Oddi InternationalPatentSystem 1987
Oddi InternationalPatentSystem 1987
Oddi InternationalPatentSystem 1987
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Duke Law Journal
A. SAMUEL ODDI*
I. INTRODUCTION
* Professor of Law, Northern Illinois University College of Law. The author wishes to ex-
press his appreciation for the research assistance of David Garner, J.D. 1987, Northern Illinois
University College of Law, in the preparation of this article, and also to acknowledge the financial
support extended to Mr. Garner by the Illinois Bar Foundation to provide such assistance.
1. Although the first known patent statute, the Venetian Statute of 1474, was enacted by a
large majority (116 for to 10 against and 3 abstaining), all senators evidently were not convinced of
its merits. See Mandich, Venetian Patents (1450-1550), 30 J. PAT. OFF. SOC'Y 166, 176 (1948)
(translated by F.D. Prager from Mandich, Le Privative Industriali Veneziane (1450-1550), 34
RIVOSTA DI DIRITTO COMMERCIALE 511 (1936)).
2. See STAFF OF SENATE SUBCOMM. ON PATENTS, TRADEMARKS AND COPYRIGHTS, 85TH
CONG., 2D SESS., AN ECONOMIC REVIEW OF THE PATENT SYSTEM, STUDY NO. 15 (Comm. Print
831
(1972)). Further legislation has been proposed to protect United States process-
against competition from imported products made abroad by the patented process.
380, 100th Cong., 1st Sess., 133 CONG. REC. H154 (daily ed. Jan. 7, 1987). At leas
considered during the last session of Congress for extending the term of patents c
drugs and agricultural and industrial chemicals. See 32 Pat. Trademark & Copyrig
793, at 442-43 (Aug. 21, 1986). See also infra note 10 for other proposed legislatio
Court has also expanded protection. See, e.g., Diamond v. Diehr, 450 U.S. 175 (1
controlled process is patentable subject matter); Diamond v. Chakrabarty, 447 U.S.
ing human-made microorganism is patentable subject matter).
It is interesting to note that at least 10 other countries extend patent protection
nisms. See 2A J. BAXTER, supra note 3, app. at 2A-14 to 2A-21. Additionally,
Jordan, Morocco, Pakistan, Syria, Uruguay, and Zimbabwe, all of which are develo
extend patent protection to computer programs. Id. app. at 2A-2 to 2A-9.
6. E.g., Patent Law of the People's Republic of China of Mar. 12, 1984, reprin
lated in 27 Pat. Trademark & Copyright J. (BNA) No. 673, at 530 (Mar. 29, 198
7. The United States had trade deficits of $144.34 billion in 1986, $122.15 bi
$112.51 billion in 1984, $67.08 billion in 1983, $36.45 billion in 1982, and $27.97
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND, 1987 INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL STATISTIC
8. Japan had trade surpluses of $92.65 billion in 1986, $55.99 billion in 1985, $4
1984, $31.46 billion in 1983, $18.08 billion in 1982, and $19.96 billion in 1981. Id
had trade surpluses of $7.72 billion in 1986, $12.62 billion in 1985, $16.59 billion
billion in 1983, $14.96 billion in 1982, and $6.61 billion in 1981. Id. at 259. The Fede
Germany had trade surpluses of $53.63 billion in 1986, $28.82 billion in 1985, $22.02
$21.48 billion in 1983, $25.03 billion in 1982, and $16.46 billion in 1981. Id. at 3
9. South Korea went from a trade deficit of $19 million in 1985-to an overall t
$4.20 billion in 1986. Id. at 439. South Korea had a $7 billion surplus with respe
States. Burgess, U.S. Protectionism Feared, Wash. Post, Feb. 8, 1987, at HI, col.
