Mandatory Pro Bono - Comfort For The Poor or Welfare of The Rich
Mandatory Pro Bono - Comfort For The Poor or Welfare of The Rich
Mandatory Pro Bono - Comfort For The Poor or Welfare of The Rich
Volume 77
Article 36
Issue 5 July 1992
Recommended Citation
Jonathan R. Macey, Mandatory Pro Bono: Comfort for the Poor or Welfare of the Rich , 77 Cornell L. Rev. 1115 (1992)
Available at: http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/clr/vol77/iss5/36
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. It has been accepted for
inclusion in Cornell Law Review by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. For more information, please
contact jmp8@cornell.edu.
PANEL VI
MANDATORY PRO BONO: COLLECTIVE
DISCHARGE OF DUTY OR COMPELLED
FREE SERVICE?
Jonathan R. Maceyt
INTRODUCTION
t J. DuPratt White Professor of Law, Cornell Law School. While I am indebted for
helpful conversations on the topic of mandatory pro bono with my colleagues Roger
Cramton and Chuck Wolfram, the views expressed in this essay are mine alone. This
Article was prepared separately for publication but draws upon the ideas the author
presented at the Convention.
1 David L. Shapiro, The Enigma of the Lawyer's Duty to Serve, 55 N.Y.U. L. REV. 735,
735 (1980).
2 COMMITTEE TO IMPROVE THE AVAILABILITY OF LEGAL SERVICES, FINAL REPORT TO
THE CHIEF JUDGE OF THE STATE OF NEW YORK (1990).
3 THE SUMMA THEOLOGICA OF ST. THOMAS AqUINAs, LXXI Part II, Question, at
273 (Fathers of the English Domincian Province trans., R&T Washbourne, Ltd., 1918).
4 Essentially Aquinas takes the position that providing legal services for the poor is
a corporal work of mercy that is very personal. The obligation to provide legal services
1115
1116 CORNELL LA W REVIEW [Vol. 77:1115
I
MANDATORY PRO BONO AND THE POOR
for the poor depends on the individual circumstances of each particular case. Because
no man has the resources or the capacity to provide help to all who need it, the obliga-
tion arises from the existence of a relationship between the person in need and the
provider:
He that lacks food is no less in need than he that lacks an advocate. Yet
he that is able to give food is not always bound to feed the needy. There-
fore neither is an advocate always bound to defend the suits of the
poor ....
... Now no man is sufficient to bestow a work of mercy on all those
who need it. Wherefore, as Augustine says... I since one cannot do good to
all, we ought to consider those chiefly who by reason of place, time, or any other
circumstance, by a kind of chance, are more closely united to us.
Id. at 274 (citation omitted).
1992] MANDATORY PRO BONO 1117
tionally decide that hiring a lawyer would not make sense. When
there is simply no material estate to fight over, it does not make
sense to hire lawyers a. combatants. What is difficult to understand
is why the supporters of mandatory pro bono think that anybody
benefits by providing impecunious couples with free legal represen-
tation. With the possible exception of matrimonial work, lawsuits
against landlords are expected to occupy the lion's share of the time
that lawyers compelled to provide legal services for the poor would
spend on mandatory pro bono. If more marginal lawsuits are
brought against landlords because lawyers need something to do to
fulfill their mandatory pro bono obligations, the landlords' costs of
providing housing to the indigent inevitably will go up. As the cost
of providing housing goes up, rents will increase, and the supply of
housing for the poor will go down. The benefit that some poor peo-
ple derive from having representation in landlord-tenant disputes
must be weighed against the increased costs to tenants that will re-
sult from a regime of mandatory pro bono in which lawsuits are
brought against landlords regardless of whether the expected bene-
7
fits to the tenants outweigh the costs of the suit.
Litigation often produces benefits for plaintiffs and for society
as a whole because individuals who expect to pay damages for the
harm they cause have an incentive to reduce their harmful activities.
But pro bono litigation is different. When clients must incur costs
to hire a lawyer, they will only bring lawsuits when the expected
benefits from litigation outweigh the costs of bringing suit, includ-
ing the costs of hiring a lawyer. In the case of pro bono lawyering,
however, the cost of mounting litigation is reduced to zero, and cli-
ents will pursue litigation that produces little or no benefits.
Mandatory pro bono significantly exacerbates this problem be-
cause lawyers are forced to find client matters to fulfill their pro
bono obligations:
[S]uppose that lawyers, looking for ways to fill their quota [of re-
quired pro bono legal work], start impeding debt collection or
complicating evictions of nonrent-paying tenants. The immediate
result is to increase the fees to the lawyers of landlords and
merchants, thus increasing the costs of those suppliers [of goods
and services to the poor]. The longer-run effect is likely worse: to
increase the price or decrease the supply of housing and credit to
the poor.8
II
MANDATORY PRO BONO AND TRANSFERS OF WEALTH
WITHIN THE LEGAL PROFESSION
If mandatory pro bono does not help the poor, then one must
wonder why it receives such enthusiastic support from elite groups
within the legal community. The basic reason stems from a linger-
ing misconception among American lawyers that prosperity, virtue,
and inequality simply can be legislated away. As a distinguished Eu-
ropean journal of public affairs recently observed, "[t]o a lot of
Americans, it now seems that prosperity can be bought like insur-
ance." 9 Thejournal went on to point out that while social engineer-
ing has become unpopular in Eastern Europe, it seems to be
flourishing in the United States. 10
A second reason for the support given to mandatory pro bono
programs is probably more psychological than philosophical. Peo-
ple generally, including lawyers, believe (or cause themselves to be-
lieve) that the work they do contributes to the good of mankind.
Therefore, lawyers, like other people, desperately want to believe
that society would benefit from maximizing, rather than merely opti-
mizing, the total level of legal services provided.
Putting self-deception aside, the ineluctable reality is that no-
body really believes that mandatory pro bono programs will help
the poor. Nonetheless, mandatory pro bono regimes find strong
support in the upper strata of the legal profession. This is not sur-
prising because these upper strata will be the real beneficiaries of
mandatory pro bono programs.
It is no coincidence that the big push for mandatory pro bono is
coming from big firm lawyers at a time when demand for the serv-
ices of those firms is lagging appreciably behind the available sup-
ply." This temporary disequilibrium is evidenced by layoffs of
partners and associates at large law firms.
Mandatory pro bono programs will help large law firms by in-
creasing the demand for lawyers to defend suits brought under such
programs. Lawyers forced to bring cases on behalf of poor people
will usually be bringing them against defendants who must pay to
hire lawyers to defend those suits. In other words, mandatory pro
bono programs artificially expand society's demand for paid legal
services. In particular, the demand for the services of lawyers at
large firms who specialize in representing defendants will increase.
As one commentator presciently has observed, "[W]henever clients
III
THE GOOD OLD DAYS: THE LEGAL PROFESSION AS
SOMETIME MONOPOLY
CONCLUSION