Charles Call - Why Peace Fails - The Causes and Prevention of Civil War Recurrence-Georgetown University Press (2012)
Charles Call - Why Peace Fails - The Causes and Prevention of Civil War Recurrence-Georgetown University Press (2012)
Charles Call - Why Peace Fails - The Causes and Prevention of Civil War Recurrence-Georgetown University Press (2012)
C H A R L E S T. C A L L
15 14 13 12 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2
First printing
List of Tables x
Acknowledgments xi
References 277
Index 303
Tables
7.4 Inclusion and Peace after the Cold War: All Cases of Recurrence
and Nonrecurrence, by Political Behavior, 1988–2007 199
THIS BOOK WAS long in the making, and I am grateful for the support of many
institutions and individuals in that process. I was honored to receive a senior
fellowship at the US Institute of Peace in 2008–9 for this project, then titled
“Making Peace Stick.” My fellowship at the Institute was rewarding not just for
the stimulating intellectual environment but also for my supportive colleagues,
including Ginny Bouvier, Chantal de Jonge Oudraat, and Shira Lowinger.
I am also grateful for support I received as a visiting scholar at the Center on
International Cooperation of New York University. Thanks to the director, Bruce
Jones, and to the former deputy director, Rahul Chandran, for their support and
friendship.
This book benefited in many intangible ways from my close collaborations
with the International Peace Institute (IPI), especially with Elizabeth Cousens,
Jenna Slotin, and Vanessa Wyeth, as part of IPI’s peacebuilding project. Indeed
the idea for the book first emerged during a 2006 event organized by IPI for the
UN Peacebuilding Commission, its first informal meeting even before it was for-
mally convened. The policy implications of the book have been honed through
my ongoing engagement with the UN System, often through IPI and the Center
on International Cooperation.
I am grateful to my colleagues in the School of International Service at Amer-
ican University, including our encouraging deans, Lou Goodman and Maria
Green Cowles. I especially want to acknowledge my supportive colleagues in
the International Peace and Conflict Resolution Program, notably our dedicated
director, Ron Fisher, our inspirational founding director, Abdul Aziz Said, and
our talented coordinator, Becca Davis. Many thanks also to Georgetown Univer-
sity Press and especially to my editor, Don Jacobs, for his support and flexibility.
Numerous individuals contributed directly to the research and content of this
project. The economist John Schmitt worked with me to prepare a quantitative
analysis of civil war recurrence that was presented at the 2009 annual meeting
of the International Studies Association. His quantitative skills and thoughtful
analysis were invaluable in my drafting of that paper, which lay the groundwork
xii Acknowledgments
for the quantitative analysis and the analysis of quantitative methods in chap-
ter 2.
Several research assistants provided indispensable help. Yolande Bouka and
Heather Svanidze were especially helpful in researching the entire pool of civil
wars to determine which qualified as full-fledged “recurrences” and “nonrecur-
rences.” Leah Gates and Heather Svanidze provided research support with the
statistical tables and the fifteen core cases of recurrence and the twenty-seven
cases of nonrecurrence.
A number of people also provided feedback on portions of the draft, for which
I am very appreciative: Peter Andreas, Pierre Englebert, Tracy Fitzsimmons,
Leah Gates, Sanjeev Khagram, Madalene O’Donnell, Jim Ron, Susan Shepler,
and Bill Stanley. My thanks also to International Studies Association panelists
who commented on the quantitative portion: Pamela Aall, Michael Brown,
Chantal Jonge de Oudraat, and Roy Licklider. I also thank the anonymous re-
viewers whose feedback improved the manuscript, including the reviewers of an
early version of the Liberia case study for the journal Civil Wars. Of course, I am
responsible for any errors of fact or judgment.
Several friends have provided intangible but very welcome support as I
worked on the volume. I owe an enormous debt of thanks to Carol Bergman, Bob
Burke, Andy Fleischmann, David Holiday, Libby Ingham, Will Ingham, Sanjeev
Khagram, Robert Lynch, Caroline Moser, Madalene O’Donnell, Peter Sollis, Bill
Stanley, and Missy Wolff-Burke. My thanks also to my extended family, from
my parents, David and JoAnn Call, and my siblings, to my parents-in-law, Don
and Carolyn Fitzsimmons, whose support in different ways aided my ability to
complete the book.
Finally, my wonderful wife, Tracy, and fantastic children, Shayla, Jag, and
Dash, have been unfailingly patient and supportive, and it is to them I dedicate
this enterprise.
Introduction
The Tragedy of Civil War Recurrence
WHY DOES PEACE, once it is widely seen as consolidated, fail? Consider the
tragic experience of Liberia. In 1996 a cease-fire between rebel factions and an
embattled government ended a bloody war that had taken 200,000 lives and
displaced most of the country during the previous seven years. With the election
of a new president in 1997 and the cessation of combat, the war was deemed
over. Peacekeepers went home, postconflict reconstruction drew to an end, and
scholars analyzed the causes of the war’s beginning and end. However, by 2000,
a new civil war, involving many of the same fighters and same issues, broke out
in Liberia. The second war displaced hundreds of thousands anew, and another
150,000 were killed. Many of these new casualties were women and children
who had developed cautious optimism with the end of the prior war, only to see
their hopes dashed and their loved ones once again threatened, conscripted, or
brutally killed.
Liberia’s experience—a devastating relapse into armed conflict after hav-
ing achieved apparent peace—is shared by other countries: Lebanon in 1975,
Nicaragua in the early 1980s, Russia in Chechnya in 1999, Burundi in 1993, the
Central African Republic in 2001, Haiti in 2004, and East Timor in 2006. In
the latter two cases, as in Liberia, renewed hostilities followed lengthy expensive
international peacekeeping operations that concluded amid declarations of suc-
cess. Given the expanding investment of troops and international resources to
stabilize places like Afghanistan, Sierra Leone, Bosnia, Iraq, and Kosovo, ensur-
ing that peace “sticks” is more important than ever.
What explains why peace sticks in some cases but not in others? Other schol-
ars have only partially addressed this question. Many have studied peace agree-
ments and have postulated that successful implementation depends alternately
on the character of the agreement, on the degree of commitment among the par-
ties, on the commitment of outside third parties, or on implementation efforts
(Fortna 2004a, 2004b; Hampson 1996; Harbom, Högbladh, and Wallentsteen
2006; Walter 2004; Stedman, Rothchild, and Cousens 2002). Yet these studies
2 Introduction
omit cases of civil wars (often with salient international elements) that have not
ended in peace agreements, such as Kosovo and East Timor in 1999, Afghani-
stan in 2001, Haiti in 2004, and Sri Lanka in 2009. These cases of victory (and,
for opponents, defeat) constitute an important and growing component of civil
wars today.
Other researchers have examined the effectiveness of peacekeeping as a
tool. Yet their research does not address societies where peacekeeping has been
viewed as successful but armed conflicts still recur, as in Liberia, Haiti, and East
Timor. Much statistical work and survival analysis examine recurrences after a
cease-fire, with either no minimal threshold once a cease-fire is reached, or a
minimal threshold of only one or two months of a cease-fire holding to enter the
data set as a terminated war (e.g., Fortna 2004a). Such data sets lump together
very “young” cease-fires, where the population or parties may well believe that
the cease-fire is temporary or tactical, with stable cease-fires, where most citizens
genuinely believe the war to have ended. Here I am not interested in short-lived
cease-fires that unsurprisingly fail but rather cease-fires characterized by wide-
spread expectation that the prior war is over and where citizens act according
to that expectation—that is, where most former combatants demobilize, most
refugees return, most political parties compete for power, and civil society modi-
fies its behavior to reflect a stable cease-fire. Rather than examine cases where the
seed of peace has been planted but its emergence remains uncertain, this book
is concerned with countries where the sapling of peace has sprung forth and
survived its first year.
loved ones’ survival, and that see fragile economic regeneration evaporate. But it
is deeply demoralizing as well. Investing in a renewed peace in one’s country and
community is more difficult when prior hopes and investment have been shat-
tered. The disillusion inspired by bloodshed after its apparent end extends also
to outside peacemakers, peacekeepers, and peacebuilders. Failure after apparent
success calls into question the entire effort and industry of peace.