10. This policy appears to have bipartisan support. In President Reagan's Stat
address on January 27, 1987, he announced the Administration's intention to prom
ness" by introducing "legal and regulatory reforms and weapons to fight unfair t
President's State of the Union Address, 23 WEEKLY COMP. PRES. Doc. 59, 63 (Fe
message submitted to Congress the same day entitled "A Quest for Excellence,"
included under the heading "Better Protecting Intellectual Property" proposed stat
that would:
Encourage patent owners to engage in newer and more novel ways to license their patents
by limiting the "patent misuse doctrine";
Raise protection for products resulting from patented processes to the same level as that
accorded such products by our major trading partners;
Amend the Clayton Antitrust Act to provide a more flexible standard of review for intel-
lectual property licensing arrangements;
Restore the bargaining power of parties contracting to license technology by codifying and
clarifying the Supreme Court holding in Lear v. Adkins;
Most Third World countries find themselves facing the same type of
trade imbalance as the United States.15 They also find themselves
strapped by large debts, to the point of default, arising in considerable
measure from such trade imbalances.16 This negative balance of trade is
tection for trademarks and copyrights. See Quigg, American Bar Association Address, 68 J. PAT.
OFF. Soc'Y 351, 372-74 (1986).
13. Legislation has been proposed to impose trade sanctions on countries that do not provide
adequate domestic protection of intellectual property rights originating in the United States or that
deny market access to United States enterprises relying on such rights. Anti-Piracy and Market
Access Act, S. 335, 100th Cong., 1st Sess., 133 CONG. REC. S953-56 (daily ed. Jan. 20, 1987). It is
also likely that legislation corresponding to the Technology Transfer and Intellectual Property Pro-
tection Act, S. 2663, 99th Cong., 2d Sess., 132 CONG. REC. S9389-91 (daily ed. July 21, 1986), will
be introduced, which would impose trade sanctions on countries that condition access by United
States firms to the market of that country on the transfer of those firms' technology.
14. The political rhetoric is much stronger,-for example, Representative Dingell's remarks
before the House Energy and Commerce Subcommittee:
[A]ll the companies and workers of this country ask is a level playing field. Yet, with a few
exceptions, this Administration continues to turn the other cheek when country after coun-
try targets industry after industry. . . . First, the intellectual property of our industry is
stolen. Then our foreign markets are flooded with counterfeits.... Finally, our firms are
driven out of business, or close to it-and, all the while, their markets are insulated from
meaningful competition.
32 Pat. Trademark & Copyright J. (BNA) No. 799, at 609 (Oct. 2, 1986). In introducing the Inter-
national Intellectual Property Protection and Market Access Act of 1986, S. 2435, 99th Cong., 2d
Sess., 132 CONG. REC. 55752-56 (daily ed. May 12, 1986), reintroduced as S. 335, 100th Cong., 1st
Sess., 133 CONG. REC. S953-56 (daily ed. Jan. 20, 1987) (under the title "Anti-Piracy and Market
Access Act"), Senator Wilson remarked:
In the area of intellectual property protection, plainly stated, criminals around the world
are costing American companies billions of dollars by cranking out millions of unauthor-
ized copies of U.S. records and tapes, movies, books, toys, computer programs, as well as
by expropriating patents and process patents, developed at great expense by U.S. compa-
nies, to make bootleg pharmaceuticals and chemicals.
What makes this illegal activity all the more outrageous is that it is often protected by
governments we consider friendly to the United States. Indeed, in many cases we have
provided special trade benefits in order to help them develop their economies.
