Repo FAQs January 2019 050221
Repo FAQs January 2019 050221
Repo FAQs January 2019 050221
Published by the International Capital Market Association (ICMA) in February 2013 and amended in
January 2019.
These FAQs are provided for information purposes only and should not be relied upon as legal, financial
or other professional advice. While the information contained herein is taken from sources believed to
be reliable, ICMA does not represent or warrant that it is accurate or complete and neither ICMA nor its
employees shall have any liability arising from or relating to the use of this publication or its contents,
including any information on any third party website which may be referred to in this document.
Topical issues.....................................................................................................................35
29. What has been the regulatory response in the repo market to the Great Financial Crisis? ......... 35
30. What is ‘short selling’ and what is the role of repo? ..................................................................... 40
31. Do repos allow for infinite leverage? ............................................................................................ 41
32. Do changes in haircuts/margins exacerbate pro-cyclicality? ........................................................ 42
33. Do banks that lend through repo receive preferential treatment over other creditors? ............. 43
34. Does repo ‘encumber’ a borrower’s assets? ................................................................................. 43
35. Was a ‘run on repo’ the cause of the Great Financial Crisis in 2007? ........................................... 44
36. Is repo a type of ‘shadow banking’? .............................................................................................. 46
37. Is repo used to remove assets from the balance sheet? ............................................................... 46
38. Could a repo rate benchmark replace LIBOR or EURIBOR? ........................................................... 47
39. How do MiFID II and MiFIR apply to the repo market in the EU? ................................................. 49
These FAQs have been written by Richard Comotto, Senior Visiting Fellow at the ICMA Centre at
Reading University.
1. What is a repo?
In a repo, one party sells an asset (usually fixed-income securities) to another party at one price and
commits to repurchase the same or another part of the same asset from the second party at a different
price at a future date or (in the case of an open repo) on demand. 2 If the seller defaults during the life of
the repo, the buyer (as the new owner) can sell the asset to a third party to offset his loss. The asset
therefore acts as collateral and mitigates the credit risk that the buyer has on the seller.
Although an asset is sold outright at the start of a repo, the commitment of the seller to buy back the
asset in the future means that the buyer has only temporary use of that asset, while the seller has only
temporary use of the cash proceeds of the initial sale. Thus, although repo is structured legally as a sale
and repurchase of securities, it behaves economically like a collateralised or secured deposit (and the
principal use of repo is in fact the secured borrowing and lending of cash).
The difference between the price paid by the buyer at the start of a repo and the price he receives at
the end is his return on the cash that he is effectively lending to the seller. In repurchase transactions,
and now usually in the case of buy/sell-backs, this return is quoted as a percentage per annum rate and
is called the repo rate. Although not legally correct, the return itself is usually referred to as repo
interest.
1
Repos are sometimes known as ‘sale-and-repurchase agreements’ or just ‘repurchase agreements’. In some
markets, the name ‘repo’ can be taken to imply repurchase transactions only and not buy/sell-backs. Repurchase
transactions are also known as ‘classic repo’. Under EU regulation --- along with securities lending, commodities
lending and margin lending --- repurchase transactions and buy/sell-backs are types of ‘securities financing
transaction’ (SFT).
2
In the Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA), the same or similar assets are described as ‘Equivalent
Securities’. ‘Equivalent’ means assets that are economically but not necessarily legally identical (the same issue of
securities with the same ISIN or, if the issue is divided into classes or tranches, the same class or tranche, but not
the same part of that issue, class or tranche).
A repo not only mitigates the buyer’s credit risk. Provided the asset being used as collateral is liquid, the
buyer should be able to refinance himself at any time during the life of a repo by selling or repoing the
assets to a third party (he would, of course, subsequently have to buy the same or a similar asset back in
order to return it to his repo counterparty at the end of the repo). This right of use (often called re-use)
mitigates the liquidity risk that the buyer takes by lending to the seller. Because lending through a repo
exposes the buyer to lower credit and liquidity risks, repo rates should be lower than unsecured money
market rates.
There is a definition of repo in the EU’s Securities Financing Transactions Regulation (SFTR) but this is
incorrect and should not be used other than for the purpose of reporting under the SFTR. Article 5 of
the SFTR defines a repurchase transaction as a transfer of ‘securities or commodities or guaranteed
rights relating to title to securities or commodities where that guarantee is issued by a recognised
exchange which holds the rights to the securities or commodities and the agreement does not allow a
counterparty to transfer or pledge a particular security or commodity to more than one counterparty at
one time’. In reality, there are no repos against guaranteed rights and true repos do not use pledges. In
addition, SFTR incorrectly defines a buy/sell-back (see question 11).
Repo performs four basic functions which are fundamental to the efficient working of many other
financial markets (see question 3).
1 One party can invest cash secured against the asset provided as collateral --- safe investment.
2 The counterparty can borrow cash in order to finance a long position in an asset, in an amount
and at a repo rate that reflect, among other things, the collateral provided to the lender --- cheap
borrowing. 3
3 One party can earn a return by lending out an asset that is in demand in the market, in exchange
for cheap cash, which can be used for funding or reinvested for profit (see question 9) --- yield
enhancement for securities investors.
4 The counterparty can borrow an asset in order to sell and establish a short position or to deliver
in order to settle a sale that has already been agreed (see question 30) --- short-selling and short-
covering. 4
For lenders of cash (repo buyers), repo offers a safe investment because:
• The buyer receives collateral to hedge his credit risk on the seller. Moreover, in a repo, title to the
collateral is sold to the buyer, which should mean that, unlike pledged collateral, it can be
liquidated in the event of the seller’s insolvency without interference from an insolvency court. In
other words, repo provides ‘bankruptcy-remote’ collateral, which reduces the credit risk of a cash
investor more than a traditional secured loan.
• The buyer can diversify his credit exposure by taking collateral issued by a third party whose
credit risk is uncorrelated with the credit risk of the seller.
• Collateralisation through transfer of title can reduce, not only the credit risk arising from lending,
but also the liquidity risk. Where a buyer is given liquid collateral, he can meet any unforeseen
3
A ‘long position’ in an asset is created by buying the asset outright. The holder benefits from price rises, the
accrual or payment of income on the asset and any other benefits of ownership.
4
A ‘short position’ in an asset is created by borrowing the asset and selling it outright. The holder will have to buy
back the asset in due course in order to return it to the asset lender. This means he will benefit from a fall in the
price of the asset between selling and buying it back, but will lose the income accruing or being paid in the interim
and any other benefits of ownership.
For borrowers of cash (repo sellers), repo offers a cheap and potentially more plentiful source of
funding because the collateral they provide to the lenders (repo buyers) reduces the risks to the latter
and does so in a more legally certain way than collateralisation by pledging.
For lenders of securities (repo sellers), repo offers a means of generating incremental income, on their
investment portfolio, as in the securities lending market (see question 13).
For borrowers of securities (repo buyers), repo offers an alternative or supplement to the securities
lending market, particularly for fixed-income securities.
The repo market is pivotal to the efficient working of almost all financial markets. Its importance reflects
the wide range and fundamental nature of repo’s applications:
• Providing an efficient source of short-term funding. By being able to offer deposits secured by
legal title to high-quality liquid assets (HQLAs) and diversification to include lenders other than
commercial banks, repo is able to mobilise cheaper and deeper funding for financial
intermediaries, in particular, securities dealers. And by reducing the degree of dependence on
commercial banks, access to short-term funding is made easier and more reliable. Cheaper and
easier funding helps to lower the cost of financial services provided by intermediaries to investors
and issuers. Institutional investors also use repo, to meet temporary liquidity requirements
without having to liquidate strategic long-term investments. Since the introduction of the Basel
regulatory requirement to clear standardised OTC derivatives across central counterparties (CCPs)
and the related imposition of margin on uncleared OTC derivatives, the repo market has become
an important source of cash for non-banks to provide as variation margin to CCPs.
• Providing a more resilient money market. The resilience of the repo market helps to mitigate
systemic risk. Repo is a more stable source of short-term wholesale funding than unsecured
deposits, because collateral in the form of HQLA (overwhelmingly the most common type) and
secured by the transfer of legal title hedges both the credit and liquidity risks of lenders (see
question 1). This means lenders are more willing to offer longer-term funding and, as recognised
in the Basel Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR), are less likely to refuse to roll-over lending, even in a
stressed market. For example, although the repo market was not immune to the disruption
triggered by the default of Lehman Brothers in 2008, it did not suffer a seizure and has been
essential in avoiding total and unsustainable dependence on central bank liquidity. 5 The stability
of repo funding is reinforced by the wide range of lenders who are willing to lend in the wholesale
money market on a suitably secured basis. Diversification creates a market which is deeper and
naturally more resilient. Repo also mitigates systemic risk by allowing traders and investors who
need liquidity in a stressed market to convert assets temporarily into cash in a way that is less
disruptive than outright sales. Outright sales would depress the price of collateral securities and
crystallize any unrealised losses on the holdings being liquidated or on hedges that have to be
5 Papadia & Välimäki point out that, between 2008 and 2011, the unsecured eurozone money market shrank by
EUR 327 billion, forcing the ECB into exceptional emergency lending in order to prevent a seizure of the financial
system and serious damage to the real economy. In fact, the ECB lent EUR 115 billion. But growth in the repo
market contributed another EUR 212 billion, without which, the burden on the ECB would have been dramatically
greater.
6
An alternative hedge for a long position in a new issue would be a short position in a related derivative
instrument, such as a bond future or interest rate swap, but the derivative will ultimately have to be hedged by
someone else borrowing the underlying security in the repo market.
7
Market-makers in corporate and other credit bonds also hedge the credit risk on any long positions that they
accumulate. This can be done, subject to various degrees of basis risk, by: (1) shorting a security from the same
issuer but issued in another part of the capital structure (eg senior against subordinated tranches); (2) shorting a
security from a similar issuer with the same seniority; (3) selling protection through a single-name credit default
swap (CDS) written on the same issuer and for the same seniority; or (4) selling protection through a CDS written
on an index that is a reasonable proxy to the issuer of the security being hedged. The use of a CDS ultimately has to
be hedged by someone else going short of the underlying security or index and covering that short position by
borrowing in the repo market.
There are large repo markets in the US and Europe (including the eurozone, UK, Denmark and Poland).
There is also a large repo market in Japan, although the form it has traditionally taken (gentan) is strictly-
speaking a type of securities lending transaction. The top 20 markets include Argentina, Australia,
Canada, India, Mexico, New Zealand, Russia, Singapore, South Africa, South Korea, Sri Lanka,
Switzerland, Taiwan, Thailand and Turkey. The remainder of the world’s repo markets are in perhaps
another 30-40 countries with reasonably active markets (excluding central bank repo). There are also
8
A ‘buy-in’ is a process whereby a buyer of a security that has not been delivered by the seller, appoints an agent
to buy in the security on his behalf or buys in directly from the market. Any cost over and above the original
purchase price is charged to the failing seller.
The ICMA’s semi-annual survey of the European repo market in June 2018 produced a figure of about
EUR 7 trillion in terms of outstanding repo contracts for the survey sample (which includes the most
active participants in the European repo market but is not comprehensive). At about the same time as
the ICMA survey, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York reported that the outstanding repo business of
its primary dealers (who may account for as much as 80-90% of the US market) as almost USD 4 trillion.
The global market, although it has contracted since 2007, may be over EUR 15 trillion in outstanding size
and turnover about EUR 3 trillion per day.
The results of the ICMA’s semi-annual survey of the European repo market, which has been conducted
since 2001 and is the most authoritative source of regional repo market data, are published on the ICMA
website.
Traditionally, the principal users of repo on the sellers’ side of the market have been securities market
intermediaries (market-makers and other securities dealers in firms called ‘broker-dealers’ or
‘investment banks’) and leveraged and other bond investors seeking funding. On the buyers’ side, the
principal traditional users have been cash investors seeking secure short-term investments, many of
whom are highly risk-averse. These include large commercial banks, central banks investing foreign
currency reserves, international financial institutions, money market mutual funds, agents investing
cash collateral received by their securities lending clients, asset managers with temporary cash
surpluses and the treasuries of large non-financial corporates and of financial market infrastructures
such as central counterparties (CCPs) and central security depositories (CSDs). Since the Great Financial
Crisis, because of generally higher risk aversion and regulatory pressure, repo has reportedly been
attracting smaller commercial banks, as well as a greater number of non-bank financials such as
sovereign wealth funds.
Most central banks rely on the repo market as the main channel for the transmission of monetary policy
to the wider financial market and to provide emergency assistance to the banking system.
Ideally, collateral should be free of credit and liquidity risk and exhibit minimal correlation (wrong-way
risk) with the credit risk of the collateral-provider. The market value of such perfect collateral would be
certain, meaning that it would be easy to sell for a predictable value in the event of a default by the
collateral-giver, even in stressed markets. The type of asset that comes closest to this paradigm, and is
in fact the most commonly-used type of collateral in the repo market, are bonds issued domestically by
central governments. The ICMA’s semi-annual survey of the European repo market estimates
government bond collateral to account for over 90% of EU-originated repo collateral. In the US,
Treasury securities may account for about two-thirds of that repo market. Much of the rest of the US
market is government-guaranteed Agency debt and Agency Mortgage-Backed Securities (MBS).
