Lecture 3 2023
Lecture 3 2023
Alessio D’Amato
Class of Environmental Economics and Policy 2023
Efficient level of flow pollution.
The cost-minimization perspective
• Market-based instruments
• emission taxes
• abatement subsidies
3
• tradable emission permits
The pollution process Command and control instruments
Ambient pollution
Ambient pollution requirements
levels
Location of Zoning
emissions
Emissions
Emissions output licenses
4
Inputs used Input restrictions
EXAMPLES OF CAC INSTRUMENTS
Instrument category Description
Input controls over quantity and/or mix of inputs Requirements to use particular inputs, or
prohibitions/restrictions on use of others
7
2. Instruments which impose minimum technology requirements
8
Ex. of use of BAT: Directive IPPC (integrated pollution prevention and control) - replaced
by Directive on industrial emissions 2010/75/EU (IED)
The IPPC Directive is based on several principles: (1) an integrated approach, (2) best
available techniques, (3) flexibility and (4) public participation.
o The integrated approach means that the permits must take into account the whole
environmental performance of the plant, covering e.g. emissions to air, water and
land, generation of waste, use of raw materials, energy efficiency, noise, prevention
of accidents, and restoration of the site upon closure.
o The permit conditions including emission limit values (ELVs) must be based on Best
Available Techniques (BAT). To assist the licensing authorities and companies to
determine BAT, the Commission organised an exchange of information between
experts from the EU Member States, industry and environmental organisations. This
resulted in the adoption and publication by the Commission of the BAT Reference
Documents (the so-called BREFs).
9
Market-based instruments
• Alter the structure of pay-offs that agents face, creating incentives for individuals
or firms to voluntarily change their behaviour.
• Change in relative prices. Two ways:
• By the imposition of taxes on polluting emissions (or on outputs or activities
deemed to be environmentally harmful), or by the payment of subsidies for
emissions abatement (or reduction of outputs or activities deemed to be
environmentally harmful).
• By the use of tradable emission permit (or allowance) systems in which permits
command a market price. Those prices are the cost of emitting pollutants.
• More generally, any instrument which manipulates the price system in such a way
as to alter relative prices could also be regarded as an incentive-based instrument. 10
Instrument category Description
Economic incentive (market-
based) instruments
Marginal
benefit (after
tax)
*
0 M* M̂ Emissions, M
• Knowledge of both the aggregate marginal pollution damage function and the
aggregate emissions abatement cost function are necessary for achieving a
socially-efficient emissions target. But it is not necessary to know each firm’s
marginal abatement cost function.
13
A general model (1)
• i = 1,..,n polluting firms (or agents)
n
• Strictly convex damages di (E) where E = ei
i =1
n
D( E ) = d i ( E )
i =1 14
A general model (2)
• Production costs increase with output (qi) and with abatement (ai)
ci (qi , ai ) where cqi 0, cai 0, cqi qi 0, (cqi qi cai ai − c 2 qi ai ) 0
• Emissions function:
15
FIRST BEST VS. DECENTRALIZED EQUILIBRIUM
• Decentralized equilibrium
ci (qi , ai )
P (Q * ) − = 0 qid qi*
qi
ci (qi , ai ) d
− = 0 aid = 0 ei ei*
ai 16
COMPARISON BETWEEN POLLUTION TAXES AND ABATEMENT SUBSIDIES
LONG RUN EFFICIENCY
• Assume all firms are identical. Entry must take place up to the point where positive
marginal social welfare can no longer be obtained. The planner solves:
nq
max qi ,ai ,n P (Q)dQ − nc(q, a ) − nF − D(ne)
0
ci (qi , ai ) s (q , a )
P(Q * ) − −v i i i = 0
qi qi
ci (qi , ai ) s (q , a )
− −v i i i = 0
ai ai
• First best is obtained if v = D' ( E * )
• Long run: firms enter the market up to where
Post-tax or post-subsidy
marginal benefit
* S5
S3 S1
S4 S6 S2
0 M*
M Emissions
An emissions tax and an emissions abatement subsidy (at the same rate) differ in
terms of the distribution of gains and losses. This has important implications for the
political acceptability and the political feasibility of the instruments. It also could
20
affect the long-run level of pollution abatement under some circumstances, by
changing the size of the industry.
Taxes vs. subsidies
Both emission taxes and emission reduction subsidies lead to the
social optimum
BUT
NONETHELESS
21
Subsidies preferred for “political” reasons
22
https://data.oecd.org/envpolicy/environmental-tax.htm
Fossil Fuels’ subsidies
23
https://www.nature.com/articles/d41586-021-02847-2
Fossil Fuels’ subsidies
24
https://www.nature.com/articles/d41586-021-02847-2
Fossil Fuels’ subsidies
25
https://www.nature.com/articles/d41586-021-02847-2
Comparing costs
26
• The optimal instrument depends on the position and on the relative slope of
marginal damages and marginal benefits.
