Ettredge Et Al 2009
Ettredge Et Al 2009
Ettredge Et Al 2009
9-2005
Part of the Accounting Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, and the
Corporate Finance Commons
Citation
Ettredge, Michael; KWON, Soo Young; and LIM, Chee Yeow. Client, Industry and Country Factors Affecting
Choice of Big N Industry Expert Auditors. (2005). American Accounting Association Annual Meeting.
Research Collection School Of Accountancy.
Available at: https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soa_research/639
This Conference Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Accountancy at Institutional
Knowledge at Singapore Management University. It has been accepted for inclusion in Research Collection School
Of Accountancy by an authorized administrator of Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University.
For more information, please email library@smu.edu.sg.
Client, Industry and Country Factors Affecting Choice of
Michael Ettredge*
University of Kansas
* Corresponding author
mettredge@ku.edu
October 2008
This study investigates client choice of industry specialist auditors from among
or decrease Big N clients’ demand for industry expertise. Using data for 29
client size, client growth opportunities, and client capital intensity. The choice of
industry specialists from among the Big N is more prevalent in countries where
Data Availability: The data are available from the Global Vantage database.
1. Introduction
quality audits select Big N auditors (Fan & Wong [2005]).1 We employ a
suggests that industry specialist auditors have both the incentives and the
ability to provide higher quality audit services. Simunic and Stein [1987]
that improve the quality of audits in the firms’ focal industries. Recent
(Bedard & Biggs [1991]; Wright & Wright [1997]; Owhoso et al. [2002]).
1
For simplicity, we will refer to audit clients not headquartered in the U.S. as ‘international’
clients.
2
By including in our sample only clients that purchase Big N audits, we avoid confounding
the choice of a Big N auditor with the choice of an industry specialist auditor.
Specialist auditors are more likely to comply with auditing standards than
with SEC enforcement actions (Carcello & Nagy [2004]). Research also
industry specialization has value to clients, and that capital markets view
audit engagements. However, the largest audit firms attempt to market their
2
[other] services, tailored to your specific industry, wherever you
concerning the extent to which the Big N firms are able to provide consistent
quality of audit services around the world, including industry expertise. The
SEC [2000, 6] states, “We are concerned that audit firms may not have
global level.”4 Hence, whether clients in countries other than the U.S. (and,
perhaps, Australia) recognize and seek industry expertise from Big N auditors
industry market share in the client’s (non-U.S.) home country. Recent studies
by Ferguson et al. [2003], Francis et al. [2005], and Francis et al. [2006]
expertise. Ferguson et al. [2003] and Francis et al. [2005] document that
higher audit fees of industry leaders in the Australia and the U.S. audit market
3
De Beelde [1997] uses 1994 data to investigate whether Big N auditors exhibit industry
specialization. His international (non-U.S.) coverage consists of seven European countries,
plus Japan. He finds little evidence of industry specialization as he defines it, and does not
examine determinants of client auditor choice. Fan and Wong [2005] find that firms in eight
East Asian countries employ Big N auditors when the firms are subject to high agency costs.
That study does not investigate audit firm industry specialization.
4
In [2000: fn. 8] the SEC expands on this theme: “See, for example, 34-40945, AAER-1098
(PricewaterhouseCoopers) and letters from the SEC Chief Accountant to the AICPA SEC
Practice Section dated November 30 ,1998, and December 9, 1999 regarding the need for
global quality internal controls over independence matters, available on the SEC website at
<www.sec.gov>.” Radebaugh and Gray [1997, 651] state: “Because most international public
accounting firms are mixtures of different national public accounting firms, the quality of
work performed is bound to vary.”
3
are driven by auditors that are city-specific industry leaders. Francis et al.
[2006] show that earnings quality is higher when the auditor is a city-specific
industry leader, but not when an auditor is a national leader without also
which we primarily rely, for information about who audits whom, does not
This study employs 1993-2005 data from 29 countries, other than the
and their industries that are associated with demand for high quality and/or
industry specialist audits (Francis & Wilson [1988]; DeFond [1992]; Craswell
et al. [1995]). These include proxies for client size, financial leverage, growth
5
Most countries in our sample are small enough for audit personnel to travel anywhere
within those countries, meet with client managers, and return to their offices, in a single day.
Smaller countries frequently contain only one or two cities in which most publicly-traded
clients are located. Thus, the distinction between city-level and national-level industry
expertise is not as important in our study as for studies of larger nations such as the U.S.
6
Use of dependent variables that capture whether clients of Big N auditors choose industry
leaders avoids confounding the demand for Big N audits with demand for audits provided by
industry specialists. It is worthwhile to note that all of our sample companies are audited by
the Big N. Thus, we investigate whether clients having certain characteristics (e.g., large size)
choose industry specialists from among the Big N.
4
The results provide substantial support for our hypotheses.7 Of the six
specialist Big N auditors in nine out of ten models in which it appears. At the
country level, the choice of industry specialists from among the Big N is
countries with more developed stock markets (LGDP, SMDEV and ECON).
These results hold even among clients located in the less developed
(HINDEX) either have coefficients that are almost all insignificant, or some
7
The results summarized are those in Table 4.
8
That is, clients in relatively wealthier countries tend to purchase industry specialist audits, even
among the set of less-developed economies.
5
systematically affect choice of industry specialist auditors around the world.9
important than industry level factors. Second, our study builds on recent
advances in the finance literature on the role of legal protection for financial
document that the level of investor protection appears to affect the demand
for industry specialist Big N auditors. Third, our study also contributes to a
demand for Big N industry specialist audits is positively related to the quality
studies have investigated the choice between Big N and non-Big N audit
firms, mostly using U. S. data, but few studies have investigated client choice
presents our models and dependent variables. Section four describes the
sample and reports our primary test results. A fifth section provides
9
We note that our use of client-level factors to explain demand for industry expert auditors is
not unprecedented in the literature (see Godfrey & Hamilton [2005]). Our use of client-level
factors in an international setting, however, is new. We control for country-level factors
because of the international nature of our sample clients.
6
2. Hypotheses and Explanatory Variables
level factors that enhance or hinder the demand for audits provided by Big N
quality audits.10 High quality audits arguably increase the economic value of
market is not fully integrated across countries due to the fact that some
settings in which demand for high quality audits is derived from the potential
quality audits choose Big N auditors (Fan & Wong [2005]). Industry
of Big N auditors who also are industry specialist auditors, represents demand
10
Industry expertise is costly to develop not only because it requires gathering and analyzing
industry data, and modifying audit procedures for different industries, but also because a
‘critical mass’ of clients must be accumulated in a target industry, in the face of competition
from other audit firms. This could lead to heavy discounting of initial audit fees.