132 CONG. REC. S5752 (daily ed. May 12, 1986).
15. See Appendix.
16. Id. The importance of a developing country's ability to generate a surplus in international
trade is dramatically illustrated by the decision of Brazil in February 1987 to suspend interest pay-
ments on its commercial loans of $67 billion out of its total debt of $107 billion. Troell & Cohen,
Brazil Debt Action Poses Challenge for Major Banks, Wall St. J., Feb. 23, 1987, at 3, col. 4. This
decision appears to have been precipitated by a drop in Brazil's trade surplus to $129 million in
January 1987 from an average of $1 billion per month during the first three quarters of 1986. The
January figures were the lowest in four years. Langfur, Brazil May Halt Debt Payments, Chicago
Trib., Feb. 20, 1987, ? 3, at 1, col. 2. The Economics Minister of Argentina has stated that the
the recommendations.21
30. J. BARTLETT, FAMILIAR QUOTATIONS 134 (15th ed. 1980) (Anonymous: Lati
artium necessitas). But cf id. at 817 (Agatha Christie: "I don't think necessity is the
invention-invention, in my opinion, arises directly from idleness, possibly also from la
save oneself trouble.").
31. See F. SCHERER, supra note 23, at 443-50.
32. See Barton, Technology Trade, 1985 AM. Soc'Y INT'L L. PROC. 77TH ANN. MEE
132 (1983 Proceedings) [hereinafter Barton 1983].
40. In the United States, for example, "[R]evenues from fees will be available to the Co
sioner of Patents [and Trademarks] to carry out, to the extent provided for in appropriati
the activities of the Patent and Trademark Office." 35 U.S.C. ? 42(c) (1982). The Commis
authorized to adjust the fees every three years in accordance with the Consumer Price In
? 41(f). Prior to increasing the fees in 1982, 25% of the actual costs of processing patent
tions were defrayed by the revenue. Under the increased fee schedule this would increase t
1996. See 24 Pat. Trademark & Copyright J. (BNA) No. 584, at 175 (June 17, 1982) (state
Rep. McClory supporting increasing fees). The appropriation for the Patent and Trademar
for 1983 was $76 million. Id. at 433. The appropriations for fiscal years 1986, 1987 and 198
respectively, $101.6, $110.4 and $111.9 million. Act of Nov. 6, 1986, Pub. L. No. 99-607,
Stat. 3470, 3470.
41. Turner, supra note 2, at 454.
42. Id. at 455.
43. Other abuses include attempting to extend the patent monopoly by dilatory prosecu
patent applications, filing closely related "improvement" patents, and extending royalty p
beyond the term of the patent. For a discussion of these forms of patent abuse, as well a
mentioned in the text, see generally W. BOWMAN, supra note 2, at 53-63; D. CHISUM, PA
? 19.04 (1987); L. SULLIVAN, ANTITRUST ?? 116-191 (1977).
44. Turner, supra note 2, at 455.
45. See F. SCHERER, supra note 23, at 446 ("[T]he pace of advance in petroleum crackin
technology was almost certainly accelerated by the vigorous efforts of companies to invent aroun
rival processes."). Scherer considered Edmund Kitch's different view of the "inventing aroun
problem as "little influenced by any concern for reality." Id. at 447 n.30. Kitch had been critical
Scherer's earlier study, Scherer, Firm Size, Market Structure, Opportunity, and the Output of Pat
ented Inventions, 55 AM. ECON. REV. 1097 (1965), for its failure to take into account the "prospe
function" of patents. Kitch, supra note 2, at 286.
46. Turner, supra note 2, at 455.
47. Id.
48. Id.
49. Id.
50. See id.
51. See supra note 23 and accompanying text.
A. Basic Assumptions.
66. For instance, enterprises in developed countries might be induced to invest in finding a cure
for malaria by the availability of patents in developing countries, particularly those with large popu-
lations suffering from malaria, even though that disease is not a significant domestic problem in
developed countries.
67. See OFFICE OF TECHNOLOGY ASSESSMENT, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS IN AN
AGE OF ELECTRONICS AND INFORMATION 229-30 (1986).
68. The following developing countries do not protect pharmaceuticals: Argentina, Bangla-
desh, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Egypt, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, India, Iran,
Iraq, Kampuchea, Kuwait, Laos, Lebanon, Libya, Mali, Mexico, Mongolia, Morocco, Pakistan,
Paraguay, Peru, Portugal, South Korea, Syria, Taiwan, Tangier Zone, Thailand, Tunisia, Turkey,
Uruguay, and Venezuela. 2A J. BAXTER, supra note 3, app. 2; see also UNCTAD REPORT, supra
note 61, at 116 table 14.