Third, these cases represent a new burden for international peacekeeping.
Many observers are familiar with cases where international troops have been re-
deployed after peacekeepers withdrew amid failure (e.g., in Angola in 1991, and
the former Yugoslavia in 1992). However, redeploying peacekeepers after a prior
peacekeeping operation seemed to succeed—and then peace failed—is a new
challenge for the international community. In only three cases has a UN peace-
keeping operation been deployed after another had been previously withdrawn
amid widespread perception of a successful peace process. These cases—Liberia
in 2003, Haiti in 2004, and East Timor 2006—all occurred in the past decade
and only three years before the formation of a new United Nations body de-
signed to tackle these challenges, the UN Peacebuilding Commission.
Fourth, these cases go to the heart of the contemporary peacebuilding chal-
lenge: How, in the wake of bloody war, can external actors help foster a society
that can resolve its conflicts without recourse to mass violence? With the ex-
ception of the United States–led wars in Afghanistan and Iraq, in recent years
the international community can claim some successes in stabilizing postwar
societies. From Bosnia and Kosovo to Sierra Leone and Liberia, from Georgia
and Moldova to Azerbaijan and Haiti, international troops have enjoyed some
success in quashing destabilizing threats to postwar societies and their regimes.
However, the threat of renewed warfare underlies the decision to retain external
troops in all these cases. What is the exit strategy for these international troops?
For many analysts, postwar state building is the answer to the challenge of
consolidating peace. Building self-sustaining legitimate and effective states obvi-
ates the need for foreign troops, reduces the international peacekeeping burden,
and advances numerous international security objectives. As Fukuyama (2004,
ix) says, “State building . . . should be at the top of our agenda.” These cases—
where peace has been secured but subsequently failed—offer a window into the
factors that determine state-building success and failure, and its relation to suc-
cessful peacebuilding.
suggest that only one or two variables are responsible for the onset or recurrence
of war. This examination of the pool of cases of reversion to internal armed con-
flict after civil war decisively undermines such monocausal claims.
Nevertheless, this study finds that one factor seems to play a more common
causal role in civil war recurrence than others. This central finding is that po-
litical exclusion, rather than economic or social factors, plays the decisive role
in most cases of civil war recurrence: Political exclusion acts as a trigger for re-
newed armed conflict.2 Conversely, political inclusion, including but not limited
to powersharing arrangements, is highly correlated with consolidation of peace.
The contribution of this book lies not only in its identification of this factor in
almost all recent cases of nonrecurrence of war and in cases of renewed armed
conflict after apparent peace, but also in its critique and subsequent development
of current postwar peacebuilding theory in ways that respond to this finding.
Political exclusion here refers to the perceived or actual deprivation of an ex-
pected opportunity for former warring parties, or the social groups associated
with them, to participate in state administration, through either appointed posts
or elective office. In separatist struggles, those opportunities are concentrated in
authority over a substate territory. Inclusionary postwar policies respond both to
the need for security guarantees among former rebels and to the need for some
degree of voice in governance among formerly mobilized elites. Inclusionary be-
havior corresponds very closely (but not perfectly) to an ability to avoid civil
war recurrence.
Two further characteristics define exclusion. First, political exclusion here
refers to processes rather than substantive policy outcomes.3 It refers to partici-
pation in political or policy processes: the opportunity either to compete in the
electoral arena or to enjoy representation in appointed state offices. Political pro-
cesses signify both the potential and the actual exercise of power, and thus they
provide a means of attaining desired ends. Chief among these ends is security
for the group and its adherents or associated populations. As such, participa-
tion in the security forces (military or police) is an especially important arena
of state inclusionary or exclusionary behavior affecting the likelihood of subse-
quent violent conflict. It is especially perilous for postconflict regimes to violate
expectations about the ability of formerly armed and mobilized social groups to
participate in the policing and defense of their own country or territory.
Second, political exclusion is contextually defined rather than measured by a
single objective standard of participation. Exclusion triggers a return to armed
conflict if it violates the expectations of either a faction of the prior war or a
social group associated with that faction. That is, exclusion refers here not to
a globally applicable objective level of political participation but to subjective
perceptions among former warring factions about whether the state engages in
Introduction 5
exclusion based on prior understandings that emerged from prior war termina-
tion. As noted above, these expectations may concern either an opportunity for
electoral participation or for representation within the armed forces, the police,
legislative posts, or Cabinet positions. And these expectations are often heavily
shaped by peace agreements, which serve as an initial indicator of minimal ex-
pectations. However, expectations are also shaped by promises by one party to
others and by initial practices that are subsequently changed. Actions that may
not be formally proscribed in an agreement can constitute a violation of expected
inclusionary behavior, such as firing or persecuting a number of members of one
or more parties associated with the prior war. Such a definition complicates, but
also enriches, cross-national comparisons.
The book also reaches a number of other conclusions. First, the nature of
peace and the factors that shape peace depend in important ways on the global
normative context. The findings suggest that how wars ended during the Cold
War, and the role of exclusion and inclusionary behavior, were not the same as
after the Cold War. Having been shaped by changes in great power policies and
transnational expectations, the parties to warfare reach negotiated settlements
more often. More pertinent, exclusionary behavior, which correlated with nonre-
currence of armed conflict during the Cold War, has since then ceased to success-
fully suppress the recurrence of armed conflict. The implications of this finding
are explored in the concluding chapters.
The research also finds that inclusionary behavior closely corresponds to suc-
cessful peacebuilding in the post–Cold War era. In separatist struggles, inclu-
sionary behavior involves a satisfactory degree of representation in the governing
apparatus of the relevant territory, through either appointive or elective posi-
tions, including the forces providing security in the separatist territory. In this
sense inclusivity refers to perceived chances to participate in state institutions
more broadly than simply the integration of former enemies into state institu-
tions. This form of “territorial powersharing” is a form of powersharing broadly
defined. I find that the integration of former enemies into state political or se-
curity institutions is the norm among successful cases of peace consolidation
after civil wars ended through negotiated settlements. Similarly, powersharing
broadly defined (either through integration of given state institutions or through
divvying up different state agencies without internal integration of each) is the
norm among successfully consolidated peace agreements. However, neither inte-
gration nor powersharing is necessary for inclusionary peacebuilding. Inclusion-
ary peacebuilding also includes the opportunity to compete electorally, without
any given guaranteed state offices. Thus inclusionary peacebuilding generally
involves powersharing but may also involve “power dividing” (Roeder 2005), so
long as the expectations of the chances for participation in politics, including key
6 Introduction
state offices or posts, are not violated. Ultimately, the importance of inclusion
and exclusion leads this book to emphasize the role of legitimate authority and
to advocate an approach I call legitimacy-focused peacebuilding.
Contributions to Theory
This book’s findings contribute to theory by calling into question four domi-
nant understandings or approaches to civil wars and postwar peacebuilding. First
and foremost, it challenges prevailing theories that economic factors, especially
poverty and a decline in economic growth, are the first place to look for factors
in civil war recurrence. The influential work of Paul Collier and his colleagues
has especially given rise to approaches emphasizing poverty, declining economic
growth, and the role of natural resources and export dependency.4 Instead, this
book shows that political decisions that exclude certain groups—whether they
are in governance, security, or economic policy—are the first line of factors in
understanding why certain countries experience recurrence and others do not.
Drawing on processes within qualitative studies of numerous cases, rather than
risk factors in quantitative analysis, the book may offer the most compelling an-
tidote to the prevalent economy-centered approaches.
Second, the book’s findings point to a central role for national actors in the
success or failure of peace. Much of the recent literature on civil wars and peace-
building explores the role of peacekeeping troops, “liberal” or “republican” mod-
els, or mediators in the duration of peace settlements (e.g., Fortna 2008, 2004a;
Paris 2004; Barnett 2006; Ghani and Lockhart 2008; Walter 2004). The book’s
case studies confirm some of the important findings of this research. Most im-
portant, the presence of third-party military troops in maintaining stability once
a cease-fire is reached seems very important in some cases. Three recurrences
took place within two years of the departure of international troops, and most
analysts believe that several “frozen conflicts” would fall into recurrence if for-
eign peacekeeping troops were to depart. However, this book finds that national
actors’ calculations hold a privileged and underemphasized role in the determi-
nants of civil war recurrence. The decisions by national elites about how to treat
former enemies, both in the state and in society, prove crucial in peacebuilding’s
failure and success. The book suggests that international actors might have more
impact through engagement with strategies for more inclusionary behavior by
elected governments.
