of the enter-
prise) and the instrumental use of law. In 2001, there were approximately 1,400 contract
bankruptcies.41 Of these, a fair proportion—probably more than half—were connected
with hostile takeovers and attempts to avoid repaying debts to outside investors or taxes to
the state. Other cases, in which external management was liquidated, may have disguised
takeovers undertaken to strip assets. Given that the hostile takeover targets were mainly
medium and large enterprises significant to Russia’s economy, the estimated figure of
1,400 points to an immense redistribution of wealth and resources.
Target selection for hostile takeovers was governed by the logic of vertical integration
(policies of concentrating assets in a given industry) and by long-term profits or short-term
asset stripping. The major targets were:
• Profitable export-oriented enterprises (e.g., aluminum, steel, or cellulose production and
electric machine-building);
Standard Oil and Yukos 253
• Enterprises of the “fuel and energy complex” (oil and gas mining facilities, oil-processing
plants, electric power plants, etc.);
• Ore-processing plants (vanadium, strontium, etc.) and similar enterprises that supplied
vital ingredients to metallurgical enterprises and were therefore vital for creating verti-
cally integrated business groups;
• Enterprises in consumer industries with stable markets (alcohol, food, cosmetics, etc.);
• Any enterprise possessing valuable assets that could be profitably sold.
This scheme’s most prominent cases took place in the metallurgy, oil, and gas industries,
and also in the cellulose and paper industries, and involved the largest enterprises of the
Soviet and post-Soviet economy. Among the most prominent cases were Siberian Alumi-
num’s (Sibal) acquisitions of the Novokuznetsk Aluminum Plant (NKAZ), the Kuznetsky
Metallurgical Plant in Kemerovo region, and the Krasnoyarsk Aluminum Plant. Sibal
belonged to Oleg Deripaska and Mikhail Chernoi’s business group and was supported
by “copper group” head Makhmud Iskanderov.42 Other takeovers included the Leningrad
Metal Plant by Potanin’s Interros and several takeovers of ore-, gas-, and oil-processing
plants by Friedman’s “Alpha-Eko” group, including the notorious 1999 bankruptcy take-
over of the oil company Chernogorneft, and the gas-extraction enterprise Rospan (eventu-
ally taken over by Yukos). These represent just a few examples.43 Bankruptcy procedures as
part of enterprise takeovers were also used during the violent dispute over the Kachkanar
vanadium ore-processing plant in the Urals, the mineral fertilizers plant Fosforit, and in
the corporate war for the huge cellulose plants in Bratsk and Kotlass between Sibal and
Ilim Pulp Enterprise in 2002–4.44
Key features of enterprise takeovers included the instrumental use of arbitration courts
to create a semblance of legality and reliance on special police forces and regional
administrations to enforce the change of management and ownership—physical and
administrative coercion. The media frequently reported violent clashes in and around
enterprise offices. The methods and practices are best illustrated by the NKAZ case.
