Environmental Economics Notes
Environmental Economics Notes
Environmental Economics Notes
Economy-Environment inter-linkages
Environment and economy are like two wheels of a bike that need to be driven
together for the growth of a nation. Many renowned economists believe that a better
environment helps a lot in strengthening the economy of the country. However both
Environment and economy are equally important for a nation and also they are
Dr. K. CHITHAMBARAIAH SETTY., HOD, EEE EEE Dept, SJCET, Yemmiganur.
(20A01605) ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS III-II EEE
2
Limits to growth
(1) Population explosion
(2) Rise in economic activity
(3) Rapid industrialization
(4) Urbanisation
(5) Deforestation
(6) Increased use of insecticides, pesticides, and chemical fertilizers.
The Environmental Kuznets Curve
The environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) is a hypothesized relationship between
various indicators of environmental degradation and per capita income. In the early stages of
economic growth, pollution emissions increase and environmental quality declines, but
beyond some level of per capita income (which will vary for different indicators) the trend
reverses, so that at high income levels, economic growth leads to environmental
improvement. This implies that environmental impacts or emissions per capita are an inverted
U-shaped function of per capita income. Fig. 1 shows an example of an estimated EKC. The
EKC is named after Simon Kuznets who proposed that income inequality first rises and then
falls as economic development proceeds.
The EKC has been the dominant approach among economists to modeling ambient
pollution concentrations and aggregate emissions since Grossman and Krueger (1991)
introduced it.
3. Nutrition questions
Why should we regional and seasonal feed?
Is the plant-based diet the diet of the future?
Will we soon be eating only artificial meat?
What if the whole world vegan would be?
4. Society questions
5. Mobility issues
Are car-free cities the future?
Will we only drive electrically in the future?
Do we need a speed limit on the highway?
6. Tourism issues
Can Tourism sustainable be?
How can the Mass tourism regulate?
7. Consumption questions
Should free online deliveries be banned?
Does a ban on firecrackers and New Year's Eve rockets make sense?
Should throwing away food be banned?
Dr. K. CHITHAMBARAIAH SETTY., HOD, EEE EEE Dept, SJCET, Yemmiganur.
(20A01605) ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS III-II EEE
5
Nonrenewable energy
Nonrenewable energy resources include coal, natural gas, oil, and nuclear energy.
Once these resources are used up, they cannot be replaced, which is a major problem for
humanity as we are currently dependent on them to supply most of our energy needs.
SCARCITY
Nonrenewable energy resources include coal, natural gas, oil, and nuclear energy.
Once these resources are used up, they cannot be replaced, which is a major problem for
humanity as we are currently dependent on them to supply most of our energy needs.
Optimal Resources
Renewable energy is energy derived from natural sources that are replenished at a
higher rate than they are consumed. Sunlight and wind, for example, are such sources that are
constantly being replenished.
Backstop Technology
Property Research
Externalities
UNIT II
Environmental Degradation:
Economic significance
The basic theory underpinning environmental economics is that environmental
amenities (or environmental goods) have economic value and there are costs to economic
growth that are not accounted for in more traditional models.
Environmental goods include things like access to clean water, clean air, the survival
of wildlife, and the general climate. Although it is hard to put a price tag on environmental
goods, there may be a high cost when they are lost.
Destruction or overuse of environmental goods, like pollution and other kinds of
environmental degradation, can represent a form of market failure because it imposes
negative externalities. Environmental economists analyze the costs and benefits of specific
economic policies that seek to correct such problems, and they may run theoretical tests or
studies on the possible consequences of these policies.
Causes Of Environmental Degradation
Externality
Market Failure
because the poor, who rely on natural resources more than the rich, deplete
natural resources faster as they have no real prospects of gaining access to
other types of resources.
Urbanisation:
Lack of opportunities for gainful employment in villages and the
ecological stresses is leading to an ever increasing movement of poor
families to towns.
2. Economic Factors
To a large extent, environmental degradation is the result of market failure.
The level and pattern of economic development also affect the nature of
environmental problems.
Transport activities have a wide variety of effects on the environment such
as air pollution, noise from road traffic and oil spills from marine shipping.
