Economics Challenge
Economics Challenge
Economics Challenge
1 of 18
1. Use a supply and demand diagram to analyze each of the following scenarios. Explain briefly.
Be sure to show how both the equilibrium price and quantity change in each case.
a) The economic downturn has led to more people staying home to watch movies, rather
than go to a movie theater. Show how this change in behavior affects the market for
microwave popcorn.
b) Suppose that drought conditions in agricultural regions increase the costs of irrigation.
How would this affect the market for fruits and vegetables?
c) The New York Times recently reported on technological advances leading to an
increase in the number of female cows. Female cows are valuable to farmers because
they can be used to produce milk. However, while farmers now have more female cows
available to produce milk, they are not happy. Use a supply and demand diagram for
the milk market to explain why.
The purpose of this problem is to get you thinking about how demand and supply curves are
affected by outside influences, and to help you distinguish between shifts of a curve versus a
movement along a curve.
a)
P
S
P1
P0
D’
D
Q0 Q1 Q
Microwave popcorn is a compliment to watching movies at home. Thus, demand for microwave
popcorn increases, shifting up and to the right. The equilibrium quantity and price both increase.
p. 2 of 18
b)
S’
P
S
P1
P0
Q1 Q0 Q
Drought conditions reduce the supply of fruits and vegetables, shifting the curve up and to the
left. The equilibrium price rises, and the equilibrium quantity falls.
c)
S
P S’
P0
P1
Q0 Q1 Q
This technological advance increases milk production. As a result, supply increases, shifting
down and to the right. Although the equilibrium quantity rises, the equilibrium price falls,
explaining why farmers are not happy. Note, in particular, that the demand for milk is usually
inelastic. Thus, the drop in price is likely to be larger than the increase in quantity demanded,
so that the farmers’ revenue likely falls.
p. 3 of 18
2. Suppose that the market for milk can be represented by the following equations:
Demand: P = 12 – 0.5QD
Supply: P = 0.1QS
where P is the price per gallon, and Q represents quantity of milk, represented in millions of
gallons of milk consumed per day.
12 – 0.5Q = 0.1Q
0.6Q = 12
Q = 12/0.6
Q = 20 million gallons
To find the price, we substitute the equilibrium quantity into either the demand or supply
equation:
Either:
P = 0.1(20) = $2
Or:
P = 12 – 0.5(20) = $2
p. 4 of 18
b) The minimum price is above the equilibrium price. Thus, there will be an excess supply of milk
– more people will want to sell milk than will be willing to buy milk. The new quantity sold will
be limited by the number of people willing to purchase milk at this higher price. We find this by
substituting $2.50 for P in the demand equation, and then solving for Q:
2.50 = 12 – 0.5Q
9.50 = 0.5Q
Q = 9.50/0.5
Q = 19 million gallons
c) To draw the graph, we begin by drawing the supply and demand curves. Note that the
equations are already solved for P. Thus, we know that the y-intercept (on the price axis) for
demand is $12. Similarly, by setting P = 0, we find that Q = 24 when P = 0 (because 12 –
0.5(24) = 0).
For supply, we know the line goes through the origin (y-intercept = 0), and intersects demand
at a quantity of 20 and a price of $2.
P
12 D
A E
F S
2.50
B
2
1.9
D
C
19 20 24 Q
With a price floor of $2.50, note that there will be excess supply, so the quantity demanded at
$2.50 determines the quantity sold. As we found in part (b), this is 19 million gallons of milk.
Consumer surplus is everything above the price and below the demand curve. Before the price
supports are enacted, this is areas A, B and E above. This is a triangle with a base of 20 and
a height of 10 (=12-2). Thus, the area of this triangle, and thus the consumer surplus, equals
0.5(20)(10) = $100.
After the price supports are in place, consumer surplus falls to just area A. This is a triangle
with a base of 19 and a height of 9.5 (=12-2.5). Thus, the area of this triangle = 0.5(19)(9.5) =
$90.25.
Producer surplus is everything below the price and above the supply curve. Without price
supports, this is areas C, D, and F. The area of this triangle = 0.5(20)(2) = $20.
p. 5 of 18
With price supports, producer surplus is areas B, C, and D. Thus, producers lose F, but gain
B. Area B is a rectangle with a height of 0.5 (=2.50 – 2) and a base of 19. Its area = (0.5)(19)
= 9.5. To find the areas for C and D, we need to know where the line between these areas hits
the supply curve at the quantity of 19. We get this by substituting 19 for Q in the supply
equation: P = 0.1(19) = 1.9. Given this, we can now calculate that rectangle C has an area of
1.9 (=0.1x19), and triangle D has an area of 18.05 (=0.5x19x1.9). Thus, the total producer
surplus = 9.5 + 1.9 + 18.05 = $29.45. As expected, producer surplus increases, and consumer
surplus decreases, after price supports are enacted.
