Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Wa0006.

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 32

Fiscal Histories

John H. Cochrane

John H. Cochrane is the Rose-Marie and Jack Anderson Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution
at Stanford University, Stanford, California. He is also a Research Associate, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts. His email address is
john.cochrane@stanford.edu and his webpage is https://www.johnhcochrane.com.

Abstract

The fiscal theory states that inflation adjusts so that the real value of government debt equals
the present value of real primary surpluses. Monetary policy remains important. The central
bank can set an interest rate target, which determines the path of expected inflation, while
news about the present value of surpluses drives unexpected inflation. I use fiscal theory to
interpret historical episodes, including the rise and fall of inflation in the 1970s and 1980s, the
long quiet zero bound of the 2010s, and the reemergence of inflation in 2021, as well as to
analyze the gold standard, currency pegs, the ends of hyperinflations, currency crashes, and the
success of inflation targets. Going forward, fiscal theory warns that inflation will have to be
tamed by coordinated monetary and fiscal policy.
What fundamentally drives inflation or deflation, or the value of money? The fiscal theory of
the price level offers a novel answer to this age-old question. It is particularly relevant today,
with inflation that seems related to large recent deficits, and given the foundational difficulties
widely acknowledged in traditional monetary, Keynesian and new-Keynesian theories.

In this essay, I offer narrative discussions of how fiscal theory can account for prominent
episodes when inflation did, or did not, occur. Why did inflation rise in the 1970s and fall in the
1980s? Why was inflation quiet in the 2010s, but then rose in 2021? Why does inflation fall in
recessions and rise in booms? These stories help us to see how fiscal theory works and how to
apply it in practice, more transparently than by staring at forests of equations.

The fact that there are such plausible stories, that fiscal theory can plausibly account for
historical episodes, is news, since many economists and commentators seem to think that fiscal
theory can be quickly dismissed by well-known episodes. Formal quantitative analysis and
evaluation builds on plausible stories, and I hope this essay and my recent book (Cochrane
2023) inspire additional formal analysis.

Fiscal Theory

First, I briefly describe fiscal theory and how it contrasts with conventional theories of
inflation. The fiscal theory states that inflation adjusts so that the real value of government debt
equals the present value of primary surpluses.

Most simply, money is valuable because we need money to pay taxes. If, on average,
people have more money than they need to pay taxes, they try to buy things, driving up prices.
In the words of Adam Smith,

A prince, who should enact that a certain proportion of his taxes be paid in a paper
money of a certain kind, might thereby give a certain value to this paper money. (Wealth of
Nations, Vol. I, Book II, Chapter II.)

Taxes are a percentage of income. Thus, as prices and wages rise, your dollar income rises,
and the amount of money you must pay in taxes rises. A higher price level soaks up excess

2
money with tax payments. Equivalently, the real value of money, the amount of goods and
services a dollar buys, declines as the price level rises. But the real value of taxes does not
change (much), so a higher price level lowers the real value of money until it equals the real
value of tax payments.

This story is simplistic. We add more realistic ingredients in order to make the theory useful
to think about economic events and policy.

First, the government also spends and transfers money to people. So money is soaked up
by government surpluses, the excess of taxes over spending, not just by taxes.

Second, governments also sell bonds. If you buy a one-year bond, you give the government
$1 today, and the government gives you $1 plus interest, say $1.05, in a year. So, the
government must print up money to redeem bonds that come due, which pushes toward
inflation. But the government can also soak up money by selling new bonds. The government
can run deficits, a negative surplus, by selling bonds. But the government cannot keep rolling
over its debts forever, issuing new bonds to repay old bonds. Eventually, all of the money
outstanding today and all of the money promised by outstanding government debt must be
soaked up by surpluses. Thus, prices adjust until the real value of all government debt, including
money, equals the present value of current and future surpluses.1

The economic logic is the same as the basic way we think of stock and bond prices. The
stock or bond price adjusts so that the value of a stock or bond is equal to the expected
discounted present value of dividends or coupons. Government bonds, repaid by surpluses, are
effectively stock in the government.

The insight that the present value of surpluses matters for inflation quickly surmounts
some armchair rejections of fiscal theory, and opens the door to a more interesting

1
In equations, the price level adjusts so that
-
𝐵"#$ Λ"*+
= 𝐸" ( 𝑠
𝑃" Λ" "*+
+./
where B=nominal government debt, P=price level, Λ is a stochastic discount factor such as marginal utility or the
inverse cumulative return, and s is the real primary government surplus. Money (cash and reserves) are part of B.

3
interpretation of events. One might think fiscal theory predicts a strong correlation between
debt or deficits and inflation. Yet while inflation is sometimes linked to debt and deficits, there
often is little or even lower inflation with deficits, as in many recessions; and there is often
inflation without big deficits. However, fiscal theory does not necessarily predict a tight
relationship between current debt or deficits and inflation. If the government runs a big deficit,
but people trust that deficit will be repaid by higher subsequent surpluses, then people are
happy to hold the extra debt rather than try to spend it, and there is no inflation. That
hypothesis is sensible. When corporation borrows to build a factory, it runs a big deficit, and
then slowly pays off the bonds, a long stream of surpluses. Governments that want to borrow,
to raise revenue to fight wars or recessions, and do not want to create inflation, will credibly
promise repayment. Fiscal theory only predicts inflation when debt is larger than what people
think the government will repay.

Inflation often seems to come from nowhere, or over-respond to small shocks. Well, news
or sentiment about long-run fiscal surpluses can change quickly, as do investor’s views of
stocks. Moreover, dynamics that resemble bank runs underlie the present value. Our
government rolls over a lot of short term debt. People may dump government debt today,
simply because they fear nobody will roll over the debt next year. Iterating forward, we
economists see the present value of surpluses, but that long-term view is not necessarily in the
minds of bondholders.

Most of all, discount rates matter to present values. When interest rates rise, bond values
fall. A higher real interest rate makes the same stream of expected surpluses less valuable. So,
higher real interest rates lower the value of debt, and act as an inflationary force even with no
surplus news. Equivalently, a higher real interest rate means that the government has to pay
more to finance its debt. As we shall see, this variation in discount rates or interest costs is
central to understanding postwar US inflation.

The central bank can set a nominal interest rate target in fiscal theory, as our central banks
do. If prices are flexible, the nominal interest rate target determines expected inflation. Central
banks remain powerful! Shocks to the present value of surpluses then determine unexpected

4
inflation, devaluing nominal debt to match the lower present value of surpluses. There is
nothing central banks can do to stop that.