7
for audit quality higher than that provided by Big N auditors who are not
industry specialists. We expect the same variables that explain choice of a Big
auditor from among the Big N. DeFond [1992] and Francis and Wilson [1988]
increasing function of proxies for firms’ agency costs. Agency costs are
agents, and when opportunities exist for agents to transfer corporate wealth to
provided by owners and lenders (client size, financial leverage, need for
[2005] and Francis et al. [1999] for additional discussion of these explanatory
variables.12 These two studies examine the demand for auditor specialization
the demand for auditor industry specialization applies around the world. Our
11
The expected coefficient sign for LOSS is unclear. Clients having poor financial
performance arguably are less likely to seek (or be accepted by) large, high quality auditors.
However, Choi and Wong [2007] find a positive association between LOSS and choice of
high quality auditor.
12
We do not include a variable that captures the operating cycle as the inclusion of that
variable reduces our sample by 50%.
8
H1: Choice of an industry specialist among Big N auditors is positively
the capital intensity measured by gross property plant and equipment divided
by sales. The need for external capital (ISSUEj) is an indicator variable that
equals ‘one’ if the change in external equity is greater than 15% and ‘zero’
who do not also audit their competitors (Kwon [1996]). As the degree of
use the same auditors, because they do not want to risk the transfer of
9
auditors are less likely to be employed in concentrated industries. 13 Our
∑
n 2
which is defined as j =1
s j where s j is market share of firm j based on sales
(AICPA) publishes individual industry audit guidelines for oil and gas
13
It is worth noting that audit firms arguably have less incentive to develop industry expertise
in highly concentrated industries since, by definition, such industries tend to contain only a
few large clients. If Big N firms tend to have fairly equal shares among clients in a
concentrated industry, then designation of one firm as the industry leader creates a distinction
without a difference. Supply-side considerations therefore suggest that there might be no
association between industry concentration and employment of an industry specialist auditor.
14
Subscript “k” denotes industry membership which is determined by the SIC code following
the classification schemes used by Frankel et al. (2002): agriculture (0100–0999), mining &
construction (1000–1999, excluding 1300–1399), food (2000–2111), textiles &
printing/publishing (2200–2799), chemicals (2800–2824, 2840–2899), pharmaceuticals
(2830–2836), extractive (2900–2999, 1300–1399), financial institutions (6000–6999), durable
manufacturers (3000–3999, excluding 3570–3579 and 3670–3679), transportation (4000–
4899), utilities (4900–4999), retail (5000–5999), services (7000–8999, excluding 7370–7379),
computers (3570–3579, 3670–3679, 7370–7379).
10
quality audits, for clients in those regulated industries. 15 In essence, client
form, is:
REGINDk is coded ‘one’ if the industry is railroad (SICs 4011 and 4100),
trucking (4210 and 4213), airlines (4512, 4513, 4522, and 4581), telephone
(4922, 4923, 4924), personal credit (6141), and insurance (6311), and ‘zero’
otherwise.
demand for industry specialist audits, are based on the idea that the value of
audits is derived from the value of high quality financial information. In turn,
financial information.
15
The existence of special reporting rules, filing guidelines, and audit standards arguably
serve as a barrier to entry for audit firms desiring to serve regulated clients. The largest
international audit firms are likely to have the resources needed to hurdle this barrier to entry.
It is also possible that leading national (rather than international) audit firms will acquire
knowledge of the industry-specific regulations that are particular to their home countries.
11
2.3.1 Protection of Outside Investors
structures, dividend policies, and firms’ equity valuations (e.g., La Porta et al.
[1997, 1998, 2000]). Bushman and Smith [2001] argue that the benefits of
of higher quality audits (by Big N industry specialists) likewise are greater in
influence on client auditor choice among the Big N. Our fourth hypothesis, in
investors.
law enforcement index (LAW_ENFl) which is the mean score of three legal
al. [2003].16 The law enforcement index values range from zero to ten, with
higher scores for greater law enforcement. The second proxy for shareholder
16
Subscript “l” denotes country “l”. The three variables are (1) the mean for 1980-1983 of a
variable provided by Business International Corp., capturing the efficiency and integrity of
the judicial system; (2) the mean for 1982-1995 of a rule of law variable obtained from
International Country Risk; and (3) the mean for 1982-1995 of a corruption variable that
assesses the corruption in government, obtained from International Country Risk.
12
shareholders to exercise their voting rights.17 This index ranges from zero to
the principal component for the two legal variables, derived from a factor
associated with greater market liquidity and lower cost of equity capital (see
Young and Guenther [2003] show that countries whose financial accounting
17
The index aggregates the following components of shareholder rights: (1) the ability to vote
by mail; (2) the ability to gain control of shares during the shareholders’ meeting; (3) the
possibility of cumulative voting for directors; (4) the ease of calling an extraordinary
shareholders meeting; and (5) the availability of a mechanism allowing minority shareholders
to make legal claims against the directors.
13
H5: Choice of an industry specialist among Big N auditors is positively
environment.
provided in each country. The first proxy is the disclosure index (DISCl)
(CIFAR [1995]), and used by Saudagaran and Diga [1997] among others. CIFAR
creates a country-specific index by rating the annual reports of at least three firms
given a score ranging from zero to 90, with higher scores indicating more
disclosure. The second proxy for financial reporting environment is the extent of
countries, financial reports effectively reflect tax laws, which in turn are
objective of tax rules is not to satisfy the information needs of capital market
participants, the value relevance of financial reports in countries with high tax-
book conformity is reduced (Ali & Hwang [2000]). The value of financial
information (and the derived value of higher quality audits) potentially is greater
when there is weak link between tax and financial accounting rules. Using Hung’s
ratings, we create variable FIN_TAXl to capture the extent of tax and financial
18
The 90 items include specific disclosures in the following seven categories: general information
(8 items), income statement (11 items), balance sheet (14 items), funds flow statement (5 items),
accounting policy disclosure (20 items), shareholders’ information (20 items), and other
supplementary information (12 items).
19
Hung [2000] classifies a country’s alignment between financial and tax accounting rules based
on the following criteria: existence of deferred taxes, dominance of legal form over substance,
allowance of additional accelerated depreciation, and dependency of amortization on tax laws.