There is a deadweight loss with the price supports, because some milk that was sold before is
now not sold. This is areas E and F. Note that these two areas are part of consumer or
producer surplus before the price supports are in place, but not afterwards. These areas
represent lost opportunities because less milk is sold. To calculate the value, note that this is
a triangle with a height of 0.6 (= 2.5 – 1.9) and base of 1 (= 20 – 19). The area is (0.5)(0.6)(1)
= $0.30.
Finally, to see the intuition of deadweight loss, compare the sum of consumer and producer
surplus before and after the policy. Before the policy, the total surplus is $120. After the policy,
the total of consumer and producer surplus is $119.70. The difference between these is $0.30.
That is, $0.30 of potential surplus is lost because of the minimum price.
d) The excess supply is the difference between the quantity supplied at a price of $2.50 and
quantity demanded at a price of $2.50. We know from part (b) that 19 million gallons are
demanded at this price. Thus, we just need to find the quantity supplied at this price:
2.50 = 0.1QS
QS = 2.50/0.1
QS = 25 million gallons
Since 25 million gallons of milk are available for sale, but consumers only purchase 19 million
gallons, the government must purchase the 6 million gallons that are not purchased by
consumers.
p. 6 of 18
3. Suppose that the market for gasoline can be represented by the following equations:
Demand: P = 10 – 2QD
Supply: P = 1 + 0.5QS
where P is the price per gallon, and Q represents quantity of gasoline, represented in millions
of gallons of gasoline consumed per year.
10 – 2Q = 1 + 0.5Q
2.5Q = 9
Q = 9/2.5
Q = 3.6 million gallons
To find the price, we substitute the equilibrium quantity into either the demand or supply
equation:
Either:
P = 1 + 0.5(3.6) = $2.80
Or:
P = 10 – 2(3.6) = $2.80
p. 7 of 18
b) The price ceiling is below the equilibrium price of gasoline. Thus, there will be excess demand
for gasoline. Consumers will want to purchase more gasoline than suppliers will make
available at the price of $2.25 per gallon. Thus, we need to find out how much supply is
available. We do this by plugging in $2.25 in the supply curve and solving for Q:
2.25 = 1 + 0.5Q
1.25 = 0.5Q
Q = 2.5
2.5 million gallons of gasoline are sold
To draw the graph, we begin by drawing the supply and demand curves. Note that the
equations are already solved for P. Thus, we know that the y-intercept (on the price axis) for
demand is $10. Similarly, by setting P = 0, we find that Q = 5 when P = 0 (because 10 – 2(5)
= 0).
For supply, we know the y-intercept is at $1, and intersects demand at a quantity of 3.6 and a
price of $2.80. Note also that the line for a price of $2.25 is below equilibrium, so that we get
the new quantity of 32.5om the supply curve.
Finally, the graph below also includes labeled areas for consumer and producer surplus. We
will use this to answer the questions below.
10 S
A
5
B C
2.8 E
D
2.25
F
1 D
2.5 3.6 5 Q
Note from the graph that it is supply, rather than demand, that determines what the new
quantity will be. Because the price ceiling is lower than the equilibrium price, the quantity is
constrained by how much suppliers are willing to make available at $2.25. There will be excess
demand.
c) Consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve and above the price. In the initial
equilibrium, this includes areas A, B, & C. This is a triangle with a height of 7.2 (= 10-2.8) and
a base of 3.6. Its area is 0.5(7.2)(3.6) = $12.96.
Producer surplus is the area above the supply curve and below the price producers receive. It
is areas D, E, & F. This is a triangle with a height of 1.8 (= 2.8 - 1) and a base of 3.6. Its area
is 0.5(1.8)(3.6) = $3.24.
p. 8 of 18
d) Again, consumer surplus is everything above the new price ($2.25) and below the demand
curve. This is areas A, B, & D. To find the area of A, we need to know the value at the bottom
of the triangle. This is the amount that consumers are willing to pay for 2.5 million gallons of
gasoline. We find this by plugging 2.5 into demand:
P = 10 – 2(2.5) = $5.