Third, the book points the recent state-building literature in a new direc-
tion: a focus on state legitimation rather than state capacity. Several scholars
and policymakers have embraced “state building” as the principal solution to
the problem not only of “failed states” but also of postconflict reconstruction
Introduction 7
(hereafter the PRIO data set). Their threshold to count as an “armed conflict”
requires only 25 battle-related deaths in a single year.
This choice has three flaws. First, the data for these lower-level armed con-
flicts are not available for all countries before 1988. Where they are available,
they are less reliable because news sources were themselves not as reliable, avail-
able, or accessible as in more recent years. Consequently, I have used internal
armed conflicts to supplement and bring up to date the F&L data set, covering
only the period 1999–2007.
Second, it also includes a number of cases that do not correspond to com-
mon concepts of “civil war” or even a smaller-scale armed conflict. Some of these
cases may be better characterized as coups that involved organized violence (as
in the Central African Republic), sporadic and poorly organized violence with
ill-defined nonstate armed factions (e.g., Haiti in 2004), or conflicts with very
few deaths (e.g., East Timor in 2006).
Nevertheless, these armed conflicts do represent a failed peace process, and
they should be included even though our language and concepts prove inad-
equate. Including these lower-level armed conflicts as recurrences offers the ad-
vantage of including a number of cases widely considered relevant for the failure
of peace. Internal armed conflicts often prove destabilizing for the state or re-
gime and hold tragic consequences for the population. Indeed, a civil war with
thousands of battle deaths is not necessarily more destabilizing than an armed
conflict of a few dozen. Consider East Timor, where riots and armed combat be-
tween different factions of the army and police in 2006 led to the fall of the gov-
ernment, the displacement of tens of thousands of people, and an Australian-led
peacekeeping intervention of 1,300 troops. Yet only thirty-four persons died
in the fighting. Conversely, few would maintain that the Aceh independence
struggle, which resulted in more than five thousand deaths in its 1998–2005
phase, threatened the stability of Indonesia. Or consider Haiti’s recurrence in
2004 that involved few armed confrontations and “only” dozens of casualties yet
led to political upheaval, an interruption of the regime, the ouster of the presi-
dent, and the deployment of foreign troops and a UN operation that remains
as of this writing. In truth this book is about civil wars that recur as “internal
armed conflict recurrences after 1999,” but this seems rather cumbersome as a
moniker. Thus I still use “civil war recurrence,” even though this label should be
understood in a broader sense.
Third and last, the lowering of the threshold of deaths to twenty-five for re-
currences also may draw in cases that are never referred to by international or
national analysts as even an armed conflict. After reviewing the secondary litera-
ture, I have therefore excluded a single case that would fall into this category—
Azerbaijan’s 2004 instances of violent attacks involving a few dozen deaths—
Introduction 11
from inclusion in the pool of cases of “recurrence.” I could find no record of any
secondary literature referring to this as a “new” or second armed conflict, but
only as isolated instances of violence.
Having offered the above explanation of what count as “civil war” and “recur-
rence” in the definition of “failed peace,” I offer the following list, which gives a
more detailed characterization of the definition used here of the failure of post-
war peace: the recurrence of internal armed conflict where a prior civil war is widely
perceived to have ended:
faction and the acquisition of some state power is at stake.13 All major data sets of
internal armed conflict use a total of 1,000 battle-related deaths as the threshold
for when an “internal armed conflict” qualifies as a “civil war.” This distinction is
arbitrary but useful.14
Similarly, knowing when a war is “widely perceived” to have ended is diffi-
cult to judge and impossible to standardize across numerous cases over time.
Certainly such perceptions can be documented through an examination of
how observers describe wars, describe periods after a cease-fire, and describe
the events that may constitute recurrence. For instance, Liberia and Chechnya
are unusual cases insofar as scholars and average citizens speak of a “first” and a
“second” civil war—a clear indication of a widespread perception of war termi-
nation. However, such language is not employed in some other cases that consti-
tute recurrence, such as the counterrevolution in “postrevolutionary” Nicaragua
from 1981 to 1990. In cases like Cambodia (1975–78), quantitative indicators
misleadingly suggest that situations of one-sided violence, or even genocide, be
scored as periods of interwar “peace.” As a proxy for countries “at peace,” I start
with countries in which Fearon and Laitin (2003) show that a civil war ended
for at least a calendar year.
In determining a perception of peace, I supplement the F&L list with an anal-
ysis of discourse in public news accounts and policy analysis that recognizes an
end to the first war. Because survey data are rarely available, I rely on analysts’
claims and the secondary literature about the extent to which the population
understood the war to be over. I also draw secondarily on these analysts’ own
perceptions about whether the first civil war ever was concluded. I count cases
as having concluded a prior war if at any time in the intervening period the wide-
spread perception emerges that the first civil war had ended. Hence it does not
matter if the population distrusted a cease-fire or peace accord in the immediate
aftermath of its adoption or if the parties had little faith in a peace accord at the
moment of signing it. What matters is whether, at some point subsequent to a
cease-fire or peace agreement (but before any recurrence), the majority of citi-
zens perceived the prior war to have ended and acted accordingly. One indicator
of this perception, for instance, is the return of many refugees. Another is the
demobilization or incorporation into the armed forces of a significant majority
of former combatants. This standard is still compatible with some minority of
people believing that the “peace” was illusory and that postwar stability repre-
sented only a lull in the fighting and prelude to renewed combat. Ultimately,
where secondary works clearly belie the F&L categorization of a period of inter-
war peace, such cases are dropped. Omitted cases include Cambodia (1970–75,
1978–92), Senegal (1989–2001, 2003), and Somalia (1981–2002, 2006–).
Nevertheless, expectations and perceptions about warfare are fluid, contextual,
and hard to determine.15 They are also shaped by interaction among the parties
Introduction 13
(Hampson 1996) and by third parties (Walter 2004). In addition, the parties to
conflict are often divided and their interests change. This study tries to be faithful
to the available evidence about expectations and their evolution, but this remains
an imperfect process.
Finally, a change in the status of a state poses challenges for categorizing such
wars as internal versus external. Consider the difficulty of coding the wars of the
former Yugoslavia after the 1991 declarations of independence by Croatia and
Bosnia, or the 1999 NATO bombing of Kosovo in which the Kosovo Liberation
Army played an enormous role as the ground troops. Analyzing war recurrence
where the status of the territory changes across decades is especially difficult.16
Many wars for independence (excluded from most data sets) are shortly fol-
lowed by related internal armed conflicts.17 None of the options is appealing,
whether it means (1) counting the recurrence as a single new war within the new
state (ignoring the prior war), (2) counting the two wars as new wars in each of
two states (ignoring their relation to one another and dropping the recurrence),
or (3) counting them as two wars within the new state (which did not exist dur-
ing the first war). Although I adopt the third option here (namely, regarding East
Timor, whose war for independence within Indonesia was followed by an inter-
nal armed conflict in 2006), no choice here is optimal.
What, then, is the pool of cases of recurrence of armed conflict? Given the dif-
ficulties described above, I develop a list using these data sets that approximates
the definition above. I use F&L’s sixty-eight cases as the initial pool, and add any
cases of recurrence of these civil wars as armed conflicts in the PRIO data set.