Direct impacts of agricultural development on the environment arise from
farming activities which contribute to soil erosion, land salination and loss
of nutrients.
3. Institutional Factors
The Ministry of Environment & Forests (MOEF) in the Government is
responsible for protection, conservation and development of environment.
The weakness of the existing system because of mis-co ordination between
both central and the state.
Equi –marginal principle
The equi-marginal principle states that a consumer will be maximizing his total utility
when he allocates his fixed money income in such a way that the utility derived from the last
unit of money spent on each good is equal.
Example:
The above four agricultural farms are in the total 80 acres, each farm in the 20 acres,
all together 80 acres. The farmer is having limited 80 employees with him for employing in
the four farms for production. In general, 80 employees are divided and employed for four
farms evenly as each farm will be allotted with 20 employees. However, in reality there is no
need to allot 20 employees for each farm, because mango farm need less number of
employees, whereas paddy farm needs more number of employees. Sugarcane and corn farms
require average number of employees. Like shown below
UNIT - III
Economics of Pollution:
Economics of Pollution
Pollution is an example of a negative externality. Economic production can cause
environmental damage. This tradeoff arises for all countries, whether high-income or
low-income, and whether their economies are market-oriented or command-oriented.
An externality, sometimes called a spillover, occurs when an exchange between a
buyer and seller has an impact on a third party who is not part of the exchange.
Externalities can be positive or negative.
Market failure is when the market does not allocate resources on its own efficiently in
a way that balances social costs and benefits; externalities are one example of a
market failure.
Social costs are costs that include both the private costs incurred by firms and also
additional external costs incurred by third parties outside the production process.
Economics Of Optimal Pollution, Regulation, Monitoring And Enforcement
Monitoring and enforcement are critical components of any pollution control policy.
Monitoring ensures that firms comply with environmental regulations or market-
based instruments, while enforcement ensures that there are consequences for non-
compliance. The costs of monitoring and enforcement can be significant, but they are
necessary to ensure that pollution control policies are effective.
Ultimately, the choice of pollution control policy depends on a variety of factors,
including the nature of the pollution problem, the technologies available to reduce
pollution, and the political and social context in which policies are implemented. An
optimal pollution control policy should balance the costs and benefits of different
approaches to achieve the most efficient and effective pollution control outcome.
Managing Pollution Using Existing Markets: Bargaining Solutions
UNIT IV
Cost – Benefit Analysis:
Economic Value Of Environmental Resources And Environmental Damage
The economic value of environmental resources refers to the benefits that people derive
from natural resources and ecosystems, such as clean air and water, fertile soil, biodiversity,
and recreational opportunities. These benefits are often categorized as either use values or
non-use values.
Use values refer to the direct economic benefits that people receive from environmental
resources. For example, forests can provide timber and non-timber forest products, while
wetlands can help to reduce flood damage and provide habitat for fish and wildlife that
support commercial and recreational fishing.
Non-use values refer to the indirect benefits that people derive from environmental
resources, even if they never use them directly. For example, people may place a value on
knowing that endangered species are protected, even if they never see or interact with those
species themselves.
On the other hand, environmental damage refers to the costs associated with the
degradation or destruction of natural resources and ecosystems. Environmental damage can
result from pollution, deforestation, habitat destruction, and other forms of human activity
that degrade the quality of the environment.
The economic cost of environmental damage can be significant, as it can lead to health
problems, reduced productivity, and decreased quality of life for individuals and
communities. In addition, environmental damage can have a negative impact on businesses
and industries that rely on natural resources, such as tourism, agriculture, and fishing.
Overall, understanding the economic value of environmental resources and the costs of
environmental damage is important for making informed decisions about how to manage
natural resources and promote sustainable development. By taking into account the economic
value of environmental resources, policymakers can make better-informed decisions about
how to balance economic development with environmental protection.
Concept of Total Economic Value
The concept of Total Economic Value (TEV) is a framework for evaluating the economic
value of natural resources and ecosystems, which takes into account both use and non-use
values. TEV is a way of assessing the economic benefits that people derive from
environmental resources, and the costs associated with the degradation or loss of those
resources.
