AM2 FTU Official 2022 DEC 1
AM2 FTU Official 2022 DEC 1
AM2 FTU Official 2022 DEC 1
def Hooks
Defining babelensure Macros for setting language files up Shorhands
Language attributes Macros for saving definitions Short tags
Hyphens Multiencoding strings Macros related
to glyphs Bidi layout Input engine
specific macros
Redefinitions for bidi layout Bidi footnotes Creating languages and
reading ini files Hy-
phen rules for ’canadian’ set to “l@english
(“language0). ReportedHyphen rules for ’australian’ set to “l@ukenglish
(“language21). ReportedHyphen rules for ’newzealand’ set to “l@ukenglish
(“language21). Reported
english
1
FOREIGN TRADE UNIVERSITY
Lecture note
ADVANCED MATH 2
Lecture note
ADVANCED MATH 2
2
2.2. Eliminating the indeterminate form using l’Hospital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
2.2.1. Multiplication indeterminate form (Zero Times Infinity). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
2.2.2. Subtraction indeterminate form (Infinity Minus Infinity). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
2.2.3. Power infinity indeterminate form. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.3. Taylor ’s series . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
2.4. Improper integral . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
2.4.1. The properties of convergence and divergence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
3
ADVANCED MATH 2 PhD. Dang Le Quang. Tel. 0764060787
4
Chapter 1
APPLICATIONS OF FUNCTIONS
OF ONE VARIABLE IN
ECONOMICS
f :X ! Y
x 7! f (x) = y
Or y = f (x), which provides us a way to return the value of the function f at an element
x, x is called a independent variable and y = f (x) is the value of the function at x. If
f is determined by a expression without any explanation is given then it automatically
means the domain of the function is a set of all the elements x such that the expression
is defined.
5
ADVANCED MATH 2 PhD. Dang Le Quang. Tel. 0764060787
1
c. Suppose y = p +log(x 2). The expression is defined if 10 x > 0 and x 2 > 0.
10 x
So, its domain is D = (2, 10).
F Function composition
Let X, Y, Z be subsets of R. If function f from X to Y f : X ! Y and function
g : Y ! Z, ”function composition” of f , g denoted by g f is a function such that:
g f :X ! Z
x 7! g f (x)
F Inverse function
Suppose X, Y ⇢ R and the function f : X ! Y is a bijection. Then, the function
f (x) has an inverse function g : Y ! X such that g f (x) = x, 8x 2 Df and f g(x) ,
8x 2 Dg . We denote the inverse function of f (x) as f 1 (x).
x1 < x2 (hoc x1 > x2 ) ) f (x1 ) < f (x2 ) hoc f (x1 ) > f (x2 )
Example 1.3. Find the intervals in which the following functions are increasing or de-
creasing in their domains:
b. f (x) = cos(x) is strictly increasing on the interval ( ⇡ + k2⇡, k2⇡) and strictly de-
creasing on the interval (k2⇡, ⇡ + k2⇡).
F Bounded function:
Let X, Y be subsets of R. A function f : X ! Y is bounded above or below in X ⇢ R
if there exists a number M such that:
the function is strictly increasing if ↵ > 0 and strictly decreasing if ↵ < 0. the graph
of this function always passes through the point (1, 1).
3. Logarithmic function: y = loga (x) (a > 0, a 6= 1). The domain is D = (0, +1)
and its inverse function is y = ax . The graph of the logarithmic function and the graph
of the exponential function are reflection of each other in the line y = x. The function
is increasing when a > 1 and is decreasing when 0 < a < 1.
4. Trigonometric functions:
• The
⇣ ⇡ function
⌘ y = arctan(x) is inverse function of the function y = tan(x) on
⇡
, .
2 2
⇣ ⇡ ⇡⌘
• The function y = arctan(x) has the domain D = R, and the range , .
2 2
Moreover, the function y = arctan(x) is an odd and increasing function.
• The function y = arccot(x) is the inverse function of y = cot(x) trong (0, ⇡).
• the function y = arccot(x) has the domain D = R, and the range (0, ⇡). Morover
y = arccot(x) is a decreasing function.
notice that the the terminology (1.2) requires 3 criteria in order to obtain the continuous
of f at a:
Example 1.5. Find the sets of points where these following functions are discontinuous
x2 x 2
(a) f (x) =
x 2
8
< 1 if x 6= 0
(b) f (x) = x2
:1 if x = 0
8 2
<x x 2
if x 6= 2
(c) f (x) = x 2
:
1 if x = 2
Solution
So, f is discontinuous at 0.
(c) We consider:
x2 x 2 (x 2)(x + 1)
lim f (x) = lim = lim = lim (x + 1) = 3
x!2 x!2 x 2 x!2 x 2 x!2
Solution
= f (a)
lim f (x) = 1 = f ( 1)
x! 1+
Theorem 1.1. If f and g are continuous at a and c which are constants, these following
functions are too continuous at a:
1. f + g
2. f g
3. cf
4. f g
f
5. nu g(a) 6= 0
g
1.1.3. Derivative
f (a + h) f (a)
f 0 (a) = lim
h!0 h
f (x) f (a)
f 0 (a) = lim
x!a x a
Solution
When we consider the model of the supply function, we construct a assumption that
all other factors are constants.
According to the law of market in economics for normal commodities, the supply
function is a increasing function and the demand function is decreasing function. The
graph of the supply function (demand function) is called the supply curve (demand
curve). The point at which the two curves intersect is the equilibrium market point.
• Watch out: In economics, there calls popularly the inverse function of the function
QS = S(p) the supply function and calls the inverse of the function QD = D(p) the
demand function.
1
QS = S(p) , p = S (QS )
1
QD = D(p) , p = D (QD )
F Cost function???: is a function which shows the dependence of the total cost
(TC) on the quantity (Q): T C = T C(Q).
F Revenue function is a function which shows the dependence of the total revenue
(TR) on the quantity (Q): T R = T R(Q).
F Profit function : is a function which shows the dependence of the total profit
⇡ (TR) on the quantity (Q): ⇡ = ⇡(Q).
– the short run is generally defined as the time horizon over which at least one
factor of production are ”sticky,” or inflexible.
– The long run is a situation where all main factors of production are variable.
: Sn = u1 + u2 + . . . + un = u1 · (1 qn)
1 q
When a geometric sequence is a infinitely decreasing geometric sequence, i.g |q| < 1,
+1
X u1
S= u n = u 1 + u2 + . . . + un + . . . =
1 q
n=1
Bt = A + rA = (1 + r)A
Let Bt be the amount of money the person have after t years, we have a geometric
sequence with common ratio q = 1 + r. One has:
Bt = B0 q t = A(1 + r)t
The future value of A that the person having today after t years is:
B = A(1 + r)t
The present value of B that the person obtaining after t years is:
t B
A = B(1 + r) =
(1 + r)t
Example 1.8. An investment project requires a current cost of 200 million VND
and will bring in 300 million VND in 4 years. With interest rate is 6%, Evaluate
whether this project should take place?
Solution
We have the future value of 200 million VND after 4 years is:
This amount is less than 300 million we will obtain, so the project should take place.
Example 1.9. An investment project after one year will bring you $3000 per year,
consecutively for the next 7 years. Ask that the capital flow must be initially invested.
How much can you accept that project if the annual interest rate is 10% ?
Gii
⇣ ⌘
✓ ◆ 10
1 10 7
1 1 1 11 11
= 3000 + 2
+ ... + = 3000 10
⇡ 14605, 26
1, 1 1, 1 1, 17 1 11
So, the project just should take place if the original capital is less than $14605,26.
Example 1.10. Suppose you intend to buy a car by making installment payments.