69. The following developed countries do not protect pharmacueticals: Canada, Finland,
Greece, Monaco, Norway, USSR and Democratic Republic of Germany. 2A J. BAXTER, supra note
3, app. 2; see also UNCTAD REPORT, supra note 61, at 116 table 14.
70. See Vaitsos, supra note 4, at 85-86 (significantly higher prices found for pharmaceuticals
protected by patents in Colombia compared to other countries that provided no such patent protec-
tion); see also Greer, supra note 4, at 235-39 (discussing considerable social costs of granting monop-
olies over "nonpatent-dependent" technologies).
71. See Greer, supra note 4, at 239.
72. See supra text accompanying notes 38-50.
73. The fees charged for services rendered by the patent-granting agency may offset some of the
costs of operating that agency. This does not, however, account for all administrative costs, nor for
the misallocation of resources. See infra text accompanying note 75.
78. See U. ANDERFELT, supra note 4, at 136-41; STAFF OF SENATE SUBCOMM. ON PATENTS,
TRADEMARKS AND COPYRIGHTS, 85 CONG., 1ST SESS., THE INTERNATIONAL PATENT SYSTEM
AND FOREIGN POLICY, STUDY NO. 5, at 12, 16-17 (Comm. Print 1957) (Vernon auth.); Penrose,
supra note 65, at 774-75.
79. See Barton 1983, supra note 32, at 137.
80. On a more cynical note, one can only speculate how much of the "counterfeiting" going on
in developing countries is financed by developed country sources.
84. Indeed, Herbert Stumpf finds the translation into the language of the developing country to
be one of the major advantages to the grant of patents. Stumpf, Interests and Conflicts of Interest in
Technology Transfer-The Role of Patents, 9 INT'L REV. INDUS. PROP. & COPYRIGHT L. 309, 315
(1978).
85. See Greer, supra note 4, at 240-42.
86. See, e.g., 3 S. LADAS, supra note 4, at 1885-86; Silverstein, supra note 23, at 370; Stumpf,
supra note 84, at 316-17. It may also be argued that the patent owner in the developed country
would not be willing to transfer technology to an enterprise in a developing country where no patent
protection exists because this would create another competitor. Yet, if such were the case, would a
patent owner who can obtain a patent in a developing country be any more ready to transfer a patent
license along with the needed additional technology to a competitor within the developing country?
indicates that a serious cost burden "relates mainly to those cases where the patent
not in fact transferred." Id.
90. The use of the terminology "patented knowledge" suggests some confusion a
of a patent. Inventions satisfying the requirements of a given patent statute m
"knowledge," as such, may not be. Evidently what the U.N. Report is trying to conv
knowledge would be transferred by means of the patent documentation (i.e., th
supplemental material) and the invention itself, if imported.
91. See, e.g., UNCTAD REPORT, supra note 61, para. 360 (90-95% of foreign-ow
developing countries are not used); Katz, supra note 4, at 67 (surveying 102 patents
tina and reporting that only 15 were being used); Vaitsos, supra note 4, at 78 (Out
relating to the pharmaceutical, textile and chemical industries only 10 were actual
lombia in 1970; in Peru, out of a sample of 4,872 patents granted between 196
industrial areas only 54 were reported as exploited.).
92. On the role of UNCTAD on the United Nations system, see generally U.N
ON TRADE & DEV., THE HISTORY OF UNCTAD 1964-1984, U.N. Doc. UNC
U.N. Sales No. E.85.II.D.6 (1985).
93. UNCTAD REPORT, supra note 61, para. 369.
94. See supra text accompanying notes 61-66.
95. See supra note 20. There are presently 116 states party
PROP. 3-5 (1987).