Thus the pool of cases of “recurrence” consists of
These categories permit one to sort all countries into three categories: those
that did not experience any new wars after a given civil war (nonrecurrence),
14 Introduction
Table I.1 All Civil Wars and Recurrences, 1946–99, plus Recurrences as Internal Armed Conflicts,
1999–2007
New Civil War, Same Country Civil War (and Internal Armed
Nonrecurrent Civil Wars or Territory Conflict) Recurrences
Angola, 1975–2002 Algeria, 1962–63, 1992–present Azerbaijan, 1992–94, 2005a
Bangladesh, 1976–97 Argentina, 1955, 1973–77 Burundi, 1972, 1988, 1993–2006
Bolivia, 1952 Chad, 1965–2002, 2005–present Cambodia, 1970–75, 1978–92a
Bosnia, 1992–95 China, 1946–50, 1991–present Central African Republic,
Costa Rica, 1948 Colombia, 1948–62, 1963– 1996–97, 2001–2
Croatia, 1992–95 present China, 1950–51, 1956–59
Cuba, 1958–59 Democratic Republic of Congo, East Timor (Indonesia), 1975–99,
Cyprus, 1974 1960–65, 1977–78, 1996– 2006
Djibouti, 1993–94 2001, 2006–present Georgia (South Ossetia),
Dominican Republic, 1965 Ethiopia, 1974–92, 1997–present 1992–94, 2004
El Salvador, 1979–92 Georgia (Abkhazia), 1992–94 Haiti, 1991–95, 2004
Greece, 1945–49 Indonesia, 1950, 1953, 1958–60, Lebanon, 1958, 1975–90
Guatemala, 1968–96 1965–present Liberia, 1989–96, 1999–2003
Jordan, 1970 Iran, 1978–79, 1979–93, 1984 Mali, 1989–94, 2007
South Korea, 1949–50 Iraq, 1959–59, 1961–74, 2004– Nicaragua, 1978–79, 1981–88
Laos, 1960–73 present Peru, 1981–95, 2007
Moldova, 1992 Kenya, 1963–67, 1991–93 Russia (Chechnya), 1994–96,
Morocco, 1975–88 Nigeria, 1967–70, 1980–85 1999–present
Mozambique, 1976–95 Pakistan, 1971, 1973–77, Rwanda, 1962–65, 1990–2002
Nepal, 1997–2006 1993–99, 2004–present Senegal, 1989–2001, 2003a
Papua New Guinea, 1988–98 Philippines, 1946–52, 1968– Sri Lanka, 1971, 1983–2002,
Paraguay, 1947 present 2003–presenta
Sierra Leone, 1991–2000 Turkey, 1977–80, 1984–present Somalia, 1981–2002, 2006–
South Africa, 1983–94 Yemen, 1962–69, 1986–87, 1994 presenta
Tajikistan, 1992–97 Sudan, 1963–72, 1983–present
United Kingdom, 1969–99 Zimbabwe, 1972–79, 1983–87
South Vietnam, 1960–75
a
Insufficient interwar peace.
those that experienced a “new” civil war or multiple civil wars simultaneously
(or, after 1999, internal armed conflict), and those that experienced a related
“recurrent” or “repeat” civil war (or, after 1999, internal armed conflict). Table I.1
presents all cases of civil wars that originated between 1946 and 1999, plus any
instances of renewed civil war during that period, plus any renewed internal
armed conflict from 1999 to 2007.18 As one can see, the total pool of what I shall
for simplicity call “war recurrence” (recognizing that this refers to civil war re-
currences from 1946 to 2007, plus internal armed conflicts from 1999 to 2007)
contains twenty countries.19
The cases of interest to this book are the twenty-seven countries of nonre-
currence in the first column and the twenty countries in the third column that
experienced “recurrent” or “repeat” civil wars (including, as described, countries
Introduction 15
that experienced civil war, then peace, then a recurrent internal armed conflict
after 1999). As indicated above, some “recurrences” are more clearly cases of an
internal war, followed by a widely shared perception of peace, followed by re-
emergence to the level of armed conflict. In seeking to advance qualitative stud-
ies, I sought to exclude cases where the perception of peace was questionable.
Thus, cases such as Cambodia’s interwar period between 1975 and 1978 (the
most intense period of genocide) were not widely perceived periods of “peace.”
Similarly, although the qualitative nature of the armed conflict in Somalia after
2006 differed from that of the prior few “interwar” years, the absence of a coher-
ent state calls into question the comparability of this case. In addition, no wide-
spread perception of “peace” prevailed.
If we remove these cases, we are left with what I call the “core cases” of oc-
currence of destabilizing internal armed conflict after a post–civil war period of
peace. (Note that no time limit for recurrence is used here.) Table I.2 contains
these fifteen clearer core cases. These core cases serve as the basis for qualitative
exploration (presented principally in chapters 3 through 7) of the book’s main
question.
Methodology
The main research objective is to discern causal patterns that explain the recur-
rence of organized political violence after a civil war has concluded. I use three
methods. First, drawing on qualitative and quantitative studies of all types of civil
wars, I briefly present a series of linear regression analyses conducted in collabo-
ration with the economist John Schmitt (Call and Schmitt 2009). The purpose
of this quantitative component of the study is to determine whether and how
16 Introduction
recurrence differs from the more widely studied onset. I also explore the limits
of quantitative methods and demonstrate the utility of qualitative methods for
understanding the causes of civil war recurrence and its absence, nonrecurrence.
Second, I present an extensive analysis of Liberia’s civil war recurrence as a
heuristic case study of an exemplary recurrence of civil war. This case was se-
lected initially as one of only three instances of reintroduction of UN peacekeep-
ing troops after the completion, amid perceived success, of a prior UN mission.
In addition, the Liberia case represents perhaps the clearest instance of a civil
war that was considered concluded amid great fanfare with heavy international
involvement, but then resumed with some of the same leading actors after a min-
imum period of stability.
The case study is theory oriented, and thus is organized around and explicitly
engages competing arguments about the causes of civil war onset and recurrence.
To the extent that the case advances the hypothesized argument over economic
or resource-based arguments, it constitutes what Eckstein (1975, 127) calls a
“least-likely” case—one that holds particular significance to call a theory into
question as a relationship is found where it is least likely (see also King, Keohane,
and Verba 1994, 209–12). This is because Liberia is generally considered one of
the principal examples of resource-based arguments. Although I conducted brief
field research in Liberia in 2004, the case study relies mainly on the extensive
primary and secondary materials available. Because the Liberia case was instru-
mental in generating the argument, it is solely illustrative and thus does not test
the argument about the role of exclusion in the context of understandings at the
close of a prior war. I also explore the role of hypothesized factors in the recur-
rence of internal armed conflict, and I examine interaction among these factors.
Third, I use structured, focused theoretically driven “mini–case studies” of
the remaining fourteen cases of recurrence of armed conflict. Here I employ
what Eckstein (1975, 108) calls a “plausibility probe” to explore the extent to
which “candidate-theories” seem to be causally operative in other cases of recur-
rence of internal armed conflicts. Alexander George and Andrew Bennett (2005,
67) set forth the case method of “structured, focused comparison,” describing a
structured case study as one where a common set of questions “are asked of each
case,” and a focused comparison as one that “deals with only certain aspects of
the historical cases examined.” I conduct structured, focused mini–case studies
of the other fourteen “core” cases of recurrence. In them I probe the extent to
which inclusion or exclusion underlies civil war recurrence, and thus examine
the role of factors such as poverty, economic downturn, ethnic and religious frac-
tionalization, dependence on natural resources exports, and geography.
These mini–case studies run the risk of failing to provide sufficient detail for a
rich and contextualized understanding of the case and processes, and they surely
do not capture all the causal dynamics or even all the variables that a lengthier
Introduction 17
cases of civil war onset and recurrence. After specifying variables and their ratio-
nale, I conduct a handful of linear regression analyses that specify how civil war
onset differs from recurrence based on a well-known data set. The chapter then re-
flects on some of the systematic weaknesses of quantitative methods in the study
of civil wars that also apply to my own findings. This analysis cautions scholars
and policymakers against excessive reliance on quantitative research, including
the celebrated causal role of poverty in civil war recurrence. It points to the need
for extensive qualitative studies of civil war and its recurrence.
Part II contains the qualitative empirics of the book. Chapter 3 contains the
most extensive qualitative case study in the book, an examination of the causes
of civil war recurrence in Liberia. This and the other mini–case studies in chap-
ters 4 through 6 explicitly address competing or prominent arguments.