The summer 2000 assault on NKAZ demonstrates the application of the bankruptcy
scheme backed by coercion.45 According to press reports, the energy company Kuzbas-
senergo (subordinated to the state-owned United Energy System headed by Chubais)
initiated the bankruptcy procedure against NKAZ, which allowed “Sibal” to change the
NKAZ’s management and appoint its representatives. Kuzbassenergo used managerial
control to influence the owners. The new management swiftly linked the enterprise to
their own trading companies and redirected its financial flows, thus acquiring de facto
control of its supplies, sales, and finances, coercing the brothers Mikhail and Yuri
Zhivilo, whose company MIKOM owned the controlling interest of NKAZ, to sell it to
“Sibal.” The Procuracy of Kemerovo oblast assisted in coercing the brothers by initiat-
ing a criminal investigation against Mikhail Zhivilo, accusing him of planning Kem-
erovo Governor Aman Tuleev’s assassination. The investigation was conducted by the
West-Siberian antiorganized crime directorate. Zhivilo left the country to avoid arrest;
MIKOM’s assets (NKAZ and a number of coal mines) were transferred to Deripaska
and Makhmudov through additionally issued shares and other techniques.46 In this case,
press reports alleged that the regional governor was directly involved in assisting the
takeover by supplying local administrative resources and claiming to be the target of an
assassination attempt.47
254 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
The April 2002 attempt to change the management of the Taganrog Metallurgical Plant
(Tagmet) in Rostov oblast represents another typical corporate conflict of the period—man-
agement with a majority or controlling share and an outside investor seeking full ownership
and control over the enterprise. The business group Alfa-Eco attempted to increase its 42
percent share of Tagmet by trying to arrange for the Federal Securities Commission to
annul the previous share issue to reduce Tagmet director Sergei Bidash’s share from 54 per-
cent to slightly over 40 percent. Bidash disputed the decision in court and refused to cede
control to Alfa-Eco. Alfa-Eco then attempted to take the enterprise by force, using special
police units—essentially antiriot police. The enterprise’s security service and workers’
militia defended the plant in a violent clash. To prevent further violence, the president’s
representative in the Southern District had to intervene and compel the sides to return to
court. Following several months of litigation and negotiations, Bidash sold his share to
Alfa’s major competitor in the metallurgical industry, the MDM business group, whose
administrative resources matched Alfa’s, making the plant less attractive to the latter.48
These episodes are reminiscent of the concentration of industrial assets and vertical
integration created during America’s Gilded Age. In some cases, Russian oligarchs used
precisely the same schemes as did the robber barons. The similar aims and methods of
achieving them were produced by the structural situation of early capitalism. Anarchic
competition, approaching a war of all against all, allowed preservation and expansion (ear-
lier referred to as “imperialism”) to override the motive of mere enrichment. In the Rus-
sian case, the oligarchs undertook vertical integration to ensure that their core enterprises
remained stable and to prevent takeovers by competitors. Consolidation aimed to secure
technologically critical transactions through direct ownership. Control over bauxite mining
enterprises and power stations were crucial for maintaining an aluminum plant. Absent
such control, energy and bauxite providers would have leverage over the plant. Protecting
one’s own assets required seizing those of others.
The Sibal group consolidated and secured aluminum production assets (also
taking Roman Abramovich’s aluminum enterprises and naming the combination Russian
Aluminum). Friedman’s Alfa/Renova achieved concentrated ownership in oil, steel, the
food industry, and telecommunications; Melnichenko’s MDM consolidated coal, steel,
pipes, banking, and insurance businesses; Potanin’s Interros created a new electric energy
machine-building holding, Power Machines; and Makhmudov and Abramov’s Ural Steel
and Mining Combine (UGMK) and Evraz-Holdings accumulated assets in nonferrous
metal production and coal. The steel industry’s powerful new actors emerged around two
large plants—the Novolipetsky steel combine (Lisin) and the Cherepovetsky combine and
ore supplier (Mordashev). Not every attempt was successful: Sibal failed to gain control
of major pulp-and-paper enterprises, losing a dramatic three-year corporate war against
Ilim Pulp Enterprise, which negotiated a favorable agreement in 2004.
Between 1998 and 2003, a new cohort of oligarchs joined the 1998 crisis survivors and
2000’s political changes, principally, Putin’s election. As with the second cohort of the
American robber barons, the Russian oligarchs were industrialists (although not industri-
alizers), compared with the more speculative and parasitical first cohort. Both employed
similar methods of concentration, especially with regard to using control over technologi-
cally critical transactions and forced bankruptcies. If the robber barons used regional courts
and lobbyists in legislatures to exploit or create laws to advance their interests, their Russian
counterparts added various private or state police units to enforce property transfers. The
Standard Oil and Yukos 255
Russians appear to have been more conscious of the media’s importance; American business
leaders largely ignored the media and public opinion (Standard Oil invested in public rela-
tions only during the last two years before its demise), but the main Russian business groups
bought significant media resources to advance their property interests. The similarities are,
nonetheless, enormous. Both groups actively exploited the holding companies’ organization
to consolidate ownership and control, and to conceal their ownership structure. Ultimately,
the property and wealth accumulated by both groups has been seen largely as illegitimate.