Repo using collateral other than high-quality government bonds is often called credit repo. On the cusp
between government and credit collateral are high grade bonds issued by supranational institutions
such as the World Bank, as well as sovereign issues (foreign currency bonds issued by governments) and
agency issues (issued by public sector bodies such as the government-guaranteed mortgage agencies in
Bonds issued by central governments in emerging markets are included in credit repo by international
investors. Nevertheless, many of these are large issues and can be reasonably liquid.
Private sector assets form the smallest sector of the repo market. Such assets tend to be riskier and
much less liquid than government bonds, although higher yielding. They include:
• Corporate bonds, typically senior unsecured debt issued by investment-grade banks and large
non-financial companies. This class of security has become less popular since the Great Financial
Crisis, in part, reflecting decreased liquidity in the cash market in corporate bonds due to
heightened risk aversion towards financial corporates and the cost of tighter regulation.
• Equity, particularly baskets reproducing market indexes such as the FTSE-100, CAC and DAX. The
use of equity as collateral has increased since the Great Financial Crisis, during which, equity
performed well as collateral (in terms of the continuous availability of tradeable prices).
• Covered bonds such as pfandbrief, which are secured by pools of public loans or mortgages held
on the balance sheet of the issuer but ring-fenced in statute by special public laws. Covered
bonds issued in countries with stronger banking sectors have been increasing in popularity as
collateral, in part, because regulators have signalled its acceptability to meet regulatory liquidity
ratios.
• Mortgage-backed securities (MBS), particularly residential MBS (RMBS), which are held largely
off the balance sheet of the mortgage issuer and ring-fenced contractually within bankruptcy-
remote special purpose vehicles (SPV). To be widely accepted as collateral, these issues need to
be AAA-rated. However, use of this type of asset as collateral fell back during the Great Financial
Crisis because of contagion from MBS backed by sub-prime mortgages and rising default rates in
some housing markets.
• Other asset-backed securities (ABS) and re-securitizations (eg CDO, CLO, CLN), which are held off
the balance sheet of the originator of the underlying assets and ring-fenced contractually within
bankruptcy-remote SPV. Most investors require a AAA-rating on such assets. This type of asset
also suffered during the Great Financial Crisis because of contagion from securities backed by
collateral pools which included sub-prime mortgages or sub-prime MBS.
• Money market securities such as treasury bills and, in some countries, certificates of deposit (CD)
and commercial paper (CP). However, CDs are not always popular because they represent an
exposure to commercial banks and CP issues are difficult to use as collateral because they tend to
be relatively small.
• Bank loans, also referred to as credit claims. Bank loans need to be made transferable in order to
be used as collateral, which can be a legal challenge in some jurisdictions. And because they are
not traded, parties have to estimate the value. Bank loans are seen as a deep pool of potential
high-quality collateral assets that could help to alleviate a possible global shortage of collateral.
• Gold. This is a specialised type of collateral but its use has been boosted by periodic interest in
gold in response to market crises.
Assets that pose material credit, liquidity and wrong-way risks can be used as collateral but not for their
full market value. Instead, the collateral value of the asset is usually set below its market value in order
to take account of potential price volatility between variation margin calls, the probable high cost of
liquidation in the event of a default and other risks. The difference is called a haircut or initial margin
(see question 21). But the question also arises as to whether such assets properly require long-term
funding, which tends to be unsecured, rather than repo, which tends to be short-term.
Traditionally, repos have been short-term instruments and the bulk of liquidity is still relatively short-
term, reflecting its core role in funding securities dealers. The US repo market is mainly overnight. The
ICMA’s semi-annual survey of the European repo market shows that the proportion of open and short-
dated repos (remaining terms of one month or less) has largely fluctuated between about 60% and 70%
of the outstanding value of repos. Of this, repo with only one day to maturity has been between about
15% and 25% of outstanding value. The ECB has estimated that, in euros, overnight repos were over 75%
of turnover.
Since the Great Financial Crisis, the share of repos with between one and three months remaining to
maturity has been growing (reaching about 15% of outstanding value), reflecting collateral
transformation transactions, and there is a well-established market in forward repos, which often start
one or more months in the future (about 10% of outstanding value). For more information, see the
results of the ICMA’s surveys.
GC or general collateral is a set or basket of security issues which trade in the repo market at the same
or a very similar repo rate, which is called the GC repo rate. GC securities can therefore be substituted
for one another without changing the repo rate much, if at all. In other words, the buyer in a GC repo is
indifferent to which of the GC securities he will receive. The fact that GC securities can be substituted for
one another means that the driver of the GC repo rate is not the supply and demand of particular issues
of securities, but of cash. For this reason, GC repo is sometimes called cash-driven repo. As a measure of
the cost of borrowing cash, the GC repo rate is highly correlated with unsecured money market interest
rates.
The basket of security issues that form a particular GC repo market belong to the same class (eg
government bonds) or sub-class (eg government bonds with no more than five years remaining to
maturity). This is why they can be substituted for each other without changing the GC repo rate. There is
usually only one GC basket in each currency and this is typically of government bonds. However, it is
possible to have several classes of GC in the same currency. For example, in the US, there is Treasury GC,
Agency Debt GC and Agency MBS GC.
In the eurozone, the Great Financial Crisis which erupted in 2007 fragmented the GC repo market in
government bonds by causing investors to differentiate between the credit of issuers in core and
peripheral eurozone countries. There is consequently a German GC market, an Italian GC market and so
on, but there is no longer a eurozone GC market.
Because the buyer in a GC repo is indifferent to which of the securities in a GC basket he will receive, the
choice is the seller’s (although subject to the buyer’s consent) and is left until the end of a negotiation. It
can also be delegated to an automated tri-party repo management system.
GC baskets have traditionally emerged through tacit market consensus. However, it is possible to
formally create a GC basket for the purposes of facilitating trading. A formal GC basket is a basket of
security issues prescribed by an automatic repo trading system (ATS) or a central clearing counterparty
(CCP) which users of those systems are able to trade with each other. Trading such a GC basket means
that users have to accept that, when they are (net) buyers, the (net) sellers have the right to deliver any
of the issues in the GC basket. This allows negotiations between users to be restricted to term, amount
and price, which simplifies and speeds up trading. In GC financing or GC pooling systems, the GC basket
A special is an issue of securities that is subject to exceptional demand in the repo and cash markets
compared with very similar issues. Competition to buy or borrow a special causes potential buyers in
the repo market to offer cheap cash in exchange. A special is therefore identified by a repo rate that is
distinctly lower than the GC repo rate (see question 8). The demand for some specials can become so
strong that the repo rate on that particular issue falls to zero or even goes negative in an otherwise
positive interest rate environment. The repo market is the only financial market in which, historically, a
negative rate of return has not been unusual.
Specialness is driven by an excess of demand for a particular issue of securities over its supply. For this
reason, special repos are sometimes described as securities-driven repo. As a special repo rate is unique
to a particular issue of securities, it is uncorrelated with the GC repo rate or other money market
interest rates.
The spread between the GC repo rate and a special repo rate represents the return which the buyer of
that security is willing to give up on the cash he pays for that security. In other words, this specialness
spread is an implicit securities’ borrowing fee and special repo can be seen as another form of securities
lending and borrowing.
The specialness spread can also be seen as a convenience yield, which is a reduction in the rate of return
on an asset reflecting the non-pecuniary benefits to investors of holding that asset (in the case of
specials, because of its value as collateral).
Because the buyer in a special repo is only interested in one particular security, the choice of collateral
is the buyer’s and is made at the start of a negotiation, in contrast to a GC repo, in which the collateral is
selected by the seller at the end of the negotiation.
Bonds trading special in the repo market will also be in demand in the cash market. 9 Indeed, demand in
the cash market is usually the reason why securities trade special in the repo market. Market-makers
and other dealers will use the repo market to borrow securities that are in strong demand in the cash
market (and therefore difficult or very expensive to buy immediately) in order to fulfil delivery
commitments on sales of those securities in the cash market. The premium in the price of a special in
the cash market means that, in theory, it should not be impossible to buy a special in the cash market
and repo it out for cheap cash in order to reap an arbitrage profit by reinvesting the cheap cash in GC
repo. There is evidence that a no-arbitrage condition prevails in the overnight repo market for US
Treasuries but academic studies have found that the term repo spread tends to overestimate future
special repo rates.
The excess demand that creates specials tends to arise because an issue is very liquid, often because it
is a benchmark or on-the-run issue, and therefore routinely in demand. For this reason, the specialness
spread is sometimes described as a liquidity premium. It is often argued that deeper liquidity is valued
9
The ‘cash’ market in a security is that segment of trading in which the security is bought outright or sold outright.
The term is used to distinguish outright buying and selling from repo trading in the same security.
One of the most common reasons for an issue of securities to go special is when that issue becomes the
cheapest-to-deliver in the futures market for that bond. Some futures sellers will have difficulty buying
what they need to deliver to the futures clearing house. As failure to deliver to a clearing house would
incur serious penalties, these parties will be forced to borrow the issue in the repo market and may
have to bid aggressively to secure it, including sometimes offering negative repo rates.
The term ‘special’ is often incorrectly used to describe any particular issue of securities that the seller
and buyer in a repo agree in advance to use as collateral, as opposed to issues selected from a GC
basket after the other terms of the repo have been settled. A special is identified only by the fact that its
repo rate is below the GC repo rate. Not all issues of securities specifically agreed in advance as
collateral trade at repo rates below the GC repo rate. Such issues could be called specifics but should
not be called ‘specials’. The latter form a subset of the former.
There is an important legal distinction between pledge-based rehypothecation on the one hand and the
sale or use of collateral in the (non-US) repo market on the other. In a pledge, title to collateral remains
with the collateral-giver. If the collateral-giver grants a right of rehypothecation to the collateral-taker,
the collateral-giver remains the owner but only until the collateral-taker exercises his right of
rehypothecation. When this right is exercised, there is a material change in the legal relationship
between the parties. The pledge is extinguished and the collateral-giver loses his title to the collateral,
which is transferred to the third party to whom the collateral has been rehypothecated. In exchange,
the collateral-giver is given a contractual right to the return of the same or similar collateral but this
claim is intrinsically unsecured (although the collateral-giver is likely to have received funding in return
for giving the right of rehypothecation to the collateral-taker and, in the event of the collateral-taker’s
insolvency, the collateral-giver may have a contractual right of set-off of all mutual obligations to and
from the collateral-taker).
In a repo, the buyer becomes the owner of the collateral at the start of the transaction and can dispose
of the collateral when and as he wishes. His right of use is not a discretionary right granted by the seller.
It is an automatic right arising from property ownership.
Unfortunately, the inappropriate use of the word rehypothecation in the context of non-US repo has
sown confusion among regulators about the nature of repo collateralisation and fed a tendency to
conceive of repo as a pledge. Looking at repo through this prism, some regulators perceive systemic risk
in the possibility that the return of collateral back along long chains of repos could be obstructed by the
failure of one party in the chain. Such an obstruction could indeed be a problem in a chain of pledges (if
such a construct were in fact feasible) as the original piece of collateral would need to be passed all the
way back along the chain. In repo, however, only equivalent collateral needs to be returned and, as
chains of repos are only possible with liquid collateral, the longer the chain, the more liquid the
collateral has to be and so the easier it should be to find equivalent collateral. Moreover, if a party in a
chain of repos fails to return collateral, its obligation can be netted against the failed party’s obligation
to repay cash, which would provide the cash to the latter to try to buy the collateral from a third party.
It is argued that misconceived regulatory concerns about collateral re-use along chains of repo are
manifest in a largely futile attempt, under the auspices of the G-20’s Financial Stability Board (FSB), to
measure the rate of collateral re-use. The chosen formula simply assumes that collateral posted by a
firm will be passively sourced pro rata from securities received as collateral and securities purchased
outright. For example, if a firm’s holdings of a bond issue came 40% from collateral received and 60%
from outright purchases, then the firm is assumed to post that bond as collateral by taking 40% from
those bonds received as collateral and 60% from outright purchases. The resulting rate of collateral re-
use may therefore be driven as much by cash trading as by repo and so will say little about re-use.
Repurchase transactions and buy/sell-backs are both types of repo and both function (outside the US ---
see question 14) by means of the legal sale of collateral but behave economically like secured deposits
(see question 1). One principal difference between these two types of repo stems from the fact that a
repurchase transaction is always evidenced by a written contract, whereas a buy/sell-back may or may
not be documented. To document a buy/sell-back, the parties to the ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase
Agreement (GMRA) agree to apply the Buy/Sell Back Annex to the standard GMRA. Because repurchase
transactions and documented buy/sell-backs are written contracts, they are legally more robust and
commercially more flexible than undocumented buy/sell-backs.
Because an undocumented buy/sell-back lacks a written contract, its sale and repurchase legs are
considered to be separate contracts. The lack of a contractual relationship between the parties to an
undocumented buy/sell-back, other than on the first and last day of a transaction, means that it is not
possible for one party to make a legally-enforceable variation margin call on the other in order to
eliminate any differences that open up between the values of the cash and the collateral during the life
of the repo. In addition, because they are undocumented, the right to net opposite obligations following
a counterparty default is less certain because obligations under separate contracts may not be regarded
as mutual in some jurisdictions and the intention of the parties has not been made explicit. These
deficiencies make undocumented buy/sell-backs riskier.