TEV is typically divided into two categories:
1. Use values: These are the direct economic benefits that people receive from
natural resources and ecosystems, such as the production of food, timber, and
other goods, as well as the provision of recreational opportunities.
2. Non-use values: These are the indirect economic benefits that people receive from
environmental resources, such as the value placed on biodiversity and the
existence of endangered species.
TEV is a useful tool for decision-makers who need to weigh the economic benefits of
natural resource use against the costs of environmental degradation. For example, a TEV
analysis might be used to compare the economic value of logging a forest with the economic
value of preserving it for its recreational, ecological, and aesthetic values.
By taking into account both use and non-use values, TEV provides a more comprehensive
picture of the economic value of natural resources and ecosystems than traditional economic
analyses that focus solely on use values. This can help policymakers make more informed
decisions about how to manage natural resources in a sustainable and socially responsible
way, balancing economic development with environmental protection.
Alternative approaches to valuation
While the Total Economic Value (TEV) approach is a useful tool for evaluating the
economic value of natural resources and ecosystems, it has some limitations. For example, it
can be difficult to accurately measure non-use values, and the values assigned to natural
resources may not reflect their cultural, spiritual, or ecological significance to local
communities.
As a result, there are alternative approaches to valuation that can provide a more nuanced
and comprehensive understanding of the value of natural resources and ecosystems. Some of
these approaches include:
1. Ecological economics: This is an interdisciplinary field of study that seeks to
integrate economic, social, and ecological considerations in the analysis of
environmental issues. Ecological economics emphasizes the importance of
recognizing the biophysical limits of the planet and the need to develop economic
systems that are more equitable and sustainable.
2. Deliberative valuation: This approach involves engaging stakeholders in a
process of dialogue and deliberation to develop a shared understanding of the
value of natural resources and ecosystems. Deliberative valuation seeks to
incorporate the perspectives of local communities, indigenous peoples, and other
stakeholders who may have a different understanding of the value of natural
resources than mainstream economic models.
3. Biocultural valuation: This approach recognizes the interconnectedness of
cultural and ecological diversity and seeks to value natural resources and
ecosystems based on their cultural significance as well as their ecological
function. Biocultural valuation emphasizes the importance of local knowledge and
traditional ecological knowledge in the management of natural resources and
ecosystems.
Overall, these alternative approaches to valuation can provide a more nuanced and
holistic understanding of the value of natural resources and ecosystems, and can help to
promote more sustainable and socially responsible management of natural resources.
Cost-Benefit Analysis And Discounting
Cost-benefit analysis (CBA) is a method used to evaluate the economic efficiency of a
project or policy by comparing the expected costs and benefits of different alternatives. The
objective of CBA is to determine whether the benefits of a project or policy outweigh its
costs.
One important consideration in CBA is the time frame over which costs and benefits will
be incurred. Since costs and benefits may occur at different points in time, it is necessary to
account for the time value of money through a process called discounting.
Discounting is the process of reducing the value of future costs and benefits to their
present value. This is necessary because money has a time value - that is, a dollar received in
the future is worth less than a dollar received today, due to factors such as inflation,
opportunity costs, and risk.
Discounting is typically done using a discount rate, which is a percentage that represents
the rate of return that could be earned if the money were invested elsewhere. The discount
rate reflects the time preference of society - that is, how much society values consumption
today versus consumption in the future.
By discounting future costs and benefits, CBA allows for a comparison of costs and
benefits that occur at different points in time. This is important for making decisions about
projects or policies that have long-term consequences, such as infrastructure investments,
environmental regulations, or public health interventions.
However, there is ongoing debate about the appropriate discount rate to use in CBA, as
well as about the ethical implications of discounting future costs and benefits. Critics argue
that discounting can lead to decisions that prioritize short-term benefits over long-term risks,
and that it may not reflect the values of future generations who will be affected by current
decisions. As a result, some experts have proposed alternative methods for evaluating the
economic efficiency of projects or policies that take a longer-term perspective, such as
intergenerational discounting or sustainability analysis.
UNIT V
Economics of biodiversity:
Economics Of Biodiversity Conservation
The economics of biodiversity conservation is an emerging field that seeks to
understand the economic benefits of preserving biodiversity and the costs of its loss.