14
‘one’ if tax accounting and financial accounting methods diverge, and ‘zero’ if
they are similar.20 The last proxy, ACCTGl, is the principal component for the
audits are more valuable in nations requiring better disclosure and financial
Claessens and Laeven [2003] and Doidge et al. [2007] posit that a
first is the level of annual GDP per capita in each country. We expect greater
companies in less wealthy countries may not be able to afford hiring high
quality auditors (Choi & Wong [2007]). Gross Domestic Product per capita
(GDP), based on 2000 constant prices, is collected from the World Bank’s
20
The various country-level variables (LAW_ENF, VOTING, DISC, and FIN_TAX) each are
measured at a specific point in time (in the 1980s or 1990s) rather than being measured each
year. We assume that countries’ institutional environments remain stable over lengthy periods
of time. To the extent this assumption is incorrect, it should bias against finding significant
coefficients for these variables.
15
World Development Indicators database. We log-transform the GDP data
(denoted by LGDP) since GDP is highly skewed. Our second proxy for
information. Fan & Wong [2005] provide evidence that firms employ high-
quality auditors when seeking external capital in the stock markets. The strong
lowering the cost of capital. Hence, we expect demand for industry specialist
Big N auditors to be greater where equity markets are more developed. Stock
divided by gross (not per capita) GDP. The data for SMDEV are obtained from
Beck et al. [2000]. The final proxy is ECONl, which is the principal
3. Research Design
industry market share (e.g., Danos & Eichenseher [1982]; Balsam et al.
16
[2003]; Krishnan [2003]).21 We calculate a Big N auditor’s market share in a
J ik
∑ SALES
j =1
ijk
ADTR _ MSik = I k J ik
(1)
∑∑ SALES
i =1 j =1
ijk
We suppress the subscript denoting a specific year. SALES denotes client sales
revenue. The numerator is the sum of the sales of all Jik clients of audit firm i
denominator in equation (1) is the sales of all Jik clients in industry k, summed
each individual country. The assumption is that audit firm i is more likely to
a large market share in the home industry k, if its value of ADTR_MS for k is
21
Conceptually, industry market share would be measured as audit fees earned by an auditor
in an industry, as a proportion of the total audit fees earned by all auditors that serve that
particular industry. Based on data availability, prior studies (such as Krishnan [2003]) use
client sales rather than auditor fees to compute proxies for auditor market shares in industries.
Following these studies, we use client sales to estimate industry market shares, since data
about audit fees are either costly to collect or not available in many of the sample countries
under investigation.
22
All Ik audit firms include both Big N and other audit firms.
17
at least 20% prior to 1998, 24% for the 1998-2001 period, and 30% for the
2002-2005 period.23
where
23
Following Neal & Riley [2004], we employ a cut off for ‘large’ market shares of (1/N)*1.2,
where N is the number of big international audit firms. The largest firms are the Big 6, during
the period 1993-1997, the Big 5 after the merger between Coopers and Lybrand and Price
Waterhouse in 1998, and Big 4 after the demise of Arthur Andersen in 2002.
18
LOSSj = a dichotomous variable coded ‘one’ if client j’s net
ECON;
rights;
disclosure;
19
LGDPl = natural logarithm of GDP per capita for country l;
country l;
4. Empirical Results
4.1 Sample
Data for the sample period 1993-2005 are obtained from the Global
begin with the 49 countries (with the necessary institutional data) that are
the criterion (that is, have one or more industries containing 10 companies).
We remove Japan, Korea, and Pakistan from the sample, because the identity
of the auditors is not indicated in the database for these countries.24 We next
remove three countries (Ireland, New Zealand, and Turkey) since most of the
data for control variables are not available for these countries in the Global
24
More than 95% of the auditor names are designated as ‘others’ in Global Vantage for these
three countries. For example, the local name for KPMG in Japan is Kainan Audit Corporation,
and it is recorded by Global Vantage as ‘other’. Hence, we are not able to obtain the identity
of the auditors in these countries.
20
Mexico, Netherlands, Norway, Philippines, Singapore, South Africa, Spain,
subsequent sensitivity analysis, we find that our results are robust after
excluding clients in the United Kingdom, and after excluding clients located
firms exceeds fifty percent for a majority of the sample countries. Countries
manufacturers.
25
We winsorize each of the continuous control variables (LEV, CAPINT, LSALE, MB) used in the
regression at the top and bottom one percent to remove extreme values.
21
4.2 Descriptive Statistics for Variables
the means for client-specific variables (SALE, LEV, MB, CAPINT, ISSUE,
The values for VOTING, LAW_ENF, and DISC are constant over time for an
individual country, e.g., the value for LAW_ENF for Australia is 9.51 for each
year. The values for SMDEV and GDP are mean values, computed over 1993-
Consider, for example, investors’ voting rights (VOTING). The level of this
variable is highest in the U.K. and its former colonies such as Australia and
Austria, Belgium, Denmark, and Germany. Yet all the countries named have
developed economies. The same is true to some extent for the other country-
level variables.
26
Eleven countries have a low conformity of accounting and tax reporting, while eight
countries have high conformity of accounting and tax rules. Ten countries are not coded as
these countries are not included in Hung [2000]’s sample and hence not reported in Hung’s
study.
22
correlated with most of the explanatory variables (LSALE, LEV, CAPINT,
emphasize that these are univariate correlations, and we rely on the regression
variables are high, so we employ them in two ways. First, we estimate models
in which we enter only one country-level variable at a time (or one country-
one model in which all principal components extracted from the legal,
27
This procedure reduces a potential multi-collinearity problem. Factor analysis indicates that
LAW_ENF and VOTING are measuring one construct. The same is true for LGDP and
SMDEV, and for FIN_TAX and DISC. Hence, we use the principal components, LEGAL,
ACCTG, and ECON, derived from the factor analysis, in the combined model.
23
less due to missing data for variables DISC and FIN_TAX. The regressions in
Table 4 employ multiple observations per client over time. Such observations
with clustered robust errors to account for both serial and cross-sectional
Choi & Wong [2007], for all tests reported below, the Wald-statistics are
chosen is an industry specialist. The first nine regression models include only
one country-level variable each, while the last regression model includes all
principal components derived from the factor analysis (LEGAL, ACCTG, and
associated with LSALE, MB, and CAPINT at the 1% level, providing support
for hypothesis H1 (i.e. three out of five proxies are significant with expected
signs). LEV is positively associated with SPEC in five models while ISSUE is
between HINDEX and SPEC. This finding agrees with a recent study by the
General Accounting Office [2003]. The GAO reports that when large public
companies were asked whether they would choose an accounting firm as their
28
We also run the regression clustered by country, industry, and year. The results are similar.
