(Microeconomics) Topic 3-2
(Microeconomics) Topic 3-2
(Microeconomics) Topic 3-2
3. Consumer Theory
* * *
I Basic Concepts of Use Value
This approach carries the similar postulates as the ordinal approach. It still emphasizes the postulate that
each person is willing and capable of substitution among goods or services, i.e. each person is willing to
give up some goods or services for another goods or services.
* Economists also add in a postulate suggesting that the marginal use value of good to a person is always
diminishing which implies that MUV depends on how much goods a person had already had.
An Example
1 20 20 20
2 38 18 19
3 54 16 18
4 68 14 17
5 80 12 16
6 90 10 15
7 98 8 14
8 104 6 13
9 108 4 12
Micro / Topic 3-2 P.2
0 Q 0 Q 0 Q
There are mainly three types of explanation suggested by economists in this case.
(1) Adam Smith distinguished the concept of use value and exchange value to settle the issue. However,
the relation between use value and exchange value is still not clear at that time.
(2) Later, a Neapolitan priest called Galiani Ferdinando ( 1728-1787 ) applied the law of diminishing
marginal utility to explain it by claiming that the MU of water diminishes sharply relative to that of
diamond. As a result, the price of water falls to a relatively low level and vice versa for the case of
diamond.
(3) Recently, economists employed the concept of use value again and MUV to answer. The
consumption of water is so large that its MUV diminishes to a very low level . The price of water had
to be low to encourage more purchase and consumption of water. Whereas the level of consumption
of diamond is relatively low, its MUV diminishes but at a relatively higher level. As a result, its price
could be high and its exchange value is high also.
The paradox arises because people confuse the concept of TUV with MUV. The exchange value of
a good depends on its relative scarcity and MUV, not its TUV !
Price, MUV
E
P1
P2
MUV
0 Q1 Q2 Good X
Micro / Topic 3-2 P.3
* Assume initially the market price is given as P1 for the good X. The consumer will decide what
quantity demanded will be based on this price.
* At a quantity demanded smaller than Q1 the consumer will find that his MUV is greater than the
market price at each level of QD ; i.e. his marginal gain (his MUV) is greater than his marginal
sacrifice ( the price paid per unit ). As a rational maximizer, he would continue to buy up to the level
Q1. The opposite would happen when he buys more than Q1 with a price of P1.
* Suppose the market price, for some reasons, falls to P2 now. The optimum situation has changed !
Q2 should be the optimum quantity demanded for him.
* As a result, whenever the market price changes, the level of quantity demanded of the consumer
moves along his MUV curve.
The MUV curve in fact tells the relation between the price and quantity demanded as well as the
consumer equilibrium. In this respect, the MUV curve becomes the consumer demand curve !
The diminishing marginal valuation of a good by a consumer also agrees with the usual downward-
sloping nature of an ordinary demand curve.
* The MUV approach is more straight-forward and simple in deriving a demand curve.
P P
P0 P0
MUV D D MUV
0 Q 0 Q
* The income effect reinforces the substitution effect in the case of a normal good.
* The income effect offsets the substitution effect in the case of an inferior good.
Micro / Topic 3-2 P.4
* The MUV approach involves marginal valuation so that the income effect is excluded, i.e. the income
effect is zero and the possibility of a Giffen good is ruled out !
P0 A
C
P1 B AUV
MUV
0 Q Quantity
Suppose the MUV and AUV curves of a consumer are given above. With a given market price of P1 his
TUV of a quantity demanded ( = Q ) is the area under the MUV curve ( = Area OMBQ ) or equal to the
product of P0 times Q ( = Area OP0AQ ).
In other words, the area mentioned can show his maximum willingness to pay for an amount of Q units of
the good.
If the supplier is able to charge an AON price to extract the consumer's surplus, the price is still P0 with
an amount of Q bought by the consumer. Otherwise, he could not have any good.
As a result, the consumer would find himself in a situation with : TEV = TUV = Area OP0 AQ
* In a free market with an uniform market price, a price of P1 will lead to the consumer to buy Q units,
i.e. the maximum willingness to pay at the margin for an amount of Q is only P1 for the consumer.
* If a simple uniform pricing is used, the price leading to an amount of Q purchased will be P 1 and the
TEV = Area OP1 BQ. There is a consumer's surplus of area MBP1 and is also called the gain from
exchange.
* There is no income effect so that the real income is constant. The AUV curve thus becomes a demand
curve under an all-or-nothing pricing arrangement - the so-called " all-or-nothing demand curve ".
Case 1 : Membership Fee Case 2 : AON Pricing Case 3 : Perfect Price Discrimination
P P
M M
P A P B
B A
D
MUV MUV
D
0 Q1 Q0 Q
0 Q0 Q1 Q
In case of a normal good, the ordinary demand curve overstates the amount of consumer’s surplus
because the income effect has not been excluded in the analysis above.
In case of an inferior good, the ordinary demand curve understates the amount of consumer’s surplus.
The reason is just the opposite of that in case of a normal good.
If the case of Giffen good is ruled out, the downward-sloping ( both money-income-constant as well as
real-income-constant ) demand curve can be tested by the reality and provides meaningful explanation of
consumer behavior.
People sometimes argue that if we maximize, then the utility-maximizing theory could be formed.
If we do not always maximize, will the utility theory be wrong ?
Economists reply by pointing out that so long as the theory can explain and explain well, the validity of
the assumptions is not important.
People go on to argue that if we always maximize, then “ whenever we act, we are maximizing utility. “
This argument becomes an tautology and could not be tested.
Economists reply, “ we have to specify the entities on utility and the possible constraints involved so
that the implications derived ( by the indifference curves and budget lines ) can be tested.
The axiom of maximization is adopted because it provides a logical framework with great analytic
power - it is easy to build theory and models with the axiom of maximization !
The ordinal approach can derive a demand curve, but not the law of demand due to the logical possibility
of the Giffen good.
The MUV approach, by excluding the income effect, can always derive a downward-sloping demand
curve. The law of demand can have a scientific ground to support its validity. In this respect, the use
value approach is better than the ordinal approach.
Whether a demand curve is downward-sloping or not depends on the nature of the good to the
consumer. The nature of a good is purely an empirical question !
The concept of Giffen good, at best, is only an ex-post label to classify some real-life observation. It is
never possible to make an ex-ante prediction as to which good is going to be a Giffen good, normal or
inferior good.
Any good can be a Giffen good whenever the income effect of reducing the quantity demanded
outweighs the substitution effect. If conflicting outcomes exist, i.e. income effect may reinforce, offset
or outweigh the substitution. It is not possible to confirm that the conclusion is a law.
On a pure scientific ground, the law of demand is not derived (under all possible cases) but it is
asserted by economists only !
However by denying the existence of Giffen good in reality, we find a downward-sloping demand curve
representative enough to allow the ordinal theory to be tested.
It is exactly with the empirical tests that economists use the principle - the law of demand.
Micro / Topic 3-2 P.7
* * *