Carbon Trading in South Africa:: Providing Flexibility or Escape Route?
Carbon Trading in South Africa:: Providing Flexibility or Escape Route?
Carbon Trading in South Africa:: Providing Flexibility or Escape Route?
POLICY
BRIEF
ZA
2018
2 The theory
Economists argue that putting a price on carbon is the most cost-
effective mechanism to reduce carbon emissions, and to address
climate change. Trading carbon emissions allows sectors with poor
mitigation potential to fund deeper emissions reductions in sectors with
better mitigation potential. It therefore helps to achieve overall emissions
reductions across the economy at least cost.
1 Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition (CPLC), 2017. Report of the high-level commission on carbon
prices. International Bank for Reconstruction and Development and International Development
Association/The World Bank. Available at: https://www.carbonpricingleadership.org/report-of-the-
highlevel-commission-on-carbon-prices/.
2 Greenhouse gases (GHG) are the gases that cause climate change. To be able to compare their
global warming effect, they are converted to ‘carbon dioxide equivalent’, CO2e. Shorthand, they are
collectively referred to as ‘carbon emissions’. They are measured in tonnes, so we write tCO2e.
3 The reality
The international experience with implementing carbon trading
has seen varying degrees of success. The global carbon market has
failed to account for all the external costs of carbon emissions and has
therefore failed to deliver economic efficiency and sustainable behaviour.
The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), for example,
has failed to achieve adequate emissions reductions commensurate with
the targets required by science. This is because of an historically weak
carbon price signal, resulting from weak demand for carbon permits and
over-allocation of free emissions permits.
4 WWF-SA position
We strongly recommend that carbon trading be excluded from
South Africa’s Mitigation System, because:
The South African economy is highly concentrated, even monopolistic in some
sectors, and thus not suitable for a carbon trading system.
It is welcomed that firms producing electricity for sale are excluded from the
carbon trading system, and the emissions of parastatal Eskom can be managed
through electricity supply policy. Since electricity generation accounts for the
Contents bulk of South Africa’s emissions, that leaves a limited spectrum of emissions to
be covered by the carbon trading system. The result could be low demand for
Summary trading and risks market failure.
2 There is high emissions uncertainty because of high flexibility in the medium to
Role of carbon long-run in the proposed carbon budgets.
pricing in carbon The carbon tax rate will act as an effective carbon price ceiling in the carbon
trading credits marketplace. The currently proposed carbon tax of R120/tCO 2e is too
4 low to drive mitigation action.
Carbon markets The carbon tax must at least be enforced as a regulatory carbon credit price floor
and carbon to ensure price stability and prevent carbon credit prices from dropping
trading – in to insufficiently low levels as was the case in the EU ETS.3
theory
The over-determination of flexibility mechanisms within the carbon tax
6
design and Mitigation System presents loopholes for firms to avoid meaningful
Carbon trading emissions reductions, and is likely to result in perverse outcomes for the
in the Mitigation economy and climate change mitigation.
System Establishing and running a carbon trading system will carry a significant
9 administrative burden.
International
experience Should carbon trading be included in the South African Mitigation System, it is
11 recommended that it meet the criteria outlined in the table entitled ‘Necessary
conditions for using cooperative approaches that involve the use of ITMOs’ in this
Ensuring
paper. In addition, the weak price signal provided by the carbon tax at R120/tCO2e,
an effective
can at best be used only to provide a price floor and therefore the rate needs to be
carbon trading
increased substantially.
mechanism
15
WWF-SA position
17
3 CPLC, 2017.
THE SOCIAL COST Government interventions in the form of carbon pricing policies are identified
as effective and cost-efficient tools to correct such market failure and to mitigate
OF CARBON climate change.7 Establishing a carbon price provides the necessary price signal
for producers and consumers to internalise the social cost of carbon emissions
“the present value by increasing the price of carbon-intensive goods. This is expected to encourage
of future damages a behavioural change in producers and consumers to move towards low-carbon
alternatives, such as renewable energy generation and energy-efficient technologies.8
associated with an
incremental increase An important condition to ensure the efficacy of the carbon price is that it should
in carbon emissions (or be set at a level that is high enough to encourage meaningful behavioural change
to collectively keep average global warming well below 2 °C in order to avoid
carbon equivalent) in a catastrophic climate change.9
particular year”
4 National Treasury (NT), 2013. Carbon Tax Policy Paper – Reducing greenhouse gas emissions and
facilitating the transition to a green economy. Pretoria: Republic of South Africa. National Treasury.