24
auditor when that firm also audits one of their competitors, 92% of the
variables, we present some models that include only one of the country-level
first the proxies employed to test H4: LAW_ENF, VOTING, and LEGAL. In
models 1-3, the coefficients of of these variables are positive as expected and
highly significant. Together, the coefficient results offer strong support for
in the model.
Next consider the results for variables used to test H5: DISC,
FIN_TAX, and ACCTG. In models 4-6, the coefficients for these variables are
29
Another possible explanation is that the Herfindahl index is a poor proxy for industry
concentration. We compute it using Global Vantage database, so only publicly traded
companies’ data are employed in constructing this index. Ideally the index should be
computed using data for both public and private firms (Ali et al. [2008]). We do not employ
private companies’ data because it is unavailable for most clients in an international setting.
25
the effect of reducing the explanatory power of REGIND, and increasing the
explanatory power of ISSUE and LOSS. Finally, consider the results for
variables used to test H6: LGDP, SMDEV and ECON. In models 7-9, the
coefficients for these variables are positive and significant, offering support
for H6. Inclusion of each of these variables does not affect the significance of
analysis in model 10. The coefficients of ACCTG and ECON are positive and
prospects, and capital intensity. The results also indicate the importance of
Finally, the results suggest that three country-level institutional factors affect
30
We note that a client-level factor, capital intensity, is significant. High capital intensity
serves as a barrier to entry, and capital intensity varies across industries. Thus it is likely that
the capital intensity variable pre-empts some of the explanatory power of industry
concentration.
26
We perform several sensitivity tests to check the robustness of our
Table 5. The results are consistent with those reported in Table 4, with the
associated with SPEC1, while in our main analysis of Table 4 we do not find
REGIND are less significant than in Table 4. Although the Table 4 and Table
industry specialists are fairly stable over the entire sample period. 31 We
before 1998 (Big N = Big 6), between 1998 and 2001 (Big N = Big 5), and
2002-2005 (Big N = Big 4). We compute a stability metric for each industry-
country pair over each sub-period. For example, consider the 2002-2005 sub-
31
If this assumption is not valid it should bias against the significance of our explanatory variables.
27
period during which Big N = Big 4. Suppose for a particular country (say
Singapore), and a particular industry (say Computers), the market leader for
the entire four years is KPMG. Then the stability metric is “1.” If KPMG is
the market leader for three of the four years, then the stability metric is ‘0.75.’
Hence the stability statistic captures the proportion of years that the same
auditor is the market leader in the industry over a specific period. The larger
the statistic is, the greater the stability of audit specialists over time. The mean
statistic for all countries and all industries for the period 2002-2005 is 0.87.
This number is quite high, indicating stable audit specialists over the years
2002-2005. We repeat the analyses for the period 1998-2001 and for 1993-
1998. The mean statistics are 0.87 and 0.90 respectively. 32 Overall, the
stability statistic is high, and does not vary much across sub-periods,
suggesting that the identities of audit specialists are stable over the entire
their shares in the U.S. market, since the firms’ auditor choice may be related
to their overseas equity issues (Fan & Wong [2005]). The results, as reported
in Table 6, provide similar results as those in Table 4 except for the following
32
We compute metrics for three sub-periods (rather than for the entire sample period) because the
identities of Big N industry specialists are non-comparable across periods due to Big N mergers.
28
model 8. Third, the coefficients of HINDEX are negative and significant in
[2003]; and (2) the accrual index constructed by Hung [2000]. Our
(untabulated) results indicate that the disclosure index and accrual index are
financial reporting quality. Our untabulated results indicate that, along with
whether legal origin (COMMON, coded ‘one’ if the country has a common
law origin, and ‘zero’ if the country has a code law origin) also is associated
with industry specialist auditor choice. The (untabulated) results indicate that
statistic 5.98, p=0.01). This finding suggests that legal origin (similar to
LAW_ENF and VOTING) captures the legal environment in each country and
29
is positively associated with demand for industry specialist auditors. We also
estimate a model that includes COMMON, along with ACCTG and ECON.
developing economies. We address this issue in two ways to ensure that our
findings are not being driven by the large number of observations provided by
the developed economies. First, given that firms in the United Kingdom
constitute 25% of the total sample, we examine whether the exclusion of these
firms affects the main results. The results are similar to those reported in
Table 4 except for the following. First, the coefficients of LEV are positive
and significant for only three (out of ten) models. Second, DISC and SMDEV
are not significant in models that contain each of them as the only country-
from the sample. To identify developed and developing countries, we use the
33
One possible explanation for this non-result might be that COMMON does not capture the
variation in legal enforcement that exists even within the common- and code- law countries.
For example, Thailand has a common law origin, but it has low enforcement
(LAW_ENF=0.48). On the other hand, Sweden has a code-law origin but it has high
enforcement (LAW_ENF=10).
30
DEV index as reported in Table 1 of Hail and Leuz [2006]. Specifically, a
The first two models report the regression results for the full sample,
using dependent variables SPEC and SPEC1, while the last two models report
the regression results for the same dependent and explanatory variables, using
39,053), the results for firms in developing countries are remarkably similar to
those in models 1 and 2. This shows that the characteristics of clients that
choose industry specialists from among the Big N auditors do not vary
results, we include the nine country-level variables in the models that are
estimated using only clients from developing countries. Our results indicate
that the coefficient estimates for LSALE, LEV, MB, and CAPINT continue to
5. Conclusion
31
In this study, we investigate client choice of industry specialist
client size, client growth opportunities, and client capital intensity. At the
with national economic development. Our results also suggest, less strongly,
that choice of industry specialists from among the Big N auditors is higher in
tests.
32
REFERENCES
Balsam, B., Krishnan, J., and J. Yang. 2003. “Auditor Industry Specialization
and Earnings Quality.” Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 22
(September): 71-97.
Carcello, J., and A. Nagy. 2004. “Client Size, Auditor Specialization and
Fraudulent Financial Reporting.” Managerial Auditing Journal 19 (5):
651-668.
Choi J., and T. Wong. 2007. “Auditors’ Governance Functions and Legal
Environments: An International Investigation.” Contemporary
Accounting Research 24 (Spring): 1-36.
Craswell, A., Francis, J., and S. Taylor. 1995. “Auditor Brand Name
Reputations and Industry Specializations.” Journal of Accounting and
Economics 20 (December): 297-322.