Biodiversity is important for a variety of reasons, including its role in maintaining ecosystem
services such as pollination, nutrient cycling, and water purification. Biodiversity is also a
source of cultural, spiritual, and recreational value.
There are several economic tools that can be used to promote biodiversity conservation,
including:
Payments for ecosystem services (PES): These are payments made to landowners or
communities in exchange for maintaining or improving the ecological services
provided by their land. PES schemes can provide economic incentives for
conservation and can help to ensure that the costs of conservation are shared fairly
across society.
Market-based instruments: These are economic tools such as taxes, subsidies, and
tradable permits that are designed to internalize the costs of environmental
degradation and incentivize environmentally-friendly behavior. Market-based
instruments can help to create a more level playing field for sustainable business
practices and can encourage innovation in biodiversity conservation.
Valuation methods: Economic valuation methods, such as the Total Economic Value
(TEV) approach discussed earlier, can be used to quantify the economic benefits of
biodiversity conservation. Valuation can help to make the economic benefits of
conservation more visible and can support decision-making processes that take
biodiversity conservation into account.
effective and sustainable approaches to biodiversity conservation that promote both economic
and ecological well-being.
Valuing Individual Species And Diversity Of Species
Valuing individual species and diversity of species is an important aspect of the
economics of biodiversity conservation.
Valuing individual species involves assessing the economic and non-economic
benefits that a particular species provides. These benefits can include direct use values, such
as the value of a species as a source of food or medicine, as well as non-use values, such as
the value of a species for its cultural or spiritual significance. The value of a species may also
be assessed in terms of its contribution to ecosystem services, such as pollination, nutrient
cycling, and pest control. By valuing individual species, it is possible to develop targeted
conservation strategies that focus on the species that are most important for ecological and
economic well-being.
Valuing the diversity of species involves assessing the economic and non-economic
benefits of maintaining a diverse array of species within an ecosystem. Biodiversity is
important for maintaining ecosystem services and for promoting ecological resilience in the
face of environmental change. The value of biodiversity may also be assessed in terms of its
cultural and aesthetic value, as well as its potential for scientific discovery and innovation. By
valuing the diversity of species, it is possible to develop conservation strategies that prioritize
the maintenance of biodiversity as a whole.
There are a variety of economic tools and approaches that can be used to value
individual species and the diversity of species. These include economic valuation methods
such as the Total Economic Value (TEV) approach, as well as ecological modeling and other
tools that can help to assess the ecological importance of different species within an
ecosystem. By combining these tools and approaches, it is possible to develop more effective
and sustainable conservation strategies that take into account the economic and ecological
value of individual species and the diversity of species as a whole.
Policy Responses At National And International Levels
Biodiversity conservation is a global challenge that requires policy responses at both
national and international levels.
At the national level, governments can use a variety of policy tools to promote
biodiversity conservation, such as:
STERN REPORT
The Stern Review, also known as the Stern Report, is a landmark study on the
economics of climate change. The report was commissioned by the UK government in 2005
and was led by economist Sir Nicholas Stern. It aimed to provide an economic analysis of the
costs and benefits of actions to mitigate climate change and adapt to its impacts.
The report concluded that the cost of inaction on climate change would far outweigh
the cost of taking action to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. It estimated that without action,
the global economy could lose up to 20% of its GDP by the end of the century. In contrast,
the cost of taking action to mitigate climate change was estimated to be around 1% of global
GDP.
The Stern Review also emphasized the urgency of taking action on climate change,
arguing that delay would only increase the cost of action in the future. It called for a rapid
transition to a low-carbon economy, with a focus on energy efficiency, renewable energy, and
other low-carbon technologies.
The report has had a significant impact on the global discussion on climate change
and has been widely cited by policymakers, economists, and environmental advocates. It has
been influential in shaping policy responses to climate change, including the development of
market-based mechanisms such as carbon pricing and the promotion of clean energy
technologies.
However, the Stern Review has also been criticized by some economists for its
assumptions and methodology, particularly around discount rates and the economic impacts
of climate change. Despite these criticisms, the report remains an important contribution to
the economics of climate change and has helped to elevate the issue to the top of the global
policy agenda.