27
Uncertainty about abatement costs – costs overestimated
MD
Loss when
licenses used
tH
t*
MC
Loss when (assumed)
taxes used
MC (true)
28
Mt M* LH
Emissions, M
Uncertainty about abatement costs – costs underestimated
MD
t*
tL
MC (true)
MC
(assumed)
29
LL M* Mt
Emissions, M
Uncertainty about abatement costs – costs overestimated
loss with
standard
MD
tH
t*
MC
(assumed)
loss with tax
MC (true)
30
Mt M* LH
Emissions, M
Uncertainty about abatement costs – costs underestimated
MD
loss with
standard
MD
t*
tL loss with tax
MC (true)
MC
(assumed)
31
LL M* Mt
Emissions, M
General result
• When the (absolute value of the) slope of the MC curve is less than the slope of the
MD curve, licences are preferred to taxes (as they lead to smaller efficiency losses).
• When the (absolute value of the) slope of the MC curve is greater than the slope of
the MD curve, taxes are preferred to licences (as they lead to smaller efficiency
losses).
32
Uncertainty about damage costs – damages underestimated
MD (true)
MD (estimated)
MC (true)
33
M* L
Emissions, M
Consequences of a threshold in the damages function
Total
damages
D
M0 34
Emissions, M
Hartwick and Olewiler (1998)
General conclusions
• Where functions are linear, and uncertainty relates to the marginal abatement cost
(MC) function, then an EA (minimising the efficiency losses arising from incorrect
information) should prefer a quantity policy (licences) to an emissions tax if MC is
flatter than MD, and an emissions tax to a licence system if the reverse is true.
• Where uncertainty pertains to the MD function, knowledge of relevant slopes does
not contain information that is useful in this way.
• Once the existence of non-linearity and/or threshold effects is admitted, general
results are harder to find. In some circumstances at least, combined tax–quantity-
control programmes may have attractive properties.
• The presence of uncertainty substantially weakens the possibility to achieve a
“socially optimal” (Pareto efficient) pollution level (we may not know where it is!)
• Other approaches may be needed. 35
Two major questions about pollution policy:
➢ Given that some target level has been chosen, what is the best
method of achieving that level?
36
Criteria for selection of pollution control instruments
37
Cost efficiency and cost-effective pollution abatement instruments
• Suppose a list is available of all instruments which are capable of achieving some
predetermined pollution abatement target.
• If one particular instrument can attain that target at lower real cost than any other,
that instrument is cost-effective.
38
Least-cost theorem of pollution control
A necessary condition for abatement at least cost is that the marginal cost
of abatement be equalised over all abaters.
39
Least-cost theorem of pollution control
40
Least-cost theorem of pollution control
o N polluting firms, i = 1, . . . , N.
o Each firm faces a fixed output price and fixed input prices, and maximises
profits by choosing output level (Qi) and emission level (Mi) - uniformly mixing
pollutant.
o 𝜋ො 𝑖 is the maximised profit in the absence of any control over its emission level
(unconstrained maximum profit level); at this profit maximum firm’s emission
level is 𝑀 𝑖 .
o 𝜋𝑖∗ is the maximised profit when it is required to attain a level of emissions
𝑀𝑖∗ < 𝑀 𝑖 - (constrained maximum level of profits), with 𝜋𝑖∗ < 𝜋ො 𝑖
41
Least-cost theorem of pollution control
• firm’s abatement costs, C, are:
𝐶𝑖 = 𝜋ො 𝑖 − 𝜋𝑖∗
• Abatement costs are a function of the severity of the emissions limit. Suppose a
quadratic function:
𝐶𝑖 = 𝛼𝑖 − 𝛽𝑖 𝑀𝑖∗ + 𝛿𝑖 𝑀𝑖∗2
• Consider the problem of an environmental protection agency meeting some
standard for total emissions (from all N firms) at the least cost: M*
42
The firm’s abatement cost function
43
Least-cost theorem of pollution control
𝛽𝑖 − 2𝛿𝑖 𝑀𝑖∗ = 𝜇 ∗
• The Lagrangian is: - MC of an increase
in pollution abatement
o FOCs:
• A least-cost solution will in general not involve equal abatement effort by all
polluters.
• Where abatement costs differ, cost efficiency implies that relatively low-cost
abaters will undertake most of the total abatement effort.