33
De Beelde, I. 1997. “An Exploratory Investigation of Industry Specialization
of Large Audit Firms.” The International Journal of Accounting 32 (3):
337-355.
Doidge, C., Karolyi, G., and R. Stulz. 2007. “Why Do Countries Matter So
Much for Corporate Governance?” Journal of Financial Economics 86
(October): 1-39.
Ferguson, A., J. Francis, and D. Stokes. 2003. “The Effects of Firm-Wide and
Office-Level Industry Expertise on Audit Pricing.” The Accounting
Review 78 (April): 429-48.
Ferguson, A., and D. Stokes. 2002. “Brand Name Audit Pricing, Industry
Specialization, and Leadership Premiums Post-Big 6 and Big 8 Mergers.”
Contemporary Accounting Research 19 (Spring): 77-110.
Francis, J., and E. Wilson. 1988. “Auditor changes: A Joint Test of Theories
Relating to Agency Costs and Auditor Differentiation.” The Accounting
Review 63 (October): 663-682.
Francis, J., Maydew, E., and H. Sparks. 1999. “The Role of Big 6 Auditors in
the Credible Reporting of Accruals.” Auditing: A Journal of Practice &
Theory 18 (Fall): 17-34.
Francis, J.R., Reichelt, K. and D. Wang. 2005. “The Pricing of National and
City-Specific Reputations for Industry Expertise in the U.S. Audit
Market.” The Accounting Review 80 (January): 113-136.
34
Francis, J., and D. Wang. 2008. “The Joint Effect of Investor Protection and Big 4
Audits on Earnings Quality Around the World.” Contemporary Accounting
Research 25 (Spring): 157-191
Godfrey, J. and J. Hamilton. 2005. “The Impact of R&D Intensity on Demand for
Specialist Auditor Services.” Contemporary Accounting Research 22 (Spring):
55-93.
Hail, L., and C. Leuz. 2006. “International Differences in the Cost of Equity
Capital: Do Legal Institutions and Securities Regulation Matter?” Journal of
Accounting Research 44 (June): 485-531.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny. 1997. “Legal
Determinants of External Finance.” Journal of Finance 52 (July): 1131-
1150.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny. 1998. “Law
and Finance.” Journal of Political Economy 106 (December): 1113-1155.
35
Leuz, C., Nanda, D., and P. Wysocki. 2003. “Earnings Management and
Investor Protection: An International Comparison.” Journal of Financial
Economics 69 (September): 505-527.
Neal, T., and R. Riley Jr. 2004. “Auditor Industry Specialist Research
Design.” Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 23 (September): 169-
177.
O’Keefe, T., Kin, R., and K. Gaver. 1994. “Audit Fees, Industry
Specialization, and Compliance with GAAS Reporting Standards.”
Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 13 (Fall): 41-55.
Owhoso, V., Messier, W., and J. Lynch. 2002. “Error Detection by Industry-
Specialized Teams During Sequential Audit Review.” Journal of
Accounting Research 40 (June): 883-900.
36
Williams, R. 2000. “A Note on Robust Variance Estimation for Clustered-
Correlated Data.” Biometrics 56 (June): 645-646.
Wright, S., and A. Wright. 1997. “The Effect of Industry Specialization on
Hypothesis Generation and Audit Planning Decisions. Behavioral
Research in Accounting 9: 273-294.
37
TABLE 1
Distribution of Sample Firms by Country, Year, and Industry
38
TABLE 1 (continued)
The sample consists of 39,053 client firm-years for 29 countries over the period 1993-
2005. The sample only includes clients audited by the Big N. Panels A and B show the
distribution of observations by country and year respectively. Panel C shows the
distribution of observations by industry. Following Frankel et al. (2002), industry
membership is determined by the SIC code as follows: agriculture (0100–0999), mining
& construction (1000–1999, excluding 1300–1399), food (2000–2111), textiles &
printing/publishing (2200–2799), chemicals (2800–2824, 2840–2899), pharmaceuticals
(2830–2836), extractive (2900–2999, 1300–1399), financial institutions (6000–6999),
durable manufacturers (3000–3999, excluding 3570–3579 and 3670–3679),
transportation (4000–4899), utilities (4900–4999), retail (5000–5999), services (7000–
8999, excluding 7370–7379), computers (3570–3579, 3670–3679, 7370–7379).
39
TABLE 2
Means for Firm- and Industry Level Explanatory Variables and Country-Level Index Values
Panel A: Mean firm- and industry level variables
Country SPEC SALE LEV MB CAPINT ISSUE LOSS HINDEX REGIND
Australia 0.40 1,233 0.15 2.27 1.63 0.31 0.22 0.20 0.02
Austria 0.53 2,796 0.10 1.08 1.74 0.25 0.13 0.15 0.00
Belgium 0.32 12,582 0.13 5.41 0.73 0.33 0.25 0.26 0.00
Brazil 0.67 4,421 0.16 4.19 1.93 0.31 0.25 0.10 0.15
Canada 0.45 1,383 0.17 2.33 2.81 0.41 0.27 0.15 0.07
Chile 0.62 77,143 0.13 9.20 1.85 0.19 0.15 0.24 0.23
Denmark 0.59 4,609 0.16 2.12 0.79 0.23 0.20 0.18 0.02
Finland 0.54 4,173 0.15 2.12 0.55 0.29 0.20 0.23 0.00
France 0.26 9,520 0.14 2.44 0.65 0.28 0.21 0.14 0.03
Germany 0.46 5,421 0.09 2.18 0.87 0.25 0.28 0.15 0.04
Greece 0.44 41,559 0.14 3.06 0.80 0.43 0.06 0.15 0.00
Hong Kong 0.46 4,408 0.09 1.50 1.43 0.25 0.26 0.22 0.14
India 0.01 15,064 0.13 4.78 0.60 0.39 0.03 0.10 0.04
Indonesia 0.36 95,713 0.07 9.32 1.54 0.37 0.41 0.24 0.08
Israel 0.16 308 0.06 3.86 0.53 0.42 0.42 0.35 0.00
Italy 0.41 13,993 0.13 8.73 1.16 0.22 0.23 0.24 0.09
Malaysia 0.30 572 0.08 1.64 1.59 0.24 0.26 0.09 0.02
Mexico 0.45 20,370 0.20 4.27 1.40 0.41 0.16 0.21 0.14
Netherland 0.45 3,135 0.13 3.75 0.58 0.30 0.17 0.25 0.03
Norway 0.49 4,913 0.19 2.70 1.68 0.36 0.29 0.33 0.04
Philippines 0.46 6,302 0.13 1.45 8.13 0.23 0.41 0.28 0.01
Singapore 0.41 405 0.09 1.70 1.20 0.26 0.26 0.14 0.03
South Africa 0.54 6,488 0.07 2.14 0.85 0.45 0.12 0.15 0.00
Spain 0.66 28,100 0.12 2.91 1.37 0.34 0.07 0.19 0.06
Sweden 0.41 13,001 0.12 2.29 0.98 0.36 0.32 0.19 0.03
Switzerland 0.42 2,604 0.16 2.27 1.12 0.25 0.14 0.21 0.11
Taiwan 0.36 25,887 0.12 1.77 1.06 0.33 0.20 0.08 0.01
Thailand 0.31 6,466 0.11 1.67 1.66 0.29 0.20 0.15 0.02
United Kingdom 0.45 1,477 0.12 3.20 1.06 0.29 0.21 0.10 0.04
40
TABLE 2 (continued)
41
TABLE 2 (continued)
Definitions of variables:
SPEC = 1 if client j purchases audits from the auditor having at least 20%/24%/30% market share (for the period prior to 1998, 1998-2001, and after
2001 respectively) in industry k in the national market, and 0 otherwise;
SALE = sales in millions US$;
LEV = long-term debt to assets ratio;
MB = Market-to-book ratio;
CAPINT = gross property plant and equipment divided by sales.