96. See supra note 20 for the General Assembly Resoluti
97. See 1 S. LADAS, supra note 4, ? 61.
98. Since its creation on April 26, 1970, 19 states have bec
these, 18 are developing countries, including the People's Re
INDUS. PROP. 6-8 (1987).
99. See, e.g., WORLD INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ORGANIZ
1984 paras. 1-410, WIPO Doc. No. BIG/282 (Aug. 1985) (lis
industrial property, assistance in revision and modernization
shops in industrial property, licensing, and access to patent
100. See, e.g., id. paras. 247, 258.
101. See id. paras. 8, 11, 247, 275, 280, for a summary of
provided by various developed countries. The "experts" w
development of the WIPO Model Law for Developing Countr
representatives from industry in developed countries. See W
GANIZATION, 1 WIPO MODEL LAW FOR DEVELOPING CO
WIPO Publication No. 840(E) (1979). It is also interesting to
United States would create a "United States Intellectual Prope
would be "to train individuals of developing nations in both m
ing the protection of intellectual property." S. 490, 100th
The directing board of this Institute would include executives of corporations that need dome
and foreign intellectual property protection. Id. ? 415(b)(6).
102. There has been little critical comment on the international patent system in general fo
last decade that has not been supportive of the status quo or moderate revision. See, e.g.,
Revision of the Paris Convention: A Realignment of Private and Public Interests in the Interna
Patent System, 8 BROOKLYN J. INT'L L. 77, 91-100 (1982); Kunz-Hallstein, supra note 4, at 664
Note, The United States Position on Revising the Paris Convention: Quid Pro Quo or Denunciatio
FORDHAM INT'L L.J. 411, 424-32 (1982). Indeed, Kunz-Hallstein had the temerity to say:
paraphrase a well-known statement by Fritz Machlup in his important study on the economic
dations of patent law, it would be irresponsible, based on the current state of our knowledge
suggest any weakening of the international patent system." Kunz-Hallstein, supra note 4,
(emphasis added). Compare this to what Machlup actually said, supra text accompanying no
Kunz-Hallstein also somehow converts Edith Penrose to the side of the status quo. Kunz-Hallst
supra note 4, at 666. Note, however, that Penrose was writing before the proposals for the
Convention were made and concluded:
Since non-industrial countries have very few inventions worth patenting in developed
countries, they cannot expect reciprocal advantages from granting patents to foreigners on
inventions worked in those countries. Hence, the presumption is strong that the less-devel-
oped countries gain little or nothing, and may even lose, from granting patents on inven-
tions developed, published, and primarily worked abroad.
Penrose, supra note 65, at 783.
103. Machlup, Patents, in 11 INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES 461,
471 (D. Sills ed. 1968). Jorge Katz suggests that developing countries may have political motives in
acceding to the Paris Convention to demonstrate economic stability and respect for property. Katz,
supra note 4, at 27-28.
104. Paris Convention, supra note 20; see 1 S. LADAS, supra note 4, ? 61.
A. National Treatment.
109. Id. art. 2, para. (1). Paragraph (1) ends with the following provision:
"Consequently, they shall have the same protection as the latter, and the same legal remedy
any infringement of their rights, provided that the conditions and formalities imposed upon na
als are complied with."
110. See supra note 61.
111. Machlup, supra note 2, at 54.
tional wealth.112
B. Right of Priority.
120. The administrative difficulty, of course, was more severe prior to the adve
rapid modern communication facilities.
121. See 1 S. LADAS, supra note 4, ? 255.
122. Paris Convention, supra note 20, art. 4, pt. A, para. (3) ("By a regular n
meant any filing that is adequate to establish the date on which the application
country concerned, whatever may be the subsequent fate of the application.").
123. Edith Penrose argues that a strong case may be made that the patent in
country should expire at the same date as the corresponding patent in the exporti
rose, supra note 65, at 776 n.1.