Some markets predominantly use repurchase transactions (eg US, UK, France, Belgium, Netherlands and
Switzerland). Other markets predominantly or even exclusively use buy/sell-backs (eg Italy until 2017,
Spain and most emerging markets).
An open repo (also known as on demand, terminable on demand or open-ended repo) is a repurchase
transaction that is agreed without fixing the maturity date. Instead, the repo can be terminated on any
business day in the future by either party, provided they give notice within an agreed period of time.
Open repo is used to invest cash or finance assets where the parties are not sure how long they will
need to do so.
Until an open repo is terminated, it automatically runs from one day to the next, offering the
convenience of not having to negotiate and settle daily roll-overs. Interest accrues daily but is not
compounded (ie interest is not earned each day on interest accrued over previous days). Where parties
have open repos outstanding between themselves over extended periods, accumulated interest is
typically paid off in aggregate every month. The initial repo rate on an open transaction should, in
theory, be slightly below the overnight repo rate given the lower operational cost, but it will not
subsequently change until the parties agree to re-set the rate or the rate has been linked to an interest
rate index which is updated automatically.
Securities lending, like repo, is a type of securities financing transaction (SFT). The two types of
instrument have many similarities and can often be used as functional substitutes for each other.
In a securities lending transaction in the international market, as in repo, one party gives legal title to a
security or basket of securities to another party for a limited period of time, in exchange for legal
ownership of collateral (although it is also possible for the collateral to be pledged and there are still
uncollateralized securities loans). The first party is called the lender, even though he is transferring legal
title to the other party. Similarly, the other party is called the borrower, even if he is taking legal title to
the security.
The collateral in securities lending can be either other securities or cash (securities lending against cash
collateral looks very much like repo). The borrower pays a fee to the lender for the use of the loaned
security. However, if cash is given as collateral, the lender is obliged to reinvest the cash and ‘rebate’ an
agreed proportion of the reinvestment return back to the borrower. In this case, the lender usually
Because the securities lending of equity transfers not only the legal ownership, but also the attached
voting rights and corporate actions, it has become convention in the securities lending market for
loaned securities (both fixed income and equities) to be subject to an express right of recall by the
lender, so that he can recover securities if he wishes to exercise voting rights or respond to corporate
actions. In contrast, unless a termination open is specifically agreed between the parties, repo does not
allow a seller to recall his securities during the life of a transaction.
Another difference between repo and securities lending is that most repo is motivated by the need to
borrow and lend cash, whereas securities lending is typically driven by the need to borrow securities.
However, there is an overlap between securities lending and the specials segment of the repo market,
which is also driven by the demand to borrow particular securities. And securities lending is sometimes
used by securities investors to raise cash.
The repo market in Europe is represented by the European Repo and Collateral Council (ERCC) of the
International Capital Market Association (ICMA), which publishes the most widely-used model contract
for international and many domestic repos, the Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA) (see
question 19). The securities lending market in Europe is represented by the International Securities
Lending Association (ISLA), which publishes the most widely-used model contract for international
securities lending, the Global Master Securities Lending Agreement (GMSLA).
There are important differences in the way that repo works in Europe compared with the US, and
between the structure and operation of the two markets.
In Europe, repo transfers legal title to collateral from the seller to the buyer by means of an outright
sale (also known as a true sale). Under New York law (the predominant jurisdiction for US repo),
transferring title to collateral has been considered legally difficult so title transfer is backstopped by the
contingent pledging of collateral but with the pledge exempted from certain provisions of the US
Bankruptcy Code that normally apply to pledges. In particular, collateral pledged in repo (as well as
securities lending and against derivatives exposures) is exempt from the automatic stay on enforcement
of collateral in the event of insolvency. In addition, unlike in traditional pledges, the pledgee/buyer in a
US repo is given a contractual general right of use of collateral. Consequently, the resulting set of rights
is deemed to be much the same in effect as those achieved by an outright sale.
In contrast to the European repo market, the US market is dominated by tri-party repo (see question
24), where post-trade collateral selection, management and settlement are outsourced to an agent. Tri-
party repo may account for something in the order of two-thirds of the US market, whereas it is only
around 10% of the European market.
The US repo market has traditionally had a shorter average maturity than the European market (see
question 7) and repo has tended to account for a higher proportion of the balance sheets of key market
intermediaries. On the other hand, the US market is a domestic market in one currency, whereas the
European market is largely cross-border.
There is no such thing as a riskless financial instrument. But repo can achieve a substantial reduction in
the credit and liquidity risks of lending, if managed prudently. The degree to which repo can mitigate
risk depends upon the careful selection of counterparties, the use of high quality and liquid collateral,
the operational ability to mobilise collateral easily and securely across clearing and settlement systems,
efficient collateral management (particularly frequent variation margining) and legal certainty about the
ownership of and right to liquidate collateral in the event of a counterparty default.
• Careful selection of counterparties is vital to the performance of repo. Collateralisation does not
change the probability of default of a counterparty, so collateral taken from risky counterparties is
more likely to be tested by a default and may turn out to be worth less than expected due to
fluctuations in price, the impact of liquidation, and possible legal and operational problems.
Consequently, collateral should be treated only as insurance against the default of the seller, not as
a simple substitute for his credit risk. This means that the primary exposure in a repo remains
counterparty credit risk. Repo does not therefore avoid the need for conventional credit risk
management and does not allow lending to parties deemed unsuitable for unsecured lending.
Rather, repo is intended to reduce the risk of lending to existing counterparties in order to make
more efficient use of the capital supporting such lending.
• Although counterparty credit risk is the primary exposure in a repo, the choice of collateral is still
very important. First, the credit risk on the collateral should have a minimal correlation with the
credit risk on the repo counterparty (ie low wrong-way risk) in order to diversify credit exposure as
much as possible. Second, collateral should have minimal credit and liquidity risks, in order to
maximise certainty about its value and ease of liquidation in the event of a default. Government
bonds have traditionally provided collateral that can best meet both criteria.
• Even the best asset is no good as collateral if it cannot be easily and securely transferred to a
counterparty. This is straightforward in an integrated market such as the US but more complicated
in Europe, which is a cross-border market that has suffered from a fragmented securities clearing
and settlement infrastructure. Great strides have been made in integrating the European
infrastructure, particularly the creation of T2S in the Eurozone, but barriers to the efficient
mobilisation of collateral persist, particularly between some domestic CSDs and the ICSDs that are
used by most cross-border investors.
• Efficient collateral management is mainly about frequent and accurate calling for variation margin
to compensate for fluctuations in the value of collateral (see question 20). It may also be helpful to
overcollateralize by discounting the initial market value of some types of collateral by applying a
haircut or initial margin (see question 21) in order to cover the intervals between variation
margining and to take account of the potential cost of liquidation following a default. Guidance on
efficient variation margining is set out in the Guide to Best Practice in the European Repo Market
published by the European Repo and Collateral Council (ERCC) of the ICMA. Collateral management
also involves dealing with coupons, dividends or other income payments on collateral during the
term of a repo, possible substitution of collateral by agreement, resetting floating repo rates,
addressing failure to deliver collateral and all the operations needed to run open repos.
• Legal certainty about a buyer’s right to collateral and the right of a non-defaulting party to net
mutual obligations with a defaulting and insolvent counterparty depend critically on robust
contractual documentation such as the ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA) (see
questions 18 and 19). This functioned well during the Lehman Brothers’ and other recent defaults.
Collateralisation does not change the probability of default of a counterparty, so collateral taken from
risky counterparties is more likely to be tested by a default and may turn out to be worth less than
expected due to fluctuations in price and the impact of liquidation. Consequently, collateral should be
treated only as insurance against the default of the seller, not as a simple substitute for his credit risk.
This means that the primary exposure in a repo remains counterparty credit risk. Repo does not avoid
the need for conventional credit risk management and does not justify lending to parties deemed
unsuitable for unsecured lending. Rather, repo is intended to reduce the risk of lending to existing
counterparties and make more efficient use of the capital supporting such lending. The principle should
be that the decision to use repo to mitigate the credit risk on a counterparty is taken after the decision
on whether to extend any credit to that counterparty (ie the decision on whether to extend credit to a
counterparty should not be driven by the decision to use repo). The primary importance of counterparty
credit risk was confirmed during the Great Financial Crisis by the refusal of parties to roll over repos
with Bear Stearns in March 2008, when doubts had arisen about the firm’s solvency, despite the firm
having substantial holdings of US Treasuries to use as collateral.
The use of repo is subject to a wide range of laws and regulations enforced by various regulatory
agencies. Regulation has significantly intensified since the Great Financial Crisis (see question 29). In
Europe, repo is impacted directly by laws and regulations implementing the EU Financial Collateral
Directive as well as by the Short Selling Regulation and the Securities Financing Transaction Regulation
(SFTR), and indirectly through regulation of market users such as commercial banks and investment
banks by banking and securities market regulators under laws and regulations implementing the Capital
Requirements and similar Directives and Regulations, which themselves implement the Basel III regime.
There is a raft of other laws and regulations affecting the repo market in the EU, including the European
Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR), the Markets in Financial Instruments Directive (MiFID) and
Regulation (MiFIR), the Bank Resolution and Recovery Directive (BRRD), the Central Securities
Depository Regulation (CSDR), a possible Securities Law Directive and the Crisis Management Directive.
And, as part of the discussion on ‘shadow banking’, the Financial Stability Board is considering so-called
macro-prudential regulation of collateral management through the use of devices such as mandatory
minimum haircuts.
The key purpose of collateralisation is to secure a cash lender (ie mitigate his credit risk) by giving him
the right to liquidate the collateral provided by the cash borrower in the event that the borrower
becomes insolvent or defaults in some other way. In traditional secured lending, the right to liquidate is
established under a pledge attached to or other type of security interest in the collateral in favour of the
cash lender. In repo, security is established (outside the US --- see question 14) by a transfer of legal title
to the collateral. In order to ensure that courts will enforce a lender’s rights to liquidate collateral, it is
prudent to provide a written contract as evidence of the original intention of the parties to create this
right for the non-defaulting party and to ensure that a court will not re-characterize the repo as a
secured loan. In many jurisdictions, such re-characterisation would deprive the holder of any rights to
the collateral, as the parties would not have originally intended to make a pledge so would not have
performed any of the formalities normally required to create a valid pledge. The lender could therefore
find himself relegated to the position of an unsecured creditor.
Use of an enforceable written contract and its variation margining provisions are the minimum
regulatory conditions for recognition of the risk mitigation impact of collateral and close-out netting in
the calculation of regulatory capital requirements and large exposure monitoring. In some jurisdictions,
the use of master agreements is a requirement for close-out netting.
Written contracts also allow the terms of a repo to be varied in order to create useful structured
transactions, such as open and forward repos. Such variations are only possible if the parties have
somewhere to record how the structures will operate, eg how much notice is required to terminate an
open repo and how forward repo will be margined.
Written contracts for financial transactions such as repo frequently take the form of a master
agreement, such as the ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA) (see question 19). A
master agreement sets out the general terms and conditions of the business relationship between the
parties, and consolidates all outstanding transactions within one contract. This not only legally
underpins transactions but also offers important operational benefits:
• Enhancing the operational efficiency of individual transactions by allowing the negotiation of
transactions to be limited to the specific commercial terms of each transaction, rather than
repeating the general terms and conditions of the relationship between two parties. For this reason,
master agreements are called ‘framework agreements’.
• Enhancing the operational efficiency of individual transactions by setting out agreed procedures for
managing repos post trade (eg dealing with income payments on the collateral).
• Consolidation of all outstanding transactions within one contract allows operational efficiencies
such as the netting of payments and collateral deliveries.
• Where standard master agreements, such as the GMRA, are adopted across the market, the
operational efficiency of the market as a whole is improved through harmonization of market
practice.
In addition to documenting repos in a master agreement, it is essential that the enforceability of the
master agreement is regularly re-assessed. Accordingly, the ICMA commissions legal opinions on behalf
of its members on the GMRA each year in over 65 jurisdictions for transactions with commercial banks,
securities dealers and other companies, and in many countries, various types of non-bank financial
institution.
GMRA is the acronym for the Global Master Repurchase Agreement. It is a model legal agreement
designed for parties transacting repos and is published by the International Capital Market Association
(ICMA), which is the body representing the cross-border bond and repo markets in Europe. The GMRA is
the principal master agreement for cross-border repos globally, as well as for many domestic repo
markets.
The GMRA was first published in 1992. It was updated in 1995 to incorporate lessons learned in the
Baring Brothers crisis and, in 2000, to incorporate lessons from the Russian and Asian financial crises.