By this method, after one month from the time of receipt, you have to pay regularly
each month a certain amount of money, consecutively for 60 months. Suppose the
price of a motorcycle at the time you buy a car is $15000 and the bank interest
rate is 1%/month. With what is the monthly payment, is the installment purchase
acceptable?
Solution
Suppose a monthly payment is a. The present value of the entire installment cash
flow at the time of receipt is:
✓ ⇣ 100 ⌘50 ◆
100
1
a a a 101 101
PV = + + ... + = ⇡ 44, 96a
1 + 0.01 (1 + 0.01) 2 (1 + 0.01)50 100
1
101
The installment purchase will be equivalent to the purchase of immediate payment
if:
F Weierstrass theorem
Theorem 1.2. If the function f (x) is continuous on the interval [a, b], then it reaches
its maximum and minimum values on the interval [a, b], i.g, there exist x1 , x2 2 [a, b]
, such that:
Theorem 1.3. Assume that f (x) is continuous on [a, b] and f (a) 6= f (b). If you
take on any value c between f (a) and f (b) that is f (a)cf (b) or f (b)cf (a), there exists
a x0 2 (a, b) such that
Corollary 1.1. If the function f (x) is continuous on [a, b] and f (a) · f (b) = 0,then,
there exists x0 2 (a, b) such that f (x0 ) = 0.i.g, the equation f (x) = 0 has at least
one solution in (a, b).
Example 1.11. The following equations describe the market equilibrium model
QS = QD :
50
QS = 0, 1P 2 + 5P + 10; QD =
P 2
Prove that the above model has an equilibrium price on the interval (3, 5). We have:
50
QS = QD , 0, 1P 2 + 5P + 10 = , 0, 1P 3 + 4, 8P 2 70 = 0 (1.1)
P 2
Given the function y = f (x) where x, y are economic variables, let x0 be a point in
the domain of the function. The following function:
M y = f 0 (x)
is called Marginal function. The value of My at x0 , M y(x0 ),is called Marginal value
of f (x) at the element x0 ( or in short, marginal value at x0 ).
Interpretation: at x0 , When x changes one unit , then the value of the function f (x)
changes a quantity approximately M y(x0 ) = f 0 (x0 ).
p
Example 1.12. Suppose the short run production function is given by Q = 40 K;
K > 0.
Solution
20
a. We have: M P K = Q0 (K) = p
K
20
b. We have: M P K(100) = p = 2. So, K0 = 100. We can conclude that if K
100
is increased by one unit, the company can increase by 2 units of its production.
Example 1.13. A monopolist firm sells its products in the market with the demand
function given by:
Q = 1500 5p
Calculate marginal revenue at the quantity Q = 650 and interpret the result.
Solution
1
We have p = 300 Q. So, the revenue function is:
5
⇣ 1
⌘ 1 2
T R = 300 Q Q = 300Q Q
5 5
Given the function y = f (x) where x, y are economic variables, let x0 be an element
in the domain of the function. The following value
y 0 (x0 )
"yx (x0 ) = x0
y (x0 )
Q0 2p 2p2
"= ·p= · p =
Q 1400 p2 p2 1400
When p = 20, we have " = 0.8. This explains that at p = 20, if the price increases
by 1%, the demand will decrease by about 0.8%.
Let y = f (x)be the function, where x, y are economic variables. The function y =
f (x) is said to obey the law of diminishing marginal utility if and only if: when the
value of the argument x increases, the marginal value M y decreases, or M y 0 = f (x)0.
For example, a simple case that is f 00 (x) < 0 for all x in its domain.
Example 1.15. Given a production function Q = aL↵ (a > 0, ↵ > 0, L > 0), find
the condition on ↵ in order to Q obeys the law of diminishing marginal utility.
Solution
We havhave:
Q0 = ↵aL↵ 1
; Q00 = (↵ 1)↵aL↵ 2
Given y = f (x) with respect to x, y which are economic variables. the function:
y
Ay = (x > 0)
x
is called average cost function (or average function). We have:
y
⇣ y ⌘0 y0
Ay 0 = = x = My Ay
(x > 0)
x x x
Therefore:
+ On the interval that the average cost function increases, M y > Ay (marginal
curve is above the average curve).
+ on the interval that the average cost function decreases, M y < Ay (marginal
curve is below the average curve).
+ At the point which the average function reaches its extremes, then M y Ay =
0 ) M y = Ay (the average line collides the marginal line at the point at which
the average line reaches its extremes).
a. Analyze the relationship between the average cost function AC(Q) and the
marginal cost function M C(Q).
We have:
MC AC
AC 0 (Q) = (Q > 0)
Q
So, on the interval that the average cost function increases, we have M C > AC
(the marginal cost curve is above the average cost curve).
and on the interval that the average cost function increases, we have M C > AC
(the marginal cost curve is below the average cost curve).
b. At the point which the average function reaches its extremes, then M y Ay =
0 ) M y = Ay (the average line collides the marginal line at the point at which
the average line reaches its extremes). At the point which the average function
reaches its extremes, then M C = AC (the average line collides the marginal line
at the point at which the average line reaches its extremes).
c. Apply for this case analysis T C(Q) = 5Q2 + 12Q + 125 (Q > 0):
T C(Q) 125
AC(Q) = = 5Q + 12 +
Q Q
125
) AC 0 (Q) = 5
Q2
AC 0 (Q) = 0 , Q2 = 25 , Q = 5 ( do Q > 0 )
- If Q > 5, then the average cost function increases and M C > AC (the
marginal cost curve is below the average cost curve)
- If Q < 5 then the average cost function decreases and M C < AC (the
marginal cost curve is below the average cost curve)
- If Q = 5, then the average cost function reaches its extremes and M C = AC
(the average line collides the marginal line at the point at which the average
line reaches its extremes).
Solution
We have:
Solution
We have:
p
5
T R = pQ = 500 L3 , L > 0
T C = pL L = 3L
p
5
⇡ = TR T C = 500 L3 3L, L > 0
2 2
⇡ 0 = 300L 3 3; ⇡ 0 = 0 , L = 100 , L = 100000
3
building table of signs and variations, we have ⇡ reaches its maximum value at
L = 100000.
b. Find the quantity that minimizes cost and maximizes profit.
Example 1.19. Given the cost function T C = 5Q3 240Q2 + 130Q (Q > 0).
Find the quantity Q that minimizes average cost.
Solution
We have:
building table of signs and variations, we have AC reaches its minimum value at
L = 100000.
Example 1.20. Given the producer’s revenue function and cost function as
follows:
Find the optimal quantity (in order to obtain the maximum profit).
Solution
– From the marginal revenue given by the function M R = (T R)0 , we deduce the
total revenue is defined by the function as follows:
Z
TR = MR
– From the marginal cost given by the function M C = (T C)0 , we deduce the total
cost is defined by the function as follows:
Z
TC = MC
0
– From the function of marginal propensity to save M P S = S(Y ) we have the
(hàm sn lng S(Y)???) production function of labor::
Z
S(Y ) = MP S
Z
adx = ax + C
Z Z Z
f (x) ± g(x) dx = f (x)dx ± g(x)dx
Z Z
k · f (x)dx = k f (x)dx
Example:
Z
3 x4
a) x dx = +C
4
Z Z
p 1 1 1 3 4
b) 3
xdx = x 3 dx = 1
x 3 +1 + C = x 3 + C
3 +1 4
Z
2 3 2
c) 2x4 + 3x3 + 2x2 + 5)dx = x5 + x4 + x3 + 5x + C
5 4 3
1
Example 1: Given production function of labor: M P L = 120L 3 . Find production
function Q(L) , given that Q(125) = 100000.