ISSUE = 1 if the annual change in equity is greater than 15% and 0 otherwise;
LOSS = 1 if net income is negative and 0 otherwise;
HINDEX =
∑
n 2
j =1
s j where Sj is market share of firm j based on sales in industry k;
REGIND = 1 if client j is in operating in regulated industry. Following Francis et al. (1999), regulated industries are defined as the following SIC codes:
railroad (4011 and 4100), trucking (4210 and 4213), airlines (4512, 4513, 4522, and 4581), telephone communications (4812 and 4813),
electric companies (4911), gas companies (492, 4923, and 4924), personal credit (6141), and insurance (6311);
LAW_ENF = mean score of three legal enforcement variables reported in La Porta et al. (1998), and used in Leuz et al. (2003). The three variables are (1)
the mean for 1980-1983 of a variable provided by Business International Corp., capturing the efficiency and integrity of the judicial system;
(2) the mean for 1982-1995 of a rule of law variable obtained from International Country Risk; and (3) the mean for 1982-1995 of a
corruption variable that assesses the corruption in government, obtained from International Country Risk. The law enforcement index values
range from zero to ten, with higher scores for greater law enforcement;
VOTING = Voting rights index which indicates how easy it is for shareholders to exercise their voting rights. This index ranges from 0 to 5, and is
constructed by La Porta et al. (1998). It aggregates the following components of shareholder rights: (1) the ability to vote by mail, (2) the
ability to gain control of shares during the shareholders’ meeting, (3) the possibility of cumulative voting for directors, (4) the ease of
calling an extraordinary shareholders meeting, and (5) the availability of mechanism allowing minority shareholders to make legal claims
against the directors. This index ranges from zero to five, with higher scores indicating greater protection of shareholders;
LEGAL = principal component extracted from LAW_ENF, and VOTING via factor analysis;
DISC = disclosure level from Saudagaran and Diga (1997, Table 2). The original source is the Center for International Financial Analysis and
Research (CIFAR 1995). The higher the number, the higher is the quality of disclosure;
FIN_TAX = an indicator variable. It equals 1 if tax accounting and financial reporting diverge and 0 otherwise. This index is constructed by and Hung
(2000);
ACCTG = principal component extracted from DISC, and FIN_TAX via factor analysis;
GDP = mean real GDP Per Capita (in US$ of year 2000 buying power), over the period 1993-2005. LGDP is the natural logarithm of GDP;
SMDEV = mean values of stock market development measured by stock market capitalization divided by GDP, over the period 1993-2005.
ECON = principal component extracted from LGDP, and SMDEV via factor analysis.
42
TABLE 3
Correlation Matrices
SPEC LSALE LEV MB CAPINT ISSUE LOSS HINDEX REGIND LAW_ENF VOTING LEGAL DISC FIN_TAX ACCTG LGDP SMDEV ECON
SPEC 1.00
LSALE 0.16* 1.00
LEV 0.07* 0.29* 1.00
MB 0.00 -0.04* -0.07* 1.00
CAPINT 0.01* -0.03* 0.26* -0.16* 1.00
ISSUE -0.01 0.00 -0.02* 0.18* -0.10* 1.00
LOSS -0.04* -0.25* -0.05* -0.10* 0.05* -0.16* 1.00
HINDEX 0.03* 0.13* 0.08* 0.01 0.12* 0.01 0.01 1.00
REGIND 0.05* 0.12* 0.12* 0.01 0.17* -0.01 -0.02* 0.17* 1.00
LAW_ENF 0.05* -0.12* 0.13* 0.09* -0.11* 0.04* 0.01 0.15* -0.01 1.00
VOTING 0.02* -0.27* 0.00 0.09* 0.01 0.04* 0.00 -0.32* 0.01 0.16* 1.00
LEGAL 0.03* -0.32* 0.05* 0.10* -0.02* 0.05* 0.02* -0.22* 0.00 0.47* 0.92* 1.00
DISC 0.00 -0.32* -0.02* 0.08* -0.15* -0.01 -0.01 -0.29* -0.04* 0.34* 0.62* 0.63 1.00
FIN_TAX 0.04* -0.25* 0.01 0.06* 0.05* 0.03* -0.01 -0.21* -0.01 0.16* 0.73* 0.68 0.36* 1.00
ACCTG 0.04* -0.01 0.02* -0.01 0.17* 0.03* 0.02* 0.19* 0.04* 0.04* 0.04* 0.07* 0.58* 0.54* 1.00
LGDP 0.03* -0.12* 0.06* 0.06* -0.19* 0.00 0.05* 0.10* 0.01 0.65* 0.09* 0.29 0.39* -0.06* -0.30 1.00
SMDEV -0.02* -0.26* -0.08* 0.03* -0.07* 0.00 0.00 -0.25* -0.01 0.05* 0.45* 0.37 0.60* 0.36* -0.24 0.23* 1.00
ECON -0.03* -0.30* -0.09* 0.00 -0.01 -0.04* -0.01 -0.29* -0.02* 0.05* 0.43* 0.35* 0.59* 0.48* -0.15* 0.13* 0.81* 1.00
Notes:
See Table 2 for variable definitions. LSALE is the natural logarithm of SALE. LGDP is the natural logarithm of GDP. The full sample for the correlation
coefficients is 39,053 client firm-years for 29 countries over the period 1993-2005.