Sticky prices produce interesting and realistic dynamics, and allow inflation to affect the
real economy. The interest rate target then determines the timing of inflation and the long-run
level of inflation, while fiscal shocks produce a drawn-out unexpected inflation. Figure 1
presents a simulation of these effects, for concreteness but also for reassurance that fiscal
theory really does lend itself to quantitative formal modeling, not just story-telling. I use the
simplest standard sticky-price model.2 Sticky prices are represented in the Phillips curve: Firms
can only change prices infrequently, but do so looking forward. If other prices will be higher
next year, firms raise prices now. As a result, inflation today is driven by expected inflation next
year, plus additional pressure if demand is high.

The top panel simulates what happens to inflation after a 1 percent fiscal shock—the sum
of current and expected future deficits rises 1 percent —while the central bank does not
change interest rates. The unexpected deficits create a protracted inflation. This is, roughly,
what I argue below happened in 2021. Bondholders lose from the long period in which inflation
is higher than the interest rate. This is a more realistic prediction than an instantaneous price-
level jump.

2
The model is
𝑥" = 𝐸" 𝑥"*$ − 𝜎(𝑖" − 𝐸" 𝜋"*$ )
𝜋" = 𝐸" 𝜋"*$ + 𝜅𝑥"
𝑖"*$ = 𝜂𝑖" + 𝜀<,"*$
A
𝜌𝑣"*$ = 𝑣" + 𝑟"*$ − 𝜋"*$ − 𝑠̃"*$
A
𝐸" 𝑟"*$ = 𝑖"
A
𝑟"*$ = 𝜔𝑞"*$ − 𝑞"
where 𝑥" = output gap, 𝑖" = interest rate, 𝜋" = inflation, 𝑣" = real value of debt, 𝑠̃" = real primary surplus scaled
A
by the value of debt, 𝑟"*$ = nominal return on government debt, 𝑞" = price of the government debt bond
portfolio. 𝜔 = 0.9 describes a geometric maturity structure of debt. 𝜎 = 0.5, 𝜅 = 0.5, 𝜂 = 1, 𝜌 = 0.98.

5
Figure 1: Responses of inflation in a fiscal-theory sticky-price model. Top: 1 percent deficit
shock with constant interest rate. Bottom: Interest rate shock with constant surpluses.

Indeed, in continuous time the price level does not move at all on the day of the shock. The
entire decline in value of debt comes from this period of drawn-out inflation. It is a fiscal theory
of inflation, of the long-run price level, but not of price level jumps, of the initial price level.

The bottom panel presents what happens to inflation and output if the Fed raises interest
rates one percentage point, and there is no change in fiscal surpluses. By including long-term
debt, this simulation expresses the common idea that an interest rate rise temporarily lowers
inflation and output. But higher interest rates eventually raise inflation. In both cases output,
not shown, roughly follows inflation.

6
The two simulations of Figure 1 offer an important benchmark for understanding events
and analyzing fiscal and monetary policy. Historical episodes and policies mix fiscal and
monetary interventions, and thus mix the two simulations. (Most interest rate hikes die out
more quickly, and we do not see the long-run positive effect.)

Money and Aggregate Demand

The most familiar theory of inflation is based on money supply and money demand.
Inflation comes from too much money chasing too few goods and services.

At first glance, the monetary and fiscal stories sound similar. And that is a good thing for
fiscal theory. If you live in a fiscal theory economy, as I think you do, you wouldn’t immediately
notice anything unusual just by looking out the window, and neither would the generations of
smart economists who have come before us.

But there are crucial differences. First, which money is inflationary? In the monetarist story,
assets such as checking accounts, created by banks, satisfy money demand, so are just as
inflationary as government-provided cash. Thus, the government must control checking
accounts and other “inside” liquid assets. In the basic fiscal theory, only government money,
cash and bank reserves, matter for inflation. Your checking account is an asset to you, but a
liability to the bank, so more checking accounts do not make the private sector as a whole feel
wealthier and desire to spend more. The government need not control the quantity of checking
accounts and other liquid assets. However, in the basic fiscal theory, government debt, which
promises money, is just as inflationary as money itself. Reserves and cash are just overnight
government debt. 3

What about episodes in which we see inflation or hyperinflation clearly caused by printing
money? In these episodes, governments print money to finance intractable fiscal deficits. They

3
Reserves are accounts that banks hold at the Federal Reserve. Banks may freely convert reserves to cash and
back. The Fed issues cash and reserves and invests in Treasury debt, just like a giant money-market fund. Since the
interest the Fed pays on reserves comes from the interest it gets from Treasury securities, and since it remits any
profits to the Treasury, we really can unite Fed and Treasury balance sheets and consider cash and reserves as very
short-term and liquid forms of government debt, at least to first order.

7
are expansions of government debt relative to the government’s ability to repay debt. They are
equally inflationary in fiscal theory. Similarly, Milton Friedman once joked that the government
could easily cause inflation, by dropping money from helicopters. But dropping money from
helicopters is a fiscal operation, a transfer payment.

The key question is whether exchanging money for debt causes inflation. If the central
bank issues reserves or cash, but takes government debt in return, does that inflate? This “open
market operation” is what central banks do. In the monetarist view, yes. In the basic fiscal view,
no. People and banks really do not care much about holding Treasury debt directly versus
holding interest-paying reserves that are backed by Treasury debt. It’s like taking your $20 bills
and giving you two $5s and a $10.

The monetary theory isn’t wrong. It just doesn’t apply to today’s economy. First, monetary
theory requires a meaningful distinction between “money,” special assets used for transactions
and “liquidity” purposes, and “bonds” or savings vehicles, and that money pays substantially
less interest than bonds. This precondition is rapidly evaporating. Second, and more
importantly, monetary theory requires that the government controls the money supply. But our
central banks do not begin to control the supply of money (M1, M2, M3) or liquid assets. The
Fed eliminated reserve requirements altogether in 2020. Our central banks set interest rate
targets.

By contrast, fiscal theory is consistent with uncontrolled inside money, financial and
payments innovation, cryptocurrency, interest rate targets, unstable money demand, elastic
money supply policies, and the disappearance of a meaningful distinction between monetary
and investment assets, all of which vitiate monetary theory. All that matters, to first order, is
total government liabilities—Treasury debt, cash, and reserves—relative to expected
repayment.

A Keynesian, looking out the window at a fiscal inflation, sees too much aggregate demand.
Fiscal theory agrees, but gives a deeper source of that demand: People can only demand more
of all goods, services, and private assets by demanding less government debt.