Chapters 4, 5, and 6 then extend the analysis to the fourteen other core cases
of internal armed conflicts, using the structured, focused mini–case studies.
Chapter 4 examines separatist recurrences in the North / South recurrence in
Sudan in 1983 after a decade of peace; the recurrence of Tibet’s independence
struggle in 1956 after five years of stability following the 1950–51 uprising under
Mao Zedong’s new Communist regime; South Ossetia’s recurrent armed conflict
in 2004 after ten years of stability (my analysis stops before the 2008 Russian-
backed conflict that led to de facto secession from Georgia of this province and
Abkhazia); and Russia’s recurrent civil war in Chechnya in 1999 after three years
of a negotiated settlement providing for provisional autonomy.
Chapter 5 turns to nonsecessionist recurrences that support the main argu-
ment. The chapter begins by examining two cases of weak states that experi-
enced recurrences: Haiti in 2004, after ten years of United Nations–supported
peace following the United States–led restoration of President Aristide in 1994
after three years of violence; and the Central African Republic’s recurrence of
armed conflict in 2001 after four years of stability. The chapter then takes up two
cases whose recurrences of armed conflict represent a distinctive pattern (noted
also by Atlas and Licklider 1999): victorious liberation movements that engage
in exclusionary behavior against former allies once independence is achieved.
These cases are East Timor’s destabilizing violence in 2006, and Zimbabwe’s
relapse into violence in 1983 four years after independence had been achieved
from Great Britain. Finally, the chapter analyzes Burundi and Rwanda in con-
junction with one another, arguing that exclusion played a particular, chronic
role in the recurrences in these two countries’ interrelated recurrent episodes of
violence and civil war.
Chapter 6 examines the cases of Lebanon, Mali, Peru, and Nicaragua, as well
as, where the argument about exclusion is insufficient, pointing to other causal
factors. In particular, regional dynamics, both neighboring states as well as the
cross-border flows of goods and services and matériel, prove decisive in these
Introduction 19
cases. The interests and strategies of great powers also drive war recurrence in a
certain small portion of the cases in the pool. Weak state institutions and poverty
certainly correlate with most cases, but these factors require further specification
and theoretical claims.
In chapter 7 I turn to cases of nonrecurrence of civil war—twenty-seven civil
wars that had not yet recurred as of 2007. Cases of nonrecurrence include Cuba
in 1959, Jordan in 1970, Vietnam in 1975, El Salvador in 1992, Mozambique in
1992, South Africa in 1994, Guatemala in 1996, Papua New Guinea in 1998,
and the United Kingdom / Northern Ireland in 1998. The chapter begins with
observations about the historicity of civil war termination since World War II,
and then examines different types of inclusionary behavior, especially different
types of powersharing. I classify these cases by whether or not postwar regimes
acted in ways that were inclusionary or exclusionary against the expectations
of the main opposition groups. The chapter ends by examining exclusion and
inclusion for the combined pool of the fifteen core cases of recurrence and the
twenty-seven cases of nonrecurrence. The analysis shows that, in contrast to the
Cold War period, exclusionary conduct in the contemporary era is likely to yield
armed recurrence and resistance. Conversely, different forms of inclusionary
conduct are a factor in virtually all cases of successful peace consolidation.
Part III represents a twofold conclusion to the book. It consists of a chapter
of conclusions related to theory, and another of conclusions related to policy
and practice. Chapter 8 recaps the central findings of the empirical analysis, and
it then reexamines theory in light of them. I first summarize how the empirics of
the book call attention to specific shortcomings of the four dominant approaches
to peacebuilding. I then propose a “legitimacy-focused peacebuilding” approach
that draws on elements of the main approaches but differs from each, offering
especially an alternative to the dominant “liberal peacebuilding” and political
economic approaches. The chapter also considers some of the limitations of
the research and of the concepts used in this field of inquiry, along with their
broader implications for the study of civil wars and peacebuilding. Even as I was
pleasantly surprised to identify certain causal patterns, the project simultane-
ously deepened questions I had about some of the concepts, terms, methods,
and approaches found in the study of war and peace. Many of the assumptions of
students, policymakers, and practitioners are based on rather rudimentary con-
cepts and causal claims that do not capture the complexity and variation of these
armed conflicts, the multiple paths to termination and recurrence, and the fluid
cross-national and subnational processes and dynamics that shape what we call
“civil wars” and “stability.”
Chapter 9 turns to policy and practice. Social scientists tend to conclude
their works by briefly explicating some policy implications of their research,
then leaving those implications unanalyzed and untested. Unfortunately, even
20 Introduction
where research findings are sound, choices to take action to transform social re-
ality in the theoretically desired direction can fail or even prove harmful. This
chapter explores the policy implications and challenges posed by the findings of
the previous chapters. I seek to anticipate negative consequences and to make
considered judgments about how policymakers might incorporate these findings
in ways that minimize harm.
Notes
1. In this interval, Fearon and Laitin (2003) record thirty-seven civil war onsets
worldwide. Of these, 11 (29.73 percent) were in states that had civil wars in the previ-
ous ten years, and twenty (54.05 percent) had experienced a prior civil war since the
start of the data set in 1945. NB: This does not account for civil wars fought with
different actors (i.e., not recurrence in the complete sense), nor does it include wars
involving nonstate actors within a territory before it became an independent state.
2. Recent quantitative work similarly finds that political exclusion is crucial in civil
war onset and secession movements. See Wimmer, Cederman, and Min (2009).
3. The relevant aspects of political exclusion evolve over time and geographical
space, shaped by international interests and norms. Although policy outcomes seem
to have been more relevant in earlier periods, the ability to participate in state institu-
tions of decision making and security are the most frequent triggers of recurrence in
the contemporary period.
4. See Collier (2002, 2007, 2008, 2009); Collier and Hoeffler (2002, 2004, 2006);
Collier, Hoeffler, and Söderbom (2006a, 2006b); and Collier et al. (2003). Also see
Ballentine and Sherman (2003).
5. For international capacities, Doyle and Sambanis (2006) refer to the presence of
international troops as well as the breadth of their mandate, inter alia. Sambanis’s work
(2007) identifies other risk factors for civil war onset and recurrence.
6. For a lengthier discussion of these concepts, and their advantages and disadvan-
tages, see Call (2008c).
7. This definition excludes organized criminal violence as a standard of failure, as
has occurred in postwar El Salvador, Guatemala, and South Africa, inter alia. For a
discussion of the breadth of the problem of postwar criminal violence, and case stud-
ies, see Call (2007).
8. For more on the UN Peacebuilding Commission, see Martinetti (2007); Murithi
(2008); Scott (2008); Street, Mollet, and Smith (2008); and CIC and IPI (2008).
9. Note that I am not equating peacekeeping and peacebuilding here. Instead, the
redeployment of a peacekeeping force is used as an indicator of peacebuilding fail-
ure. To see the breakdown of all UN peacekeeping operations, and whether they were
coded as successfully ending the prior war, see Call (2008c, table 1, 179).
10. For Eckstein (1975, 108), plausibility probes fall short of testing theories with
“crucial cases” but are more disciplined than heuristic case studies.
Introduction 21
11. David J. Singer and Melvin Small’s 1963 Correlates of War Project (most recent
version 1997, also adapted and updated by several others, including Paul Collier and
his colleagues in 2001) set the “industry standard” for quantitative cross-national anal-
ysis of warfare by social scientists. See the official Correlates of War Project homepage,
www.correlatesofwar.org.
12. This formulation draws on their replication tables (which exclude their list of
colonial wars) and condenses overlapping wars because for this study the country-year,
rather than the war itself, is the unit of analysis. See Fearon and Laitin (2003, “Ad-
ditional Tables for ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency and Civil War,’ February 6, 2003,” appendix
with list of wars, p. 7).
13. See the work of the Human Security Report Project of Simon Fraser University,
especially its MiniAtlas on Human Security (2010), and Uppsala Conflict Data Program.
14. Classification of particular conflicts by states themselves is often highly politi-
cal, as seen in the 2005–6 debate in the United States over whether Iraq was experi-
encing a civil war. States also resist the classification of a conflict as an internal armed
conflict (much less a civil war) in order to elude the application of the laws of war.