Solution
Q0(L) = M P L
Z Z
1 1 1
+1 2
) QL = M P LdL = 120L 3 dL = 120 ⇥ L 3 + C = 180L 3 + C
1
+1
3
Since Q(125) = 100000,
2
180 ⇥ 125 3 + C = 100000 ) C = 95500
From here, we have the formula for the production function Q(L) isis:
2
Q(L) = 180L 3 + 95500
M C(Q) = 4Q 20
SolutionSolution
a. We havehave:
Z Z
C(Q) = CQdQ = (4Q 20)dQ = 2Q2 20Q + C
b. We have:
Solution
Z Z
1 0,3Q
C(Q) = M CdQ = 30 · e0,3Q dQ = 30 ⇥ e +C
0, 3
1 0,3Q
C(Q) = 30 ⇥ e +C
0, 3
Example 4: The marginal revenue is defined by given function M R(Q) = 120 2Q.
a. Find ⇡(Q) , given that if the company sells only 100 units of the product, it will
lose 50,000.
0,5
M P C = 0, 8 + 0, 1Y
Example 7: Given M P S = 16 0, 4Y 0,5 . Find the saving function S(Y ) , given that
S(400) = 0.
a. Definition:
– A consumer surplus (CS): the price that the customers are willing to pay
for a product or service is p1 but the equilibrium price of the market (of that
product) is p < p1 .
=) This situation is beneficial to the customer.
=) the di↵erence amount of money in this situation is called consumer
surplus
– Producer Surplus (P S): p2 the equilibrium price of the market (of that
product) p > p2 .
=) This situation is beneficial to the producer.
=) The di↵erence amount of money in this situation is called producer
surplus.
8
<Q = D
D (p)
b. Formulas for costumer Surplus and Producer Surplus:
: QS = S
(p)
8
< Q = p + 60
D
Vı́ d 1: Given: . Find CS; P S.
: QS = 3p 120
Gii
– Step 2: Transform to the inverse demand function and the inverse supply func-
tion:
8 8
< Q = p + 60 < p = 60 QD
D
()
: QS = 3p 120 : p = 40 + 1 QS
3
ZQ Z15 ✓ ◆ 15
1 1 2
CS = D(Q) dQ Q p= (60 Q)dQ 45 ⇥ 15 = 60Q Q 45 ⇥ 15
2 0
0
✓ ◆0
1
= 60 ⇥ 15 ⇥ 152 0 675 = 112, 5
2
Similarly, we have P S:
ZQ Z15 ✓ ◆ ✓ ◆ 15
1 1 1
PS = Q p S(Q) dQ = 45 ⇥ 15 40 + Q dQ = 675 40Q + Q2
3 6 0
0 0
✓ ◆
1
= 675 40 ⇥ 15 + ⇥ 152 = 37, 5
6
Definition 2.1 (Extreme value of the function ). Given a function f (x) defined on
the interval (a, b) and x0 2 (a, b). A point x0 is called a maximum value (minimum
value ) of the function f (x) if there exists an interval (x0 , x0 + ) ⇢ (a, b) ( > 0)
such that for all x 2 (x0 , x0 + ) , f (x0 ) f (x) f (x0 ) f (x) . Maxima (plural
form of maximum) and minimum are in general called extreme values of the function.
• Be careful: The value of the function at a maximum value (minimum value) is
probably not the greatest value (smallest value) of the function on (a, b). So, Extreme
points can be local or global. Therefore, we say a function f (x) reaches its maximum
value (minimum value) at x0 locally.
Theorem 2.1 ( Fermat’s Theorem). Suppose f (x) is defined on the interval (a, b).
If f (x) is di↵erentiable and has an extreme value at c 2 (a, b), then f 0 (c) = 0.
Theorem 2.2 (Rolle theorem). If f (x) is continuous on the interval [a, b], as well
as, di↵erentiable on the interval (a, b) and f (a) = f (b), then there exists a number
c 2 (a, b) such that f 0 (c) = 0.
29
ADVANCED MATH 2 PhD. Dang Le Quang. Tel. 0764060787
Theorem 2.3 ( Cauchy’s theorem). Suppose f (x), g(x) are 2 defined, continuous
on the interval [a, b], and di↵erentiable on the interval (a, b).Then, there exists at
least an element c 2 (a, b) such that:
⇥ ⇤ ⇥ ⇤
f (b) f (a) g 0 (c) = g(b) g(a) f 0 (c)
Theorem 2.4 ( Lagrange’s theorem). If f (x) is continuous on the interval [a, b],
and di↵erentiable on the interval (a, b), there exists at least one element c 2 (a, b)
such that:
geometric meaning: There exists an element c 2 (a, b) at which the tangent line
parallels to the line connecting two points at the edge.
x0 c
• Note: Suppose x0 = a and x=b a, then b = x0 + x and for any ✓ =
x
(0 < ✓ < 1) or c = x0 + ✓ · x. Therefore, we have the following formula that is
called finite increments formula hoc công thc s gia gii ni??.
’s rule l’Hospital ’s rule. Suppose f and g are di↵erentiable and g 0 (x) 6= 0 on the
open interval I containing the point a (possibly except at a).Suppose:
Or:
0 1
In the other word, we have the indeterminate form or , then,:
0 1
f (x) f 0 (x)
lim = lim 0
x!a g(x) x!a g (x)
Solution
since:
0
, the limit is the indeterminate form . Apply L’Hospital ’s rule l’Hospital :
0
0 1
ln(x) ln(x) x 1
lim = lim 0
= lim = lim = 1
x!1 x 1 x!1 (x 1) x!1 1 x!1 x
ex
Example 2.2. Find lim .
x!1 x2
Solution
f g
fg = or f g =
1/g 1/f
0 1
This transforms the limit into the indeterminate form hay which we can apply
0 1
l’Hospital ’s rule.
Solution
The given limit is a indeterminate form since while x ! 0+ , the first factor (x)
1
approaches 0, the second factor ln(x) approaches 1. Write x = , we have
1/x
1
! 1 when x ! 0+ . Therefore, we apply l’Hospital ’s rule:
x
ln(x) 1/x
lim x ln(x) = lim = lim = lim ( x) = 0
x!0+ x!0+ 1/x x!0+ 1/x2 x!0+
If lim f (x) and lim g(x) are both equal to 1 (or 1) then:
x!a x!a
⇥ ⇤
lim f (x) g(x)
x!a
Solution
1 ⇡
⇣ ⌘
Notice that ! 1 and tan(x) ! 1 when x ! . So, this is an in-
cos(x) 2
determinate form. We transform it into the form of division and apply l’Hospital ’s
rule:
✓ ◆ ✓ ◆
1 1 sin(x)
lim tan(x) = lim
x!( ⇡2 ) cos(x) x!( ⇡2 ) cos(x) cos(x)
1 sin(x) cos(x)
= lim = lim =0
x!( ⇡2 ) cos(x) x!( ⇡ ) sin(x)
2
The limit of each of these forms can be found by taking the natural logarithm:
⇥ ⇤g(x)
Suppose y = f (x) , then ln(y) = g(x) · ln f (x)
Both of two methods leads to obtain the multiplication indeterminate form g(x) ·
ln f (x) , which is the form of 0 · 1.
cot(x)
Example 2.5. FInd lim+ 1 + sin(4x)
x!0
Solution
From here, We can find the limit of ln(y). To find the limit of y, we notice that
y = eln(y) :
cot(x)
lim+ 1 + sin(4x) = lim+ y = lim+ eln(y) = e4
x!0 x!0 x!0
Solution
Notice that this limit is an indeterminate form since 0x = 0 for all x > 0 but x0 = 1
for all x 6= 0.By expressing the function as an exponential function, we have
x
xx = eln(x) = ex ln(x)
Apply the results obtained from the previous example (2.3), we have lim+ x ln(x) = 0.
x!0
Therefore:
Zb
Definition 2.4. An Improper integral is the limit a definite integral f (x)dx as
a
an endpoint of the interval(s) of integration approaches either a specified real number
or positive or negative infinity;
Property.