In a World Bank study of industrial concentration in Russia that depicted the situa-
tion in 2003, the country’s twenty-two largest private owners were estimated to account
for 42 percent of employment and 39
“If the robber barons used regional percent of annual sales. Their assets
tended to be in sectors with higher
courts and lobbyists in legislatures to levels of concentrated ownership. The
exploit or create laws to advance their top ten ownership groups held assets
interests, their Russian counterparts representing 60.2 percent of Russia’s
added various private or state police stock market. By 2004, Russia had
units to enforce property transfers.” nineteen individuals whose wealth
was in excess of $1 billion. The sur-
vey also established that oligarch-
controlled enterprises displayed a
modestly higher efficiency (8 percent)
than average private firms and per-
formed significantly better than firms
under government control.49 None of Russia’s new business groups achieved a degree of
monopolization in a given industry comparable to the near complete control enjoyed by
Rockefeller, Carnegie, Vanderbilt, and a few others. The natural resource monopolies,
Gazprom and Unified Energy System, are predominantly state-owned, whereas the railway
system was split into several independent operators. Otherwise, key industries have at least
two or more competing core groups.
$100 million loan from the state-owned Vneshekonombank, Berezovsky agreed to transfer
his 49 percent stake in the ORT television company back to the state. In July, procurators
started an investigation of Berezovsky in connection with Aeroflot’s foreign currency
accounts; by November 2000, he had gone into exile and Abramovich had bought out his
share in Sibneft.50 Tax police and tax inspectors visited LUKOil and Sibneft offices in the
summer of 2000, and Potanin was pressured to pay more for his acquisition of Norilsk
Nikel. These measures were intended to display resolve, demonstrate the government’s
capacity for independent political action, and impose tax discipline. Above all, they estab-
lished the state (and its leader) as an independent actor. The pressure on the first cohort of
oligarchs was combined with a radical tax reform that lowered the personal income tax to
a 13 percent flat rate and the profit tax to 24 percent.
After the change of power, the central question posed by big business was: Would they
have immunity for their Yeltsin-era acquisitions? In 2000, the president and oligarchs
concluded an implicit contract. The government mysteriously referred to it as the “new
social contract.” Later, Khodorkovsky would recall in his last public interview before his
arrest that the problem of privatization’s irreversibility was “kind of solved in the year
2000, when the President, having gathered big businessmen, said that we are creating a
watershed: that which was before 2000 is now subject to history, and now, after 2000, let
us live according to a different set of laws. But if someone does not want to live according
to them, then we will sort them out (budem razbiratsia). I think that this social contract
was that which allowed a stable development of society over three years.”51
The contours and logic of this contract are clear enough. The state would not review
previous privatization deals; private business groups would not interfere in public politics
or buy officials; because the state protects property laws, large businesses would invest; the
state would reduce the tax and bureaucratic burden; and businesses would pay taxes (cease
tax-evasion schemes). Putin also revived the Union of Industrialists and Entrepreneurs as
a corporate lobby and representative of large business in negotiations with the govern-
ment. Gussinsky’s and Berezovsky’s dispossession and pressure on other companies were
examples of enforcing the contract.
In practice, both sides had difficulty abiding by the contract’s terms. First, both the state
and the big businesses are collective entities lacking internal cohesion. Each experienced
collective-action problems. The state could not enforce order in its own ranks and failed
to discipline agencies that marketed their administrative and coercive capacity for private
gain. During the period of hostile takeovers, business groups actively formed alliances
with regional governors and administrators to gain advantage in the fierce competition for
assets. Observers identified at least three different competing factions, even within the pres-
ident’s office and the government. The state did not successfully restrain its rent-seeking
bureaucrats, who systematically interfered in property disputes. Business groups, in turn,
continued lobbying and sought tax optimization.