8
US history

I take a narrative tour of recent US inflation history, to see how events can be interpreted
via fiscal theory.

The Great Inflation

The United States last experienced a major inflation in the 1970s, which ended swiftly in
the early 1980s. Figure 2 presents inflation as measured by the core (less food and energy)
consumer price Index, and the federal funds interest rate.4 Inflation came in three great waves,
punctuated by recessions.

The conventional story of this episode focuses on monetary policy: Policy was too loose in
the 1960s and 1970s, accommodated the oil price shocks of the 1970s, and reacted too slowly
to inflation. Inflation was conquered in the early 1980s by persistently high real interest rates,
at the cost of two bruising recessions.

The fiscal side of the 1970s and 1980s is less well investigated, but suggestive. Figure 3
plots the real primary surplus.5 The graph emphasizes that most variation in deficits and
surpluses comes from business cycles: Tax receipts fall in a recession, spending on social
programs and discretionary stimulus rises. Surpluses rise in the subsequent expansion. We have
to see changes in the present value of surpluses on top of this regular pattern. I plot the inverse
unemployment rate to allow some eyeball correction for business cycles.

4
Federal funds are overnight unsecured loans between banks, borrowing and lending reserves. This is the rate that
the Federal Reserve targets most directly.
5
I plot the primary surplus, not including interest costs on the debt, as the value of government debt equals the
present value of real primary surpluses. Interest costs enter the government debt valuation equation through the
discount rate. I scale by a linear trend fit to log GDP, as we want to see how greater surpluses induced by greater
GDP help to repay debts. I plot NIPA quantities for easy reproducibility, but they are not ideal measures especially
of interest costs of the debt.

9
Figure 2: Core CPI inflation and federal funds rate

Figure 3: Real primary surplus (left scale) and negative unemployment rate (right scale).
Real primary surplus is federal net lending or borrowing plus interest payments, converted to
2012 dollars via the GDP deflator and divided by trend real GDP.

Standard economic history recognizes fiscal deficits of the late 1960s as a cause for
inflation, due to President Lyndon B. Johnson’s desire to fund both the Great Society and the

10
Vietnam War without tax increases. However, these deficits are smaller than deficits that came
later, and did not cause inflation.

The stresses of the Bretton Woods era are less well studied, and may help to explain why
relatively small deficits caused inflation. Under Bretton Woods, the US committed to exchange
dollars for gold at a fixed rate with foreign central banks. This system, effectively tying the price
level to gold, is incompatible with any sustained inflation, even the few percentage points of
the 1960s. Moreover, capital markets were largely closed, so the US could not finance trade or
fiscal deficits by selling assets abroad. It had to finance trade deficits with dollars and thereby
gold. These constraints provoked essentially a foreign exchange and debt crisis in 1971, when
the US fully abandoned the gold and currency pegs of Bretton Woods, and thereby abandoned
its commitment to running fiscal policy consistent with those pegs. Bretton Woods amounted
to a precommitment against persistent trade deficits and foreign financing of fiscal deficits,
which the US now practices on a grand scale. Bretton Woods made US currency more fragile
when it wished to violate those commitments.

The US suffered an economic slowdown in the 1970s, and a break in fiscal policy. Since
World War II, the US government had run moderate deficits in recessions, steady primary
surpluses in expansions, and slowly reduced the debt/GDP ratio. The 1970s growth slowdown
and severe recessions provoked much larger deficits, lower surpluses in expansions, and less
GDP in the debt/GDP denominator. The 1975 deficit in particular was larger than any since
World War II. Together with the abandonment of Bretton Woods, concern rose over long-run
US debt sustainability.

One can digest the waves of inflation in the 1970s with the two experiments of Figure 1.
Fiscal shocks lead to sustained inflation. Monetary policy, tightening interest rates without any
change in fiscal policy, alleviates inflation temporarily, but eventually makes inflation worse.
Sims (2011) offers this analysis and calls that pattern “stepping on a rake.”

Inflation was not conquered in the 1980s by monetary policy alone. First, though there
was much commentary about “Reagan deficits” in the early 1980s, fiscal policy was not in fact
tremendously loose. Primary deficits, reflecting tax and spending decisions, were

11
unremarkable, especially given the severe recessions of 1980 and 1981-1982. A big part of the
measured deficit was simply higher interest costs on existing debt. Second, economic reforms
likely encouraged economic growth and thereby helped the budget. Deregulation, starting with
airlines, trucks, and telephones, began under President Jimmy Carter, and it, or simply a halt to
the regulatory trend of the 1970s, continued. Tax reforms in 1982 and 1986 improved
incentives by slashing federal marginal tax rates--the top personal marginal tax rate fell from 70
percent to 28 percent--while removing many exclusions and “loopholes,” and thereby
broadening the tax base. Whether for these reasons or just good luck, economic growth rose,
tax revenues rose, and so did surpluses. As Figure 3 shows, by the late 1990s, the government
was running large primary surpluses, fully justifying the 1980s disinflation. The actual surpluses
were larger even then shown in the figure, as trend real GDP was 80% larger in 2000 than in
1980.

The rise in primary surpluses overcame substantial headwinds. Again, higher real interest
rates are an inflationary force, raising the discount rate for future surpluses or equivalently
raising interest costs on the debt. As Figure 2 emphasizes, the US government had to finance
debt at large real interest rates for a decade. Taxpayers paid for that. Moreover, investors who
bought 10 year bonds at 15 percent yield in 1980, expecting inflation, got repaid in an
environment of 3 percent inflation by 1990, a 12 percent windfall real return. Taxpayers paid
for that too.

Thus, the end of inflation in the 1980s was a joint monetary, fiscal, and microeconomic
reform. In the context of Figure 1, there was a disinflationary shock to the present value of
surpluses, a negative of the top panel, largely resulting from greater long-run economic growth.
That allowed the additional temporary disinflationary effect of higher interest rates—the
bottom panel of Figure 1—to push down inflation quickly and, this time, durably. Without
budget surpluses to pay a windfall to bondholders and high interest costs on the debt, the
disinflation would likely have failed again.

The reforms of the 1980s came after the monetary tightening, and surely it was unclear
that they would be as durable and successful as they turned out to be. In turn, that uncertainty
may help to explain why the recessions of 1980-1982 were so bruising. The high ex-post real

12
interest rates of the 1980s may similarly reflect some probability that the policy mix would
unravel once again. Latin American history is full of examples in which monetary stringency
temporarily stops inflations, but fiscal and microeconomic reforms fail to materialize and
inflation spirals upward again (Kehoe and Nicolini 2021). On the other hand, as we shall see, an
even better outcome was possible. The ends of hyperinflations and the adoption of inflation-
targeting regimes, which installed new fiscal, monetary, and microeconomic regimes more
quickly and durably, quickly stopped inflation and expected inflation without bruising
recessions.