45
EMISSIONS TAXES ARE COST-EFFECTIVE
min 𝐶𝑇𝑖 = 𝐶𝑖 + 𝑡 ∗ 𝑀𝑖 = 𝛼𝑖 − 𝛽𝑖 𝑀𝑖 + 𝛿𝑖 𝑀𝑖 2 + 𝑡 ∗ 𝑀𝑖
𝑀𝑖
FOCs:
𝜕𝐶𝑇𝑖
= −𝛽𝑖 + 2𝛿𝑖 𝑀𝑖∗ + 𝑡 ∗ = 0, 𝑖 = 1,2, … , 𝑁
𝜕𝑀𝑖
48
Marketable emissions permits
Marketable permit systems are based on the principle than any increase in
emissions must be offset by an equivalent decrease elsewhere.
There is a limit set on the total quantity of emissions allowed, but the regulator
does not attempt to determine how that total allowed quantity is allocated
among individual sources.
Two types:
o ‘cap-and-trade’ system
o emission reduction credit (ERC) system
49
Cap and trade permit systems
51
Auctioned permits case
Fixed supply of
permits
*
0 M* M̂ Emissions,
M
A firm will bid to purchase an additional emission permit whenever the marginal cost of abating
emissions exceeds the permit price. The market equilibrium permit price is determined by the 52
value of the aggregate marginal abatement cost at the level of abatement implied by the total
number of issued permits.
Free initial allocation case
*
54
Efficient abatement with two firms and marketable permits
55
Least-cost pollution control using transferable emissions permits
Suppose that the EA issues to each firm licences permitting 𝐿0𝑖 units of emissions.
Firms are allowed to trade with one another in permits.
The ith firm will trade in permits so as to minimise the sum of abatement costs
and trade-acquired permits:
𝐶𝐿𝑖 = 𝐶𝑖 + 𝑃 𝐿𝑖 − 𝐿𝑖 0 = α𝑖 − 𝛽𝑖 𝑀𝑖 + 𝛿𝑖 𝑀𝑖 2 + 𝑃 𝐿𝑖 − 𝐿𝑖 0
where P is the market price of one emission permit.
Given Li = quantity of emissions produced after trade:
𝐶𝐿𝑖 = 𝐶𝑖 +𝑃 𝐿𝑖 − 𝐿𝑖 0 = α𝑖 − 𝛽𝑖 𝐿𝑖 + 𝛿𝑖 𝐿𝑖 2 + 𝑃 𝐿𝑖 − 𝐿𝑖 0
56
Least-cost pollution control using transferable emissions permits
𝜕𝐿
The necessary condition for minimisation is: = −𝛽𝑖 + 2𝛿𝑖 𝑀𝑖 ∗ + 𝜇∗
𝜕𝑀𝑖∗
𝜕𝐶𝐿𝑖
= −𝛽𝑖 + 2𝛿𝑖 𝐿𝑖 ∗ + 𝑃
𝜕𝐿𝑖
which can be interpreted as the firm’s demand function for permits.
If the EA sets a total emissions target of M* then M* is the total supply of permits and:
𝑁 𝑁 𝑁
𝜕𝐿 𝜕𝐿
𝑀∗ = 𝐿𝑖 0
= 𝐿𝑖 = = − 𝑀∗ + 𝑀𝑖 ∗ = 0
𝜕𝜇 𝜕𝜇
𝑖=1
𝑖=1 𝑖=1
59
Air emission trading schemes around the world
60
European Emission Trading Directive – EU ETS
61
European Emission Trading – EU ETS
➢ It is the world's first and biggest international emissions trading system. It accounts for
over three-quarters of international carbon trading.
➢ Trial period: 2005-2007. Second trading period: 2008-2012
➢ Aim to meet obligations outlined by the Kyoto Protocol during the 2008-2012 trading
period, not during the trial period. Plan to continue after 2012 (post-Kyoto)
➢ Set an absolute cap on CO2 emissions in the EU.
➢ Tradable allowances distributed equal to cap quantity. Most allowances freely allocated.
➢ Facilities measure and report CO2 emissions. One allowance per ton of CO2 emitted.
➢ Initially limited to certain sectors (power, combustion facilities, certain industries -- not
transportation or buildings). Plan to expand over time. 62
European Emission Trading – EU ETS
• Characteristics (now):
➢ >11,000 installations, 31 countries; over 500 aircraft operators flying between EEA's
airports. It covers around 39% of the EU's GHG emissions.