Second, both parties continued to perceive their relationship with the other as a zero-
sum gain, despite the rhetoric of partnership. The state strengthened the executive branch
with a contingent of officials transferred from the Federal Securities Bureau and account-
able to the presidential administration.52 The state also consolidated its own economic
assets by creating state holdings in strategic branches (e.g., military and aerospace) and
reorganizing the management of state enterprises and those companies with a significant
state share (Gazprom, Transneft, and Rosneft). Fearing the state’s growing power, busi-
Standard Oil and Yukos 257
ness groups turned to large foreign investors, and some renewed attempts to move assets
offshore.53 However, both parties generally preferred to see the contract respected rather
than broken, especially because its implicit nature allowed enough room to renegotiate
details and to adjust to new circumstances. The resulting equilibrium helped produce an
impressive economic recovery that benefited all parties. But there were exceptions.
Yukos’s Growth
The company was created by the 1992 merger of Yuganskneftegaz and Samarneftegaz,
and Khodorkovsky acquired the company in December 1995 for $160 million in cash
and a promise of $150 million in investments. David Hoffman offers a graphic descrip-
tion of the deal and characterizes it as theft—Khodorkovsky’s price was far below the
company’s value and part of the money came from Yukos’s unpaid taxes and loans for
future oil supplies.55 Later, Yukos acquired control over east Siberian oilfields. By 2003,
258 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
Yukos’s capitalization was approaching $30 billion. It was Russia’s largest company in
terms of its assets’ market value, the second largest in terms of profits, and fourth in sales.
As Khodorkovsky once boasted, Yukos fueled every sixth car in Russia. Yukos’s growth
came from several sources: (1) the rise of oil prices after 1999 tripled oil revenues; (2)
large investments, chiefly from foreign credits, made it possible to increase production and
acquire new assets (Tomskneft, Talakan oil fields); (3) elaborate tax optimization schemes
saved approximately $2 billion per year; and (4) the creation of an efficient management
structure with the highest proportion of foreign citizens among top management and
shareholders of any Russian company. Yukos was partly owned by Menatep and by two
offshore companies, Yukos Universal Limited and Halley Enterprises, both based on the
Isle of Man. As in many companies, the real owners and beneficiaries were hidden behind
a multilevel holding structure.
Yukos and Sibneft’s merger was a defining moment. Plans for the merger were first
announced in early 1998 (when Berezovsky still owned Sibneft), in preparation for auc-
tioning state oil company Rosneft; but these were abandoned four months later, as oil
prices dropped. Rosneft remained under state control. As the oil sector recovered, so too
did the planned merger. By the summer of 2003, Yukos completed the deal with Sibneft
and was on the verge of creating the largest Russian oil company and the fourth largest in
the world, paving Yukos’s way to global leadership. Yukos paid $3 billion plus 26 percent
of its own stock for 92 percent of Sibneft.
Yukos’s postmerger enlargement increased its share of oil production and its mar-
ket value. Negotiations were under way to sell a large share (40 percent or higher) of
the newborn giant to U.S. investors, either Exxon-Mobil or Chevron-Texaco. Such a
deal could have firmly secured property rights for Khodorkovsky and his associates,
because putting pressure on or confiscating a company with a large foreign share,
especially American, was beyond the Russian state’s capacity at the time. By increas-
ing the company’s size, introducing international transparency standards, and involv-
ing foreign investors, Khodorkovsky was clearly moving toward a much stronger and
independent position vis-à-vis the state, perhaps strong enough to be able to ignore
the implicit contract.
For the state (and especially security-minded people, whose presence increased dur-
ing the Putin administration), this was clearly a threat. An economically powerful actor
within the state’s boundaries created the potential for unpredictable shifts in the power
balance and political consequences. It does not matter whether Khodorkovsky really
intended to change the political regime or to claim a top executive position for himself,
as the first cohort oligarchs did. The ruling elite saw that he was acquiring the capacity
to do so. Additionally, the government feared that U.S. oil transnationals would gain
control over a large share of Russian oil, and in the eyes of Russian statesmen, Ameri-
can transnationals, the White House, and the Pentagon are all part of the same entity.