Available at: http://www.treasury.gov.za/public%20comments/Carbon%20Tax%20Policy%20Paper%20
2013.pdf.
5 Kaufam, N., Obeiter, M. & Krause, E., 2016. Putting a price on carbon: reducing emissions. Available
at: https://www.wri.org/sites/default/files/Putting_a_Price_on_Carbon_Emissions.pdf.
6 Kaufam, et al., 2016.
7 World Bank and Ecofys, 2018. State and trends of carbon pricing 2018, Washington, DC: World Bank.
8 NT, 2013; Kaufam, et al., 2016.
9 OECD, 2015. Adapting transport policy to climate change: carbon valuation, risk and uncertainty.
Available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789282107928-en.
production process
Existing global carbon prices
In 2018, 45 national and 25 sub-national jurisdictions had established a carbon price,
covering approximately 20% of global carbon emissions.13 Existing carbon prices within
various carbon trading systems globally, range from R15/tCO2e to R352/tCO2e. On the
other hand, existing carbon prices introduced as a carbon tax, range from R15/tCO2e to
R2 056/tCO2e.14
11 Vivid Economics, DNA Economics & Tyler, E., 2016. Integrating the carbon tax and carbon budgets in
South Africa. Available at: https://www.caia.co.za/wp-content/uploads/2016/09/14-july-2016-alignment.
pdf.
12 Cloete, et al., 2013.
13 World Bank and Ecofys, 2018.
14 Haites, E., 2018. Carbon taxes and greenhouse gas emissions trading systems: what have we learned?
Climate Policy, 18(8): 955–966.
Carbon
price MCM Firm B
R570/tCO2e
Aii
R80/tCO2e Ai
15 The Climate Reality Project, 2017. Handbook on Carbon Pricing Instruments.Available at: https://www.
climaterealityproject.org/sites/climaterealityproject.org/files/HandbookonCarbonFinancing_Final_
May16.pdf.
16 CPLC, 2017
17 Vivid Economics, DNA Economics & Tyler, E., 2016. Integrating the carbon tax and carbon budgets in
South Africa. Available at: https://www.caia.co.za/wp-content/uploads/2016/09/14-july-2016-alignment.
pdf.
18 Narassimhan, E., Gallagher, K., Koester, S. & Alejo, J., 2018. Carbon pricing in practice: a review of
existing emissions trading systems. Climate Policy, 18(8): 967–991.
19 Haites, E., 2018. Carbon taxes and greenhouse gas emissions trading systems: what have we learned?
Climate Policy, 18(8): 955–966.
Advantages Disadvantages
In the face of lobbying by high emitters, two flexibility mechanisms are proposed,
carbon trading and carbon offsets. These mechanisms are not by definition essential
to the carbon budgets system, not are offsets essential in the tax system. The stated
intention is to minimise socio-economic impact of the carbon budgets or tax, and
achieve emissions reductions at lowest economic cost.
CARBON OFFSETS Carbon trading isproposed in DEA’s draft Mitigation System. Only non-
electricity generating entities will be allowed to trade, to avoid carbon leakage.22
Company A pays for
emissions reductions Carbon offsets are proposed in the Mitigation System and by Treasury.
Offsets, allowed up to a maximum of 10% of its carbon budget, can keep a
to be done by entity company within its carbon budget or reduce the overshoot, and in any case will
B. Company A chooses reduce its carbon tax liability. In the tax system, 5--10% of emissions can be
rebated by the use of carbon offsets. WWF supports carbon offsets which satisfy
to do this as it costs A the Gold Standard and other criteria, since they are meant to lead to additional
less than doing its own mitigation. There must be only one carbon offsetting system, which needs to
reduction, or it can do be rationalised across both the Mitigation System and operation of the carbon
tax to ensure no double-crediting of the same emissions reductions. Offset
no more reductions certificates cannot be used both against a company’s carbon budget (which then
itself. Company A is in itself reduces tax liability) and again as a rebate against tax payable.
then allowed to deduct This proposed carbon trading system establishes an absolute emissions baseline (in
the amount of emissions the form of entity level carbon budgets) as a maximum emissions limit.23 Carbon
reduced by B from
A’s own emissions
21 Cloete, et al., 2017.
22 Cloete, et al., 2017.
reductions.