The 2000s: stable inflation with large deficits

Fiscal events turned around in 2000. As seen in Figure 3, debt and deficits grew
astronomically. The US public debt/GDP ratio rose from 31 percent in 2001 to 105 percent in
2020. Potential causes include a halving of trend GDP growth in 2000, the recessions of 2000,
2008, and 2020, the allure of low debt service costs, or simple political dysfunction. Long-term
projections from the Congressional Budget Office point to steady roughly 5 percent of GDP
primary deficits, followed by worse deficits as aging boomers drain Social Security and
Medicare. And those projections assume we don’t have another crisis, war, or pandemic.

Yet inflation stayed subdued until 2022. Why? Discount rates are the most natural
candidate: Real interest rates, and consequently debt-service costs, went on a steady
downward trend, becoming negative for the 2010s. Policy discussion turned to “r < g,” the
possibility that with interest rates permanently below economic growth, government debt
never has to be repaid. Olivier Blanchard’s (2019) influential AEA presidential address argued
that “public debt may have no fiscal cost.” Calls for cost-free fiscal expansion based on “secular
stagnation” and “modern monetary theory” grew. Whether true or not, these views captures a
widespread set of expectations, that repaying debt would be easy.

At higher frequency, consider the recession of 2008-2009 after the Great Financial Crisis.
The deficit widened dramatically, from 1.1 percent of GDP in 2007 to 9.8 percent, 8.6 percent
and 8.3 percent in 2009-2011. Yet inflation declined. CPI inflation fell from a peak of 5.5 percent

13
in July 2008, to 2 percent deflation in July 2009. Inflation stayed below 2 percent for the rest of
the decade. Shouldn’t those deficits have caused inflation?

Not necessarily. People might have expected that deficits, financing temporary spending to
meet an extraordinary crisis, would be repaid by higher surpluses when the crisis was over. The
Obama administration promised that debt reduction would follow the stimulus. That’s possible.
However, I don’t think that explanation is plausible in this case, and it is not what happened
after the fact. Instead, real and nominal interest rates –discount rates, debt service costs –fell
like proverbial stones. The Federal Funds rate fell from 5.25 percent in July 2008 to effectively
zero, 0.25 percent, and stayed there until 2016. The real short-term interest rate was thus
nearly negative 2 percent for a decade, and most analysts expected very low interest rates to
continue indefinitely. In a quantitative evaluation of events like the 2008 recession (Cochrane
2021, 2023 Chapter 4), I find that this decline in real interest rates accounts quantitatively for
the general pattern that inflation is lower in recessions, despite deficits, and conversely in
booms. About two-thirds of all inflation shocks corresponds to such discount-rate variation.
Similarly, Japan has a debt to GDP ratio of over 200 percent , yet slight deflation. Why? Among
other reasons, Japan has had very low real interest rates for three decades.

Why was there no deflation in 2008, as there was in 1933?

In 2008, the world experienced the Great Financial Crisis. Many people rightly worried that
we would repeat the early 1930s, in which a banking crisis led to a disastrous 30 percent
cumulative deflation. Why did it not happen? Many differences between the two episodes have
been adduced, but there is an important fiscal difference. Imagine that prices and wages fall 30
percent . Now, government bonds are worth 30 percent more in real terms. The government’s
tax revenues fall by 30 percent, and more as a result of the deep recession. But the government
must make the same payments to bondholders. To avoid default, the government must raise
taxes or cut spending.

Now, can you imagine our Congress and administration saying in a painful recession that
the government must dramatically raise taxes, cut spending, subject us to “austerity,” all to pay

14
an unexpected windfall to bondholders? Isn’t the government instead likely to pursue fiscal
stimulus, to regard deflation as a “bubble,” a temporary aberration that fiscal policy should
ignore, if only because once the desired reflation occurs, government revenues will recover?
That is, of course, exactly what governments did with the minor deflation we observed, as you
can see in the large 2008 deficits and larger 2021 deficits in Figure 3. And if that is what people
expect, a large deflation cannot happen in the first place. Deflation can only happen if the
expected present value of surpluses rises.

The deflation of 1933 included the opposite fiscal commitment. The US was on the gold
standard. When the value of gold and currency rose relative to goods and services– deflation –
the US was committed to repay debt in more valuable dollars, which needed tax hikes or
spending cuts. By devaluing gold from $20.61 dollars per ounce to $35, and largely abrogating
the gold standard in 1933, the US government repudiated this commitment. Deflation stopped
immediately (Jacobson, Leeper, and Preston 2019). This new reputation, that the government
will not raise taxes or cut spending to validate deflation, is exactly, in my reading, why the
feared deflation of 1933 did not break out again in 2008.

These episodes clarify a central assumption and theoretical controversy of fiscal theory.
Any theory which wishes to determine the price level elsewhere must assume the former sort
of “passive” (Leeper 1991) fiscal policy to turn off fiscal theory: Deflation, produced by other
means (money growth, etc.) raises the value of debt. Governments respond with fiscal
austerity, which raises the present value of surpluses to match the higher value of debt. Here, I
make vivid, and I hope plausible, the central contrary “active” assumption of fiscal theory: Fiscal
policy does not respond one-for-one to arbitrary inflation and deflation, paying bondholders
whatever the whims of a changed price level require.

15
The zero-bound era: A test of theories

The zero bound era following the financial crisis of 2008 offers an illuminating test of
monetary theories.6 Interest rates were essentially zero in the US from 2009 to 2016. The
episode was longer in Europe, lasting through early 2020, and longer still in Japan where
interest rates effectively hit zero 1995.

What happens to inflation if interest rates stay at or near zero for many years, and are
expected to remain at zero for more years? In these episodes, nothing. The pattern of inflation
following the 2008 recession was nearly identical to that following the 2000 recession. If
anything, inflation at the long zero bound was less volatile than in the earlier period.

Existing theories of inflation make clear and contrary predictions. Conventional theories
predict a “deflation spiral:” Lower aggregate demand produces a recession and lower inflation
or even deflation. The Fed lowers interest rates to stimulate the economy. But when interest
rates hit zero, the Fed can do no more. Now real interest rates are too high. That further lowers
aggregate demand, provoking lower inflation or deflation, which raises real interest rates even
more, in a never-ending loop. This longstanding view, based on adaptive expectations, goes
back to Milton Friedman’s (1968) celebrated Presidential Address, which taught that inflation
under an interest rate peg is unstable.