The latest version was published in 2011. Although this version followed the Great Financial Crisis that
erupted in 2007, it was not the result of any material shortcomings exposed by the crisis. Indeed, the
GMRA 2000 performed well, including following the Lehman Brothers default in 2008. Rather, the
updating mainly reflected the desire to harmonise the GMRA more closely with other master
agreements, including the Global Master Securities Lending Agreement (GMSLA) and the ISDA Master
Agreement, and the need to reflect changes in market practice and general legal developments since
2000. The opportunity was also taken to clarify certain terms and conditions.
The GMRA consists of a pre-printed master agreement that contains standard provisions, which are
generic to the market in standard repo, and Annex I, which lists specific choices that need to be made
by the parties to operationalize the agreement (eg fixing minimum delivery periods) and provides
somewhere to record supplemental terms and conditions, if the parties wish to customise the master
agreement to reflect the special character of the business relationship between them. The specific
commercial terms of each transaction are recorded in confirmations, a model template for which is
provided in Annex II of the GMRA.
The GMRA is designed for short-term repos of simple high-quality fixed-income securities that take the
form of repurchase transactions between principals under the law of England and Wales. To apply the
GMRA to repos of equities, repos by or with an agent, or repos in the form of buy/sell-backs, it is
necessary to amend the master agreement. This can be done by signing the standard Equity, Agency
and Buy/Sell-Back Annexes, respectively. Other product annexes accommodate certain domestic
securities (eg UK gilts). To adapt the master agreement to jurisdictions other than England and Wales,
there are also a number of country annexes. In addition, the parties can add special supplementary
terms or conditions to Annex I of the GMRA.
To ensure that the GMRA remains effective, the ICMA commissions legal opinions on behalf of its
members every year on the enforceability of the whole agreement, the effectiveness of title transfer, its
mechanism for close-out netting in insolvency and other provisions in over 65 jurisdictions for
transactions with commercial banks and investment firms, and in many countries, transactions with
various types of non-bank financial institution. If parties agree material amendments to the GMRA, they
will need to see their own supplementary legal opinions to ensure that their amendments have not
affected the legality, validity and enforceability of the contract.
Regulators require repos to be documented under robust written legal agreements like the GMRA,
supported by regularly updated legal opinions, as a condition of recognising the reduction of credit risk
by collateral and close-out netting in the calculation of regulatory capital requirements and large
exposures.
The first step is collateral selection. Collateral that is high quality and liquid will be inherently more
stable in value. In addition, collateral issued by a party whose credit risk is uncorrelated with that of the
repo seller will diversify exposure and avoid so-called wrong-way risk, which is the danger of the
collateral value falling as the creditworthiness of the seller deteriorates.
Whatever collateral is accepted, buyers then need to anticipate potential problems in liquidating less
liquid collateral in the event of a default, possibly during an episode of market stress, by applying a risk
adjustment to its market value in the form of a haircut or initial margin (see question 21).
Once the terms of a repo have been agreed, both parties should revalue the collateral frequently
(preferably daily) and as accurately as possible. When the value of collateral falls, the buyer should
promptly call for variation margin from the seller to rebalance cash and collateral and vice versa. It is
also important for parties to agree deadlines for calling, agreeing and delivering margin and to try to
agree what assets will be acceptable as margin. Guidance on efficient variation margining is set out in
the Guide to Best Practice in the European Repo Market published by the European Repo and Collateral
Council (ERCC) of the ICMA. There is an alternative mechanism to variation margining involving the early
termination and replacement of transactions, which was designed for documented buy/sell-backs, that
achieves the same result as margining but is not widely used.
In order to minimise the problems that may occur in the aftermath of a default, it is important to have a
robust written legal agreement such as the ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA). This
protects the rights of the buyer to sell collateral in an event of default, including insolvency, and to net
his exposures to the defaulter, as well as providing flexibility in terms of the timing and method of
valuation of obligations in order to accommodate less liquid collateral and difficult market conditions.
A haircut is the difference between the initial market value of an asset and the purchase price paid for
that asset at the start of a repo. An initial margin is analogous in function to a haircut. The difference
between the two is merely a matter of expression. A haircut is expressed as the percentage deduction
from the market value of collateral (eg 2%), while an initial margin is the initial market value of collateral
expressed as a percentage of the purchase price (eg 105%) or as a simple ratio (eg 105:100).
Ideally, collateral should be free of credit and liquidity risks. The market value of such risk-free collateral
would be more certain, meaning that it would be easy to sell for a more predictable value in the event
of default by the collateral-giver. The type of asset that comes closest to this paradigm, and is in fact the
most commonly-used type of collateral in the repo market, is a domestic bond issued by a creditworthy
central government.
Assets that pose material credit and/or liquidity risks can be used as collateral but their value needs to
be adjusted for their risk by deducting a haircut from the market value of collateral in order to calculate
the purchase price or multiplying the purchase price by an initial margin in order to calculate the
required collateral market value.
A haircut or initial margin represents the potential loss of value due to factors such as:
• price volatility between regular variation margining dates (in case there is a default between a
calculation of a variation margin call and the payment or delivery of that variation margin;
The potential loss could be increased by delays in responding to a variation margin call due to
operational problems or a legal challenge to the non-defaulting party’s title to the collateral or his right
to net. If the cash and collateral are denominated in different currencies, price volatility must include
the effect of exchange rate fluctuations. It is arguable as to whether the credit risk of the repo
counterparty should affect the size of a haircut or initial margin, given that the risk of a liquidation loss
by a non-defaulting party is a function of the collateral and that party’s collateral management rather
than the credit of the counterparty (which should in theory be compensated by the repo rate).
However, it is appropriate to take account of any significant correlation between the credit risks of the
repo counterparty and the issuer of the collateral (so-called wrong-way risk), as this will diminish the
effectiveness of the collateral. In practice, many parties do factor in the credit risk of their repo
counterparties but this probably reflects differences in the relative commercial power of parties who
have different credit ratings.
The use of haircuts and initial margins is explained in the guidance on efficient margining set out in the
Guide to Best Practice in the European Repo Market published by the European Repo and Collateral
Council (ERCC) of the ICMA.
During the life of a repo, the buyer holds legal title to the collateral. In other words, the collateral is his
property. He is therefore entitled to any benefits of ownership, including any coupons, dividends or
other income that may be paid by the issuer of the collateral.
However, the seller of collateral retains the risk on the collateral, as he has committed to buy it back in
the future for its original value plus repo interest (so, if the price falls between selling and buying, the
seller will suffer the loss and vice versa). The seller would not accept the risk on the collateral unless he
also receives the return, including coupons, dividends or other income. To satisfy the seller, under the
ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA), in the case of repurchase transactions, the buyer
agrees to immediately pay compensatory amounts to the seller equivalent to any income payment
received on the collateral. In the UK, these are called manufactured payments. In the case of buy/sell-
backs, the seller is compensated, not by a manufactured payment, but by a reduction in the repurchase
price that the seller is required to pay back at maturity.
23. Who can exercise the voting rights and corporate actions attached to
equity and corporate bonds being used as collateral in a repo?
During the life of a repo, the buyer holds legal title to the collateral. In other words, the collateral is his
property and he is entitled to any benefits of ownership. In the case of equity, and sometimes corporate
bonds, the benefits of ownership may include voting rights. The buyer can, if he wishes, vote in
accordance with the wishes of the seller but he is under no obligation whatsoever to do so. However,
while the buyer obtains any rights to vote that are attached to collateral securities, it is unacceptable
10
It is also possible that the non-defaulting party may have to buy securities that it had expected to receive from
the defaulting party. In this case, its risk is that buying will drive up market price.
In the case of equity and sometimes corporate bonds, options may arise such as rights issues and stock
splits --- so-called corporate actions --- on which holders are required to make a choice. As with voting
rights, under the ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA), the decision about how the
corporate action is exercised with regard to a security provided as collateral rests entirely with the
buyer, as he is the owner (assuming the buyer is still holding the security when a decision has to be
made). However, who should take the decision, after a corporate action, about which security is to be
delivered back to the seller at the end of the repo (called the Equivalent Securities in the GMRA)? This is
not expressly stated in the GMRA. On the one hand, it could be argued that the GMRA should be
consistent with the Equity Annex, which expressly allocates the decision to the seller, as does the Global
Master Securities Lending Agreement (GMSLA). In addition, one of the economic principles underlying a
repo is that only the seller should be exposed to the risk and return on the collateral, which implies that
the seller should decide how to respond to a corporate action. On the other hand, it can be argued that
the securities to be returned at the end of a repo, like the securities delivered at the start, should always
be agreed between the parties, so the buyer should be consulted.
Tri-party repo is a transaction for which post-trade processing --- collateral selection, payments and
deliveries, custody of collateral securities, collateral management and other operations during the life of
the transaction --- is outsourced by the parties to a third-party agent. A tri-party agent can be a
custodian bank, an international central securities depository (ICSD) or a national central securities
depository (CSD). In Europe, the principal tri-party agents are Clearstream Bank Luxembourg, Euroclear
Bank, Bank of New York Mellon, JP Morgan and SIS. In the US, there is now a single so-called ‘clearing
bank’, which is an industry utility providing US Treasury settlement clearing and tri-party management
services. This is Bank of New York Mellon. JP Morgan ceased to be a ‘clearing bank’ in 2018 but remains
a tri-party service-provider.
Because a tri-party agent is just an agent, use of a tri-party service does not change the risk relationship
between the parties. If one of the parties defaults, the impact falls entirely on the other party. This
means that parties to tri-party repo need to continue to sign bilateral legal agreements such as the
ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA).
Nor does the tri-party agent provide a trading venue where the parties can negotiate and execute
transactions (although some tri-party agents are linked to trading platforms). Instead, once a
transaction has been agreed directly between the parties --- usually by telephone or electronic
messaging --- both parties independently notify the tri-party agent, who matches the instructions and, if
successful, processes the transaction. The agent will typically automatically select, from the securities
account of the seller, sufficient collateral that satisfies pre-agreed credit and liquidity criteria,
concentration limits and any transaction preferences agreed between the buyer and the seller. The
selected collateral will be delivered against simultaneous payment of cash from the account of the
buyer (delivery-versus-payment or DVP), subject to the deduction from the collateral of pre-agreed
initial margins. Subsequently, the tri-party agent manages the regular revaluation of the collateral,
variation margining, income payments on the collateral, as well as (in the case of most European tri-
party agents) substitution of any collateral which ceases to conform to the quality criteria of the buyer,
substitution to prevent an income payment triggering a tax event, substitution to retrieve a security
being used as collateral which is then sold by the seller to another party and substitution at the request
of the seller. Tri-party agents also conduct optimisation of collateral, which means the ongoing
Because collateral is typically selected automatically by the tri-party agent, tri-party repo cannot be
used for borrowing and lending specific securities. It is a pure GC funding facility. This is reflected in the
large average deal size of tri-party repo and collateralization by multiple securities.
Moreover, because tri-party collateral operations are automated and benefit from the agent’s
economies of scale, and because settlement is across the books of the agent, the post-trade costs of tri-
party repo are less than those managed in-house and settled across a securities settlement system
(which charges a settlement fee for each issue of securities transferred). This makes it economic to
collateralise a tri-party repo with multiple securities. Tri-party agents also have the capability to
efficiently manage baskets of collateral denominated in several currencies. The ability to collateralise
with multiple securities facilitates larger deal sizes.
On the other hand, the lower post-trade overheads of tri-party repo also makes it economic to use non-
government securities as collateral. These less liquid securities trade in smaller amounts than
government securities, which can make bilateral transfers across securities settlement systems
prohibitively expensive. Consequently, repos of equity, corporate bonds, MBS, ABS and other structured
securities are concentrated in tri-party repo.
Tri-party is the preferred repo market segment for many customers (non-intermediaries) given that the
delegation of collateral management to a tri-party agent allows these firms to avoid the cost of setting
up and running their own collateral management operation. This includes central banks, some of whom
allow the use of tri-party agents by the counterparties in their monetary policy operations and others
who use tri-party services when conducting investment operations.
There are two occasions when this might happen: at the start of a repo, the seller may fail to deliver to
the buyer; or at the end of a repo, the buyer may fail to deliver to the seller.
In the event of a failure by a seller to deliver collateral securities to the buyer at the start of a repo, if
the parties have signed the ICMA’s Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA), one of the following
will happen:
• If the parties have agreed, when they negotiated their agreement, to treat a failure to deliver
collateral securities as an event of default, the buyer could place the seller in default. However,
putting a counterparty into default is a very serious step. Before doing so, it is important to be sure
that the seller’s failure to deliver reflects credit problems and not temporary operational problems,
infrastructure frictions or market illiquidity, which can be beyond the seller’s control.
• The contract remains in force, allowing the seller to deliver the collateral securities at any time
during the remaining life of the contract. Only if and when delivery eventually takes places will the
buyer pay the seller. But at any time while the failure to deliver continues, the buyer can terminate
the contract and the seller will be contractually obliged to pay the repo interest accrued up to that
point. In other words, the seller will have to pay repo interest even though he will not have had the
use of the buyer’s cash. This means that the seller is charged for failing to deliver and the buyer is
recompensed.
In the event of a failure by the buyer to deliver collateral securities to the seller at the end of a repo, if
the parties have signed a GMRA, one of the following will happen:
• If the parties have agreed, when they negotiated their agreement, to treat a failure to deliver
collateral securities as an event of default, the seller could place the buyer in default. As for a fail
on the purchase date, before placing a counterparty into default for failing to deliver, it is
important to be sure that the buyer’s failure to deliver reflects credit problems and not temporary
operational problems, infrastructure frictions or market illiquidity, which are all beyond the buyer’s
control.