C. Independence of Patents.
125. The invalidation in 1970 in the United States of the patent covering the drug ampicillin on
the ground of having been obtained by fraud illustrates the economic consequences of this. Corre-
sponding patents on this drug had been obtained in more than 60 other countries. U.N. CONFER-
ENCE ON TRADE & DEVELOPMENT, TRADE & DEVELOPMENT BOARD, COMMITTEE ON TRANSFER
OF TECHNOLOGY, GROUP OF GOVERNMENTAL EXPERTS ON THE ROLE OF THE INTELLECTUAL
PATENTS SYSTEM IN THE TRANFER OF TECHNOLOGY, U.N. Doc. TD/B/C.6/AC.3/2 (1977) [here-
inafter UNCTAD, PARIS REVISION].
126. Various proposals have been made for the exchange of information concerning the ultimate
fate of patent applications or patents in the various countries. See, e.g., Id., para. 72 ("[I]t is neces-
sary for the [Paris] Convention to be amended to include the compulsory exchange of information
among member countries in respect of results of litigation on the validity of a patent."). Such ex-
change of information, however, would involve time delays as well as expense. Even with the receipt
of the information, article 4"' precludes the automatic invalidation of the patent, and any invalida-
tion procedure would again impose delays and expense.
D. Import Monopolization.
127. The most likely challenges would come from the patent-granting age
public agency operating in the public interest. The patent statute or other laws
country would have to provide for such a procedure. The United States patent st
requires the clerks of United States courts to notify the Commissioner of Patent
the filing of any patent action and their disposition, 35 U.S.C. ? 290 (1982), but
authorize the Patent and Trademark Office itself to seek invalidation in the pub
128. This paragraph provides:
The importation by the patentee into the country where the patent has bee
articles manufactured in any of the countries of the Union shall not entail forf
patent.
Paris Convention, supra note 20, art. 5, pt. A, para. (1).
129. This paragraph provides:
Each country of the Union shall have the right to take legislative measures providing for
the grant of compulsory licenses to prevent the abuses which might result from the exercise
of the exclusive rights conferred by the patent, for example, failure to work.
Id. art. 5, pt. A, para. (2).
130. This paragraph provides:
Forfeiture of the patent shall not be provided for except in cases where the grant of com-
pulsory licenses would not have been sufficient to prevent the said abuses. No proceedings
for the forfeiture or revocation of a patent may be instituted before the expiration of two
years from the grant of the first compulsory license.
Id. art. 5, pt. A, para. (3).
131. This paragraph provides:
A compulsory license may not be applied for on the ground of failure to work or insuffi-
cient working before the expiration of a period of four years from the date of filing of the
patent application or three years from the date of the grant of the patent, whichever period
expires last; it shall be refused if the patentee justifies his inaction by legitimate reasons.
Such a compulsory license shall be non-exclusive and shall not be transferable, even in the
form of the grant of a sub-license, except with that part of the enterprise or goodwill which
exploits such license.
Id. at art. 5, pt. A, para. (4).
132. See 1 S. LADAS, supra note 4, ? 322.
133. This is recognized in U.N. REPORT, supra note 60, paras. 116-20.
134. See Machlup, supra note 2, at 12. See generally E. PENROSE, supra note 4, at 137-61 (dis-
cussing compulsory working of foreign patents).
135. Barton 1983, supra note 32, at 132.
136. Id.
States, the theory underlying compensation by the government for the infringement of a patent is
that the infringement is a "taking" within the "eminent domain" power. See, e.g., Pitcairn v. United
States, 547 F.2d 1106, 1114 (Ct. Cl. 1976); N. V. Philips' Gloeilampenfabrieken v. Atomic Energy
Comm'n, 316 F.2d 401, 407 (D.C. Cir. 1963).
147. See Armstrong, Political Components and Practical Effects of the Andean Foreign Invest-
ment Code, 27 STAN. L. REV. 1597, 1602 (1975).