Another dangerously uncertain issue was what Khodorkovsky could do with $10–15
billion once the share of Yukos was sold. The government believed there was a high
probability that this money would end up in offshore accounts. The paradox is that each
stage of the Yukos reorganization could be justified in terms of economic efficiency
and profit, but the total result points to core national security issues on which the state
claims a monopoly. According to Nevzlin’s latest revelations, Abramovich’s actions sent
Yukos down.56 In short, Abramovich wanted to sell Sibneft to Yukos at a high price, so
Standard Oil and Yukos 259
he convinced Khodorkovsky that they could then sell it to Americans at an even higher
price, claiming that he had already secured a go-ahead from the Kremlin. Abramovich
either lied or overestimated his influence, so that when the Kremlin learned about the
negotiations between Khodorkovsky and the U.S. multinationals, it decided to destroy
Yukos. Abramovich called back the merger agreement, walking away with a $3 billion
advance from Yukos and his company still intact.
the end of summer 2003. On December 23, 2004, at a press conference that took place just
a few days after the Yuganskneftegaz auction, Putin described his vision of the outcome:
“the state, using absolutely legal market mechanisms, secures its interests.”59
Conclusion
Comparing early capitalism in the United States from the 1870s to the first decade of the
twentieth century and Russian early capitalism between 1992 and 2005 reveals similar
structural conditions that produced similar actors and outcomes. The rapid accumulation
of capital proceeded under weak moral and legal constraints and led to the ascension
of extraordinarily powerful economic actors. The state’s weak and highly regionalized
political system provided ample opportunities for converting economic power into politi-
cal power, further undermining the divide between economy and polity. This situation
subjected Russia to particular business groups’ interests and threatened to turn the state
itself into a business enterprise. Robber barons and oligarchs initially emerged because of
predatory, mediatory, and redistributive practices in a weak institutional environment that
rewarded aggressive and predatory behavior. At a later stage, especially in the American
case, a second cohort of business tycoons’ further concentration of economic power was
predicated on aggressive managerial policies in industry and high rates of growth. Public
attitudes toward business leaders remained largely negative, irrespective of their actual
contribution to the accumulation of national wealth. Growing social tensions and mass
alienation caused an increased demand for stronger political states in the United States and
Russia. The state’s rise in the field of unregulated competition led to multiple conflicts with
existing strong actors as the state constituted itself as the agency endowed with powers
to regulate, set the rules, and pursue economic policies. Both the 1902–12 trust-busting
cases in the United States and Russia’s selective pressure and 2000–5 administrative cam-
paigns against oligarchs were more political than economic in nature; the key issue was
the state’s establishing sovereignty at the expense of big business, rather than generating
public benefits through regulation.
There are also significant differences between these periods in U.S. and Russian his-
tory. The Standard Oil case highlights the stronger constraints on the state’s actions in the
United States. At no stage in the Standard Oil proceedings did the American government
contemplate expropriating assets or pressing criminal charges against their owners. The
principle of respect for private property shaped the course and outcome of trust-busting.
The American state could not conceivably go as far as the Russian state in prosecuting
owners and managers, even though the robber barons were involved in a number of illicit
business practices. The Standard Oil case, and other trust-busting cases, changed the power
balance between the economy and polity but reinforced the power of private property as
an ethical and legal principle. In Russia, Yukos’s destruction generated growing concerns
about the security of property rights.
The international context is another major difference and another factor that shaped
the outcomes. I discussed its role only when unavoidable, as in discussion of some Rus-
sian tycoons’ strategic international partnerships. Although Standard Oil was one of the
world’s leading oil exporters by 1900, its transnational scale did not play a decisive role
in its power politics and defensive strategies vis-à-vis the government. Rockefeller could
not move capital freely across the globe; thus, Standard Oil was largely America’s internal
affair. Yukos was quite different in this regard. The internationalization of Yukos’s business
262 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
activity and foreign pressure in the company’s defense only made matters worse for the
company because it amplified painful sovereignty concerns, making the Russian state less
inclined to compromise.