➢ In phase 3 (2013-2020), the sectors with stationary installations regulated by the EU ETS
are energy intensive industries
including power stations and other combustion plants with >20MW thermal rated input (except hazardous or
municipal waste installations), oil refineries, coke ovens, iron and steel, cement clinker, glass, lime, bricks,
ceramics, pulp, paper and board, aluminium, petrochemicals, ammonia, nitric, adipic, glyoxal and glyoxylic
acid production, CO2 capture, transport in pipelines and geological storage of CO2.
➢ The aviation scope of the EU ETS was limited to flights within the EEA in the period 2013-
2016, pending the adoption of a global approach by the International Civil Aviation
Organization. To support the development of the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction
Scheme for International Aviation (CORSIA), in 2017 the limitation to intra-EEA flights was 63
prolonged until 2023.
European Emission Trading – EU ETS
• Characteristics:
• The EU ETS covers carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions, but also nitrous oxide (N2O) emissions
from all nitric, adipic, glyoxylic acid and glyoxal production, and perfluorocarbons (PFC)
emissions from aluminium production.
• Even though participation in the EU ETS is mandatory, in some sectors only installations
above a certain size are included.
• Participating countries can exclude small installations (emitting less than 25 000 tonnes of
CO2e) from the system if alternative and equivalent measures are in place.
• In phase 4 very small emitters (with reported emissions of less than 2 500 tonnes of CO2e
in the last three years) can be excluded from the EU ETS subject to the existence of
simplified monitoring arrangements to assess the quantity of their emissions.
• Participating countries may also add more sectors and GHGs to the EU ETS (so called “opt- 64
in”).
EU ETS – mechanism functioning (2003 Directive)
68
69
European Emission Trading – EU ETS
• Since 2009 => a surplus of emission allowances in the EU emissions trading system.
• The surplus of allowances is largely due to the economic crisis (which reduced emissions
more than anticipated).
• The surplus amounted to around 2 billion allowances at the start of phase 3 and
increased further to more than 2.1 billion in 2013.
• This has led to lower carbon prices and thus a weaker incentive to reduce emissions.
• Introduction of short- and long-term measures.
• In the short term: the surplus risks undermining the orderly functioning of the carbon
market.
• In the longer term: it could affect the ability of the ETS to meet more demanding
emission reduction targets cost-effectively.
70
https://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets/reform_en
Market prices and quantities
71
European Emission Trading – EU ETS
• Subsequent amendments:
• 2008: inclusion of aviation;
• 2008: emission cap level to require a reduction of 21% compared to 2005 for EU ETS
sectors + Effort Sharing Decision to reduce emission by non-ETS sectors of 10%
compared to 2005 (shared among Member States);
• from the third period (2013-2020): linear reduction 1.74% of the average total quantity
of allowances issued annually in 2008-2012 + new allocation method: full auctioning for
the whole power sector; progressive transition to auctioning for other sectors (reduction
30% year); completely free allocation for sectors at risk of carbon leakage;
• - from the fourth phase (2021-2030): increase in the pace of emissions cuts (overall
number declining at an annual rate of 2.2%); better targeted carbon leakage rules (from
177 to 50 sectors at risk) and new mechanisms to stimulate low-carbon innovation and
energy sector modernization. 72
European Emission Trading – EU ETS
• Subsequent reforms:
➢2014: (short-term measure) Back-Loading of allowances: postponing the auctioning of 900
million allowances until 2019-2020.
This measure affects only the distribution of the allowances over the third period, not their
overall number:
• The auction volume was reduced by:
• 400 million allowances in 2014
• 300 million in 2015
• 200 million in 2016.
➢ From 2019: Introduction of the Market Stability Reserve (long-term measure):
• The back-loaded 900 million allowances transferred to the reserve rather than auctioned in
2019-2020.
• Unallocated allowances transferred to the reserve. The exact amount will only be known in
2020. However, market analysts estimate that around 550 to 700 million allowances could 73
remain unallocated by 2020.
EU ETS: emission reduction
74
Price CO2 European Union Allowances 2017-2019
between 4€
and 6€
throughout
2016 and
2017
75
Price CO2 European Union (source: trading economics)
76
RUOLO ISTITUZIONI FINANZIARIE
ISPRA – SISTEMA REGISTRY EUROPEI
ALTRI SISTEMI: CINA (WU ET AL. 2021)
ALTRI SISTEMI: CINA (SLATER ET AL. 2019)
Intertemporal and spatial analysis of pollution
Case of stock pollutants that have relatively long damaging lifespan, but
which are uniformly mixing.
Two implications:
1. the uniformly mixing assumption implies that pollutant
concentrations do not differ from place to place, and so the spatial
dimension of emissions control is no longer of direct relevance.
2. persistence of pollution stocks over time means that the temporal
dimension is of central relevance.