148. The proposals made for the revision of the Paris Convention by UNCTAD, and introduced
by developing countries, largely have not been acceded to. Moreover, the proposals themselves pro-
viding limited preferential treatment for developing countries do not directly address the underlying
developed-country bias of the Paris Convention. See supra notes 104-46 and accompanying text. On
preferential treatment, see generally Dorsey, Preferential Treatment: A New Standard for Interna-
all manufactured or natural products, for example, wines, grain, tobacco leaf, fruit
minerals, mineral waters, beer, flowers, and flour.
Paris Convention, supra note 20, art. 1, para. 3. This understanding, however, does
that all of these classes be protected; they are merely protectable, and such protection
vided within the wisdom of the public policy of the legislating state.
154. For example, the United States limits the grant of patents to a "process, machi
ture, or composition of matter." 35 U.S.C. ? 101 (1982). The Supreme Court discusse
in Diamond v. Diehr: "This Court has undoubtedly recognized limits to ? 101 and ever
is not embraced within the statutory terms. Excluded from such patent protection a
ture, physical phenomena, and abstract ideas." 450 U.S. 175, 185 (1981). The Court
alia, Parker v. Flook, 437 U.S. 584 (1978) (Formula for computing and updating "ala
catalytic conversions is unpatentable subject matter.); Gottschalk v. Benson, 409
(algorithm unpatentable subject matter); Funk Bros. Seed Co. v. Kalo Inoculant Co.
(1948) (product of nature unpatentable subject matter).
155. See, for example, UNCTAD REPORT, supra note 61, at 116 table 14, where it
that pharmaceuticals are denied protection in 46 countries. Of these, 37 are members
Union. Foodstuffs are denied protection in 21 countries. Id. Of these, 15 are member
Union.
156. See UNCTAD REPORT, supra note 61, at 120 table 15. The duration for which the patent
is granted bears upon the incentive provided to inventors and the costs that may arise for the monop-
oly period. Note, however, as Professor Goldstein concludes: "The judicial and legislative judg-
ments produced-conceivably, for example, judgments that to reduce the duration of the patent or
copyright term by half would not diminish technological or artistic incentive one whit-would mark
a worthy return to first principles." Goldstein, The Competitive Mandate: From Sears to Lear, 59
CALIF. L. REV. 873, 904 (1971) (footnote omitted).
157. Significant renewal fees may be envisioned.
158. G. BODENHAUSEN, GUIDE TO THE APPLICATION OF THE PARIS CONVENTION FOR THE
PROTECTION OF INDUSTRIAL PROPERTY 24 (1969). Article 1, paragraph (2) defines "industrial
property" as follows: "The protection of industrial property has as its object patents, utility models,
industrial designs, trademarks, service marks, trade names, indications of source or appellations of
origin, and the repression of unfair competition." Paris Convention, supra note 20, art. 1, para. (2).
Bodenhausen carries this definition further:
However, this statement has not completely exhausted the question in view of other provi-
sions in the Convention. Protection of several subjects of industrial property has been
expressly prescribed in the Convention, namely, industrial designs (article 5 quinquies),
service marks (article 6 sexies), collective marks (article 7 bis), trade names (articles 8, 9,
10 ter), indications of source (articles 10, 10 ter); and protection against unfair competition
(articles 10 bis and 10 ter) is also mandatory, as well as the temporary protection of certain
subjects exhibited at international exhibitions (article 11). Moreover, attention must be
directed to article 25 of the Convention ....