Zb
1. If f (x)dx is a definite numer =) The integral is convergent.
a
Zb
2. If f (x)dx is infinite or not definite =) The integral is convergent.
a
Z1
dx
a. A =
x2
1
Z+1
x2
b. B = x·e dx
0
Z+1
dx
c. C = (a > 0; ↵ > 0)
x↵
a
Z1
dx
d. D = p
1 x2
1
Z1
dx
e. E =
1 x
0
I property 1:
I Property 2: Suppose f (x) and g(x) are integrable on the interval [a, b] and
0 f (x) g(x), 8x a, then we have:
Z+1 Z+1
– If f (x)dx diverges then g(x)dx diverges.
a a
Z+1
dx
Example:Consider the convergence or divergence of the integral I = .
x3 + 2
0
Solution
Z+1 Z+1
1 1 dx dx
We have 3 3 , since converges, it leads to converges.
x +2 x x3 x3 +2
0 0
I Property 3: Let f (x) and g(x) be non negative functions and integrable on
the finite interval [a, b]. If:
f (x)
lim =k (0 < k < +1)
x!+1 g(x)
Z+1 Z+1
f (x)dx and g(x)dx
a a
sin(x) ⇡ x
x2
cos(x) ⇡ 1
2
tan(x) ⇡ x
ln(x + 1) ⇡ x
ex ⇡ x
Z+1 Z+1 2
2x2 e x
a. dx e. dx
2x3 + 1 x2
0 0
Z1 Z1
dx
b. ln(2x)dx f.
1 + cos(2x)
0 0
Z1 Z1
dx sin(2x)
c. x
g. p dx
2e + 1 x
0 0
Z+1 Z+1
dx ln(x)
d. h. dx
x2 + 2x + 3 1 + 2x2
0 1
Di↵erentiation of Functions of
Several Variables
Definition 3.1. A funtion f of two variables is a mapping taking each pair of two
real numbers (x, y) in D to a unique real number denoted as f (x, y). The set D is
the domain of f and its range is values of f , i.g:
f (x, y)|(x, y) 2 D
Example 3.1. Calculate f (3, 2) and find the domain of these following functions.
p
x+y+1
(a) f (x, y) =
x 1
(b) f (x, y) = x ln(y 2 x)
Solution
(a) p p
3+2+1 6
f (3, 2) = =
3 1 2
The expression f makes sense if the denominator is non-zero and the quantity
under the square root sign is not negative. So the domain of f is:
D = (x, y)|x + y + 1 0, x 6= 1
(b)
f (3, 2) = 3 · ln(22 3) = 3 · ln(1) = 0
39
ADVANCED MATH 2 PhD. Dang Le Quang. Tel. 0764060787
Since ln(y 2 x) is defined if and only if (i↵) y 2 x > 0, i.g, x < y 2 , the domain
of f is:
lim f (x, y) = L
(x,y)!(a,b)
if for all " > 0, there is a corresponding numer > 0 such that if (x, y) 2 D and:
p
0< (x a)2 + (y b)2 < then f (x, y) L <✏
Solution
lim x2 y 3 x3 y 2 + 3x + 2y = 12 · 23 13 · 22 + 3 · 1 + 2 · 2 = 11
(x,y)!(1,2)
x2 y 2
Example 3.3. what points are the function f (x, y) = continuous at ?
x2 + y 2
Solution
f (x + h, y) f (x, y)
fx (x, y) = lim
h!0 h
f (x, y + h) f (x, y)
fy (x, y) = lim
h!0 h
@f @ @z
fx (x, y) = fx = = f (x, y) = = f1 = D1 f = Dx f
@x @x @x
@f @ @z
fy (x, y) = fy = = f (x, y) = = f2 = D2 f = Dy f
@y @y @y
Solution
) fx (2, 1) = 3 · 22 + 2 · 2 · 13 = 16
fy (x, y) = 3x2 y 2 4y
) fy (2, 1) = 3 · 22 · 12 4·1=8
✓ ◆
x @f @f
Example 3.5. If f (x, y) = sin , tı́nh and .
1+y @x @y
Solution
@z @z
Example 3.6. Find and when z is defined as an implicit function with
@x @y
respect to x and y by equation:
x3 + y 3 + z 3 + 6xyz = 1
@z
Find , we find the derivative of the implicit function with respect to x, be careful
@x
when considering y as a constant:
@z @z
3x2 + 3z 2 + 6yz + 6xy =0
@x @x
Solve the equation above, we get:
@z x2 + 2yz
=
@x z 2 + 2xy
Similarly, the implicit function with respect to y is:
@z y 2 + 2xz
=
@y z 2 + 2xy
f (x, y + h, z) f (x, y, z)
fy (x, y, z) = lim
h!0 h
f (x, y, z + h) f (x, y, z)
fz (x, y, z) = lim
h!0 h
and it is found by considering y and z as constants and the derivative f (x, y, z)
a function with respect to x. In general, if u is a function of n variables, u =
f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ), then the partial derivative with respect to the i, xi variable is:
Gii
fx = yexy ln(z)
Similarly,
exy
fy = xexy ln(z) và fz =
z
Let f be a function of two variables, then its partial derivatives fx and fy are also functions
of two variables, so we can find their partial derivatives (fx )x , (fx ))y , (fy )x and (fy )y are
called second partial derivatives of f . Let z = f (x, y), we use the following notations:
✓ ◆
@ @f @ 2f @ 2z
(fx )x = fxx = = =
@x @x @x2 @x2
✓ ◆
@ @f @ 2f @ 2z
(fx )y = fxy = = =
@y @x @y@x @y@x
✓ ◆
@ @f @ 2f @ 2z
(fy )x = fyx = = =
@x @y @x@y @x@y
✓ ◆
@ @f @ 2f @ 2z
(fy )y = fyy = = =
@y @y @y 2 @y 2
@ 2f
Hence the notation f (x, y) or means that we first derive with respect to x and then
@y@x
with respect to y, in contrast to the calculation fyx , first the derivative with respect to y
and then the derivative with respect to x
Example 3.7. Find the second order partial partial derivatives of:
f (x, y) = x3 + x2 y 3 2y 2
Solution
therefore:
@ @
fxx = 3x2 + 2xy 3 = 6x + 2y 3 fxy = 3x2 + 2xy 3 = 6xy 2
@x @y
@ @
fyx = 3x2 y 2 4y = 6xy 2 fyy = 3x2 y 2 4y = 6x2 y 4
@x @y
Theorem 3.1 (Clairaut). Suppose f is defined on a disk D containing the point (a, b).
If the functions fxy and fyx are continuous on D then:
are also di↵erentiable the functions on G ⇢ Rm and have the domain D1 ⇢ D, then we
have the composite function:
a. Find z 0 (t) if x = t2 , y = t3 .
We have:
@z p x
⇣
⇡ @z
⌘
= 2e sin x + y + ; = ex cos(x + y)
@x 4 @y
Using the formula we can calculate:
p 2
⇣ ⇡
⌘ 3
z 0 (t) = 2 2tet sin t2 + t3 + + 3t2 et cos t2 + t3
4
@z @z
b. Find , nu x = ts, y = t + s.