23 MMA, 2009. Baseline and Credit versus Cap and Trade Emissions Trading Schemes, Policy Brief. The
Climate Institute – Australia.
The draft Mitigation System envisages the carbon tax rate as a price floor/ceiling
for trading, to prevent carbon credit price volatility, and in doing so, to promote
effectiveness of the carbon trading system. Should carbon trading be included in the
Mitigation System, it is highly recommended that the carbon tax be used as a price
floor – serving as a minimum price determinant for carbon trading.
When the carbon price is not strong enough to encourage meaningful mitigation
action
Advantages Disadvantages
INTERNATIONAL
EXPERIENCE
Two key carbon trading approaches that have
been deployed to reduce carbon emissions are
the Emission Trading Schemes (ETS) and offset
mechanisms. While a number of regional and
national ETS are under operation, a primary
offset mechanism developed under the UNFCCC
was the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM).
Emissions trading for reducing carbon emissions began in 2005 with the European
Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS). In 2005, it provided 5% coverage of
global emissions (2.1 GtCO2e). Since then, ETSs have spread across many countries,
regions, provinces and cities. As of 2018, they cover 15% of global emissions
(7.4 GtCO2e).27 Apart from Europe, different jurisdictions in North America, Asia and
Pacific have ETSs in force, scheduled or under consideration. Colombia, Brazil and
Chile in Latin America are also considering ETS as a policy option. Some of these
jurisdictions have started to cooperate by linking their systems. For example, ETSs
in California, Ontario and Quebec are linked, so is the EU ETS with Switzerland.
Talks are ongoing on linking various other ETSs as well.
The average price for allowances in 2017 ranged from R52.2 to R254.4/tCO2e.
Share of allowances that are not provided free of cost, ranged from 0–100%.
27 ICAP, 2018. Emissions trading worldwide: Status Report 2018. Available at: https://icapcarbonaction.
com/en/?option=com_attach&task=download&id=547.
28 ICAP, 2018.
National Switzerland
level
New Zealand
Provincial Alberta
level
Another study found that in 2015, ETS covered 4 280 million tCO2e (MtCO2e). The
average ETS allowance price is put at R109.2 and the revenue generated (in 2013)
is estimated to be R115.18 billion in 2018 prices.30 In comparison, carbon taxes
generated twice the revenue. However, of the revenue generated from carbon tax,
only 14% is used for ‘green’ spending, whereas the corresponding figures for ETSs
stands at 70%, so there is greater allocation of revenue generated through ETSs for
‘green’ spending.
7 805
Developing countries have participated in carbon markets primarily through the
Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) under the Kyoto Protocol, as suppliers
of Certified Emission Reductions (CERs). These CERs are bought by developed
The number of carbon countries to meet their emissions reduction targets. Since it came into being in
reduction projects 2004, CDM has approved (registered) 7 805 carbon reduction projects. A total
of 1 904 million CERs have been issued so far. China, India, South Korea and
registered through CDM
29 Based on ICAP, 2018.
30 Haites, 2018.
31 Bang, G., Victor, D. & Andersen, S., 2017. California’s cap-and-trade system: Diffusion and lessons.
Global Environmental Politics, 17(3): 12–30.
32 Haites, 2018.
Brazil account for 84.3% of the CERs issued.33 It is estimated that CDM led to an
investment of more than R4 169 billion in sustainable development projects. African
countries, including South Africa, did not benefit much from CDM.
The biggest demand for CERs came from the EU ETS during the first five-year
commitment period under the Kyoto Protocol. The CDM market has sharply
contracted since the first commitment period of EU ETS ended in 2012.34 For
example, out of the registered projects, 4 214 are now considered dormant as
they have had no contact with the UNFCCC Secretariat since 2013.35 Clearly the
significance of CDM and its relevance under the Paris Agreement is in decline.
However, the experience gained from its operation should be used to design future
mechanism for involving developing countries, such that their exposure to volatility
in developed countries can be minimised.
33 UNEP DTU, 2018. CDM pipeline overview. United Nations Environment Programme. Available at:
http://www.cdmpipeline.org/.
34 UNFCCC, 2017. CDM value clear, future cloudy. UN Climate Change News.Available at: https://unfccc.
int/news/cdm-value-clear-future-cloudy.
35 UNEP DTU, 2018.
From the South African perspective five considerations make it difficult to consider
carbon trading as a policy intervention in its current form.