It did not happen. Deflation spirals never broke out. Even in Japan, deflation bumped
around one or two percent at worst.

Rational expectations and new-Keynesian models clearly make a different prediction: At


the zero bound, inflation becomes indeterminate and thus volatile. The interest rate
determines expected inflation, but unexpected inflation wanders randomly. In normal times,
the Fed can cut off these “multiple equilibria” by threatening to raise or lower interest rates
aggressively. But once interest rates hit zero, the Fed is powerless to do so. This is also a
longstanding doctrine. Sargent and Wallace (1975) showed that inflation is stable but

6
Economists call it the “zero lower bound,” because negative interest rates will prompt people to take their money
out of banks and hold cash. Several central banks set certain interest rates as low as -1 percent , and the
inconvenience of cash kept cash arbitrage from breaking out. Since the bound is not exactly zero, it is sometimes
called the “effective lower bound” instead. This section summarizes Cochrane (2018) and Cochrane (2023, Ch. 20).

16
indeterminate under an interest rate peg with rational expectations. Clarida, Galì, and Gertler
(2000) and Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohé, and Uribe (2001) emphasize that this indeterminacy
occurs in new-Keynesian models when the Fed does not react and at the zero bound.

It did not happen. Again, inflation was if anything less volatile with interest rates stuck at
zero than before.

In monetarist thought, the zero bound does not constrain monetary policy. The Fed can
still create reserves or print cash, use it to buy bonds, and let more M in MV=PY raise output (Y)
and the price level (P). Starting in 2009, central banks embarked on just such a massive
“quantitative easing” (QE) program. Reserves rose from $15 billion in 2007 to $2,759 billion by
August 2014, an 18,400 percent increase. The monetarist prediction is clear: hyperinflation.

It did not happen. Inflation trundled along a bit less than 2 percent. It is hard to see any
effect of QE in plots of inflation or long-term interest rates. Instead, we learn that money and
bonds are perfect substitutes after all when they pay the same rate of interest. Yes, economists
continue to debate whether QE had a few tenths of a percentage point effect on long-term
interest rates, but for our purposes the debate is over. An 18,000 percent increase in bank
reserves is an atom bomb. If you’re debating whether somebody heard a firecracker, it was a
dud.

Fiscal theory is consistent with the long quiet zero bound and the silence of QE. The
interest rate target determines expected inflation. Unexpected inflation is determined by news
to the present value of future surpluses. Inflation is both stable (no spirals) and determinate (no
multiple equilibria or sunspots) at the zero bound. If there is no fiscal or discount-rate news,
there is no unexpected inflation either. That’s not proof: I don’t have an independent measure
of deficit and discount rate expectations. But fiscal theory is at least consistent with the
episode, in a way that conventional theories are not. And it’s at least plausible that the steady
recovery after 2009, combined with very low real interest rates, led people not to worry any
more or less than before about debt repayment.

The zero bound era is thus a powerful experiment. The predictions of classic Keynesianism,
new-Keynesianism, monetarism are large, clear, and fail. Fiscal theory is at least consistent

17
with—not rejected by—the episode. More generally, the zero bound episode empirically
reverses classic doctrines: Inflation can be stable and quiet at the zero bound, and by
implication at an interest rate peg greater than zero.

The prediction of long-run neutrality, embodied in the bottom panel of Figure 1, that
inflation eventually rises to meet the interest rate, is an inescapable consequence of inflation
stability. But “eventually” can take a long time, and it is reasonable that until the zero-bound
era central banks and economists never saw interest rates that stayed still long enough,
without fiscal news, to observe long-run neutrality. Conversely, the experience of the zero
bound era should make us less nervous about the long-run neutrality proposition embodied in
Figure 1.

In the theories, stability comes from rational expectations, which I have used in the model
and discussion, more than fiscal theory per se. New-Keynesian models are also stable, and
inflation eventually rises to meet higher interest rates. One might also pair fiscal theory with
adaptive expectations. Such a model will still rule out deflation spirals, but produce much
different dynamics.

Inflation Rises From the Dead in 2021; and How Will it be Contained?

Inflation rose suddenly in early 2021, reaching 9 percent by June 2022. From a simple
fiscal-theory armchair, this event looks like a helicopter drop, a large version of the fiscal shock
plotted in the top panel of Figure 1. From 2020 through 2021, the Fed and Treasury together
sent people and businesses checks worth about $5 trillion (Cochrane 2023, Chapter 21).

But in fiscal theory, a budget deficit is only inflationary if people do not expect it to be
repaid by subsequent surpluses. So we must explore why people apparently did not expect the
new debt of 2020-2021 to be repaid, in full or in part, and tried to spend it, where they held the
new debt of 2008-2020.

There are many suggestive stories. First, politicians and administration officials in 2020-
2021 did not emphasize repayment, while deficit-reduction promises were a constant theme of

18
the earlier era. Instead they repeated the view that low interest rates allow for fiscal expansion
without worrying about repayment. For example, in her confirmation testimony, just before
passage of the $1.9 trillion “American Rescue Plan,” Treasury Secretary Janet Yellen (2021)
opined that “right now, with interest rates at historic lows, the smartest thing we can do is act
big.”

Second, I argued above that the sharp decline in real interest rates between 2007 and the
decade following 2008 helps to account for the lack of inflation from that era’s deficits. But it is
unlikely that the 2020s will see an additional 3 percentage point or so decline in real interest
rates.

Third, the 2020-2021 deficits were much larger than the 2008-2009 era stimulus.
Moreover, the pandemic recession was largely a reduction in the economy’s productive
capacity, not lack of demand. Restaurants were not closed because people didn’t have the
money to go out to dinner. When supply is constrained, a massive increase in aggregate
demand shows up more quickly in prices.

Finally, creating bank reserves and sending checks to people may be more quickly
inflationary than borrowing in Treasury markets and spending. Who gets debt matters to how
quickly it is spent. Whether the additional debt is in the form of Treasury debt or bank reserves
may matter to expectations of repayment.

How will inflation be contained? If, as I suggest, we have suffered a fiscal shock, as shown
in the top panel of Figure 1, then in this simple model monetary policy alone can only reduce
that inflation temporarily, by adding the inflation path produced by higher interest rates shown
in the bottom panel of Figure 1. Monetary policy can give us lower inflation now, but at the cost
of higher inflation later, a form of Sargent and Wallace’s (1981) “unpleasant arithmetic.”
Postponing inflation is still useful: A smaller but longer lasting inflation is desirable in many
economic models, as it reduces the disruptive effects of inflation. A Taylor-type rule in which
interest rates react to inflation produces such smooth but long lasting inflation, and reduces
output volatility.