Thus, triangle A has a height of 5 (= 10 – 5) and a base of 2.5. Its area equals 0.5(5)(2.5) =
$6.25. The area of the rectangle comprised of B & D has a height of 2.75 (= 5- 2.25) and a
length of 2.5. Its area equals (2.75)(2.5) = $6.875. Thus, the total consumer surplus is
$13.125.
Producer surplus is just area F. This is a triangle with a height of 1.25 (= 2.25 – 1) and a base
of 2.5. Its area is 0.5(1.25)(2.5) = $1.5625.
The difference between these two is $1.5125. This difference is the deadweight loss.
Deadweight loss is the lost welfare resulting from potentially beneficial transactions that took
place before but do not occur after rent control is in place. Note that we can check our work
by referring back to the graph. The deadweight loss is the triangle comprised of areas C & E.
It has a base of 1.1 (= 3.6 – 2.5) and a height of 2.75 (= 5 – 2.25). The area is thus
0.5(1.1)(2.75) = $1.5125.
p. 9 of 18
4. You are the manager of a store that carries generic soft drinks. Due to a local economic boom,
your customers’ incomes are forecasted to rise by five percent during the next month. The
income elasticity of demand for these products is estimated to be –2.0. Estimate the change
in the quantity of your soft drink orders required to accommodate the new demand without a
surplus or shortage of inventory (that is, how much will demand for the generic soft drinks
change due to the increased income?).
Income elasticity is the percentage change in quantity demanded due to a one percent
change in income. In this case, a one percent increase in income leads to a two percent
decrease in quantity demanded. Since income is rising by 5 percent, quantity demanded
will decrease by 10 percent (5% X –2%).
%∆𝑄𝑄
= −2
5
%∆𝑄𝑄 = −10
p. 10 of 18
5. Concerned about the behavior of his own teenage children, the governor of a large Southern
state is considering policy to help reduce consumption of alcoholic beverages. His advisors
have suggested a new tax, the Tax Against Beer (TAB). While beer is currently taxed, this tax
would increase the overall tax on beer. It would have the effect of raising the price of beer (and
thus the tax revenue raised per unit of beer sold) by 10%. You are given the following
information, and asked to calculate the effect of the tax on both consumption of alcoholic
beverages and on government revenue.
a) By how much will consumption of alcoholic beverages fall after the tax is imposed?
b) Will government revenue increase or decrease after the tax is imposed? How do you
know this?
c) How might your answers to (a) and (b) vary if looking at the long-run, rather than the
immediate effect?
We are given the percent change in price (10%) and the elasticity. Thus, we can calculate
the change in quantity:
%𝛥𝛥𝛥𝛥
−0.4 =
0.1
%𝛥𝛥𝛥𝛥 = (−0.4)(0.1) = −0.04
Quantity will fall by 4%.
To find the reduction in terms of number of beverages consumed, simply multiply this by the
total number currently consumed (1,000,000). Thus, we find that consumption of alcoholic
beverages falls by 40,000.
b) Government revenue will increase. Demand is inelastic. Thus, the decrease in quantity
demanded will be small relative to the increase in price resulting from the tax.
c) One reason that alcoholic beverages have an inelastic demand is because they are addictive.
Those who are addicted will purchase alcohol at nearly any price. However, higher prices may
discourage new users from consuming alcohol and becoming addicted. Thus, in the long run,
demand is likely to be more elastic. The fall in quantity consumed should be greater. The
increase in revenue will be smaller, and revenue may decrease if demand becomes elastic.
p. 11 of 18
6. From an analytic standpoint, a subsidy is simply a negative excise tax that confers a benefit
to certain groups rather than imposing a burden on them. For decades, the federal
government has given fairly large subsidies to farmers for producing everything from grain to
honey.
a) Under what conditions of supply and demand would farmers enjoy all the benefits of
these subsidies?
b) Under what conditions of supply and demand would farmers enjoy none of the benefits
of these subsidies? Who does benefit from the subsidy in this case?
a) This problem is simply a tax incidence problem in reverse. Consider how the subsidy affects
the agricultural market:
S
P
S’
PS
P0
PC
Q0 Q1 Q
Just like a tax on farmers would shift the supply curve in, a subsidy for farmers shifts the supply
curve out. The equilibrium quantity increases from Q0 to Q1.