• The seller could call a mini close-out, which is a colloquial term for the right of the buyer to
terminate the failed transaction (but no others), value the collateral in that transaction using the
methodology set out in the GMRA for defaults (see question 26), offset this against the cash he
owes the buyer and settle any difference. However, mini close-outs can prove to be very expensive
for parties failing to deliver. In repo markets, such as those for government bonds, which trade at
narrow spreads, the risk/return ratio is so skewed that it is felt that the threat of mini close-outs
would drive many banks out of the market and fatally damage its liquidity, so mini close-outs are in
practice restricted to fails in types of collateral such as corporate bonds. Note that the mini close-
out mechanism works differently from the buy-in procedure used in the cash market when the
seller fails to deliver to the buyer in an outright transaction (in this case, the security is bought from
the market and any extra cost is passed to the failing party).
If the parties have documented their repo business under a master agreement, such as the ICMA’s
Global Master Repurchase Agreement (GMRA), default means that one of the parties has committed
one of the Events of Default listed in the agreement. In the GMRA, the standard list of Events of Default
includes Acts of Insolvency such as the presentation of a petition for the winding-up of the party or the
appointment of a liquidator or equivalent official. Other standard Events of Default are:
• failures to pay cash amounts (such as purchase price, repurchase price and manufactured
payments) or to meet variation margin calls;
• making an admission of one’s inability or intention not to meet debts as they fall due (under the
GMRA 2000, this admission has to be in writing);
• making materially incorrect or untrue representations;
• being suspended or expelled from a securities exchange for specified reasons or (under the GMRA
2000) from a self-regulatory organisation;
• being suspended for specified reasons from dealing in securities by an official body (a ‘government
agency’ under the GMRA 2000 or ’Competent Authority’ under the GMRA 2011, the latter term
being intended to include the new types of agency established in the wake of the Great Financial
Crisis, such as resolution authorities);
• (under the GMRA 2000) having assets transferred to a trustee by a regulator.
There is also a catch-all provision that failure to perform any other obligation under the GMRA is also an
Event of Default, if it is not remedied within 30 days of a notice being given of such failure. The parties
can also elect to make failure to deliver collateral an Event of Default.
Under the GMRA 2000, the occurrence of either of two particular Acts of Insolvency --- the filing of a
petition for the winding-up of a party and the appointment of a liquidator or similar officer ---
automatically puts the insolvent party into default. For all other Events of Default, under the GMRA
2000, a party is not actually in default until its counterparty serves a default notice. Under the GMRA
2011, a party is in default as soon as an Event of Default occurs: notice is necessary only to initiate the
process of terminating the agreement.
Default notices under the GMRA must be served in writing in English. They can be delivered:
• in person or by courier;
• by registered mail;
• by telex (but not under the GMRA 2011);
• by fax;
• in the form of an electronic message which is capable of reproduction in hard copy (under the
GMRA 2011, but not the GMRA 2000, electronic messaging includes e-mail).
Under the GMRA 2000, default starts when letters are delivered; registered mail is either delivered or
delivery is attempted; telexes prompt an answerback from the recipient; faxes are received by a
Under the GMRA 2000, once a party is formally in default, the process of close-out netting starts. Under
the GMRA 2011, close-out netting requires the non-defaulting party to serve a notice specifying a
termination date or as soon as an Event of Default has occurred that the parties have pre-agreed should
be subject to Automatic Early Termination. Close-out netting has three stages.
• First, all outstanding obligations due on repos documented under the same GMRA are accelerated
for immediate settlement and all variation margin held by the parties is called back.
• Second, the Default Market Value of the collateral securities is fixed and transactions costs and
professional expenses included. The non-defaulting party can also add the cost of replacing
defaulted repos or, if he considers it reasonable, the cost of replacing or unwinding hedges.
• Third, all sums are converted into the same currency (the one chosen as the Base Currency by the
defaulting party when the GMRA was negotiated) and are netted off against each other to produce
a single residual amount, which must be notified to the defaulting party. Whoever owes the residual
sum must pay it by the next business day. Either party can be charged interest on late payment.
The speed of the valuation stage of the close-out netting process will depend upon the liquidity of the
collateral assets. Valuation is under the control of the non-defaulting party. Under the GMRA 2000, he
has five business days from the formal date of default to complete the valuation (although this can be
extended in exceptional circumstances). Under the GMRA 2011, the non-defaulting party is required
only to complete valuation as soon as reasonably practicable. Under both versions of the GMRA, the
non-defaulting party has a menu of three valuation options. If he buys or sells collateral, he can use the
actual dealing prices realized by selling the collateral. Or he can use dealing prices realized when selling
other holdings of the same security. These dealing prices can be applied to whatever collateral is
liquidated at the time or to the whole amount. Or the non-defaulting party can use market quotes, or a
mix of dealing prices and market quotes, provided the quotes are from two or more market-makers or
regular dealers in ‘commercially reasonable’ size. However, if the collateral is so illiquid that the non-
defaulting party cannot buy or sell the collateral or, acting in good faith, he cannot find market quotes,
does not think it commercially reasonable to try to obtain quotes or he can find quotes but believes it
would not be commercially reasonable to use them (eg they are for amounts much smaller than
needed), then he can estimate the Net Value of the collateral. This is a measure of their fair market
value, calculated using whatever pricing sources and methods the non-defaulting party deems
appropriate in his reasonable opinion. Sources can include, without limitation, securities with similar
maturities, terms and credit characteristics. In effect, the calculation of Net Value is marking-to-model
(calculating a theoretical fundamental price) as opposed to marking-to-market (using dealing prices or
quotes). Net Value under the GMRA is different from fair market value as defined in accountancy
standards. Fair market value for accountancy purposes should be agreed between a willing buyer and a
willing seller, neither being under any particular compulsion to trade. The GMRA, on the other hand, is
designed for the liquidation of securities after one of the parties has been placed in default, possibly in
stressed market conditions.
The non-defaulting party cannot use the close-out netting process to try to recover what are called
consequential losses (with the exception of the cost of replacing repos or the cost of replacing or
unwinding hedges). These are downstream losses caused by the default (those not immediately due to
the default on repos).
CCP is the acronym for central (clearing) counterparty. In exchange-traded markets, they are known as
clearing houses. CCPs perform two so-called clearing functions:
• Once a transaction has been agreed between two parties and registered with a CCP, the CCP inserts
itself into the transaction (so that one contract becomes two --- a legal process called novation) or is
deemed to be an original party to the transaction (one transaction negotiated between two CCP
members does not produce a contract between them but instead automatically generates two
contracts, between the CCP and each of the members --- a process called open order). The CCP
famously becomes the buyer to every seller and the seller to every buyer. On this basis, if one of the
CCP members defaults, the CCP guarantees scheduled settlement for other members.
• The CCP will net transactions between members on a centralized basis (netting by a CCP is referred
to as ’clearing‘). This means that a delivery of a security sold via the CCP by party A to party B can be
netted off against deliveries of the same security on the same date bought via the CCP by party A
from party C, thereby reducing A’s exposure. The same applies to cash payments in the same
currency. This produces much smaller net exposures than decentralised bilateral netting, in which
netting is only between separate pairs of parties. This type of netting is often called multilateral
netting.
During the crisis that erupted in 2007, CCP clearing helped to preserve access to the repo market for
banks from some peripheral Eurozone countries who were being squeezed out of the uncleared market
by other banks cutting their risk limits on these countries.
The principal CCPs clearing repos in Europe are LCH Ltd in the UK, LCH SA in France, Eurex Clearing in
Germany, CC&G in Italy and BME Clearing (formerly MEFF) in Spain.
Most CCP-cleared repos are negotiated on automatic repo trading systems (ATS) such as NEX Markets
(formerly BrokerTec), Eurex Repo and MTS. However, repo negotiated directly between parties or via a
voice-broker can also be registered with a CCP post trade.
Following the global financial crisis which erupted in 2007, various rates of return in Europe started to
become negative. Since 2014, negative rates have become persistent and widespread. Initially, many
cash investors have been reluctant to accept negative rates, including parties to repo transactions being
remunerated on deposits of cash margin and on income due on securities they have given as collateral.
Before the crisis, repo was the only financial instrument which paid a rate of return that could become
negative under normal market conditions. Negative repo rates can happen when a particular collateral
security is subject to exceptional borrowing demand and/or reduced supply in the repo market. In order
to borrow these securities, buyers have to tempt potential sellers with cheap cash. ‘Cheap’ means a
repo rate less than the GC repo rate. When the repo rate on a particular collateral asset falls below the
GC repo rate (see question 8), that asset is said to have gone ‘on special’ (see question 9).
In the case of very special collateral, the repo rate can fall so far that it becomes negative. This naturally
happens more frequently when the GC repo rate is already close to zero, as there is less distance for a
special repo rate to fall in order to become negative.
During periods of financial stress in Europe, GC repo rates in several currencies became negative. This
meant that most, if not all, securities in a particular currency were subject to exceptional demand.
Typically, these securities were the government bonds of strong economies and were strongly sought
after because they were seen as ‘safe haven’ assets.
Since 2014, negative rates have also been driven by the exceptional lending extended by the ECB and
other European central banks in order to try to head off deflation, as well as regulatory disincentives to
wholesale deposit-taking by banks (who try to deter depositors by quoting negative interest rates).
A negative repo rate means that the buyer (who is lending cash) effectively pays interest to the seller
(who is borrowing cash). For example, consider a one-week repo with a purchase price of EUR 10 million
at a repo rate of -0.50%. The repurchase price will be:
The buyer (cash lender) pays the purchase price of 10,000,000 and receives the repurchase price of
9,999,027.78, therefore making a loss; whereas the seller (cash borrower) receives the purchase price of
10,000,000 and pays the repurchase price of 9,999,027.78, therefore making a gain.
The reinvestment rate on coupons, dividends and other income payments on collateral during the term
of a buy/sell-back which is closed out following an event of default or used in the calculation of net
exposure for the purpose of margin maintenance
When income is paid on collateral in a repo, it is paid to the buyer, who is the legal owner. But the buyer
is obliged to make an equivalent payment to the seller. In a repurchase transaction, the payment is due
immediately and is often called a ‘manufactured payment’ (see question 22). But in a buy/sell-back, this
payment is deferred until the repurchase date, when it is deducted from the repurchase price. In the
interim, the buyer is obliged to reinvest the value of the payment in order to compensate the seller for
the delay in reimbursement. If (1) such a buy/sell-back is terminated because of a default by one of the
parties or (2) the exposure on the transaction is being calculated for the purpose of variation margining,
a reinvestment rate has to be assumed. The reinvestment rate is given in the formula for the Sell Back
Price (which is equivalent to the repurchase price) in the Buy/Sell-Back Annex of the GMRA (see
paragraph 2(a)(iii)(y)):
(P + AI + D) − (IR + C)
where:
P Purchase Price – ie the clean price of collateral in the case of a buy/sell-back.
AI amount equal to Accrued Interest at the Purchase Date, paid under paragraph 3(f) of the
Buy/Sell-Back Annex – which is coupon interest accrued on the collateral security since the last income
payment date.
D Sell Back Differential (equivalent to repo interest).
IR amount of any coupon income in respect of the Purchased Securities payable by the issuer on
or, in the case of registered Securities, by reference to, any date falling between the Purchase Date and
the Repurchase Date – which is a coupon, dividend or other income paid during the term of the
buy/sell-back.
C aggregate amount obtained by daily application of the Pricing Rate for such Buy/Sell Back
Transaction to any such income from (and including) the date of payment by the issuer to (but
excluding) the date of calculation – which is the reinvestment income on the income payment
calculated at the repo rate on the buy/sell-back.
In practice, this problem may not be significant for parties who are active dealers in buy/sell-backs,
given the likely alternation in the direction of underlying positions and payments of income, as well as
the likely infrequency of income payments.
Under paragraph 4(f) of the GMRA, parties holding cash margin are obliged to pay interest “at such rate,
payable at such times, as may be specified in Annex I… or otherwise agreed between the parties…”
Parties could have agreed to use the repo rate on the underlying transaction, particularly where that
transaction is being margined in isolation. In the first case, if the agreed repo rate goes on special --- in
other words, if it falls below the GC repo rate --- that rate is no longer representative of the going rate
for cash reinvestment. The spread between a special repo rate and the GC repo rate represents a
borrowing fee for the specific collateral asset. Using a special repo rate as a cash investment rate is
therefore implicitly charging a fee that has nothing to do with the value of cash. Accordingly, the use of
a special repo rate violates the principle that the use of a security as collateral in a repo should not
cause the seller to gain or lose on his investment in that security as a consequence of having repoed it
out. However, whatever the economic argument, a party cannot unilaterally change the cash
reinvestment rate previously agreed with its counterparty. It must seek to negotiate a new interest rate
with the counterparty.
The perverse incentive created by negative repo rates to sellers to fail to deliver on the purchase date
If a seller fails to deliver collateral on the purchase date of a repo, he will not receive or be able to retain
the purchase price until he does deliver. However, the seller will remain obliged to pay repo interest to
the buyer, even if he delivers the collateral late and therefore has delayed use of the cash. Having to
pay interest without having the use of cash is a cost that provides an incentive to the seller to remedy a
failure to deliver as well as providing compensation to the buyer.