19
But in this analysis monetary policy alone cannot durably eliminate a fiscally-induced
inflation. To durably end inflation, monetary, fiscal, and growth-oriented microeconomic policy
have to work together, as I argued above they did in the 1980s. And the fiscal headwinds are
larger today. In 1980, the debt to GDP ratio was 25 percent. Now it is 100 percent. A 5 percent
real interest rate raises interest costs by 5 percent of GDP, $1.2 trillion, for every year it lasts.

On the other hand, the experience of the zero bound era and the top panel of Figure 1 say
that inflation from a single fiscal shock will eventually die off on its own, even if the Fed does
nothing, so long as fiscal policy does not get worse. As inflation did not spiral downward at the
zero bound, it does not spiral upward now. This prediction comes also from rational
expectations more than fiscal theory per se, but it contravenes conventional wisdom which says
the Fed must raise nominal interest rates above inflation to stabilize the latter, and its slowness
to act has added greatly to inflation.

This outlook also assumes that we do not have additional adverse fiscal shocks, and that
people maintain faith that the US will pay off the remaining debt. If people did not have faith
that the $5 trillion of 2020-2021 debt will all be repaid, will they believe that additional $1
trillion deficits in the next few years will be repaid by later surpluses? If—when—the next crisis
hits, and the US wishes to borrow or print $5 trillion of new debt and money, will people hold
the extra debt, or will inflation come even more quickly?

Moreover, debt that is viewed as sustainable because of low interest costs is


fundamentally unstable. If investors get scared and demand higher real interest rates, interest
costs rise, and the debt becomes unsustainable. Inflation surges, seemingly out of nowhere, or
far out of proportion to the initial shock. Abundant fiscal space, a background of healthy long-
run surpluses, and financing deficits with long-term debt, which passes higher rates more
slowly to interest costs, would squelch these worries. But the US government no longer has
that fiscal space.

20
A Wider and Institutional History

A good theory of inflation should be able to analyze a wide variety of historical episodes
and policy regimes, not just postwar US time series. I give a short tour.

The Gold Standard

In an idealized gold standard, the government promises that you can always bring in a
dollar and get, say, 1/20 of an ounce of gold. This promise appears to nail down the price level.

The gold standard retains an allure. Monetary policy follows a simple and transparent rule,
not requiring divinations by clairvoyant central bankers. The US didn’t even have a central bank
in most of the 19th century.

But the gold standard is really a case of fiscal theory, not an alternative theory. The
government has to have the gold! Governments did not back currency 100 percent with gold,
and they certainly never backed debts 100 percent with gold. If they had that much gold, they
wouldn’t have had to borrow in the first place. So, if people wanted to turn in a lot of currency
for gold, the government had to raise taxes or borrow against credible future taxes in order to
get the needed gold. Currency and nominal debt were backed by the government’s ability to
tax, not by vaults of gold.

Sims (1999) cites a nice example:

From 1890 to 1894 in the U.S., gold reserves shrank rapidly. U.S. paper currency
supposedly backed by gold was being presented at the Treasury and gold was being
requested in return. Grover Cleveland, then the president, repeatedly issued bonds for
the purpose of buying gold to replenish reserves. This strategy eventually succeeded.

Cleveland persuaded bond buyers that the United States would run larger future fiscal
surpluses, so those buyers were willing to lend.

The United States’ final abandonment of gold in 1971 followed a similar outflow to foreign
central banks, who presented dollars for gold. The Nixon administration was unable or unwilling

21
to take the fiscal steps necessary to buy or borrow gold. In part, it likely did not want to suffer
the deflation that restoring gold parity would have implied.

The gold standard is a fiscal commitment. The stream of expected future surpluses is, on its
own, a bit nebulous and hard to forecast, as stock dividends are hard to forecast. The gold
standard offers a commitment of just what that present value will be: The government will
raise taxes or cut spending just enough to repay government debt at the gold value (e.g. $20
per ounce), no more and no less. Bond and money holders don’t need specific surplus forecasts,
they just need to understand the commitment, and a general sense that the government has
the fiscal space and the will to do whatever it takes so that the present value of surpluses will,
in fact, be the value of government debt.

The gold standard had many flaws, however. First, the gold standard era also featured
inflation, devaluation, runs, and crises when governments couldn’t or wouldn’t tax or borrow to
get gold. Those episodes reinforce the fundamentally fiscal nature of the gold standard, and
they remind us that all governments have fiscal limits. Second, there was much short-run
inflation and deflation under the gold standard. Money does not rise or fall in value relative to
gold, but money and gold together can rise and fall in value relative to goods and services. We
want a standard that stabilizes the general price level. Third, as above, the gold standard is
vulnerable to deflation, when it commits the government to fiscal austerity.

Currency pegs

A foreign exchange peg is a lot like a gold standard. A government promises to freely
exchange its currency, say pesos, for another, say dollars, at a fixed rate. This peg is likewise a
fiscal commitment. As with gold, attention often focuses on reserves—how many dollars the
central bank has. But, as with gold, no country ever has backed all of its debt with foreign
exchange reserves. So in the end, the foreign currency peg depends on the government’s ability
to tax, to get dollars, or to promise future taxes, to borrow dollars. Even currency boards, which
back currency 100 percent , can fail. When the government can no longer borrow to finance
deficits, it abrogates the board and grabs its assets. Argentina’s (imperfect) currency board,

22
which pegged the peso to the dollar one for one from 1991 to 2002 with large dollar reserves,
fell apart in this way.

An exchange rate peg also suffers the same practical and fiscal problem as the gold
standard. A rise in the real exchange rate forces an unwanted deflation, and forces the
government to validate that deflation with fiscal austerity.

Gold price or foreign exchange targets offer some of the fiscal commitment without the
run- or speculative-attack inducing offer to freely buy or sell. But the latter is also a stronger
precommitment.

Foreign or indexed debt; the corporate finance of government debt

Many governments issue indexed debt,7 or borrow in foreign currency. A higher price level
or a lower exchange rate does not reduce the real value of foreign currency debt or indexed
debt. The government must raise surpluses to pay off such debt, or default. Thus foreign or
indexed debt act like corporate debt, which must be repaid to avoid default. Domestic currency
or nominal (non-indexed) debt acts like corporate equity, whose value can fall to meet lower
expected profits.