1. In any given jurisdiction, carbon trading should include a large number of
entities. The EU ETS, for example, operates in 31 countries and accounts for
emissions from more than 12 000 stationary installations, and 1 400 aircraft
operators.36 This creates a dynamic system that is not captive to monopolistic
behaviour. Given the oligopolistic market structure of the energy
industry, the country’s emissions profile is heavily determined by one or two
major emitters, such as Eskom and Sasol. This increases the threat of the carbon
price being captive to vested interest. Partly to deal with Eskom’s role in the
economy, and because the mitigation potential for electricity generation is high
and affordable, electricity-generating entities will not be allowed to trade.
2. There is not enough experience with ETS in developing countries.
Other than South Korean ETS and city level ETS in China, almost all other ETSs
have operated in developed countries. There is very little experience of actual
ETS implementation to argue for ETS as a suitable policy intervention for a
developing country operating under financial and capacity constraints.
3. Due to low demand, the price signal provided by EU ETS up until now
has not been strong enough to drive mitigation commensurate with the
targets required by science. As a result, it may not generate enough resources
for the state to run an administratively complicated system. Demand for carbon
credits in South Africa is unpredictable and thus at this stage, it is unknown
whether the trading system will generate enough funds to run the system.
4. In 2018, all the jurisdictions that have ETS also have a carbon tax in place, apart
from Japan.37 While carbon tax and carbon budgets can operate simultaneously,
having carbon tax and carbon trading for addressing emissions reductions
from the same emission sources can lead to institutional complexities and
financial constraints. We therefore suggest having a high carbon tax to enhance
institutional and financial effectiveness.
5. As a developing country, South Africa’s proposed carbon trading system may
possibly overcome some of these constraints if its carbon trading system is
linked to developed countries’ ETS – either as an ETS or as an offset provider.
However, as experience with CDM suggests, such an option will hold the
carbon price in the South African system captive to the policy and
price preferences of the demand centres.
36 EEA, 2018. EU Emissions Trading System (ETS) data review. Available at: https://www.eea.europa.eu/
data-and-maps/dashboards/emissions-trading-viewer-1.
37 Haites, 2018.
ENSURING AN EFFECTIVE
CARBON TRADING MECHANISM
Post-2020, any future approaches for reducing
carbon emissions must meet the criteria set forth
in the Paris Agreement.
Article 6 of the Paris Agreement recognises that some signatory countries would
use cooperative mechanisms to facilitate emissions reductions, including market-
based mechanisms. Article 6 paragraph 2 sets the basis for engaging in voluntary
“cooperative approaches that involve the use of internationally transferred mitigation
outcomes (ITMOs) towards Nationally Determined Contributions (NDC)”. Article 6
paragraph 4(c) indicates that trading emissions reductions from Party A to Party B is
allowed as a means to fulfil the NDCs of Party B.
Conditions of ITMOs
ITMOs must meet certain conditions, including: being voluntary; promoting
sustainable development; ensuring environmental integrity; and transparency –
including in the governance of ITMOs – and they must apply robust accounting to
avoid double counting. Any new mechanism must embody these characteristics.
Based on these guidelines, below we propose the bare minimum conditions that a
South African carbon trading system should meet for it to be eligible to be considered
as an ITMO. It is important to highlight that Article 6 paragraph 4 does not prescribe
carbon markets as the only channel for ITMOs. Paragraph 8 “recognize[s] the
importance … [of] nonmarket approaches being available to Parties to assist in
the implementation of their NDCs, in the context of sustainable development and
poverty reduction”.
The aforesaid mechanism should only be open to the signatory South Africa is a signatory party to the Paris Agreement.
parties to the Paris Agreement.
South Africa’s mitigation targets under its NDC should reflect South Africa’s current NDC does not reflect its fair
its fair contribution to the global mitigation effort required for a contribution. The emissions commitments in the NDC
1.5 temperature goal, and be well below its business-as-usual are based on those in domestic policy. South Africa’s
(BAU) levels. national ‘peak-plateau-decline’ emissions trajectory range is
established and can be reviewed as enabled by the National
Climate Change Response Policy. Only the mid to low end
of the range can be said to match South Africa’s fair share
as calculated using the Climate Equity Reference Calculator.
The draft Mitigation System speaks of a Benchmark National
Emissions Trajectory, which is yet to be determined. The draft
Climate Change Bill enjoins the Minister to set and revise the
Benchmark Trajectory.