15. I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for emphasizing this point.
16. Fearon and Laitin (2003, 76), for instance, include colonial wars for indepen-
dence in their data set of civil wars on the understanding that these should not a priori
be excluded, counting Algeria’s war for independence as internal to France, etc. Yet
when conflict recurs in Algeria, it appears as a new war altogether. Such problems are
inherent to cross-national data collection and comparison.
17. Examples include recurrent armed conflicts in newly independent Algeria,
Rwanda, Vietnam, and Burundi.
18. The table includes the initial civil war, which appears in the “recurrence” col-
umn if it corresponds to any repeat war, and in the “new war” column if subsequent
wars involve none of the same nonstate actors. Walter (2004) refers to these types of
civil wars as “repeat wars.”
19. Five of these countries—Burundi, Iraq, Lebanon, Rwanda, and Sri Lanka—
experienced more than one repeat civil war. In addition, some countries (viz., China,
Iraq, and Yemen) also experienced more than one “new” civil war as well as a “repeat”
or “recurrent” civil war.
This page intentionally left blank
Part I
Why Peace Fails: Theory
This page intentionally left blank
1
What Do We Know about Why
Peace Fails?
WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT why peace fails? Most relevant for answering
this question are two key literatures that overlap: that on civil wars, and that on
peacebuilding. The former addresses the causes and character of civil wars: why
they occur, why they end, what makes them persist, what consequences they
have, and so on. Part of this analysis involves the roles of external actors, but the
units of analysis are generally countries (that experience civil wars or do not) and
civil wars themselves.
The latter literature—on peacebuilding—proposes and tests claims about
the role of external, and sometimes internal, actions or interventions on the
process of peace consolidation, stabilization, or war recurrence. Although the
term “peacebuilding” has expanded to encompass preconflict prevention and
wartime peacemaking efforts at mediation or negotiation, the bulk of publishing
on peacebuilding refers to postconflict societies, and thus de facto exclusively
addresses those societies that have experienced conflict and a cease-fire, either
through victory or a negotiated settlement. Therefore, the bulk of peacebuilding
research directly addresses the recurrence of armed conflict; however, the unit
of analysis is not so much wars and countries at war as peace processes; interna-
tional organizations and their structures, policies, or programs; or the combi-
nation of programs and actions undertaken by external and / or internal actors.
Although some quantitative works can be considered to lie in this field (as well
as in the “civil wars” literature, in some cases), the majority of the research in this
peacebuilding literature is qualitative, either case studies, comparative work, pol-
icy analysis, or midlevel generalizations across several cases of peace processes or
institutional structures or programs.
In this chapter I first examine the literature on the onset and recurrence of
civil wars. Some of this research is qualitative, but most works that are both in-
fluential and recent have tended to rely upon quantitative methods. The chapter
then presents the dominant approaches found in the peacebuilding literature.
I focus on four broad categories of understandings: the “liberal,” “republican,”
26 Why Peace Fails: Theory
Recurrence
I now turn to the quantitative research on civil war recurrence. Although re-
search on civil war’s recurrence is less developed than that on its onset, scholars
have offered analogous explanations. The dominant views of the causes of civil
war’s onset emphasize the political economy of war, including risk factors re-
lated to poverty. Walter (2004), for instance, uses data from the Correlates of
War Project and finds that indicators of “quality of life”—infant mortality, life
expectancy, and adult literacy rates—are the best predictors of war recurrence.4
She argues that low quality of life fosters war recurrence, although it is difficult
to see why such factors operate differently from war onset. She finds that factors
28 Why Peace Fails: Theory
Table 1.1 Risk Factors for Civil War Onset and Recurrence: Quantitative Findings
Political factors
Powersharing agreements Hartzell and Hoddie 2003, 2007
Nonmajoritarian democratic system Mukherjee 2006
State institutions
Weak state institutions Fearon and Laitin 2003
Local capacity Doyle and Sambanis 2006
Coercion / military factors
Third-party guarantees Walter and Snyder 1999; Walter 1997, 2004;
Hartzell and Hoddie 2003
International military capacity (multi- Doyle and Sambanis 2006; Collier et al. 2003;
dimensional) to support negotiated Fortna 2004a
settlements
State with large military Fortna 2004a
Existence of DDR program Collier et al. 2003
Military spending Collier and Hoeffler 2006
Political economy indicators
Low infant mortality rate Walter 2004
Low GDP per capita Collier et al. 2003; Fearon and Laitin 2003
Economic growth Collier et al. 2003; Fearon and Laitin 2003
Social factors / conflict dynamics
Ethnolinguistic fractionalization Collier and Hoeffler 2000
Identity wars Doyle and Sambanis 2000
Duration of war Walter 2004; Fortna 2004a, 2004b
Partition Walter 2004; Sambanis 2000
Lack of large diaspora Collier et al. 2003; Lyons 2006
War ending in victory Collier et al. 2003; Suhrke and Samset 2007;
Quinn, Mason, and Gurses 2007; Licklider
1995; Hartzell and Hoddie 2003
yielded mixed results. Walter finds no significance in her study specifically of war
recurrence. However, Sambanis (2000) finds that Fearon and Laitin’s (2003)
variable ethnic fractionalization holds negative statistical significance for war
recurrence. He also finds that ethnic heterogeneity and ethnolinguistic fraction-
alization have no statistical significance for peacebuilding (a dependent variable
that includes a measure of recurrence).
Related to the questions of ethnic and religious identity is that of whether
a state breaks apart or achieves independence. Walter (2004) and Sambanis
(2000) found a high correlation between partition and war recurrence. Because
secession is generally tied to group identity and the nationalistic claims arising
therefrom, partition may signify a preemptive or failed attempt to manage eth-
nic conflict. It is apparent, however, that explanations emphasizing ethnicity or
30 Why Peace Fails: Theory
religious identity have fallen out of favor in the relatively limited scholarship on
civil war recurrence.
In sum I find tremendous disparity among scholars about whether certain
factors are important or not, and about the degree to which they are important.
Many variables are relatively static and do not lend themselves to easy manipu-
lation. Chapter 2 returns to this topic and draws on the variables mentioned in
this section, for there I present a quantitative analysis of the question of civil
war recurrence. However, it bears mention here that such methods require us-
ing indicators for variables, and finding accurate proxies for the variable is often
difficult, especially in poor or war-torn societies where data are often unavailable
or have been destroyed. These methods have particular difficulty getting at in-
ternational strategies. An early creative effort to address the role of international
actors and their different efforts was the work of Doyle and Sambanis (2000,
2006), who measured the presence of different types of UN peace efforts. Fortna
(2008) uses quantitative methods and case studies to show that peacekeeping
contributes to the duration of peace. She utilizes hazard or survival models to
address the problem of “censored” data whose projected future values cannot be
known (Fortna 2008, 10–11).5
Liberal Peacebuilding
The most prevalent alternative to an economic opportunity model of civil war
and peacebuilding is a political approach that has come to be called “liberal
peacebuilding.” Although no theorist holds himself or herself up as the avatar of
“liberal peacebuilding,” the concept is useful because it depicts a collection of ele-
ments that seem to underlie and infuse international policies and programs, seen
as a whole. In essence, liberal peacebuilding consists of the promotion of democ-
racy and of market-based economic reforms in postwar societies. Roland Paris
(2004, 5) defines it thus: “In the political realm, liberalization means democrati-
zation, or the promotion of periodic and genuine elections, constitutional limita-
tions on the exercise of governmental power, and respect for basic civil liberties,
including freedom of speech, assembly and conscience. In the economic realm,
liberalization means marketization, or movement toward a market-oriented eco-
nomic model, including measures aimed at minimizing government intrusion in
the economy, and maximizing the freedom for private investors, producers, and
consumers to pursue their respective economic interests.”