@t @s
@z p is
⇣ ⇡
⌘
= 2se sin ts + t + s + + eis cos(t + s + ts)
@t 4
@z p t
⇣ ⇡
⌘
= 2te sin ts + t + s + + ets cos(ts + t + s)
@s 4
Definition 3.6. Given the function f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) defined and continuous on the set
D ⇢ Rn satisfying:
n o
D= X (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) 2 R : ai < xi < bi ; ai , bi 2 R, i = 1, 2, . . . , n
n
We say the function f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) reaches a local maximum (local minimum) at the
point X = x1 , x2 , . . . , xn 2 D if there exists a neighborhood S X, r ⇢ D (r > 0 is
sufficient small enough) such that:
⇣ ⌘
f x 1 , x2 , . . . , x n f x 1 , x 2 , . . . , x n f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )
Theorem 3.2. If the function f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) is defined, continuous and has partial
derivatives with respect to all the independent variables in D and reaches extreme value (
maximum or minimum) at the point X (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) 2 D then
Theorem 3.3.
@f
(x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = 0, i = 1, 2, . . . , n (3.1)
@xi
It is a necessary condition for a function having extreme points. The point X (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )
satisfying the condition (3.1) is called the stationary point of the function f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ).
From the above theorem we see that the function f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) can only reach its
maximum at stops. However, this is only a necessary condition, not a sufficient condition.
The following sufficient condition will help us to check whether at the stationary point the
function reaches its extreme value or not.
Corollary 3.1. Suppose the function f (x, y) has continuous second partial derivatives at
the point M0 (x0 , y0 ) and the point M0 (x0 , y0 ) is stationary point of the function f (x, y).
We set:
@ 2f @ 2f @ 2f A B
A= (x ,
0 0y ) , B = (x ,
0 0y ) , C = A = (x0 , y0 ) , = = AC B 2
@x2 @x@y @y 2 B C
Then:
8
<A > 0
+ If then M0 (x0 , y0 ) is the minimum point of f (x, y).
: >0
8
<A < 0
+ If then M0 (x0 , y0 ) is the maximum point of the function f (x, y).
: >0
+ If < 0 then M0 (x0 , y0 ) is not a extreme point of the function f (x, y).
+ If = 0, we can not give any conclusion.
Example 3.9. Find the extreme points of the function f (x, y) = x3 + y 3 3xy
Solution
@f @f
= 3x2 3y, = 3y 2 3x
@x @y
@ 2f @ 2f @ 2f
= 6x, = 3, = 6y
@x2 @x@y @y 2
The stationary point of the function f (x, y) is the solution of the system of equations
8
> @f ( ( (
< =0 3x2 3y = 0 x=0 x=1
@x , , _
> @f 3y 2 3x = 0 y=0 y=1
: =0
@y
a) Definition: Given the functions z = f (x, y), '(x, y) are defined and continuous on
the set:
n o
D= M (x, y) 2 R : a < x < b.c < y < d; a, b, c, d 2 R
2
⇢ R2
We say the function z = f (x, y) reaches a local maximum (local minimum) at the point
M0 (x0 , y0 ) with the condition '(x, y) = 0 if there exists a neighborhood S (M0 , r) ⇢
D (r > 0 is small enough) such that f (x, y) f (x0 , y0 ) f (x, y) f (x0 , y0 ) for
every point M (x, y) 2 S (M0 , r right), M 6= M0 and '(M ) = '(x, y) = 0.
From the equation '(x, y) = 0, we have a curve (C). So we only compare f (x0 , y0 )
with f (x, y) when the point M (x, y) lies on (C) only .
b) Necessary condition for extreme value:
Suppose M0 (x0 , y0 ) is the extreme point of the function z = f (x, y) with the condition
'(x, y) = 0 where f (x, y), '(x, y) are functions which have continuous partial deriva-
@'
tives in a neighborhood of the point M0 (x0 , y0 ) and (x0 , y0 ) 6= 0. Then there exists
@y
2 R such that:
8
> @f @'
>
> (x0 , y0 ) + (x0 , y0 ) = 0
>
< @x @x
@f @' (3.2)
> (x 0 , y 0 ) + (x0 , y0 ) = 0
>
> @y @y
>
:
' (x0 , y0 ) = 0
S dc gi là nhân t Lagrange. Hàm L(x, y) = f (x, y) + g(x, y) dc gi là hàm s
Lagrange.
Nh vy, h phng trı̀nh (3.2) có th dc vit li di dng:
8
> @L
>
> (x0 , y0 ) = 0
>
> @x
<
@L
(x0 , y0 ) = 0 (3.3)
>
> @y
>
>
>
: @L
(x0 , y0 ) = 0
@
0 '1 '2
D= '1 L11 L12
'2 L21 L22
Where:
@' @'
'1 = (x0 , y0 ) , '2 = (x0 , y0 )
@x @y
@ 2L @ 2L
L11 = (x ,
0 0 y ) , L12 = (x0 , y0 )
@x2 @x@y
@ 2L @ 2L
L21 = (x0 , y0 ) , L22 = (x0 , y0 )
@y@x @y 2
Theorem 3.5. If D > 0, the point M0 (x0 , y0 ) is the conditional maximum of the
function f (x, y). If D < 0 then the point M0 (x0 , y0 ) is the conditional minimum of
the function f (x, y). If D = 0, there is no conclusion in this situation.
Theorem 3.6. Suppose that X (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) is the extreme point of the function
f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) with the condition that ' (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = 0 where f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) , ' (x1 , x2 , . . .
functions such that their partial derivatives are continuous in a neighborhood of the
This is called the Lagrange’s function. Thus, the system of equations (3.4) can be
rewritten:
8
> @L
< (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = 0; i = 1, 2, . . . , n
@xi (3.6)
>
: @L (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = 0
@
c) Sufficient conditions for extreme values
Suppose (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn , ) is the stationary point of the function L (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn , ),
i.e. a solution of the system of equations (3.6). Assuming the functions f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) , ' (x1 , x2 , .
has continuous second-order partial derivatives at the point X (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ). Then
second-order partial derivatives of the function L (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn , ) exists and it is
also continuous at the point X (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ). We set up the matrices:
2 3
0 '1 '2 ··· 'n
6 7
6 '1 L11 L12 · · · L1n 7
6 7
H=6 '
6 2 L 21 L 22 · · · L 2n 7
7
6 7
4· · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 5
'n Ln1 Ln2 · · · Lnn
Where
@'
'k = x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ; k = 1, 2, . . . , n
@xk
@ 2L
Lij = x1 , x2 , . . . , xn , ; i, j = 1, 2, . . . , n
@xi @xj
We consider these determiners:
Let D be a closed set, bounded in Rn with boundary @D given by the equation '(x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )
that is a continuous function on D. The following is the rule to find the maximum and
minimum value of f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) on D.
+ Find suspicious points that are likely to be extreme value of f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) with the
condition '(x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = 0.
+ Find the stationary points of f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) in D.
+ The maximum (minimum) value of f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) on D is the largest (smallest)
values of the function at the points we had found above.
Example 3.10. Find the maximum and minimum value of the function f (x, y) = x2 +
2y 2 x on the domain D : x2 + y 2 1.
Solution
8
>
<x = 1
@f @f 2
We have = 2x 1; = y. Hence f (x, y) has only one stationary point is ,
@x @y >
: y=0
which belongs to D. Set L(x, y) = x2 + 2y 2 x + (x2 + y 2 1). Solve the system of
equations:
8
> @L
>
> = 2x 1+2 x=0
>
> @x
<
@L
= 4y + 2 y = 0
>
> @y
>
>
>
: @L = x2 + y 2 1 = 0
@
✓ p ✓ p ◆
1 3 1 3
We have the possible points that are ( 1, 0), (1, 0), , bigg), , .