However, if the repo rate on a particular transaction is negative (whether this is because the collateral is
on special or because GC repo rates have gone negative), the automatic cost of failing to deliver
collateral becomes a perverse incentive to fail. This is because the repo interest due to be paid is
negative, which means it has to be paid by the buyer, despite the fail being caused by the seller. Thus,
the seller will be rewarded for his failure! 11
To eliminate the perverse incentive arising from negative repo rates, the ICMA issued a
recommendation in November 2004 on behalf of the then European Repo Council (ERC) that, when the
seller fails to deliver on the purchase date of a negative rate repo, the repo rate should automatically
reset to zero until the failure is cured, while the buyer has the right to terminate the failed transaction
at any time. Subsequently, this recommendation has been included as an optional supplementary
condition in Annex I of the GMRA 2011. For parties using the GMRA 2000, it is best practice to adopt the
11
Even at zero or low positive repo rates, there is a perverse incentive on the Seller to fail, inasmuch as a failure to
deliver creates a free option on the repo rate. If the repo rate rises subsequently, the Seller can cure the fail with
collateral borrowed through a separate reverse repo. He will owe interest at the original repo rate on the cash he
receives on repo on which he has just delivered but will receive interest at the new higher rate on the cash he gives
on the reverse repo.
The negative interest rates that appeared following the crisis that erupted in 2007 were historically
unusual, episodic in appearance and not expected to persist. Many parties therefore felt that it was
inappropriate to apply negative rates to cash margin paid under repo agreements and to the
reinvestment of income payments on collateral in buy/sell-back.
However, as already explained, whatever the economic argument, a party cannot unilaterally change
the cash reinvestment rate previously agreed with its counterparty. It must seek to negotiate a new
interest rate with the counterparty.
Since 2014, it has become apparent that negative interest rates are likely to persist for some time in
many currencies. They have become a ‘new normal’. It is now no longer possible to sustain an argument
that negative interest rates are some sort of aberration.
What is the most appropriate cash investment rate for use in repo transactions?
The most appropriate rate for the reinvestment of cash margin and collateral income in buy/sell-backs is
the GC repo rate for the currency. In the case of cash margin, this should be the overnight GC repo rate,
given that margin can change daily. In the case of the reinvestment of collateral income in buy/sell-
backs, the theoretical choice would be a GC rate for a tenor equal to the interval until the repurchase
date (the reinvestment period). However, GC repo rates for some tenors may be difficult to agree, in
which case, the next best choice would also be the overnight GC repo rate (depending on the perceived
roll-over risk).
If it is not possible to agree on the fixing of an overnight GC repo rate, the most pragmatic alternative
would be to use a recognized overnight unsecured interbank deposit rate benchmark. Under normal
market conditions, there should not be much difference between overnight secured and unsecured
rates. And in practice, such overnight indexes are already commonly used in the repo market as cash
reinvestment rates.
29. What has been the regulatory response in the repo market to the Great
Financial Crisis?
The international regulatory response to the Great Financial Crisis that erupted in 2007 has been co-
ordinated by the G-20’s Financial Stability Board (FSB). The FSB identified a number of financial stability
risks in the use of securities financing transactions (SFTs), which it defines to include repo, securities
lending, commodities lending and margin lending. These have been grouped into risks (1) affecting the
regular banking system, (2) arising in the so-called ‘shadow banking’ sector, and (3) spanning both
sectors. Shadow banking is defined as market finance involving credit intermediation or ‘bank-like’
activities by non-banks.
Those risks arising from SFTs which are seen as threats to the regular banking system have been
addressed through broad reforms of the Basel international banking supervision regime.
• The Leverage Ratio was introduced to stop the build-up of excessive leverage in the market by
imposing a simple backstop to the traditional Basel risk-weighted capital calculations, which the FSB
believe did not accurately reflect the degree of leverage in the financial system due to defects in risk
modelling and data, and regulatory arbitrage. The ratio is between Tier 1 capital and exposures
calculated from balance sheet positions in: traditional instruments like deposits; SFT like repo;
derivatives; and other off-balance sheet positions such as guarantees. For the purpose of calculating
the Leverage Ratio, positions are not risk-weighted, no account is taken of collateralisation and
there are severe restrictions on netting positions other than in derivatives.
• The Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR) was introduced to tackle market liquidity risk --- the possibility of
the whole market drying up --- by ensuring firms have a stock of high-quality liquid assets (HQLA) to
sell or repo out which provides a buffer that is sufficient to cover projected net cash outflows during
a hypothetical 30-day market crisis. To calculate the stock of HQLA available to a firm, the
authorities list which assets qualify as HQLA and grade them by quality, prescribing haircuts and
concentration limits for lower-grade HQLA. To calculate projected net cash outflows in a stressed
market, the authorities prescribe: (1) inflow factors to be applied to each type of asset and in-the-
money off-balance sheet position (ie all receivables) maturing within 31 days to estimate the extent
to which these positions are not likely to be rolled over or extended; and (2) run-off factors to be
applied to each type of liability and out-of-the-money off-balance sheet position (ie all payables)
maturing within 31 days to estimate the extent to which these positions are not likely to be rolled
over or terminated. The available stock of HQLA must exceed any excess of estimated receivables
over estimated payables.
• The Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR) is being introduced to address funding liquidity risk --- arising
because of asset-liability mismatches between long-term assets and short-term liabilities and
because of wholesale funding of leveraged non-banks by banks --- by ensuring that firms have
sufficient sources of ‘stable’ funding to sustain the financing of their assets and off-balance sheet
positions during a year-long market crisis. Each type of asset and in-the-money off-balance sheet
position is prescribed a required stable funding weight, which measures its expected liquidity in a
crisis and the importance attached by the authorities to this type of asset continuing to be financed.
Each type of liability and out-of-the-money off-balance sheet position is prescribed an available
stable funding weight, which measures the likelihood of it being able to be rolled over during a
crisis. The amount of available stable funding must exceed the amount of required stable funding
for each legal entity.
• The FSB was concerned that non-banks can use repos to conduct the ‘bank-like’ activities of
maturity and liquidity transformation outside the regular banking system and beyond the reach of
prudential liquidity and capital regulation. This means the financing of longer-term and/or less liquid
assets with leveraged short-term and more liquid ‘money-like’ liabilities. But if the assets being
financed become very illiquid or lose value, their worth as collateral will be reduced or disappear
altogether, forcing non-banks to seek other sources of financing. In contrast to banks, non-banks
are generally not directly or permanently supported by any official safety net (deposit insurance or
guarantees, and access to central banks as lenders of last resort). Instead, they are reliant on private
sector guarantees (such as back-up lines for asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP), credit
guarantees, and credit default swaps (CDS) provided by insurers, credit derivative product
companies and credit hedge funds). In systemic crises, private credit and liquidity support can prove
ineffective, as providers are unable to perform due to stress on their own balance sheets,
potentially leading to bank-like runs on confidence. These are thought by the FSB to be more likely
in shadow banking because the wholesale or institutional cash which finances this sector, in
contrast to the retail cash which finances much of regular banking, is seen as unstable (being
described as ‘well-informed, herd-like and fickle’). Moreover, shadow banks are seen as more
dependent on wholesale sources of financing than traditional banks are reliant on retail deposits.
Consequently, wholesale funding is seen as inherently fragile. It is often compared with the free
banking system of the US in the 19th and early 20th century. And, whereas banks are subject to a
well-developed system of prudential regulation, the shadow banking system and funding through
wholesale market instruments like repo are seen by the FSB as being subject to less stringent, or no,
oversight.
• The vulnerability of shadow banking to a run on confidence can be accentuated by excessive
leverage built up through the repetitive use of repos (eg repoing out assets for cash to buy more
assets, which can then be repoed out for more cash and so on).
• Fluctuations in the value of assets driven by the financial cycle tend to be self-reinforcing. Thus,
falling asset values reduce the net worth, creditworthiness and borrowing capacity of borrowers,
who may as a result be forced to deleverage, which would amplify the fall in asset values and so on.
Rising asset values would trigger the opposite process. The propensity for cycles to reinforce
themselves is called pro-cyclicality. Regulators are concerned that collateralised financing, including
repo, may be more pro-cyclical than traditional unsecured wholesale financing because of the direct
relationship of borrowing capacity to the value of the assets used as collateral and because
additional feedback loops are introduced by collateral management procedures such as haircuts
and variation margining, which can create feedbacks that amplify financial cycles, alternately
accentuating up-cycles and down-cycles. The concern is that a surge in confidence is reflected in
rising asset prices, reduced or reversed variation margin calls and shallower haircuts, all of which
increase firms’ net worth, creditworthiness and borrowing capacity, which will tend to increase
asset purchases and boost asset prices, so reinforcing the up-cycle. A collapse in confidence, on the
other hand, will trigger a fall in asset prices, increased variation margin calls and deeper haircuts, or
even the exclusion of assets from the pool of eligible collateral, which decreases firms’ net worth,
creditworthiness and financing capacity, which will tend to decrease asset purchases and depress
asset prices, so reinforcing the down-cycle. In addition, inadequate collateral management practices
at some firms, such as infrequent variation margin calls and insufficient haircuts, particularly for
illiquid collateral, can amplify pro-cyclicality by encouraging firms to belatedly and dramatically
tighten up lending practices after a crisis has broken. This was believed to have happened in the US
MBS market during the Great Financial Crisis. Pro-cyclicality may also be amplified by the increased
The FSB set out three approaches to tackling possible systemic risk arising from repos:
• improvements in transparency
• improving market practice with regard to collateral management
• reinforcing repo market structure
The FSB decided that regulatory authorities need more information to help detect and monitor systemic
risks as they are building up. Their concern is that direct exposures between large institutions would
mean the failure of one institution would destabilise other large institutions by making them more
vulnerable to a liquidity shortage, particularly if their repo financing was excessively short-term. To
monitor such risks, they proposed the collection of more granular data on repo (and other SFTs)
between large international financial institutions, in order to detect major bilateral linkages as well as
common exposures to and dependencies on countries, sectors and financial instruments. They
envisaged leveraging the work of the FSB Data Gaps Group, which had been established to build a
consistent global framework to pool and share data on major bilateral credit linkages between large
international financial institutions. The FSB proposed to aggregate national and regional data to provide
a consistent global picture of exposures.
12
Attempts to model financial networks as a basis for regulatory analysis and prescription need to be treated with
caution. Work to date is entirely theoretical and not calibrated against any real interbank market. The results of
theoretical modelling are very sensitive to parameters such as the degree to which banks will withdraw credit lines
from other banks in a crisis. This is usually set to 100%, whereas anecdotal evidence suggests withdrawal tends to
be gradual and only becomes total immediately prior to a default. When this parameter is relaxed, the impact on
models tends to be dramatic.
In the EU, regulatory reporting of repo has been mandated under the Securities Financing Transactions
Regulation (SFTR), which dramatically expands the FSB’s data list. In part, this reflects the authorities
belief that they need to ‘learn’ about the repo market through research and because some authorities
originally (but incorrectly) believed that the necessary data was readily available from central securities
depositories (CSDs). The ECB and Bank of England have imposed separate money market reporting
regimes in advance of SFTR.
The FSB propose to publish some aggregated information from the data they collect.
The FSB also saw a need for accounting standards bodies to improve the disclosure about repo (and
other SFT) activities in firms’ financial statements, including greater consistency in reporting across firms
and jurisdictions, speedier publication, more detail and measurement of risk rather than just nominal
size. The FSB proposed a ‘sources and uses of securities collateral’ statement (from whence collateral is
received and to where it is despatched) as well as more qualitative information on counterparty
concentration, maturity profile, composition of collateral, haircuts, re-use of collateral, client business
and credit exposures, all broken down by type of SFT.
The FSB believed that investors should be informed frequently of the degree to which investment
managers leverage their portfolios through the use of repo in order for them to be able to better select
investments on the basis of risk. They recommended the reporting of the amount of repo, repo
maturity profile, repo currencies, repo rates, the top 10 collateral issues, types of collateral, collateral
maturity profile, top 10 counterparties and location, re-use of collateral, use of CCPs or tri-party agents,
number of custodians and holdings of assets by each, and use of segregated or omnibus accounts.
4.2.1 Mandatory minimum haircuts for risky collateral assets in SFTs with the shadow banking sector
The FSB argued that collateral haircuts calculated over a whole financial cycle would remove the need
for firms to increase haircuts when market conditions deteriorated, thus reducing pro-cyclicality. Higher
haircuts were also seen as useful in restraining the build-up of leverage by progressively reducing the
financing potential of collateral each time it is re-used.
The FSB proposal, since adopted by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, was for a set of floors
under haircuts applied to non-centrally cleared repos against non-government bonds through which
regulated financial intermediaries provide finance to shadow banks. The scope of the proposal includes
collateral swaps constructed of back-to-back repo and reverse repo, as well as securities lending against
cash collateral (unless the use of cash is restricted) and securities lending against non-cash collateral
(unless the collateral cannot be re-used). After consultation, the haircuts were set in line with the
standard supervisory haircuts applied under the Basel regime for the calculation of risk-weighted capital
requirements.