G. BODENHAUSEN, supra, at 24-25.
159. Paris Convention, supra note 20, art. 25, para. (1).
160. Id. art. 25, para. (2).
161. G. BODENHAUSEN, supra note 158, at 25.
162. Paris Convention, supra note 20, art. 5qiq'"""". See supra note 158 for a listing of other
mandatory provisions of the Paris Convention. The Convention provides for resolution of disputes
among member states over interpretation by the International Court of Justice (ICJ) when negotia-
tions fail or another method of settlement cannot be agreed upon. Paris Convention, supra note 20,
art. 28, para. (1). Paragraph (2) of article 28 permits a state to make a reservation to the jurisdiction
of the ICJ under paragraph (1) "at the time it signs this Act or deposits its instrument of ratification
or accession." Id. art. 28, para. (2). The Convention does not otherwise permit reservations to any
of its provisions, except as provided in article 28, paragraph (2) and article 20, paragraph (1), clause
(b), which would permit a member state of a version prior to the Stockholm text to declare that its
ratification or accession to the Stockholm text would not apply to articles 1 through 12 or 13
through 17. This would enable such a state to reject either the substantive articles (1-12) or the
administrative articles (13-17) of the Stockholm text and be bound by those, respectiv
previous text to which the reserving state was a party. Id. art. 27, paras. (2)-(3).
163. The original signatories at the International Conference of 1883 in Paris we
Brazil, France, Guatemala, Italy, Netherlands, Portugal, El Salvador, Serbia, Spain and
Acts of accession were filed by Great Britain and Ireland, Tunis and Ecuador prior to
date of the Convention. The United States adhered on May 30, 1887. See 1 S. LADAS, s
?? 48-49.
164. E. PENROSE, supra note 4, at 123-24. It is also interesting to note that the Netherlands did
not have a patent statute at the time it adhered to the Convention. In 1869, it repealed its patent law
originally enacted in 1817 and did not reenact one until 1910. Id. at 15.
165. See id. at 120-24; see also Kronstein & Till, supra note 4, at 778-79, for further background
on the German-Swiss controversy.
169. See 1 S. LADAS, supra note 4, ? 218. Ladas lists 24 countries offering such patents, includ
ing Spain, 14 Latin American countries, Barbados, Haiti, and Jamaica.
170. Id.
171. UNITED INTERNATIONAL BUREAUX FOR THE PROTECTION OF INTELLECTUAL PROP-
ERTY, MODEL LAW FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES ON INVENTIONS annex A, ? IV, para. (1)(d).
BIRPI Publication No. 801(E) (1965).
172. Id. annex A, ? V. This section provides:
Direct or indirect importation by the owner of the patent of introduction or by a licensee
under such a patent of a product, the subject of the patent of introduction, or of a product
obtained directly by means of the process, the subject of the patent of introduction, shall
constitute an offence punishable according to Section 50. Importation of model or proto-
type products shall not constitute such an offence.
173. The improved features are:
(a) It should be available to the owner of a foreign patent provided he applies in the
developing country within five years from the grant of his foreign patent.
(b) If the foreign patentee fails to apply within the said period, then any other person may
so apply on the basis of an outstanding foreign patent.
(c) The first essential requirement for the grant of such patent should be that the subject
matter has not been manufactured in the developing country. Publication alone should not
be a bar.
(d) The application for such a patent should be published and be open to third-party
opposition.
(e) The second essential requirement should be that the invention covered by the Patent
of Introduction must be manufactured in the country within a period of two years from
grant. In the case of unjustified failure of such working, the patent would be forfeited.
(f) Until the invention was actually manufactured in the country, the Patent of Introduc-
tion would not prevent importation of the subject matter.
(g) The Patent of Introduction should endure for the unexpired term of a foreign patent
with a minimum term of ten years.
1 S. LADAS, supra note 4, ? 218.
174. Id.
B. Potential Repercussions.
VI. CONCLUSION
196. For example, exports from the United States to developing countries amounted to about
$60.2 billion in 1985, but imports to the United States from developing countries stood at $93.9
billion. See STATISTICAL ABSTRACT, supra note 194, at 837 table 1467.
197. Ladas, Existing Uniformity of Industrial Property Laws and Revised Patent of Introduction:
Means for Transfer of Technical Information to Less Industrialized Countries, 12 IDEA: THE PAT-
ENT TRADEMARK & COPYRIGHT J. RES. & EDUC. 163, 163 (1968).
APPENDIX
APPENDIX