2 2 2 2
Finding the values of f (x, y) at these points we have:
✓ ◆ ✓ p ◆
1 1 1 3 9
min f = f ,0 = ; max f = f ,± =
D 2 4 D 2 2 4
APPLICATIONS FUNCTIONS OF
MULTIPLE VARIABLES IN
ECONOMY
1 3
Example 4.1. Assume that the production function of a firm is Q = 20K 4 L 4 where
K, L, Q are capital usage, labor usage, and daily quantity of products respectively. Assume
that the firm is using 16 units of output and 81 units of labor in one day i.e K = 16;
55
ADVANCED MATH 2 PhD. Dang Le Quang. Tel. 0764060787
L = 81. Determine the marginal product of capital and labor at that point and explain
the meaning of them?
Solution
Example 4.2. Suppose a consumer’s daily consumption function for two goods is U =
3 1
2x12 x12 .Where x1 , x2 are the units of good 1 and good 2, U is the daily utility. Assume that
a consumer is consuming 64 units of good 1 and 25 units of good 2 in a day. Determine
the marginal utility of the goods at that point and explain the meaning of it?
Solution
That is, if a consumer increases his use of good 1 by one unit from 64 to 65 and keeps
his consumption of good 2 the same per day, the utility increases by 60 units. Similarly,
if the use of good 1 is kept the same and the usage of good 2 is increased by one unit from
25 to 26 per day, the utility increases by about 102.4 units.
Example 4.3. Suppose the demand function for good 1 in the market for two related
goods has the form:
5 2
Q1d = 6300 2p21 p
3 2
Where p1 , p2 is the price of goods 1,2, respectively. Determine the price elasticity of
demand p1 for the price of that good at (p1 , p2 ) and determine the price elasticity of
demand p1 for the price of the second good p2 at (p1 , p2 ) and explain the meaning of this
at the point (p1 , p2 ) = (20, 30).
Solution
The price elasticity of demand p1 for the price of that good at (p1 , p2 ):
p1
"Q
p1 =
1d
4p1 ·
5 2
6300 2p21 p
3 2
Price elasticity of demand p1 for the price of the second good p2 at (p1 , p2 ):
10 p2
"Q
p2 =
1d
p2 ·
3 5 2
6300 2p21 p
3 2
In economics, the law of diminishing marginal utility says: the value of z – the marginal
value of the variable x decreases as x increases and y remains constant. Similarly, the
value of z – the marginal value of the variable y decreases gradually as y increases and
x remains constant (note: we consider in terms of the value of the variables x, y large
enough). The mathematical basis is:
@z @f @ 2z @ 2f
+ = (x, y) is a decreasing function when = (x, y) < 0.
@x @x @x2 @x2
@z @f @ 2z @ 2f
+ = (x, y) is a decreasing function when = (x, y) < 0.
@y @y @y 2 @y 2
Example 4.4. The production function of a firm of the Cobb-Douglas’ form is as follows:
Q = aK ↵ L (↵, > 0)
Find the condition of ↵, > 0 so that the above function obeys the law of diminishing
marginal utility.
Solution
@Q
Marginal product function of capital: = a↵K ↵ 1L .
@K
@Q
The marginal product function of labor: = a K ↵L 1.
@L
Manifestations of the law of diminishing marginal utility are:
8
> @ 2Q 8
>
< = a↵(↵ 1)K ↵ 2L <0 <↵ < 1
@K 2
)
> 2 : <1
:@ Q =a (
> 1)K ↵ L 2 <0
@L2
8
<0 < ↵ < 1
So the conditions are .
:0 < <1
1 3
Apply to specific problem with production function Q = 20K 4 L 4 where K, Q, L is the
level capital use, labor use, and daily output. This function satisfies the law of diminishing
marginal utility.
@f @f @f
f is a homogeneous function of degree k , x1 + x2 + . . . + xn =k·f
@x1 @x2 @xn
Q = Q0 , aK ↵ L = Q0
U = U0 , ax↵ y = U0
is called the equation of the indi↵erence curve at the point (x0 , y0 ). The slope (or slope)
of that line at the point (x0 , y0 ) is equal to:
@U
dy (x0 , y0 )
(x0 , y0 ) = @x
dx @U
(x0 , y0 )
@y
Example 4.10. A household has the following consumption utility function for two goods:
Where x is the number of units of goods 1, y is the number of units of goods 2 (x, y > 0)
. At the point (x0 , y0 ) = (32, 32) write the equation of the indi↵erence curve, determine
the slope of that line and explain the meaning of it.
SOlution
U0 = 5 · 320.4 · 320.4 = 80
U = U0 , x0.4 y 0.4 16 = 0
F x, y(x) = 0, 8x 2 (a, b)
F x, y(x) = x + (1 x) 1 = 0, 8x 2 R
p
So, we say the equation x + y 3 1 = 0 defines the function 3
1 x as a implicit
function in R. In this example, the implicit function can be represented as the
p
explicit function y = 3 1 x.
Example 4.12. Given the equation F (x, y) = x2 + y 2 1 = 0.
p
For each x 2 [ 1, 1], there are two values y = ± 1 x2 making F (x, y) = 0 so
this equation doesn’t define any implicit function. In many cases, although we can
show that the equation F (x, y) = 0 defines a function y = y(x), we can not express
y with respect to x directly. In these cases, we must consider the function y = y(x)
indirectly as the equation F (x, y). The notation y = y(x) only has a formal meaning
to say that y is a function of the variable x.
b) The implicit function theorem Suppose the function F (x, y) is defined, continu-
ous and has continuous partial derivatives in a neighborhood of the point M0 (x0 , y0 )
and at M0 (x0 , y0 ), it satisfies the following conditions:
@F
F (x0 , y0 ) = 0; (x0 , y0 ) 6= 0
@y
Then:
+ There exists > 0 such that the equation F (x, y) = 0 defines a function:
y = y(x), 8x 2 (x0 , x0 + )
+ y(x0 ) = y0
+ The function y = y(x) has a continuous derivative on the interval (x0 , x0 + ).
c) Derivatives of implicit function
The above theorem states the existence of the implicit function defined by the equation
F (x, y) = 0 and the derivatives of the implicit function (when the conditions of the
theorem are satisfied). Thus, to calculate the derivatives of an implicit function (when
the derivatives exist), we just need to apply the rule for calculating the derivative of
the composite functions F x, y(x) = 0.
Assume the function y = y(x) is an implicit function defined by the equation F (x, y) =
0 then:
F x, y(x) = 0, 8x 2 (x0 , x0 + )
@F @F
(x, y) + (x, y)y 0 (x) = 0
@x @y
@F
@F (x, y)
Since (x, y) 6= 0 then y 0 (x) = @x
@y @F
(x, y)
@y
Example 4.13. Consider the implicit function from the equation 2x2 + y 2 1 = 0.
We have F (x, y) = 2x2 + y 2 1 = 0. Therefore:
@F
(x, y) 4x 2x
y 0 (x) = @x = =
@F 2y y
(x, y)
@y
@f
f = @t
f
Normally f is scaled by %.