We can then think of the choice between domestic and foreign currency debt or nominal
versus indexed debt as we think of a corporation’s choice between debt and equity. Nominal
debt, like corporate equity, allows the government to share the risks of fiscal stress, to let
inflation or currency devaluation avoid the pain of formal default. On this basis, for example,
Sims (2001) argues that Mexico should not adopt the dollar. The same argument lies behind the
view that countries like Greece should not join the euro.

But equity invites moral hazard. Surpluses are choices, not exogenous shocks. Countries
are tempted to inflate rather than fix fiscal problems. Default is costly, so countries that borrow
in foreign currency or indexed debt have an extra incentive to run the surpluses ex-post that

7
An indexed bond protects investors against inflation. In simple terms, rather than get $1 a year from now, an
indexed bond pays $1 adjusted upward for any increase in the CPI. Naturally, you pay more for this protection up
front. TIPS (treasury inflation protected securities) are indexed debt in the US.

23
they promised ex-ante. That precommitment allows them to borrow in the first place, and at a
lower rate. So, despite the risk-sharing and default-cost reductions of equity, corporate finance
recommends widespread use of debt.

Nominal government debt, like corporate equity, works better when government accounts
are more trustworthy, and when the country has other means to commit to repay rather than
habitually inflate away debt ex-post. The control rights of shareholders are that mechanism for
corporate equity. Most naturally, voters are that mechanism for government debt. If inflation
devalues nominal government debt and causes chaos throughout an economy, a lot of voters
are really mad.

Thus, the standard ideas of corporate finance suggest that countries with precommitment
problems, poor fiscal institutions, unstable politics, and untrustworthy government accounts,
should issue indexed or foreign currency debt or even dollarize. Countries that have alternative
precommitment mechanisms, strong institutions, and stable democracies with a widespread
class of people who prefer less inflation, have their own currencies and borrow in those
currencies.

Confirming this view, dollarization, currency pegs, and foreign debt are common in the
developing and undemocratic world. Successful non-inflating currencies and large domestic-
currency debts seem to be the province of stable democracies.

Inflation targets

In the early 1990s, several countries that were experiencing inflation instituted inflation
targets, including New Zealand, Canada, Sweden, and Israel. The targets usually included a
formal agreement between government and central bank, mandating that the central bank
focus on inflation. In these and other cases, inflation dropped on the announcement of the
inflation targets and stayed there. (Svensson 2011 includes a short history.)

Just how were these miracles achieved? Did previous central banks just lack the guts to do
what’s right, in the face of political pressure to inflate? Moreover, just what does the central

24
bank do to produce low inflation after the inflation target is announced? One would have
thought, and most people did think, that the point is to insulate the bank from political
pressure during a long period of high interest rates and painful recession, such as the US
experienced in the early 1980s. But nothing of the sort occurred. Inflation simply fell like a
stone on the announcement of the target. Well, “expectations became anchored” when the
target was announced, but why? The long history of inflation certainly does not lack for
speeches and promises from politicians.

Inflation targets are an agreement between central bank and government. They therefore
include an implicit commitment by the government to run fiscal affairs so as to pay off debt at
(say) 2 percent inflation, no more, and no less. Above-target inflation will lead to fiscal
tightening. Below-target inflation will lead to stimulus. In this reading, the inflation target is
similar to the fiscal commitments of a gold standard or an exchange rate target. But the
inflation target aims at inflation directly, not the price of gold or exchange rate, eliminating an
unwelcome source of relative price variation. The inflation target also avoids the promise to
freely trade cash for gold or foreign currency, which can induce runs or speculative attack.

The inflation targets were part of a suite of fiscal, financial, regulatory, and pro-growth
reforms. The latter matter: Tax revenue equals tax rate times income, so the surest way to get
more tax revenue is to allow more economic growth. Raising tax rates is like walking up a sand
dune, since each rise in tax rate lowers income.

The fact that inflation fell quickly after the announcement of inflation targets, without a
period of high interest rates or recession, is also revealing. Expected inflation can fall quickly
when people see the underlying fiscal problems have been addressed in a durable and credible
way.

An inflation target failed instructively in Argentina 2015-2019 (Cachanosky and Mazza


2021, Sturzenegger 2019), one of many cases in which Latin American inflation monetary
policies failed because the countries did not solve the underlying fiscal problems (Kehoe and
Nicolini 2021). These failures reinforce the point that a successful inflation target is as much a
fiscal commitment by the government as commandment to the central bank.

25
This implied fiscal commitment is not written in official inflation targeting agreements, nor
is it (yet) much discussed in the economic literature. But it surely seems like a reasonable
interpretation of the government’s side of the deal, and the fact of fiscal and microeconomic
reforms in inflation-targeting events. A more formal fiscal rule, announcing how fiscal policy will
and won’t react to inflation, might anchor expectations more solidly.

The Ends of Inflations

The success of inflation targets echo Sargent’s (1982) classic study of the ends of
hyperinflations in Austria, Germany, Poland, and Hungary in the early 1920s.

The price level in Germany rose by a factor of 1012. Germany was printing money to finance
intractable deficits. Sargent (1982) writes: “Germany owed staggering reparations to the Allied
countries . . . considerably larger sums were initially expected of Germany than it ever was
eventually able to pay.”

Germany’s hyperinflation stopped instantly when the long-term fiscal problem was solved.
(See Sargent 1982 Figure 2.4.) “The Dawes plan assigned Germany a much more manageable
schedule of payments.” Germany also made permanent reforms to the government budget, in
particular firing many unnecessary government and railway workers. With the fiscal problem
solved, “Simultaneously and abruptly three things happened: additional government borrowing
from the central bank stopped, the government budget swung into balance, and inflation
stopped.”

The end of Germany’s hyperinflation did not involve any monetary tightening. Indeed,
Germany printed more money. Absent inflation, people are willing to hold a larger real quantity
of money. In the similar Austrian case, Sargent (1982) continues, “circulating notes of the
Austrian central bank increased by a factor of over 6” after inflation stabilization. There was
also no recession: “By all available measures, the stabilization of the German mark was
accompanied by increases in output and employment and decreases in unemployment.”