NOTES
1. For an overview of the Standard Oil cases, see Bruce Bringhurst, Antitrust and the Oil
Monopoly: The Standard Oil Cases, 1890–1911 (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1979).
2. For an overview of the Yukos collapse, see “Timeline: The Rise and Fall of Yukos,” BBC
News, May 31, 2005, http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/4041551.stm (accessed July 30, 2008).
3. Karl Marx introduced the term “primitive accumulation.” “Wild capitalism” is a common
journalistic catchphrase.
4. This vision goes back to the neorealist theory of international politics formulated by
Kenneth Waltz. See Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading, MA: Addison-
Wesley, 1979). Waltz sought to explain international politics’ logic, arguing that anarchic
environments will produce this type of competition and politics irrespective of the nature
of participating units. In contrast to that, in hierarchically organized and institutionally con-
strained environments, as within states, politics will differ significantly. In such environments,
peaceful economic competition and cooperation will develop. Central to neorealism is the
divide between international politics and domestic politics and that between states and markets.
Here, I assume that the divide between international politics and internal politics is historically
contingent and, under certain circumstances, the neorealist analysis is applicable to the internal
political-economic realm.
5. For the general exposition of the period, see Sean Cashman, America in the Gilded Age: From
the Death of Lincoln to the Rise of Theodore Roosevelt. 3rd ed. (New York: New York University
Press, 1993).
6. Charles Van Hise, Concentration and Control: A Solution of the Trust Problem in the United
States (New York: Macmillan, 1912), 31–34.
7. Ibid., 21.
8. For the analysis of vertical integration’s causes, see Oliver Williamson, The Economic Institu-
tions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting (New York: Free Press, 1987).
9. See Henry Demarest Lloyd, “The Lords of Industry,” North American Review 331 (June
1884): http://www.fordham.edu/halsall/mod/1884hdlloyd.html (accessed July 25, 2008).
10. The most prominent figures in the roster of robber barons were railroad owners Cornelius
Vanderbilt, James Hill, Collis Huntington, John Fisk, Jay Gould, Leland Stanford, and Edward
Harriman in the first cohort. The second cohort consisted of Rockefeller, the creator of the
Standard Oil monopoly; steel monopolist Andrew Carnegie; bank magnate J. P. Morgan; and
meat producer Philip Armour. There were more than thirty smaller and less notorious business
leaders—all together forty-three men, according to the list composed by the economic historian
Chester Destler. Fifteen were railroad magnates, fourteen were manufacturers, five were bankers,
and the rest were promoters or speculators. See Chester Destler, “Leadership among the Robber
Barons,” in The American Past: Conflicting Interpretations of the Great Issues, ed. Sidney Fine
and Gerald S. Brown (New York: Macmillan, 1961), 2: 49.
11. Matthew Josephson, The Robber Barons: The Great American Capitalists 1861–1901 (New
York: Harcourt, Brace and Co., 1934), 3.
12. Destler, “Leadership among the Robber Barons,” 49.
13. See Thomas Cochran, Railroad Leaders, 1845–1890 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press, 1953).
14. Josephson, The Robber Barons, 131.
15. See Bradford DeLong, “Robber Barons,” Brad DeLong’s Personal Web Site, January 1, 2008,
http://econ161.berkeley.edu/Econ_Articles/carnegie/delong_moscow_paper2.html (accessed June
17, 2008).
16. Werner Sombart, The Quintessence of Capitalism: A Study of the History and Psychology of
the Modern Business Man (New York: Howard Fertig, 1967), 172.
Standard Oil and Yukos 263
17. See Edward Kirkland, “The Robber Barons Revisited,” The American Historical Review 66,
no. 1 (1960): 68–73.