The FSB recommended that firms should calculate haircuts to cover, at a high level of confidence, the
maximum expected decline in the market price of a collateral asset over a conservative liquidation
horizon taking account of how much longer it would take transactions to be closed out in stressed
conditions and the possible widening of bid-offer spreads. The price observation period should cover a
least one past stress period.
It was also recommended that risks other than collateral price volatility should be taken into account by
firms when calculating haircuts, such as large concentrations of collateral, wrong-way risk and any
currency mismatches between cash and collateral, as well as the specific characteristics of each type of
collateral, including asset type, issuer credit risk, structure, price sensitivity and residual maturity.
Haircuts should also take account of the frequency of valuation and variation margining.
The FSB recommended that firms should be subject to minimum regulatory standards in their
jurisdictions which:
• restrict them to taking collateral which they could hold after a counterparty default without
breaching legal or regulatory restrictions and which they are able to value, manage and liquidate in
an orderly way;
• require them to have contingency plans to deal with the failure of their largest counterparties in
both normal and stressed markets;
• require at least daily marking-to-market and variation margining of material net exposures.
In the aftermath of the Great Financial Crisis, proposals were made for the mandatory central clearing
across CCPs of all repos, similar to the mandatory central clearing of standardised OTC derivatives.
However, the FSB recognised that there were problems in trying to impose a blanket requirement for
central clearing across all parts of the repo market. They also believed that there were sufficiently
strong incentives for central clearing already in place in the inter-dealer market for high-quality
collateral but that repos with customers and against lower quality collateral would be difficult to clear.
It was left to regional and national jurisdictions to assess the situation in their own markets.
The FSB considered academic arguments that repo should lose its exemption from the automatic stay
on the enforcement of collateral and other measures imposed by insolvency regimes. Some academics
claimed that the so-called safe harbour status conferred on repo by its exemption increases its ‘money-
like’ status, which encourages the rapid growth of cheap but potentially unstable short-term funding; is
likely to trigger fire sales after a default; and reduces the incentive of creditors to monitor counterparty
credit risk (see question 3).
The FSB also examined academic proposals for an official body to buy collateral at market prices less
pre-defined haircuts from the repo creditors of a firm in default and subsequently sell off the collateral
in an orderly manner when the market recovered, with profits or losses being attributed to the
creditors. The FSB decided the practical and legal challenges were too great.
Short-selling is the sale of a security which the seller has not yet purchased. In due course, the short-
seller will have to buy the borrowed security back from someone else in the market, in order to return it
to the lender. Between selling and then buying back the security, the short-seller is said to have a short
position. If the price of the security falls before it is bought back from the market, the short position will
yield a capital gain (and vice versa). Short-sellers can borrow securities in the repo or securities lending
markets.
Short-selling incurs significant risks and costs. It must therefore be undertaken cautiously.
• Risk. The price of a security sold short may rise, in which case, it will have to be bought back at a
price higher than that at which it was sold, which means a capital loss. In theory, there is no limit
to where the price of a security can rise, so the possible capital loss on a short position is
potentially unlimited. On the other hand, since the price of a security can only fall to zero, there is
a limit to the possible capital gain on a short position. In this respect, taking a short position can
be compared to the risky practice of writing a call option.
• Running cost. A daily loss will accrue on a short position at a rate equal to the coupon on the
security sold short (since the daily accrual of coupon interest on the security will add to the
Borrowing to cover short positions can be arranged before or after a short sale is agreed, but should be
done before delivery is due. Short-selling without borrowing before delivery is said to be uncovered or
naked. Concern is sometimes expressed that uncovered short-selling permits unlimited selling of a
security, allowing speculative forces to massively leverage negative sentiment and manipulate the
market. However, many, if not all, uncovered short positions are either temporary and/or unintentional.
Temporary uncovered short positions are usually only intraday and arise because it is more convenient
to borrow after a short sale has been agreed (otherwise, there is a risk of borrowing and then not selling
short). Unintentional uncovered short positions arise when it turns out to be difficult to borrow
securities in the market because of lack of supply, or because lenders fail to deliver (which is often due
to inefficient clearing and settlement, particularly of cross-border transactions).
Uncovered short-selling becomes a market abuse in the case where a seller has no intention of
borrowing and delivering the securities that he has sold short. However, in contrast to the equity
markets of the past, this is difficult to do in fixed-income markets, given that it will always result in
failure to deliver a security, which incurs costs and penalties, and would be unacceptable to the
counterparties expecting delivery. Anyone who has failed to receive a delivery of bonds that he has
purchased in the cash market also has recourse to buy-ins, which allow him to buy the bonds from a
third party and pass any extra costs (which can be significant) to the seller who has failed to deliver.
There are different fail management mechanisms in the repo market (see question 25).
In the EU, the EU Short Selling Regulation which came into force in November 2012 prohibits uncovered
short-selling of government bonds or listed shares in Europe, other than by market-makers or banks
involved in the issuance of government bonds.
In theory, one could buy a security with one’s own funds and then repo out that security to raise more
funds, which could be used to buy another security, which could be repoed out for yet more funds, and
so on, ad infinitum.
However, in practice, this infinite multiplier would come up against the credit limits imposed by all
banks on their counterparties and regulatory capital constraints (including new measures such as the
Basel Leverage Ratio). Even if the borrower tried to borrow from different firms, the inflation of its
balance sheet would soon become visible and deter potential lenders. There are also practical
constraints such as the impact of haircuts or initial margins, where the purchase price is set below the
market value of collateral, reducing its financing potential.
Pro-cyclicality means a propensity to amplify cycles of financial activity. Policy-makers and regulators
have expressed concern that increases in haircuts and initial margins demanded by collateral-takers
(including buyers in repos) in response to a cyclical deterioration in credit and liquidity conditions, while
rational for the individual parties, may worsen the problem for the market as a whole. On the other
hand, reductions in haircuts and initial margins in response to a cyclical improvement in credit and
liquidity conditions may add fuel to market exuberance.
This hypothetical scenario underpins a broader claim that the market crisis of 2007-09 was essentially, if
not entirely, a “run on repo”. The main proponents have been two US academics, Gorton and Metrick
(see question 35). However, they based their hypothesis on a single set of data on collateral haircuts
taken on highly structured securities by a single anonymous US broker-dealer. This type of collateral
constitutes a very small part of the repo market. It has been argued that it is naïve to extrapolate events
in this narrow sector of the US repo market to the entire global repo market without any calibration of
the importance of such collateral. Such an extrapolation of the Gorton-Metrick hypothesis has been
refuted by the evidence of other studies, including that gathered by a Study Group of the Committee on
the Global Financial System (CGFS) at the BIS, which observed that haircuts were generally stable during
the 2007-09 crisis and that credit was very largely tightened by the reduction or closing of credit limits
and the shortening of lending. Nevertheless, the Gorton-Metrick thesis has spawned proposals for
mandatory minimum haircuts as a macroprudential regulation to dampen the pro-cyclicality ascribed to
haircuts and initial margins (as well as to reduce leverage). The idea is that, if haircuts are deep enough
before a crisis, they will remain stable across a financial cycle as there will be no need for the market to
increase them in response to a crisis.
Ironically, there is a counter-argument that deep haircuts will allow creditors to run from the market
earlier, as deep haircuts will be able them to better absorb fire sale losses. In addition, there is criticism
of the implicit assumption underlying haircuts that the borrower (repo seller) will always be the risky
counterparty. Defaults in the Russian repo market a few years ago were by repo buyers who benefited
from deep haircuts.
A detailed discussion of the role of Haircuts and initial margins in the repo market was published by the
ICMA in February 2012.
Some commentators have claimed that parties receiving collateral through repos have an unfair priority
over other creditors, particularly unsecured creditors, in the event of a default by the collateral-giver.
However, this perception is based on the legal form of collateralisation of US repo, where US Treasury
and Agency securities can (if a court rejects the argument that title to collateral has been transferred)
be given as collateral through a pledge which is exempt from the provisions of the Bankruptcy Code that
normally apply to pledged collateral, in particular, the stay on the enforcement of rights to collateral in
an insolvency. In Europe and elsewhere, the legal form of a repo involves purely the outright sale of
legal title to collateral. The buyer in a repo therefore has exactly the same rights as someone who has
purchased securities in an outright transaction. There is no preference. Unfortunately, some
commentators and European regulators have assumed that the legal structure of all repo markets is
identical to that of the US (see question 14).
If a borrower pledges collateral to a lender, legal title to the assets remains with the borrower, unless
and until he defaults on the loan. As a result, the assets are said to have been encumbered by the legal
interest in the assets given to the lender. This means that, in the event of a default by the borrower, his
unsecured creditors cannot benefit from the liquidation of these assets.
The argument that repo encumbers assets is largely illusory. Consider a bank with assets of 10 in the
form of bonds funded with liabilities in the form of 5 of equity and 5 of unsecured deposits. Assume the
bank then repos out the bonds for cash of 10. On its balance sheet, it now has 20 of assets in the form
of 10 of now encumbered bonds (as they have been repoed out) and 10 in cash. Against these assets,
the bank has 20 of liabilities in the form of 5 of equity, 5 of unsecured deposits and 10 of repo debt.
Assume the bank then uses the borrowed cash to buy 10 more in bonds, so that it still has 20 of assets
but now in the form of 20 in bonds and 20 of liabilities in the same form as before. 10 of the bonds
remain encumbered. In the event of a default by the bank, its 10 of repo debt would be netted off
against the 10 in cash owed to the repo counterparty. This would leave the bank with the same 10 of
assets (in the form of 10 unencumbered bonds) that it had at the start to cover the 5 of unsecured
deposits. The bank’s unsecured depositors are as well protected as they were before the bank repoed
out the bonds, even though the ratio of encumbered assets to total assets has risen from zero to 50%.
The example is summarised in the table below.
Those unfamiliar with repo are sometimes misled by its accounting treatment. Assets sold as collateral
in a repo remain on the balance sheet of the seller, even though legal title to those assets has been
transferred. This could give the appearance that the assets would be available to other creditors in the
event of default. The collateral does not leave the balance sheet of the seller because he is committed
to buy back the collateral at the original price plus repo interest, which means that the seller retains the
risk and return on the collateral (if the market price of the collateral falls during the repo, the seller has
to buy back at a loss, and vice versa). Balance sheets are intended to measure the economic substance
The one occasion on which repos can really encumber assets is when there is a haircut or initial margin
imposed on the collateral, as there is no cash received in exchange for those assets. In addition,
potential variation margin calls can be seen as contingent asset encumbrance. However, this is a
marginal encumbrance. Ironically, official proposals for a minimum mandatory haircut on collateral may
make encumbrance a more material issue.
35. Was a ‘run on repo’ the cause of the Great Financial Crisis in 2007?
This phrase was coined by two academics, Gary Gorton and Andrew Metrick of Harvard University, in a
paper published in 2010, which has had a major influence on the regulatory debate on the pro-
cyclicality of haircuts, spawning the idea of a minimum mandatory haircut and changes to the treatment
of repo in insolvency. 13 Unfortunately, there are fundamental flaws in the calibration of their model.
Gorton and Metrick argue that the Great Financial Crisis of 2007-08 was akin to a traditional banking
deposit panic but was precipitated specifically by a run on the repo market, which they describe as
being part of the ‘securitised banking’ market. Securitized banking is defined as the business of
packaging and re-selling loans, with repo as the source of funding. Gorton and Metrick propose that
deepening haircuts reduced the value of collateral to such an extent that it forced massive deleveraging
in the financial system. Firms from which repo funding was progressively withdrawn by the imposition
of higher and higher haircuts were forced to deleverage by selling assets. The resulting fire sales
amplified and aggravated the crisis. The importance attached to the Gorton and Metrick hypothesis
derives in large part from the empirical evidence they employ in the form of a set of data series on
collateral haircuts taken on 10 classes of highly structured securities by a large (but anonymous) US
broker-dealer between 2007 and 2009.
The main shortcoming with Gorton and Metrick’s data is that it only includes highly structured securities
(ABS, RMBS, CMBS, CLO and CDO). Gorton and Metrick mistakenly assume that the collateral used in
the US repo market is ‘very often’ securitized bonds. They offer no data on US Treasuries and Agencies,
which constitute by far the largest pool of repo collateral in the US, and ignore evidence from the tri-
party market, which may have accounted for almost two-thirds of outstanding US repo. This is
significant because, although the US Task Force on Tri-Party Repo Infrastructure (2009) concluded that
‘tri-party repo arrangements were at the center of the liquidity pressures faced by securities firms at the
height of the financial crisis’, they concluded that the available data suggested that initial margins in the
tri-party repo market did not increase much during the crisis, if at all. They observed that, ‘It appears
that some tri-party repo investors prefer to stop financing a dealer rather than increase [initial] margins
to protect themselves’. This point was also made by the BIS Committee on the Global Financial System
(CGFS) Study Group. Gorton and Metrick ignore the reduction or closing of credit limits and the
shortening of lending. There is also no recognition of the evaporation of unsecured credit. They are
therefore simply incorrect to attribute the entire deleveraging of the US financial system and loss of
liquidity in the US money market to the dynamics of the repo market in the form of deepening haircuts.