43
TABLE 4
Logistic Regression Results Explaining Choice of Big N Industry Audit Specialists:
Dependent variable: SPEC
Exp. Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model
Sign 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
-2.666 -1.766 -1.655 -2.785 -1.713 -1.230 -3.444 -1.434 -1.447 -1.524
Intercept
(117.17)*** (151.72)*** (283.46)*** (45.23)*** (203.47)*** (162.62)*** (80.05)*** (150.48)*** (209.09)*** (242.84)***
LSALE + 0.171 0.164 0.181 0.171 0.195 0.171 0.160 0.151 0.158 0.193
(153.38)*** (172.69)*** (214.72)*** (230.68)*** (243.40)*** (157.87)*** (138.19)*** (129.63)*** (144.11)*** (251.58)***
LEV + 0.156 0.274 0.132 0.271 -0.015 0.104 0.213 0.391 0.385 0.036
(1.61) (5.35)** (1.17) (6.08)*** (0.01) (0.57) (3.39)* (11.36)*** (11.24)*** (0.06)
MB + 0.005 0.004 0.005 0.005 0.003 0.003 0.005 0.004 0.005 0.003
(27.64)*** (18.12)*** (26.36)*** (26.32)*** (10.39)*** (10.39)*** (22.23)*** (16.97)*** (22.20)*** (12.94)***
CAPINT + 0.012 0.009 0.011 0.011 0.013 0.011 0.012 0.010 0.010 0.012
(17.17)*** (11.23)*** (14.38)*** (17.50)*** (15.82)*** (13.75)*** (16.44)*** (12.38)*** (14.03)*** (16.38)***
ISSUE + -0.038 -0.044 -0.049 -0.031 -0.068 -0.065 -0.035 -0.034 -0.025 -0.062
(1.71) (2.41) (2.97)* (1.11) (5.22)** (4.59)** (1.42) (1.32) (0.72) (4.47)**
LOSS ? 0.032 0.029 0.046 0.047 0.123 0.089 0.020 0.015 0.026 0.120
(0.70) (0.61) (1.61) (1.75) (10.20)*** (4.94)** (0.28) (0.16) (0.46) (9.68)***
HINDEX - -0.091 0.221 0.197 0.112 -0.163 -0.345 -0.122 0.054 0.101 -0.225
(0.25) (1.37) (1.16) (0.37) (0.77) (3.51)* (0.43) (0.08) (0.29) (1.48)
REGIND + 0.218 0.179 0.178 0.201 0.116 0.118 0.213 0.194 0.194 0.091
(9.99)*** (6.86)*** (6.55)*** (8.46)*** (2.57)* (2.81)* (9.62)*** (7.96)*** (8.11)*** (1.64)
LAW_ENF + 0.142
(35.37)***
VOTING + 0.095
(13.56)***
LEGAL + 0.230 0.079
(39.60)*** (2.79)*
DISC + 0.017
(11.29)***
FIN_TAX + 0.404
(22.24)***
ACCTG + 0.175 0.204
(11.38)*** (15.50)***
LGDP + 0.216
(31.71)***
SMDEV + 0.091
(2.67)*
ECON + 0.113 0.164
(5.44)** (6.32)***
χ2 stat 355.86*** 355.73*** 444.40*** 436.33*** 496.26*** 338.91*** 330.73*** 285.28*** 581.16*** 542.55***
N 39,053 39,053 39,053 38,871 32,558 32,558 39,053 39,053 32,558 32,558
44
TABLE 4 (continued)
Notes:
SPECjk equals ‘one’ if client j, headquartered in nation l purchases audits from the auditor having at least 20%/24%/30% market share (for the period prior to
1998, 1998-2001, and after 2001 respectively) in industry k in the national market. SPECjk is defined as ‘zero’ otherwise. See Table 2 for other variable
definitions. LSALE is the natural logarithm of SALE. LGDP is the natural logarithm of GDP.
We report the Wald statistic in the parenthesis. */**/*** Significance level of 0.1, 0.05 or 0.01 (two-tailed) respectively.
45
TABLE 5
Logistic Regression Results Explaining Choice of Big N Industry Audit Specialists:
Dependent variable: SPEC1
Exp. Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model
Sign 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
-3.011 -2.230 -2.167 -2.681 -2.244 -1.838 -3.853 -2.062 -2.059 -2.086
Intercept
(141.90)*** (225.30)*** (370.46)*** (59.25)*** (267.90)*** (282.85)*** (80.79)*** (362.71)*** (401.59)*** (346.50)***
LSALE + 0.146 0.138 0.152 0.143 0.159 0.139 0.138 0.132 0.139 0.157
(134.79)*** (152.37)*** (173.70)*** (157.18)*** (157.64)*** (105.51)*** (137.21)*** (146.57)*** (161.74)*** (163.85)***
LEV + 0.203 0.311 0.194 0.293 0.049 0.149 0.239 0.401 0.392 0.097
(2.36) (6.08)*** (2.24) (5.88)*** (0.12) (1.05) (3.82)** (10.11)*** (9.89)*** (0.43)
MB + 0.004 0.003 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.001 0.004 0.003 0.004 0.003
(25.22)*** (15.58)*** (22.77)*** (20.53)*** (9.74)*** (2.85)* (21.25)*** (16.30)*** (20.90)*** (8.49)***
CAPINT + 0.010 0.008 0.009 0.009 0.009 0.008 0.010 0.008 0.009 0.009
(14.95)*** (9.30)*** (11.77)*** (12.68)*** (11.16)*** (8.62)*** (14.91)*** (10.85)*** (12.19)*** (10.59)***
ISSUE + -0.017 -0.022 -0.025 -0.009 -0.024 -0.023 -0.015 -0.015 -0.005 -0.019
(0.39) (0.66) (0.85) (0.10) (0.65) (0.55) (0.28) (0.30) (0.03) (0.39)
LOSS ? 0.057 0.052 0.066 0.069 0.139 0.112 0.049 0.046 0.056 0.450
(2.15) (1.75) (2.99)* (3.36)* (12.74)*** (7.57)*** (1.49) (1.37) (2.06) (5.72)**
HINDEX - 0.429 0.654 0.642 0.573 0.504 0.369 0.396 0.554 0.598 0.450369
(5.93)** (13.49)*** (13.57)*** (10.95)*** (7.27)*** (3.86)** (4.95)** (10.31)*** (11.85)*** (5.72)**
REGIND + 0.142 0.114 0.111 0.134 0.073 0.073 0.140 0.117 0.119 0.048
(4.91)** (3.23)* (2.99)* (4.49)** (1.13) (1.12) (4.75)** (3.55)* (3.56)* (0.51)
LAW_ENF + 0.116
(23.72)***
VOTING + 0.069
(8.06)***
LEGAL + 0.178 0.062
(22.99)*** (2.94)*
DISC + 0.009
(4.32)**
FIN_TAX + 0.339
(15.54)***
ACCTG + 0.150 0.179
(10.06)*** (12.59)***
LGDP + 0.197
(21.43)***
SMDEV + 0.111
(5.14)**
ECON + 0.124 0.145
(8.08)*** (6.97)***
χ2 stat 236.47*** 242.92*** 266.91*** 237.30*** 291.74*** 234.98*** 237.17*** 242.52*** 268.75*** 329.61***
N 39,053 39,053 39,053 38,871 32,558 32,558 39,053 39,053 39,053 32,558
46
Notes:
SPEC1jk equals ‘one’ if client j, headquartered in nation l, purchases audits from the auditor having the largest value of ADTR_MS in industry k in nation l.