26
In Sargent’s telling, restoring central bank independence was also important, but primarily
as a fiscal precommitment, to make it harder for the central bank to finance fiscal deficits. After
describing how the new Austrian central bank backed note issue by foreign currency and gold,
not treasury debt, Sargent continues, that Austrian currency was backed “ultimately by the
power of the government to collect taxes . . . by the commitment of the government to run a
fiscal policy compatible with maintaining the convertibility of its liabilities into dollars. Given
such a fiscal regime, to a first approximation, the intermediating activities of the central bank
did not affect the value of the [Austrian] crown “

Sargent emphasizes that a change in regime was necessary for people to believe that the
present value of surpluses changed. Announcements, decisions, promises, temporary and
reversible “austerity” policies by today’s politicians don’t budge long-term expectations. But
with a regime change, people’s expectations can shift suddenly, not after a slow period of
learning by watching inflation itself.

Successful inflation stabilizations involve joint monetary, fiscal, and microeconomic reform,
in a durable new regime. They do not have to involve recessions.

Currency crises

Many currency collapses have clearly fiscal underpinnings. But many large debts and
deficits have not led to currency devaluation or inflation. Crises, inflations, and devaluations
have also happened with few ex-ante fiscal problems (Reinhart and Rogoff 2011).

The insight that expected future surpluses and deficits drive the value of currency offers a
way to understand many episodes. Burnside Eichenbaum and Rebelo (2001) study the East
Asian financial crises of the late 1990s, in which pegged exchange rates suddenly collapsed.
Why? The economies were growing well, the governments did not have substantial debts or
deficits, and there was no unusual monetary loosening. However, Burnside Eichenbaum and
Rebelo show that the crises were precipitated by bad news about prospective deficits. Banks
had borrowed a lot of short-term foreign-currency debt. The government was poised to bail out
banks. A run on banks then became a run on government surpluses.

27
The episode has broader lessons. The form of international investment matters, and
endangers the currency when it entangles government finances. Foreign equity investors might
decide pull out, and a government may ignore the fact that they sell to locals at low prices. But
short-term foreign-currency debt, in banks that the government implicitly or explicitly
guarantees, endangers the currency. Contingent, or off-the-books liabilities, such as bailouts of
banks, businesses, homeowners, or other debts, make a government more fragile to inflation
and devaluation, and are not reflected in conventional surplus and deficit forecasts.

Concluding comments

The statement that the real value of government debt is equal to the expected present
value of surpluses is an ingredient of a theory, not a complete theory by itself. How “fiscal
theory” behaves depends on how one fills out the rest of an economic model. In this essay, I
place fiscal theory in the context of simple new-Keynesian models with rational expectations.
One can easily embed fiscal theory in more general models, featuring all the frictions and
heterogeneities that make macroeconomics fun and interesting. Better models by which higher
interest rates can temporarily lower inflation are an urgent agenda item. Though such
embedding is technically easy, the questions one is led to ask and the results can be quite
different, and counter usual intuition.

One might wish for formal tests of fiscal theory. The history of economics warns against
that approach. Attempts to construct formal tests of monetarist vs. Keynesian vs. rational
expectations vs. real business cycle vs. new-Keynesian theories as a class have never been
productive. Instead, each of these models has been evaluated by their ability to plausibly and,
later, quantitatively understand episodes and data, and to guide policy, after suitable
elaboration. The fiscal theory of the price level will rise or fall in the same way.

Two takeaways: First, monetary and fiscal policy are both important to inflation, as
exemplified by the flexible-price case in which the interest rate sets expected inflation and
fiscal news determines unexpected inflation, or by the two simulations of Figure 1. Monetary
policy is important, as a simplistic reading of “fiscal theory” might not recognize; but fiscal

28
policy also creates inflation that monetary policy cannot fully control, as a simplistic reading of
the dictum “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon” might deny.

Second, price-level control requires a well-designed monetary-fiscal regime. The present


value of the long stream of future budget surpluses is somewhat nebulous on its own. As a
result, governments create institutions designed to control, communicate, and commit to that
present value. The gold standard, currency pegs, independent central banks, inflation or foreign
exchange targets, and the hard-won reputations of governments for repaying debts are
examples of such institutions. The fiscal theory of the price level leads us to study such
institutions or regimes and think about how to improve them.

29
Acknowledgements

I thank Erik Hurst, Ed Nelson, Nina Pavcnik, and Timothy Taylor for helpful comments.

30
References

Benhabib, Jess, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé, and Martín Uribe. 2001. “Monetary Policy and
Multiple Equilibria.” American Economic Review 91 (1):167–186.

Blanchard, Olivier. 2019. “Public Debt and Low Interest Rates.” American Economic Review
109:1197–1229.

Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo. 2001. “Prospective Deficits and the
Asian Currency Crisis.” Journal of Political Economy 109:1155–1197.

Cachanosky, Nicolás and Federico Julián Ferrelli Mazza. 2021. “Why Did Inflation Targeting
Fail in Argentina?” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 80:102–116.

Clarida, Richard, Jordi Galí, and Mark Gertler. 2000. “Monetary Policy Rules and
Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
115:147–180.

Cochrane, John H. 2018. “Michelson-Morley, Fisher, and Occam: The Radical Implications
of Stable Quiet Inflation at the Zero Bound.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 32:113–226.

———. 2021. “The Fiscal Roots of Inflation.” Review of Economic Dynamics 45:1-21

———. 2023. The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.

Jacobson, Margaret M., Eric M. Leeper, and Bruce Preston. 2019. “Recovery of 1933.”
Working Paper 25629, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Kehoe, Timothy J. and Juan Pablo Nicolini, editors. 2021. A Monetary and Fiscal History of
Latin America, 1960–2017. Minneapolis MN: University of Minnesota Press.

Leeper, Eric M. 1991. “Equilibria Under ‘Active’ and ‘Passive’ Monetary and Fiscal Policies.”
Journal of Monetary Economics 27:129–147.

Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2011. This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of
Financial Folly. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

31
Sargent, Thomas J. 1982. “The Ends of Four Big Inflations.” In Inflation: Causes and Effects,
edited by Robert E. Hall. Chicago IL: University of Chicago Press, for the NBER, 41–97.

Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace. 1981. “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 5:1–17.

Sims, Christopher A. 1999. “The Precarious Fiscal Foundations of EMU.” De Economist


147:415– 436.

———. 2001. “Fiscal Consequences for Mexico of Adopting the Dollar.” Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 33:597–616.

———. 2011. “Stepping on a Rake: The Role of Fiscal Policy in the Inflation of the 1970s.”
European Economic Review 55:48–56.

Sturzenegger, Federico. 2019. “Macri’s Macro: The Elusive Road to Stability and Growth.”
In Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, edited by Janice Eberly and James H. Stock.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 339–411.

Svensson, Lars. 2011. “Inflation Targeting,” in Friedman, Benjamin M., and Michael
Woodford, eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, Volume 3b, chapter 22, Elsevier.

32

You might also like