To see what happens to prices, remember that we get the price consumers pay off of the
demand curve. This is PC. Consumers pay less as a result of the subsidy, since there is more
food available. However, farmers earn more money, since they get both the price consumers
pay and the subsidy. The total amount received by farmers is PS.
Now, consider what must be true for farmers to enjoy all the benefits. That can only be true if
the price consumers pay does not change. When might that occur? There are two possibilities.
One is when demand is perfectly elastic, consumers will continue to pay the same price. Thus,
suppliers receive the entire benefit of the subsidy. This is illustrated below:
S
P
S’
PS
P0 = PC
D
Q0 Q1 Q
Alternatively, if supply was perfectly inelastic, the quantity sold would not change, so
consumers would continue to pay the original price. Again, in this case, suppliers would receive
the entire benefit of the subsidy.
p. 12 of 18
b) Farmers enjoy none of the benefits when the price paid by consumers falls by the entire amount
of the tax. An example of when this would occur is when demand is perfectly inelastic. In this
case, there is no demand for extra agricultural products, so the price falls to discourage
additional production. This is illustrated below:
D
S
P
S’
P0 = PS
PC
Q0 Q
Alternatively, this could occur if supply were perfectly elastic. In that case, the subsidy would
simply induce more and more farmers to grow crops, so that the price farmers receive always
remains the same.
p. 13 of 18
7. Suppose that demand and supply of apples are described by the following equations:
P = 100 - 3Q (demand)
P = 20 + Q (supply)
a) Calculate the equilibrium price and quantity. Illustrate.
b) Suppose a $4 tax is placed on apples. What is the new equilibrium quantity? How
much do consumers pay to get this quantity? How much do suppliers receive for selling
this quantity? Show your results on a supply & demand diagram.
In equilibrium, the quantity supplied by sellers must be the same as the quantity demanded by
consumers. If not, there will be either an excess demand or excess supply, and the price will
be bid up or down accordingly. Thus, to find equilibrium, we find the intersection of supply and
demand:
100 - 3Q = 2Q + 20
80 = 4Q
Q = 20
Having found the quantity, we now plug this answer into either the supply or demand equation
to find the equilibrium price:
P = 100 - (3)(20) P = 20 + 20
= 100 – 60 or
= 40 P = 40
The graph for this market is:
P
100 S
40
20
D
20 33.33 Q
To draw each line, we need two points. We can use the following information to draw the graph.
First, the demand curve has a y-intercept of 100. Second, we can solve for Q when P = 0 to
find that the demand curve must cross the x-axis at 33.33. For the supply curve, we know
that the y-intercept is 20. Starting from there, we proceed to draw a curve with a slope of 1 –
that is, for each 1 unit increase in Q, the price must also increase by 1.
p. 14 of 18
b) Recall from class that a tax requires us to shift either the supply curve or demand curve in.
Note that your results will be the same no matter which one you choose. For example, let’s
shift the supply curve.
The supply curve shifts in by the amount of the tax. That is because at any given price,
suppliers now receive $4 less, with the remainder going to the government. This is the
supply curve faced by consumers. Algebraically, P - 4 = 20 + Q ⇒ P = 24 + Q. We subtract
$4 because P is the price consumers pay. Suppliers get to keep this price less the four dollar
tax. Graphically, note that the y-intercept of the graph has shifted up by the amount of the
tax.
S’
P
100 S
43
40
39
24
20
D
19 20 33.33 Q
We begin by finding the new equilibrium. Equate the new supply curve with the old demand
curve.
24 + Q = 100 - 3Q
4Q = 76
Q = 19
However, $4 goes to the government, leaving $39 for suppliers. Note that we can also get
this off the old supply curve (39 = 20 + 19). We use the old supply curve because what we
are interested in is what suppliers are willing to supply after the tax has been paid.
p. 15 of 18
8. Suppose the market for cameras has a supply curve of P = 30 + Q, and a demand curve of P
= 240 – 2Q. Assume that the market is perfectly competitive.
a) What will the equilibrium price and quantity of cameras be?
b) Calculate the producer and consumer surplus associated with the equilibrium found in
part (a). Illustrate on a graph.
c) Suppose the government levies a tax of $18 per camera sold. What is the new quantity
of cameras sold? What price do consumers pay? What price do producers receive?