In the early years of the twenty-first century, liberal peacebuilding became the
label capturing the overall thrust and assumptions of Western donors and inter-
national organizations in their policies toward postconflict countries. Liberal-
ism inconvertibly captured common elements of international strategies, which
included the explicit expectation that relatively free elections would mark the
32 Why Peace Fails: Theory
transition of conflict resolution from the battlefield to the political realm. These
strategies also included liberal notions about providing the necessary supportive
social environment for electoral competition through civil liberties enshrined in
constitutions as well as space for civil society to represent interest groups and
check government behavior.
A sophisticated example of liberal peacebuilding is the work of Michael Doyle
and Nicholas Sambanis, whose 2000 article was the most serious quantitative
attempt to identify factors that account for peacebuilding success. They found
that international capacities deployed (including multidimensional mandates in
peacekeeping missions), local capacities (measured with indicators like electrical
capacity), and the ease of the conflict context (e.g., fewer and more coherent in-
surgent groups) proved decisive in increasing the chances for peacebuilding suc-
cess. They found that UN mediation efforts alone and traditional deployments,
without expansive efforts to build state institutions and hold elections, had no
statistical influence on peacebuilding success. However, more multidimensional
efforts—those “with extensive civilian functions, including economic recon-
struction, economic reform, and election oversight”—were statistically sig-
nificant for success. One of the most significant implications of their research,
enhanced in their book Making War and Building Peace (Doyle and Sambanis
2006), was to ratify the importance of expansive UN peace operations that as-
pired to the liberal goals of transforming societies. Thus, although Doyle and
Sambanis did not label their work “liberal,” it set a foundation for liberal peace-
building approaches by emphasizing elections and economic reform.
The liberal character of international policies has been most explicit in the
economic domain. International actors, especially international financial insti-
tutions like the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund, used their
influence to advance minimal states in postconflict countries. These programs
assumed that minimizing the state would animate free enterprise and interna-
tional investment and provide the space for the private sector to create growth
and jobs, and thus help to ease poverty and integrate the local economy into the
globalized economy.
One aspect of the liberal approach merits reconsideration: its combination of
economic and political liberalism. Paris (2004), for instance, defines the “liberal
international” approach to peacebuilding as including both neoliberal economic
policies and liberal democratic models centered on elections. However, “liberal”
political actors and policies frequently diverge from neoliberal economic pre-
scriptions, as shown in an early critique by the UN diplomats who mediated
the peace agreement in El Salvador. In a seminal article, de Soto and del Cas-
tillo (1994) bemoaned the neoliberal policies of the economic wing of the in-
ternational community (mainly the international financial institutions), which
worked at odds to their efforts at political (liberal) peacebuilding. Conversely,
What Do We Know about Why Peace Fails? 33
Republican Peacebuilding
Illiberal peacebuilding, however, is not necessarily authoritarian. Michael Bar-
nett (2006) proposes a “republican” alternative to liberal peacebuilding. His ap-
proach comes closer to providing the scaffolding for an inclusionary, legitimacy-
focused approach to peacebuilding by offering valuable remedies for liberalism’s
neglect of issues of exclusion and legitimacy. For instance, Barnett argues (2006,
94) that modern republicanism (represented by Niccolò Machiavelli and James
Madison, rather than their republican predecessor Aristotle) is concerned largely
with stability in the face of contentious factions. Drawing on republican theory,
Barnett suggests three core elements of republican postconflict peacebuilding:
deliberation, representation, and constitutionalism.
On deliberation, Barnett (2006, 94) praises Machiavelli’s view of “the domes-
ticating influence of public deliberation; by compelling individuals to speak in
the language of community they might develop a greater sense of patriotism, that
is, a love of country.” In line with the need for the multivalent forms of participa-
tion I advanced above, he suggests that representation go beyond democratic
elections to include alternative forms of participation (p. 102). Such participa-
tion may include consultations but rests principally with representatives that es-
chew direct participation by the masses. Finally, Barnett calls for constitutional
constraints that divide power and regulate the behavior of representatives. He
contends that “all constitutional systems have (1) an agreement over the rules of
the game and the underlying principles that are to maintain the political order;
(2) rules and institutions that limit the exercise of power; and (3) rules that are
relatively difficult to amend” (p. 105). In this Barnett falls not far from liberal
theory and its concern with the social contract.
that international peacekeeping troops could maintain stability, but it was ap-
parent that the withdrawal of peacekeepers meant a renewed risk of conflict. By
2001, for instance, the Dayton-negotiated cease-fire had held for five years in
Bosnia, with no end in sight for the need for NATO troops.
The main instrument of self-sustained peace, it was increasingly believed by
policymakers, was a self-sustaining polity or state with the ability to resolve con-
flict without reliance on outside troops. In essence the success of these peace
operations depended on the emergence of a successful state, which made gover-
nance the key to peace (Caplan 2004a, 2005; Chesterman 2001, 2004; Beauvais
2000). Some of the works in this field focus on governance broadly, especially
whether democracy emerges or not. Thus a burst of scholarship unfolded on
postwar democracy (Call and Cook 2003; Bermeo 2003; Ottaway 2000), on
powersharing (Sisk 1996; Hartzell and Hoddie 2003, 2007; Hoddie and Hartz-
ell 2005), on partition (Kaufmann 1996, 1998), and on governance (Sriram
2008). These approaches argued that the formula or the institutions of gover-
nance constituted key factors in the sustainability of postwar peace. They are
considered in more detail below.
In addition, scholars took up the question of the state as it relates to consoli-
dating peace. Some scholars believed that the liberal peacebuilding model was at
fault, and that its central weakness was insufficient attention to institutions and
the state. As exemplified here by the work of Roland Paris (2004), policymakers
and analysts concluded that spoilers were taking advantage of liberal practices
to block peace consolidation. Consider, for example, how former armed parties
in West Africa and the Great Lakes region used multiparty elections and liberal
freedoms to mobilize voters via hate, to engage in exclusionary behavior once
elected, and to mobilize opponents of peace through liberal democratic mecha-
nisms. Paris’s answer was “institutionalization before liberalization.” Stronger
state institutions must first be in place in order to moderate politics, to check ex-
treme behavior by elected officials, and to provide controls on hate-mongering in
the media and in public discourse (see also del Castillo 2008). In Paris’s (2004,
187) words, “What is needed in the immediate postconflict period is not demo-
cratic ferment and economic upheaval, but political stability and the establish-
ment of effective administration over the territory.”
The terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, attributed to a “failed state” in
Afghanistan, elevated the emphasis on “state building” in both fragile states
and postwar countries. Thus a spate of new research focused on state building
emerged (Fukuyama 2004; Ghani and Lockhart 2008; Chesterman, Ignatieff,
and Thakur 2005; Call 2008a; Ghani, Lockhart, and Carnahan 2005), which
contributed to a new understanding of peacebuilding as consisting largely of
state building. The state-building approach focused international efforts on
strengthening the capacity and legitimacy of state institutions. It struck a con-
trast to prior emphases on replacing the state (as in East Timor; see Krasner
What Do We Know about Why Peace Fails? 35
with the liberal approach seems mistaken. The liberal vision is not philosophi-
cally or historically rooted in an emphasis on state building. As Paris emphasizes
(2004), classic liberal philosophers like Locke and Kant assumed the presence
and prevalence of institutions of governance with some degree of state capac-
ity. Political liberalism emphasizes liberal civil rights, the individual as the key
unit of analysis, and elections as an elevated expression of individual preferences.
However, states and state institutions were not central to their understanding of
political development, of freedom, or of rights. These institutions were ancillary.
Liberal theory includes institutions but does not emphasize them.
In contrast state builders emphasize limitations on rights, the collective as the
unit of analysis, and institutional strength (rather than elections) as the keys to
effective governance. State institutionalization may reflect Western assumptions
and values, but it is not liberal. Instead, the emphasis on state institutionalization
reflects the conservative, republican value of order more than it does the em-
phasis on rights and individual freedom inherent in liberalism (Barnett 2006).
To paint state building and its concerns with the same brush as liberalism and
its concerns is to conflate important and distinct approaches to peacebuilding.
Furthermore, neither political liberalism nor state-building theorists necessarily
embrace conventional neoliberal economic policies, as Richmond and Franks
(2009) and Paris (2004) suggest.