18. See, for example, Matthew Josephson, The Politicos, 1865–1896 (New York: Harcourt, Brace
and Co., 1938); John Dobson, Politics in the Gilded Age: A New Perspective on Reform (New York:
Praeger, 1972).
19. Cited in Gilbert C. Fite and Jim E. Reese, An Economic History of the United States (Boston:
Houghton Mifflin), 297.
20. Destler, “Leadership among the Robber Barons,” 54.
21. Samuel Huntington made this observation, which was cited in Richard Bensel, Yankee
Leviathan: The Origins of Central State Authority in America, 1859–1877 (Cambridge, England:
Cambridge University Press, 1990), 4–5.
22. Stephen Skowronek, Building a New American State: The Expansion of National Adminis-
trative Capacities, 1877–1920 (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1982); Morton
Keller, Affairs of State: Public Life in Nineteenth Century America (Cambridge, MA: Belknap,
1977).
23. Skowronek, Building a New American State, 123.
24. Arthur Link and Richard McCormick, Progressivism (Arlington Heights, IL: Harlan David-
son, 1983).
25. Robert Wiebe, The Search for Order, 1877–1920 (New York: Hill and Wang, 1967), 186.
26. This exposition is based on several sources. See Allan Nevins, Study in Power (New York:
Scribner’s, 1953); Ida Tarbell, The History of the Standard Oil Company (New York: McClure,
Phillips & Co., 1904).
27. Van Hise, Concentration and Control, 104–6.
28. Cashman, America in the Gilded Age, 56.
29. Hans Thorelli, The Federal Antitrust Policy: Origination of an American Tradition (Balti-
more, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1955), 587.
30. See also Bringhurst, Antitrust and the Oil Monopoly.
31. Leonard White, “In Retrospect,” The American Past, 192.
32. Thorelli, Federal Anti-Trust Policy, 414.
33. Theodore Roosevelt, “The Big Stick and the Square Deal,” in Theodore Roosevelt: An
Autobiography (New York: MacMillan, 1914), http://www.bartleby.com/55/12.html (accessed July
25, 2008).
34. Cited in Nevins, Study in Power, 383.
35. For more on privatization deals and the oligarchs’ rise, see David Hoffman, The Oligarchs:
Wealth and Power in the New Russia (New York: Public Affairs, 2001).
36. See Vadim Volkov, Violent Entrepreneurs: The Use of Force in the Making of Russian
Capitalism (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2002).
37. Cynthia Roberts and Thomas Sherlock, “Bringing the Russian State Back in: Explanations of
the Derailed Transition to Market Democracy,” Comparative Politics 31, no. 4 (1999): 477–98.
38. Cited in Andre Piontkovsky, “What Went Wrong: Asian Flu or Russian Pneumonia?”
Prism 5, no. 12 (1999): http://www.jamestown.org/publications_details.php?volume_id=6&issue_
id=376&article_id=3669 (accessed September 4, 2008).
39. See Andrew Barnes, “Russia’s New Business Groups and State Power,” Post-Soviet Affairs
19, no. 2 (2003): 154–86; Vadim Volkov, “Hostile Enterprise Takeovers: Russia’s Economy in
1998–2002,” Review of Central and East European Law 29, no. 4 (2004): 527–48.
40. One of the 1992 bankruptcy regulation’s major shortcomings was that it established the debt
threshold at the level of the enterprise’s assets’ value, which was too burdensome to calculate, and
was thus regarded as an obstacle to the bankruptcy process. It also favored debtors’ interests over
creditors’. The 1998 law removed this obstacle.
41. Volkov, “Hostile Enterprise Takeovers: Russia’s Economy,” 531.
42. Nataliya Gotova, “Temnaya loshadka” [The Dark Horse], Kompaniya, August 21, 2000,
http://www.ko.ru/document.php?id=2015 (accessed July 30, 2008).