SPEC1jk is defined as ‘zero’ otherwise. See Table 2 for definitions of other variables. LSALE is the natural logarithm of SALE. LGDP is the natural
logarithm of GDP.
We report the Wald statistic in the parenthesis. */**/*** Significance level of 0.1, 0.05 or 0.01 (two-tailed) respectively.
47
TABLE 6
Logistic Regression Results Explaining Choice of Big N Industry Audit Specialists:
Dependent variable: SPEC (Removing clients cross-listed in the U.S.)
Exp. Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model Model
Sign 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
-2.538 -1.651 -1.543 -2.611 -1.596 -1.079 -3.301 -1.297 -1.307 -1.376
Intercept
(95.91)*** (122.74)*** (216.55)*** (39.42)*** (166.99)*** (119.28)*** (70.47)*** (116.03)*** (161.52)*** (184.27)***
LSALE + 0.156 0.147 0.166 0.156 0.178 0.152 0.145 0.134 0.140 0.173
(115.34)*** (125.43)*** (160.35)*** (170.08)*** (181.08)*** (113.64)*** (100.49)*** (93.18)*** (103.99)*** (180.56)***
LEV + 0.149 0.272 0.121 0.278 -0.003 0.116 0.212 0.394 0.389 0.057
(1.39) (4.94)** (0.91) (6.13)*** (0.01) (0.67) (3.22)* (11.10)*** (11.06)*** (0.15)
MB + 0.005 0.004 0.005 0.005 0.003 0.001 0.005 0.004 0.004 0.003
(19.71)*** (13.00)*** (19.23)*** (19.25)*** (6.55)*** (1.59) (15.90)*** (11.86)*** (15.50)*** (7.30)***
CAPINT + 0.011 0.008 0.009 0.010 0.011 0.010 0.011 0.008 0.009 0.011
(14.36)*** (8.65)*** (11.71)*** (14.33)*** (13.03)*** (10.51)*** (13.64)*** (9.57)*** (10.83)*** (13.13)***
ISSUE + -0.045 -0.051 -0.056 -0.037 -0.071 -0.068 -0.040 -0.039 -0.030 -0.065
(2.24) (2.98)* (3.79)** (1.47) (5.34)** (4.70)** (1.83) (1.62) (1.05) (4.53)**
LOSS ? 0.010 0.008 0.025 0.026 0.104 0.067 -0.001 -0.007 0.002 0.099
(0.07) (0.04) (0.49) (0.53) (7.51)*** (2.82)* (0.01) (0.04) (0.00) (6.73)***
HINDEX - -0.273 0.044 0.025 -0.066 -0.359 -0.575 -0.308 -0.137 -0.088 -0.439
(2.20) (0.05) (0.02) (0.12) (3.90)** (10.12)*** (2.73)* (0.51) (0.22) (5.94)**
REGIND + 0.165 0.129 0.129 0.155 0.065 0.058 0.165 0.146 0.146 0.038
(5.19)** (3.28)* (3.09)* (4.60)** (0.72) (0.61) (5.17)** (4.13)** (4.20)** (0.26)
LAW_ENF + 0.141
(32.31)***
VOTING + 0.097
(13.61)***
LEGAL + 0.234 0.073
(38.16)*** (3.36)*
DISC + 0.017
(10.49)***
FIN_TAX + 0.418
(23.44)***
ACCTG + 0.196 0.222
(14.13)*** (18.04)***
LGDP + 0.214
(30.45)***
SMDEV + 0.083
(2.20)
ECON + 0.100 0.167
(4.19)** (6.45)***
χ2 stat 258.29*** 249.07*** 313.99*** 309.45*** 362.25*** 255.89*** 227.52*** 199.77*** 227.94*** 385.42***
N 36,934 36,934 36,934 36,752 30,604 30,604 36,934 36,934 36,934 30,604
48
Notes:
We delete 2,119 client firm-years, relating to those clients that cross-list their shares in the U.S. market, since the firms’ auditor choice may be related to their
overseas equity issues. See Table 2 for definitions of the variables. LSALE is the natural logarithm of SALE. LGDP is the natural logarithm of GDP.
We report the Wald statistic in the parenthesis. */**/*** Significance level of 0.1, 0.05 or 0.01 (two-tailed) respectively.
49
TABLE 7
Logistic Regression Results Explaining Choice of Big N Industry Audit Specialists:
Full Sample versus Developing Countries
Notes:
See Tables 2 and 5 for variable definitions. In models 3 and 4 the sample only includes firms in the developing countries. Countries are considered as
developing if the country’s equity market is not included in the Morgan Stanley Capital International database (Hail and Leuz [2006] Table 1). Based on this
definition, 12 countries are included in models 3 and 4, namely, Brazil, Chile, Greece, India, Indonesia, Israel, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, South Africa,
Taiwan, and Thailand. Models 1 and 2 provide results using the full sample.
We report the Wald statistic in the parenthesis. */**/*** Significance level of 0.1, 0.05 or 0.01 (two-tailed) respectively.
50