South Africa’s mitigation efforts are not primarily dependent A carbon trading system is proposed to be employed as one
on making use of cooperative approaches. Cooperative flexibility mechanism, in the face of carbon budgets and a
approaches are only used as a supplementary means to carbon tax. However, this will increase the administrative
support its domestic mitigation action. burden. More importantly, it provides an escape route for
firms to avoid meaningful emissions reductions. Therefore,
WWF-SA recommends carbon trading be omitted from
South Africa’s Mitigation System.
Institutional arrangements to realise South Africa’s national South Africa’s Climate Change Bill is currently being
emissions trajectory or targets are operational by means of developed and will determine the institutional arrangements
clearly defined and recognised climate change law. for facilitating its implementation.
The carbon price should reflect the true (social and While South Africa’s carbon tax will be used as a price
environmental) cost of carbon. The price floor for such a benchmark, the carbon price does not reflect the true social
carbon price level may be defined by the carbon tax. cost of carbon. The carbon tax rate should be increased from
the currently prescribed R120/tCO 2 e to be within the price
range of R570-R1 140/tCO 2 e by 2020. 38
To ensure environmental integrity, emission units should: Institutional arrangements need to be put in place to ensure
• Be real, measurable, additional, permanent these conditions are met.
• Avoid leakage
• Be measurable, reportable, and verifiable, in a transparent
manner
• Comply and go beyond national, social and environmental
safeguards.
South Africa must ensure robust accounting of emission units A transparent accounting system to track ITMOs in real-time
in the following ways: needs to be set up.
• Use IPCC defined metrics for carbon accounting, as it does.
• Verify whether the credits will be accounted in South Africa
or in another jurisdiction in terms of meeting NDC targets.
• Set up robust MRV systems domestically.
• Make sure there is no double counting.
• Ensure transparent and real-time tracking of the ITMOs.
• Make the host country attestation/approval process
stringent.
• Provide oversight for international transfers.
38 This price is based on the minimum global carbon price required to achieve the 2 °C target (IEA, 2015. World Energy Outlook 2015.
International Energy Agency. Paris, France. Available at: http://www.worldenergyoutlook.org/weo2015/; Kolstad, C. et al., 2014. Chapter 3:
Social, Economic and Ethical Concepts and Methods. In: IPCC, Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Cambridge University
Press. Available at: http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar5/wg3/ipcc_wg3_ar5_chapter3.pdf.
WWF-SA POSITION
WWF-SA does not support including carbon
trading in South Africa’s proposed Climate Change
Mitigation System due to a variety of challenges.
In theory, carbon trading systems are said to be the most economically-efficient and
least-cost mitigation instruments. Trading carbon emissions should allow sectors
with poor mitigation potential to fund deeper emissions reductions in others with
better mitigation potential and, therefore, achieve emissions reductions across the
economy at least-cost options.
In reality, however, the experience with implementing carbon trading has been quite
arbitrary. The EU ETS has failed to achieve adequate emissions reductions due to
a consistently weak carbon price, resulting from weak demand and over-allocation
of free emissions permits.39 However, the EU has taken up some initiatives recently
to reform the EU ETS – including setting up a €12 billion (roughly R170 billion)
fund for assisting industry to innovate and invest in low-carbon technology. 40
A developing country like South Africa cannot afford to pump such a huge sum
of money into reforming its carbon trading scheme if it fails to meet its desired
objectives, especially considering the current macro-economic climate.
Therefore, the exclusion of carbon trading from South Africa’s Mitigation System, at
least in the initial phase (2020–2025), is recommended for the reasons that follow.
39 Lubbeke, I. & Van den plas, S., 2016. Last chance for Europe’s carbon market. Time to rescue the EU
ETS from redundancy. WWF-Europe.
40 The Guardian, 2017. Reform of EU carbon trading scheme agreed. Available at: https://www.
theguardian.com/environment/2017/feb/28/reform-of-eu-carbon-trading-scheme-agreed.
Eskom accounted for 45% of South Africa’s total carbon emissions in 2010. Since
the idea is that electricity-producing entities will not be eligible for carbon trading
under the proposed Mitigation System, this leaves only about half of South
Africa’s emissions to be covered by the carbon trading scheme. Further subtract
emissions from entities emitting an amount below the threshold at which reporting
becomes mandatory, which may be not insignificant in aggregate. Given the high
administrative costs involved, it won’t be a judicious use of available resources.