Illustrate on a graph.
d) Find the new producer and consumer surplus associated with your answer to part (c).
e) How much revenue does the government raise from the tax?
f) How does the sum of consumer surplus, producer surplus, and revenue after the tax
(your answers to (d) and (e)) compare to the sum of producer and consumer surplus
found before the tax (your answer to (b))? What does the difference between the two
represent?
b)
P
240
100
30 D
70 Q
Consumer surplus is the triangle above the price and below demand. It has a height of 140
(= 240 – 100) and a base of 70. Its area = 0.5(140)(70) = $4,900.
Producer surplus is the triangle below price and above supply. It has a height of 70 (= 100 –
30) and a base of 70. Its area = 0.5(70)(70) = $2,450.
p. 16 of 18
c) The result of the tax is to shift either the supply curve or demand curve in. Note that your
results will be the same no matter which one you choose. In this example, I’ll shift the supply
curve. The supply curve shifts up by the amount of the tax. The new supply curve represents
the supply curve faced by consumers. If P is the price consumers pay, suppliers get P - 18,
with $18 going to the government. Graphically, we shift the supply curve up by $18, so that the
new intercept is $48.
P
240
S’
S
112
100
94
48
30 D
64 70 Q
Algebraically, recall that the tax places a wedge between the consumer and producer price, so
that PC = PS + tax. Suppliers care about the money they receive after paying the tax, which is
just PS. For suppliers to get that amount, the price paid by consumers will need to go up to
help cover the tax. Adding the tax represents the upward shift of the supply curve. The demand
curve equals the new supply curve, which represents both the original costs to suppliers and
the tax that suppliers must pay. Equating the old demand curve with the new supply curve:
48 + Q =240 – 2Q
192 = 3Q
Q = 192/3
Q = 64
We plug this quantity into the original supply and demand curves to get the post-tax prices.
With a quantity of 64, suppliers receive:
Consumers must pay $18 more than this, or $112. Note that we can verify this using the
demand curve, where we get PC = 240 – 2(64) = 240 – 128 = $112.
p. 17 of 18
d)
P
240
A S’
S
112
B C
100 F
94 D E
G
H
48
30 D
64 70 Q
Note that we use the original supply and demand, at the new prices and quantities, to find
consumer and producer surplus.
Area A in the above graph represents consumer surplus. This is a triangle with a height of 128
(= 240-112) and a base of 64. Its area = 0.5(128)(64) = $4,096.
Areas G and H in the above graph represents producer surplus. This is a triangle with a height
of 64 (= 94 - 30) and a base of 64. Its area = 0.5(64)(64) = $2,048.
$18 x 64 = $1152.
f) Before the tax, the sum of consumer and producer surplus was $7,350. Afterwards, the sum
of consumer surplus, producer surplus, and revenue is $7,296. The difference is $54.
Graphically, this is the area of triangles C & F.
This difference is the deadweight loss. It is the value of lost opportunities, because some
potentially beneficial transactions do not occur after the tax. For the quantities between 64 and
70, demand is above supply. This tells us that consumers are willing to pay more than the
marginal cost of producing the good. However, because of the tax, these units are not sold.
The potential producer or consumer lost because of this is the deadweight loss.
p. 18 of 18
9. Suppose that after graduation you take a position in the Department of Health, Education, and
Welfare. You are asked to show what will happen in the market for college education after the
enactment of a new $1,000 tax credit for college tuition. You are given the following
information:
• 15.3 million students are enrolled in college, either at private or public institutions. (This
does not include enrollments in graduate programs).
• The average tuition paid by these students is $5,192 per year.
• Assume that, overall, colleges are operating near capacity, so the possibility of expanding
enrollments is minimal.
Use a supply and demand diagram to show the initial equilibrium and the effect of the tax
credit. Who is the major beneficiary of the tax credit – students or colleges? Explain intuitively
why this is the case. How would your answer change if we did not assume that colleges are
operating near capacity?
Colleges, not students, will be the main beneficiaries. The assumption that colleges are
operating near capacity means that supply is nearly fixed – it is inelastic. Just as inelastic
parties bear the burden of taxation, they reap the benefits of tax credits, as shown in the
graph below.
P
S
PS
5,192
PC
D’
15.3 Q
Q1
The tax credit shifts the demand for college up. However, since quantity cannot increase
by much, tuitions received by colleges increase (PS). Students pay PC, which equals PS
minus the tax credit. Note that although the price students pay does fall somewhat, the
drop is not nearly as large as the gain received by colleges. Most of the $1,000 from the
tax credit goes to colleges. If colleges were not at full capacity, students would benefit
more, as enrollments could increase without tuition increasing as much.