43. John Varoli, “LMZ Creditors Signal Financial Health,” St. Petersburg Times, September 26,
2000, http://www.sptimes.ru/index.php?action_id=2&story_id=12687 (accessed July 30, 2008);
264 DEMOKRATIZATSIYA
Alexandr Tutushkin, “TNK vziala Rospan” [TNK Has Taken Rospan], Vedomosti, January 15,
2003.
44. See Dmitry Sivakov and Konstantin Semin, “Semeinyi konflikt” [The Family Conflict],
Ekspert, February 7, 2000, http://expert.ru/printissues/expert/2000/05/05ex-kachgok/ (accessed
July 30, 2008); Nikolai Ulyanov, “Khronika provintsialnogo konflikta” [The Chronical of a
Provincial Conflict], Ekspert-Ural, August 28, 2000, http://expert.ru/printissues/ural/2000/05/05
ur-kachkan/ (accessed July 30, 2008)
45. Nataliya Gotova, “Delo biatlonista-otrovitelia” [The Affair of a Biatlonist-Poisoner], Kom-
paniya, August 14, 2000, http://www.ko.ru/document.php?id=1999 (accessed July 30, 2008).
46. Gotova, “The Dark Horse.”
47. Having fled abroad, Zhivilo appealed to New York’s district court, which accepted the case,
setting the claim amount at $2.7 billion. In April 2003, the court refused to process the case further,
arguing that the case should be considered in Russia.
48. Sergey Kisin, “Kak zashchishchalas stal” [How Steel Was Defended], Kommersant, April 2,
2002, http://kommersant.ru/doc.aspx?DocsID=316672 (accessed July 30, 2008); Pavel Arabov and
Alexei Ivanov, “Tagmet eshche povoiuet” [Tagmet Will Continue Fighting], Kommersant-Dengi,
April 24, 2002, http://kommersant.ru/doc.aspx?DocsID=319669 (accessed July 30, 2008).
49. Sergey Guriev and Andrei Rachinsky, “The Role of Oligarchs in Russian Capitalism,” Journal
of Economic Perspectives 19, no. 1 (2005): 131–50.
50. For details on Gussinsky’s and Berezovsky’s ousting, see Hoffman, The Oligarchs.
51. Mikhail Khodorkovsky, “Poslednee intervyu,” Mikhail Khodorkovsky’s personal Web site,
July 7, 2003, http://www.khodorkovsky.ru/speech/732.html (accessed June 18, 2008).
52. Olga Kryshtanovskaya and Stephen White, “Putin’s Militocracy,” Post Soviet Affairs 19, no. 4
(2003): 289–306.
53. See Alexander Radygin, “Rossiya v 2000–2004 godakh: Na puti k gosudarstvennomu
kapitalizmu?” [Russia in 2000–2004: On the Path to State Capitalism?], Voprosy Ekonomiki 13,
no. 4 (2004): 42–66.
54. See, for example, Andrew E. Kramer, “Russian Oil Magnate Forced to Sell to Putin Loy-
alist, He Says,” New York Times, July 31, 2007, http://www.nytimes.com/2007/07/31/business/
worldbusiness/31russneft.html (accessed July 25, 2005).
55. Hoffman, The Oligarchs, 301–8.
56. Leonid Nevzlin, “Yukos razrushili troe” [Three Destroyed Yukos], Vedomosti, April 18,
2005.
57. David Woodruff, “Khodorkovsky’s Gamble: From Business to Politics in the Yukos Conflict,”
Program on New Approaches to Russian Security Policy Memorandum, no 308. 2003, http://www
.csis.org/media/csis/pubs/pm_0308.pdf (accessed July 25, 2005).
58. Cited in Vadim Visloguzov, “Deputat barrelia” [Deputy of the Barrels], Kommersant-Vlast,
December 8, 2003, 26.
59. Vladimir Putin, “Press Conference,” December 23, 2004, http://www.president.kremlin.ru/
appears/2004/12/23/1414_type63380type82634_81691.shtml (accessed June 18, 2007).