F Properties
Solution
1
K0 4 1
K = = =
K 1 8+t
2+ t
4
the Growth rate of labour is:
1
L0 6 1
L = = =
L 1 18 + t
3+ t
6
Gii
Assume that Q1 , Q2 is the outputs of the first and second products of the firm. To
sell all that amount of products, the factory must sell at the price P1 , P2 such that:
8 8
< 5P P2 = 1230 14Q1 < P = 360 3Q1 Q2
1 1
,
: P1 3P2 = 14Q2 1350 : P2 = 570 Q1 5Q2
The revenue is :
⇡=R C= 3Q21 5Q22 2Q1 Q2 + 360Q1 + 570Q2 Q21 + Q1 Q2 + Q22 = 4Q21 6Q22
@ 2⇡ @ 2⇡ @ 2⇡
= 8, = 3, = 12 ) A = 8, B = 3, C = 12
@Q21 @Q1 @Q2 @Q22
(
= AC B 2 = ( 8)( 12) ( 3)2 = 87 > 0
A= 8<0
⇡=R C = PQ wL rK
1 1
⇡ = 3L 3 K 3 L 0, 02K
@⇡ 2 1 @⇡ 1 2
= L 3 K 3 1; = L3 K 3 0, 02
@L @K
@ 2⇡ 2 5 1 @ 2⇡ 1 2 2 @ 2⇡ 2 1 5
= L 3K3; = L 3 K 3 ; = L3 K 3
@L2 3 @K@L 3 @K 2 3
get L = 50, K = 2500. Consider second order partial derivatives at the stationary
points (L0 , K0 ) = (50, 2500).
1 1 1 A B 1
A= < 0, B = , C= , = >0
75 7500 187500 B C 18750000
Example 4.17. Given a consumer utility function for two goods U (x, y) = x0,4 y 0.6
where x is the unit of good 1, y is a unit of good 2 (x, y > 0). Assume that the prices
of the goods are 2and3, respectively, and the consumer’s income is 130. Determine
the quantity demanded of each good so that the consumer gets the maximum benefit.
• Step 1: Find the maximum of the function U with the condition 2x + 3y = 130.
• Step 2: Write the Lagrange’s Function L(x, y, ) = x0,4 y 0.6 + (2x + 3y 130)
• Step 3: Solve the system of equations:
8 8 8
> @L
>
> =0 >
> x 0,6 y 0,6 =5 >
> x = 40
>
> @x >
> >
>
< < <
@L 10 y = 60
=0 , x0,4 y 0,4 = ,
>
> @y >
> 3 >
> ⇣ 3 ⌘0,6
>
> >
> >
> 1
>
: @L : 2x + 3y = 130 : =
=0 5 2
@
✓ ⇣ 3 ⌘0,6 ◆
1
It leads that the stationary point is M = 40, 60,
5 2
@' @'
'1 = = 2; '2 = =3
@x @y
0 2 3
0 2
D1 = 3 L11 L12 > 0; D2 = = 4<0
2 L11
3 L21 L22
SERIES, DIFFERENTIAL
EQUATION AND DIFFERENCE
EQUATION
5.1. Series
If the sequence {sn } converges and lim sn = s exists as a real number, then one says
X n!1
that the series an is convergent and we write:
1
X
a1 + a2 + . . . + an + . . . = s or an = s
n=1
The number s is called the sum of the series. If the sequence {sn } diverges then the series
is divergent.
1
X
Example 5.1. Assume that we know the nth partial sums of the series: an that is:
n=1
2n
s n = a1 + a2 + . . . + an =
3n + 5
70
ADVANCED MATH 2 PhD. Dang Le Quang. Tel. 0764060787
Then the sum of the series is equal to the limit of the sequence {sn }:
1
X 2n 2 2
an = lim sn = lim = lim =
n!1 n!1 3n + 5 n!1 5 3
n=1 3+
n
Definition 5.2 (Geometric series). A geometric series is defined as follows :
1
X
arn 1
= a + ar + ar2 + . . .
n=1
10 20 40
5 + + ...
3 9 27
Solution
The first term is a = 5 and the ratio of each two consecutive terms is r = 2/3. Since
|r| = 2/3 < 1, the series in convergent and its sum is:
10 20 40 5
5 + + ... = 2
=3
3 9 27 1 3
1
X
Example 5.3. Find the sum of the series xn , where |x| < 1.
n=0
Solution
This is a geometric series with a = 1 and r = x. Since |r| = |x| < 1 the series is
convergent:
1
X 1
xn =
1 x
n=0
1
X
Theorem 5.1. If the series an is convergent then lim an = 0.
n!1
n=1
P
Proof. Gi sn = a1 + a2 + . . . + an . Khi dó an = sn sn 1. Vı̀ an hi t nên dãy {sn }
cũng hi t. Cho lim sn = s. Vı̀ n 1 ! 1 khi n ! 1 nên ta cũng có lim sn 1 = s.
n!1 n!1
Therefore
Theorem 5.2 (Divergence test). If lim an does not exist, or if lim an 6= 0, the series
n!1
1
X
an is divergent.
n=1
1
X n2
Example 5.4. Prove that the series is divergent.
5n2 + 4
n=1
Solution
We have:
n2 1 1
lim an = lim = lim = 6= 0
n!1 n!1 5n2 + 4 n!1 5 + 4/n2 5
Definition 5.3. alternating series is a series in which the positive terms and negative
terms appear alternatively. Here are two examples of alternating series:
X 1
1 1 1 1 1 11
1 + + + ... = ( 1)n
2 3 4 5 6 n
n=1
1
X
1 2 3 4 5 6 n
+ + + ... = ( 1)n
2 3 4 5 6 7 n+1
n=1
From the above example, we can see that the nth term of a series has the form:
an = ( 1)n 1
bn an = ( 1)n bn
where bn is a positive number.
Theorem 5.4 (Divergence conditions). If the alternating series :
1
X
( 1)n 1
bn = b1 b2 + b3 b4 + b5 b6 + . . . bn > 0
n=1
satisfies:
is called a Power series in the domain (x a) or a Power series having the central
point at a or a Power series in the neighborhood of a.
1
X
Example 5.7. What values of x are the series n!xn convergent at?
n=0
Solution
an+1 (n + 1)!xn+1
lim = lim = lim (n + 1)|x| = 1
n!1 an n!1 n!xn n!1
So the series above is divergent when x 6= 0. In other words, the series is only convergent
when x = 0.
1
X
Theorem 5.5. With a given power series cn (x a)n , There areare only three possi-
n=0
bilities exist
Watch out. The number R in the case of (??) is called radius of convergence of
the power series.
Example 5.8. Find the radius of convergence and the range of convergence of the series:
1
X ( 3)n X n
p
n+1
n=0
Solution
p
Set an = ( 3)n xn / n + 1. Then:
p r
an+1 ( 3)n+1 xn+1 n+1 n+1
= p · = 3x
an n+2 ( 3)n xn n+2
r
1 + (1/n)
=3 |x| ! 3|x| khi n ! 1
1 + (2/n)
According to the ratio criteria, the given series converges if 3|x| < 1 and diverges if
3|x| > 1. So the series is convergent if |x| < 1/3 and is divergent if |x| > 1/3. This
means that the radius of convergence of the series is R = 1/3.
Considering x = 1/3, the series becomes:
1
X 1 n 1
X
( 3)n 3 1 1 1 1 1
p = p = p + p + p + p + ···
n+1 n+1 1 2 3 4
n=0 n=0
and it is convergent according to the alternating series conditions. So the range of con-
vergence of the series is ( 1/3.1/3].
y 0 = xy
Example 5.9. Prove that each member of the following family of functions:
1 + cet
y=
1 cet
1
is a solution of the di↵erential equation y 0 = (y 2 1).
2
Solution
1 4cet 2cet
= =
2 (1 cet )2 (1 cet )2
So, for each value of c, the given function is a solution of the di↵erential equation.
dy
Where y 0 = , g is a function that depends only on the variable y; f is a function
dx
that depends only on the independent variable x and f (x), g(y) is continuous (phn
s???) on some interval (a, b). The method of solving Separate-factor equations is to
integrate (indefinite integral) both sides of the equation (5.1). Equation (5.1) is of the
form:
g(y) · y 0 (x)dx = f (x)dx
b) Separable equation
⇤ Consider a di↵erential equation of the form:
g1 (y) f2 (x)
dy = dx
g2 (y) f1 (x)
Watch out:
Method:
y
• Step 1:Set t = and consider t as a function with respect to x. We have:
x
y = tx ) y 0 = t + xt0 .