Emissions uncertainty
In theory, implementing an emissions cap is said to provide emissions certainty.
However, if emissions caps (carbon budgets in the domestic context) are made
variable, then there is limited traction on total emissions reduction objectives.
While carbon budgets are fixed in the short-term (over five years), in the medium- to
long-term, they can be varied. This is evident in the Mitigation System allowing for
carbon budgets to be adjusted upwards or downwards after each five-year rolling
period. While it is encouraged that carbon budgets be ratcheted downwards in line
with science-based targets, it is strongly recommended that they not be allowed to be
adjusted upwards.
The system is unlikely to achieve the required emissions reductions to meet South
Africa’s international commitments, if carbon budgets are not informed and guided
by what is required by science to achieve the 2 °C target, let alone the 1.5 °C target,
and instead are established according to historical emissions.
Carbon budgets (or carbon space) should be auctioned from the very beginning of
each five-year rolling period, which will generate much needed revenue. In doing so
there will be increased buy-in and commitment from firms to remain within their
carbon budget, and greater incentive to avoid taxes on emissions in excess of their
budget (should that be the final design of the carbon budget-carbon tax interface).
The climate change mitigation debate in South Africa needs to move from improving TOPICS IN SERIES
efficiency within a projection of the existing economy, to innovation and options beyond
the constraints of the current dispensation and structure of the economy. It may take step BARRIERS
changes in the development path to achieve mitigation adequate to South Africa domestic
LABOUR MARKET
and international commitments, and maximise economic development and social wellbeing.
Business models presently unconsidered may be waiting in the wings.
CONSUMPTION
Working variously with government, business and labour, the project reaches from
Authors:
providing input to emerging government mitigation policies and measures; through Reinhardt Arp, Prabhat Upadhyaya and
investigating the business and socio-economic case for selected mitigation initiatives which Louise Naudé, WWF
Available at:
hold growth potential in energy, transport, industry, waste, and land use; to analysing http://www.wwf.org.za/report/SA_
potential future economic trajectories and the systemic opportunities offered by these. carbon_trading
Contact for WWF South Africa:
Saliem Fakir, Head: Policy and Futures
This policy-related paper examines whether the inclusion of carbon trading in Unit, telephone +27 (0)21 657 6600,
South Africa’s Mitigation System provides flexibility to the major emitters in e-mail sfakir@wwf.org.za
Series editor:
reducing their emissions, or serves as an escape route from accounting their Barbara Hutton
emissions against the true social cost of carbon. Design:
Farm Design, www.farmdesign.co.za
Photos: Unless otherwise indicated,
The project is funded by the International Climate Initiative (IKI) of the Federal Ministry all photos by Shutterstock.com
of the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety of Germany, and implemented Published in 2018 by WWF-SA, Cape
Town, South Africa. Any reproduction in
by WWF-SA. full or in part must mention the title and
credit WWF-SA as the copyright owner.
Copyleft: You are welcome to quote the
information in this paper provided that
WWF South Africa’s Policy and Futures Unit undertakes enquiry into the you acknowledge the source as follows:
Arp, R., Upadhyaya, P. & Naudé, L.,
possibility of a new economy that advances a sustainable future. The unit convenes, 2018. Carbon trading in South Africa:
investigates, demonstrates and articulates for policy-makers, industry and other players providing flexibility or escape route?
WWF-SA.
the importance of lateral and long term systemic thinking. The work of the unit is
If you would like to share copies of this
oriented towards solutions for the future of food, water, power and transport, against the paper, please do so in this printed or
backdrop of climate change, urbanisation and regional dynamics. The overarching aim electronic PDF format.
Every effort has been made to trace
is to promote and support a managed transition to a resilient future for South Africa’s copyright holders, but if any copyright
people and environment. The organisation also focuses on natural resources in the areas infringements have been made, we would
be grateful for information that would
of marine, freshwater, land, species and agriculture. enable any omissions or errors to be
corrected in subsequent impressions.
wwf.org.za
wwf.org.za/energy
© 1986 Panda Symbol WWF-World Wide Fund for Nature (Formerly World Wildlife Fund)
® “WWF” is a WWF Registered Trademark. WWF, Avenue du Mont-Blanc, 1196 Gland,
Switzerland – Tel. +41 22 364 9111 Fax +41 22 364 0332. For contact details and further
information, please visit our international website at wwf.panda.org