13
Gorton, Gary, & Andrew Metrick, Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo (9 November 2010).
It is therefore a serious mistake to extrapolate certain events in one small part of the US credit repo
market into the entire global repo market. This can be demonstrated by quantifying the impact of
changes in haircuts/initial margins in the European market. In a paper published by the ICMA in
February 2012, an estimate was made of the likely impact over 2007-09 of changes in haircuts/initial
margins in the European repo market using the results of the ICMA’s semi-annual European repo
market survey for June 2007 and June 2009, and the CGFS Study Group survey of haircuts. 14 Even on
the basis of conservative assumptions, the impact on the value of collateral of changes in haircuts/initial
margins on repo balances is less than 3%, which is insignificant in terms of the scale of deleveraging
seen over the same period (eg the headline totals of the ICMA survey dropped by 28.1%, from a peak of
EUR 6,775 billion in June 2007 to EUR 4,868 billion in June 2009, and the maximum fall was 31.6% to
December 2008). Although the estimations are necessarily approximate, the difference is of an order of
magnitude, which seriously calls into question haircut spiral models such as Gorton and Metrick’s as
feasible explanations for the market crisis of 2007-09.
These doubts have been reinforced by a study by Krishnamurthy, Nagel and Orlov, who make the point
that ‘much of the discussion of the repo market has run ahead of our measurement of the repo
market.’ 15 They derived a new data set from regulatory and industry sources on investment in the US
repo market by money market mutual funds and securities lenders’ cash reinvestment desks. These
institutions are estimated to have provided some two-thirds of the cash borrowed by shadow banks in
the US repo market in 2007. Krishnamurthy et al calculated that only some 3% of non-Agency MBS and
ABS were financed by repo bought by money market mutual funds and securities lenders. Most of their
repo collateral was US Treasuries or Agencies (80% for money market mutual funds and 65% for
securities lenders). While there was a deterioration in repo terms (rates, maturities and haircuts) for
structured security collateral, there was no contraction in purchases of repo against Treasuries and
Agencies. Krishnamurthy et al also observed no increase in haircuts on Treasury and Agency collateral.
Moreover, in the tri-party market, they measured only modest increases in haircuts for structured
securities and corporate bonds, from 3-4% in 2007 to 5-7% in 2009, compared to the changes in Gorton
and Metrick’s data for structured securities in the bilateral repo market, which showed haircuts often
rising from 0% to in excess of 50%. The evidence is once again that, rather than increasing haircuts,
market users initially responded to the crisis by reducing or withdrawing credit lines, shortening the
terms for which they were willing to lend and narrowing the range of eligible collateral. The conclusion
is that repo was not key to the funding of shadow banking and had a modest impact on changes in
aggregate funding conditions.
14
Haircuts and initial margins in the repo market, ICMA (8 February 2012).
15
Krishnamurthy, Arvind, Stefan Nagel and Dmitry Orlov, Sizing Up Repo, Stanford University (November 2011).
‘Shadow banking’ is an unfortunately pejorative term which has been applied, since the Great Financial
Crisis, to market finance (as opposed to bank finance). It is defined, for regulatory purposes, as
traditional banking activity conducted by non-banks. The regulatory concern is that this bank-like
activity falls partially or entirely outside the scope of prudential capital and liquidity regulation and
beyond the safety nets provided by deposit protection or official lenders of last resort. Nevertheless,
there are linkages and feedbacks into the regulated banking system. Moreover, credit intermediation in
the shadow banking sector involves maturity and liquidity intermediation and the creation of leverage
on a scale that could pose systemic risk. And because the process often takes place in stages, along
complex chains of transactions between separate entities, and lacks safety nets, it is seen as particularly
susceptible to contagion risk, which may amplify systemic risk. Complexity is also seen as making the
repo market opaque. Moreover, it is argued that, because of the lack of safety nets, shadow banks have
to rely on securities financing transactions (SFT), including repo, and that collateral is pro-cyclical
(amplifying credit growth in booms and accentuating credit shrinkage in busts --- see question 32).
However, repo is not intrinsically a shadow banking instrument, as it is not used exclusively by so-called
shadow banks. Indeed, it is mainly employed by commercial banks and securities firms --- all of which
are regulated entities --- and increasingly by regulated end-users such as pension funds and insurance
companies. This is the predominant case in Europe (whereas money market mutual funds --- classic
shadow banks --- play a major role only in the US market). Repo is also the principal tool used by central
banks in the implementation of monetary policy and when acting as lenders of last resort.
This question has been prompted by incidents such as Lehman Brothers’ ‘Repo 105’ or MF Global’s use
of repo-to-maturity. In both cases, assets sold in repos were accounted for as disposals and removed
(temporarily) from the balance sheets of the sellers. This disguised their true leverage. However, in both
cases, this accounting treatment made use of provisions specific to US Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles (GAAP). These options have since been closed.
In Europe, such accounting options have never been available and repo must be accounted for in the
standard way. This follows the principle that balance sheets are intended to measure the economic
substance (the value and risk of a company) not the legal form in which it has structured its
transactions. In a repo, as the seller commits to repurchase the collateral at its original price plus repo
interest, he retains the risk and return on that collateral. Accordingly, the collateral remains on the
balance sheet of the seller, even though he has sold legal title to the collateral to the buyer. The logic of
this accounting treatment is confirmed by the consequence that, because the cash paid for the
collateral is added as an asset to the seller’s balance sheet (balanced on the liability side by the
repayment due to the buyer at maturity), this will expand, thereby signalling that that seller has
increased his leverage by borrowing. In order to make it clear to the reader of a balance sheet which
assets have been sold in repos, the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) require that
The concern that emerged in 2012 over the collusive manipulation of widely-used interest rate
benchmarks such as LIBOR and EURIBOR by banks on the fixing panels also served to highlight the long-
standing problem of dwindling liquidity in longer-term unsecured interbank deposits on which such
indices are based. For example, what have been the sources of rates such as 6, 9 and 12-month LIBOR
and EURIBOR, given the thin or non-existent trading in such tenors over many years? The unsecured
interbank deposit market had become increasingly illiquid since the 1990s and liquidity vanished
entirely during the Great Financial Crisis that erupted in 2007. Illiquidity, even more than the
manipulation of fixings, has called into question the validity of these traditional money market
benchmarks. Manipulation can be prevented but liquidity cannot be invented. Given that liquidity has
been migrating from unsecured to secured money markets, the logical question is whether a repo rate
benchmark should be substituted for LIBOR, EURIBOR and other unsecured interbank deposit (IBOR)
benchmarks.
The question has become more urgent following the announcement by the UK regulator that panel
banks will no longer be required to contribute to LIBOR after 2021. It is expected that few, if any, will
continue after this date and it is questionable whether other IBORs can survive much longer. Moreover,
formerly reliable unsecured overnight benchmarks such as EONIA have been undermined by the
reduction in market liquidity caused by the exceptional monetary policies pursued by many central
banks following the Great Financial Crisis and new regulation aimed at discouraging short-term
wholesale market funding. As a consequence, regulators have been leading a search for virtually risk-
free rates to act as replacement benchmarks for both overnight and term interest rates. Repo provides
a virtually risk-free rate.
As a practical matter, it will be difficult to redesign or renegotiate the trillions of dollars of financial
contracts currently linked to LIBOR, EURIBOR and other IBORs. And even if the legal obstacles can be
overcome, the transition cost of switching to a new benchmark would be substantial.
A fundamental theoretical obstacle to the construction of any meaningful interest rate benchmark is the
current fragmented state of the financial markets. Interest rate benchmarks have traditionally
measured the average cost of wholesale funding to banks. However, heightened anxiety about
counterparty credit risk has resulted in the tiering of banks in terms of perceived creditworthiness and
cost of funding, undermining the idea of any average cost of funding.
If the repo rate were to be used as the source of a future interest rate index, it would have to be the GC
repo rate given that this is cash-driven (see question 8). To produce a pure GC repo rate, it will be
necessary to minimise the influence of the credit risk of the repo counterparties, the credit and liquidity
risks of collateral and the correlation between the credit risks of the repo counterparty and collateral
issuer (so-called wrong-way risk).
In the case of IBORs, the influence of counterparty credit risk has been minimised by taking quotes only
from prime banks, something which has become increasingly difficult as bank credit ratings have
generally deteriorated. In the case of repo, it is proposed to eliminate counterparty credit risk by using
rates for repo cleared and therefore guaranteed by CCPs.
One attempt to circumvent these problems is the MTS/NEX Markets family of Repo Financing Rates
(RFR), in which a statistical filter trims the upper and lower quartiles of daily repo rates. In principle, the
repo rates of risky countries should be trimmed off the top and the repo rates of specials should be
trimmed off the bottom.
An alternative is to take rates from Eurex’s Euro GC Pooling market, which uses a rules-based algorithm
to select the collateral. As collateral selection by the algorithm is post trade and therefore unknown
when transactions are being priced, the repo rate could be considered to be a GC rate.
However, in all indices, there appears to be insufficient term business in repo to extend the yield curve
beyond the very short term. Most proposals and plans for term indices therefore rely on the emergence
of futures and interest rate swap markets to extrapolate term rates.
The manipulation of traditional indices such as LIBOR and EURIBOR has made both the market and the
authorities cautious about the use of contributions from panels of banks or brokers’ associations
(including the now defunct sterling Repo Overnight Index Average (RONIA)). There is a preference for
using rates from sources such as trading venues, CCPs, and clearing and settlement systems, which also
have the advantage of offering rates on transactions rather than quotes. However, such sources need to
have wide market coverage in order to be useful. Ultimately, the success of any interest rate benchmark
is likely to depend upon the degree to which it is correlated with the rates at which banks actually fund
themselves.
Unlike the FRBNY and SNB, the Bank of England has not adopted a repo-based virtually risk-free rate. It
has instead reformed the unsecured sterling overnight index SONIA by taking control of its fixing and
using transaction rates reported under its money market reporting regime. The decision to reform
SONIA was driven by market objections to the transition cost of switching to a secured benchmark
(something to which the Swiss market was not exposed). The Bank of Japan has retained the Tokyo
uncollateralised overnight call money index, TONAR. The ECB is proposing to replace EONIA with a new
unsecured index called the Euro Short-Term Rate or ESTER.
39. How do MiFID II and MiFIR apply to the repo market in the EU?
MiFID II is the EU’s second Market in Financial Instruments Directive and MiFIR is the Market in Financial
Instruments Regulation. MiFID’s objective is to harmonize investment services across the EU in order to
increase competition and consumer protection. MiFID II came into effect in July 2014 and extends the
scope of the first Directive into fixed income markets. MiFIR came into effect at the same time. The
regulatory technical standards (RTS) and implementing technical standards (ITS) for MiFID II and MiFIR
were implemented in 2018.
When MiFID II and MiFIR were published, it was unclear which provisions would apply to repo and other
securities financing transactions (SFT). It has been argued that the authors of the legislation did not
seem to be aware of the existence of repo. Some questions about the application of the legislation to
repo still remain to be answered. At this stage, the sections of MiFID II and MiFIR relevant to repos
would seem to be as follows:
Pre- and post-trade transparency (trade reporting) obligations under MiFIR Article 1
This requires trading venues and systematic internalizers (SI) to continuously publish current bid and
offer prices, the depth of trading interest and of actionable indications of interest (requests for quotes),
and data on executed trades in fixed income securities. However, an amendment to MiFIR in June 2017
exempted repos and other SFT.
Under RTS Article 27, execution venues are required to publish a wide range of relevant statistics on the
quality of execution of client orders including price, costs, speed and likelihood of execution. Repos and
Under RTS Article 28, investment firms are required to annually publish summaries of the volumes of
each type of client order and quality of execution on their top five execution venues. Best execution
data for repos and other SFTs does have to be reported.
Investment firms are required to report to each client the total execution costs charged for orders
transacted on their behalf, whether the firm was acting as agent or principal, when it executed the
order and an itemisation of costs. It is unclear how cost and charge disclosure will apply to repo and
other SFTs.
In a provision that mirrors the information and consent provisions applied by Article 15 of SFTR to the
re-use of collateral, MiFID requires investment firms are required to highlight to clients the risks
involved and the effect on the client’s assets of repos and other title transfer collateral arrangements.
MiFID prohibits the use of repo and other title transfer collateral arrangements with retail clients,
including local authorities.
There is also a requirement under MiFID Article 6 that investment firms should consider the
appropriateness of repo and other title transfer collateral arrangements for non-retail clients.
MiFID requires firms to ‘maintain relevant data relating to all orders and all transactions in financial
instruments which have been carried out, on own account and on behalf of a client’ for at least five
years. Record-keeping requirements apply to repo.
ICMA represents financial institutions active in the international capital market worldwide. ICMA’s
members are located in over 60 countries. ICMA’s market conventions and standards have been the
pillars of the international debt market for over 50 years, providing the framework of rules governing
market practice which facilitate the orderly functioning of the market. The ICMA European Repo and
Collateral Council (ERCC) is a special interest group established under the auspices of ICMA to represent
the major banks active in Europe’s cross-border repo markets.
www.icmagroup.org
These FAQs have been written by Richard Comotto, Senior Visiting Fellow at the ICMA Centre at
Reading University.