• Step 2: Substituting this into the equation, we have:
y 0 + p(x)y = 0
dy
= p(x)y (5.6)
dx
If y 6= 0, then dividing both sides of (5.6) by y we have:
dy
= p(x)dx
y
R
p(x)dx
Hay y = Ce , (C 6= 0) (5.7)
- Step 2: Find the general solution of the equation (5.7) of the form:
R
p(x)dx
y = C(x)e
Z !
R R
Hay y = e p(x)dx
q(x)e p(x)dx
dx + C (C 2 R) (5.11)
e) Bernoulli’s equation
a Bernoulli’s equation is the di↵erntial equation of the form:
With p(x), q(x) are continuous functions on some (a, b) interval and ↵ 6= 0, ↵ 6= 1.
Method: Assuming y 6= 0, multiplying both sides of the equation (5.12) by y ↵ we get:
↵ 0
y y + p(x)y 1 ↵
= q(x) (5.13)
z 0 + (1 ↵)p(x)z = (1 ↵)q(x)
Watch out:
+ We see that y = 0 is also a solution of the equation (5.13) when ↵ > 0.
+ When ↵ > 1 then y = 0 is a general solution.
+ When 0 < ↵ < 1 then y = 0 is a singular solution.
f ) Exact equation a exact equations is the di↵erential equation of the form
du = 0 or u(x, y) = C
So, solving the equation above becomes finding a function of two variables u(x, y) such
@u @u
that = f (x, y), = g(x, y). There are two ways to solve this equation:
@x @y
1. Method 1: Z Z
@u
• Integrate both sides by the variable x : dx = f (x, y)dx (consider y as
@x
a constant). Z
• Suppose that we have: u(x, y) = f (x, y)dx + C(y).
@u
• Take the derivative of both sides and substitute into the expression =
@y
g(x, y). From here we find the function C(y). Z
• So the general solution of the equation is u(x, y) = f (x, y)dx + C(y).
2. Method 2: Since du = f (x, y)dx + g(x, y)dy, so:
Zx Zy
u(x, y) = f (x, y)dy + g(x0 , y)dy
x0 y0
Zx Zy
Hay u(x, y) = f (x, y0 )dy + g(x, y)dy
x0 y0
a) Di↵erence
Given the function y = f (x) defined on the set D = x 0 , x1 , x2 , . . . , x n , . . . with
xi < xi+1 (8i). Assume x < x⇤ are two consecutive values of D. Set h = x x⇤ or
x⇤ = x + h. We call hy = h f (x) = f (x + h) f (x) the di↵erence of the function
f at x.
2
h f (x) = h( h (f (x)))
= h (f (x + h) f (x))
= (f (x + h + h) f (x + h) f (x + h) + f (x))
= f (x + 2h) 2f (x + h) + f (x)
is the second order di↵erence of function f at x. Similarly, we have the n order
di↵erence of the function f at x, denoted by n f (x)
h
The solutions of the equation (5.15) are functions y = y(x) defined on the set of
integer values D such that every x 2 D has F x, yx , yx , . . . , ny = 0. The
x
equation (5.15) can be converted to the equivalent form x, yx , yx+1 , . . . , yx+n =
0.
Example 5.11. Consider the following examples:
a. The di↵erence equation yx = 2 can be written as yx+1 yx = 2.
b. The di↵erence equation yx = 0.1y can be written as yx+1 yx = 0.1yx or
yx+1 0.9yx = 0.
a) iterative method
A first order di↵erence equation is a recursively defined sequence in the form
y1 = f (0, y0 )
y2 = f (0, y1 )
...
We find yx with x = 0, 1, 2, . . ..
Example 5.12. Consider the following examples:
a) Solve the equation y = 2, y(0) = y0 . We have yx+1 yx = 2 or yx+1 = yx + 2.
From that:
y1 = y0 + 2
y2 = y1 + 2 = (y0 + 2) + 2 = y0 + 2.2
y3 = y2 + 2 = (y0 + 2.2) + 2 = y0 + 3.2
...
yx = y0 + x.2, x = 0, 1, 2, . . .
b) Find the solution of the equation y= 0.1y, y(0) = y0 . We have yx+1 = 0.9yx .
Therefore:
y1 = 0, 9y0
y2 = 0, 9y1 = (0, 9)2 y0
...
yx = (0, 9)x y0 , x = 0, 1, 2, . . .
b) Linear di↵erence equation of first order with constant coefficients
Consider the equation:
b
+ If a 6= 1 then an eigenvalue of (5.17) is yx = . Hence, the general solution
1+a
b
of (5.17) is yx = C( a)x + .
1+a
+ If a = 1 then an eigenvalue of (5.17) is yx = bx. Thus, the general solution of
(5.17) is yx = C( 1)x + bx = C + bx.
a) Cobweb’s model
The execution of a production plan often takes time. When deciding on a production
plan, the producer must base it on current market prices, but the commodities will
only be sold in the next period. This means that the quantity supplied at the time t + 1
depends on the time t.
If the product price is p, the quantity supplied is QS , and the quantity demanded is
QD , the market equilibrium model is of the form:
8
>
< QD,t+1 = QS,t+1
>
QD,t+1 = a bpt+1 vi a, b, c, d là các hng s dng
>
>
:
QS,t+1 = c + dpt+1
a+c
⇣ a+c
⌘ ✓ d ◆t
pt = + p0
b+d b+d b
a+c
Let p = be the temporary equilibrium price. Then the solution of (5.19) is:
b+d
✓ ◆t
d
pt = p + (p0 p) (5.20)
b
We call (5.20) the trajectory in time. From (5.20) we see:
+ When p0 6= p the market price’s trajectory over time fluctuates around the equi-
librium price p.
+ The steady-state condition for the equilibrium price is d < b. If d > b then the
time trajectory of the price is further and further away from the equilibrium price.
b) Harrod’s model
The Harrod’s model is used to explain the dynamics of growth in the economy. As-
sumptions of the model:
+ Saving in each period is proportional to the income of the same period: St = sYt ,
s is a constant, 0 < s < 1 is called the marginal propensity to save.
+ Investment is proportional to the rate of change of national income over time:
Ii = a (Yt Yt 1) , a >0
[1] NGUYN TH TOÀN. Lý thuyt toán cao cp 1. NXB Thông tin và truyn thông,
năm 2012.
[2] PHÙNG DUY QUANG. Bài tp toán cao cp 1. NXB Thông tin và truyn thông,
năm 2012..
[3] LÊ SĨ DNG. Toán cao cp (phn gii tı́ch). NXB Giáo dc, năm 2007.
[4] LÊ THANH CNG. Bài tp Toán cao cp - hc phn II. NXB Giáo dc, năm 1998.
[5] LÊ DÌNH THÚY. Toán cao cp cho các nhà kinh t (Phn I, II). NXB Di hc Kinh
T Quc Dân, năm 2013.
[6] NGUYN DÌNH TRÍ. Toán cao cp (Tp 1, Tp 2, Tp 3). NXB Giáo dc, năm 2008.
[7] PHÙNG DUY QUANG. Hng dn gii bài tp Toán c s ng dng trong phân tı́ch kinh
t. NXB Thông tin và truyn thông, năm 2012.
[8] http: // khoacoban. ftu. edu. vn
[9] Gilbert Strang. Introduction to Linear Algebra, Fifth Edition. Massachusetts
Institute of Technology, 2016.
[10] Nathaniel Johnston. Introduction to Linear and Matrix Algebra 1st ed.
Springer, 2021.
85