At the same time, critical theorists’ contributions merit attention. They have
called for greater attention to the particularities of cultural and social context,
and have decried cookie-cutter bureaucratic approaches. Richmond and Franks
(2009, 182) argue that “the local, the everyday, the customary, human needs,
human security, and the social contract need to be positioned far higher up the
practical agenda than they currently are.” Richmond and Franks (2009, 33) have
called for “a detailed understanding (rather than co-optation or ‘tolerance’) of
local culture, traditions, and ontology.” They have also called for unmasking the
interests of powerful states and economic elites that underlie peacebuilding pro-
grams. Richmond and Franks (2009, 34) insist that “international support for
these processes” not introduce “hegemony, inequality, conditionality, or depen-
dency.” Critical peacebuilding theorists reflect frustration with the absence of
local voices in deciding what governance models will be adopted in their society,
and the injustices of external and self-serving imposition of certain economic
and political institutions.
Defining Legitimacy
I adopt here a definition from Mark Suchman (1995, 574) of legitimacy drawn
from organization theory that encompasses both the relationship between an
institution and its external environment as well as its relations with its internal
components or constituents: “Legitimacy is a generalized perception or assump-
tion that the actions of an entity are desirable, proper, or appropriate within some
socially constructed system of norms, values, beliefs, and definitions.”
42 Why Peace Fails: Theory
anced measurements are impossible. Where fear and its habituation are not ap-
parent, however, it should be possible to measure degrees of relative legitimacy.
class, caste, tribe, and language can serve to distinguish social groups (Holsti
1996, 106). Thus, the state’s legitimacy within Israel is extremely high among
Israeli Jews but is low among those living in the West Bank and Gaza. This trans-
lates into a diminished level of horizontal legitimacy for that state. A regime can
also suffer divided legitimacy if the norms, rules, and procedures governing the
inclusion or selection of rulers are not perceived as proper or appropriate by a
salient social group. The depth and breadth of that sense of impropriety—and
thus of state or regime legitimacy—can vary.
These concepts of legitimacy are linked in important ways to the theoreti-
cal debates over peacebuilding. Liberal peacebuilding, for instance, is founded
on the individual unit of analysis, one that sees the state’s relations to society
mediated by individuals who hold the state accountable. This perspective em-
phasizes vertical legitimacy rather than horizontal legitimacy. Liberal theory sees
individuals as the undifferentiated central agent in society, rather than as social
groups. Republican peacebuilding, with its recognition of minority communi-
ties and dialogue among salient social groups, has a place for both vertical and
horizontal legitimacy. The state-building perspective explicitly embraces legiti-
macy as a necessary component for consolidation of peace, but theorists em-
phasize legitimacy versus capacity to different degrees. Moreover, state-building
approaches to peacebuilding generally fail to distinguish between vertical and
horizontal legitimacy.
How, then, does exclusion relate to state legitimacy? Exclusion is not an ex-
plicit component of the four principal approaches to peacebuilding. Certainly re-
publican theory’s notion of different factions involves social groups as important
units of analysis. Exclusion would contradict this vision. Critical peacebuilding
theorists eschew the collusion of international and national elites in the man-
ufacture of a modus vivendi that leaves the population out of procedural and
substantive agreements about postwar authority. However, these approaches
emphasize distinct roles for international actors rather than particular concepts
of intrastate and state–society relations as the foundation for peace.
Horizontal legitimacy provides the conceptual entry point of exclusionary
conduct into peacebuilding theory. Horizontal legitimacy requires some degree
of inclusion of the main social groups into the polity. Inclusionary practices or
institutions are not sufficient for horizontal legitimacy, but they are necessary.
Thus, the concept of inclusionary peacebuilding, with its focus on the inclusion
of important social groups, leads to a theoretical concern with horizontal legiti-
macy. Legitimacy is a more difficult, historically rooted, and broader concept
than inclusion.
If inclusion offers a causal mechanism tied to sustained peace, then legiti-
macy, especially horizontal legitimacy, offers the “why” that such inclusion is
necessary and a frame for understanding and advancing a holistic concept for
What Do We Know about Why Peace Fails? 45
Conclusion
Understanding the question of why peace fails or succeeds requires examining
two overlapping and related clusters of scholarship. The first is highly quantita-
tive in nature and focuses on risk factors for civil wars’ onset and recurrence. A
good deal of research on civil wars’ onset emerged in the wake of the Cold War.
The most influential body of this research is quantitative, and it points to widely
agreed-on variables as risk factors for onset. These variables include low gross
domestic product per capita, falling gross domestic product per capita, infant
mortality rates, mountainous terrain, and the prior experience of civil war. This
literature largely downplays the importance of ethnic or religious identity, and
other factors that may correspond to grievance-based approaches to the question
of civil war.
The second cluster of research focuses on external, and to a lesser extent in-
ternal, efforts to maintain and consolidate peace, which I bring under the widely
used term “peacebuilding.” Although many distinct approaches to peacebuild-
ing might be identified, I have focused here on the four coherent approaches
linked to theoretical traditions and roots—liberal, republican, state building /
governance, and critical. In the past few years liberalism has become the prevail-
ing framework for peacebuilding. As with realism in the theory of international
relations, liberal peacebuilding in its diverse guises occupies a central reference
point for most theoretical work. Those alternatives have offered criticism aimed
at either replacing or improving the dominant liberal peacebuilding framework,
but they have not yet supplanted it with a coherent alternative.
As is seen in later chapters, this book follows in this vein; it chips away at the
dominant liberal model and ultimately offers a theoretical approach that is sym-
pathetic to state building but explicitly challenges some of the assumptions, em-
phases, and recommendations of liberalism. My theorizing relies heavily on the
concepts of exclusion, inclusion, and state legitimacy explicated above. But be-
fore taking up this endeavor, I present the book’s empirics. The next chapter thus
begins with the widest possible scope of analysis, by examining the entire pool of
civil wars and analyzing those that have experienced recurrence and those that
have not. It takes up the quantitative findings and knowledge presented in this
chapter and applies them to the phenomenon of civil war recurrence.
48 Why Peace Fails: Theory
Notes
1. For discussions of multiple perspectives, see Brubaker and Laitin (1998) and
Horowitz (1985).
2. Note that Collier and Hoeffler (2002) found that countries with an ethnic group
composing between 45 to 90 percent of the population were more likely to experience
civil war onset, although they dismissed these findings later. Also see Collier et al.
(2003) and Collier and Hoeffler (2004).
3. This is from Ron (2005), giving these examples: Mahdavy (1970); Karl (1997);
Ross (1999).
4. See the website of the Correlates of War Project, www.correlatesofwar.org.
5. Fortna (2008, 11) uses Cox proportional hazard models and Weibull models,
which are robust.
6. Outstanding here are the knowledge created around all of the US military’s wars
since Vietnam, UN peacekeeping operations, and NATO’s interventions in Kosovo
and Afghanistan.
7. Discriminatory treatment of ethnic groups that belong to majorities nationally
but minorities within a region (e.g., the maltreatment of Azeris by authorities within
Nagorno-Karabakh within Azerbaijan) would count here, but such treatment was not
found to be a factor in armed conflict recurrences. One case that comes close is the
Marxist FARC’s abuses of Colombian government sympathizers within its autono-
mous zone in 1998–2002, largely leading to a renewal of offensive actions against the
zone; however, this civil war never ended during this period, and thus does not con-
stitute a recurrence. Armed attacks (as in Dagestan by Chechen warlords and in Mali)
would count as recurrences themselves.
8. Obviously, social exclusion occurs in virtually all societies. The threshold here
consists of an identifiable state policy or decision that abrogates the expectation of the
target population.
9. Note, as in the case of Afghanistan in 2001, that taking power by force in a suc-
cessful regime change does not necessarily mean battlefield “victory” and the end of
warfare but may transform insurgents into the state, and the state into insurgents in an
ongoing war.
10. Physical extermination, or politicide or genocide, is of course the most extreme
treatment of one group by another. However, this would come under a different label,
and is not commonly thought of as “exclusion.”
11. The exclusion of women in many societies exemplifies this absence of a correla-
tion or causal relationship between severe exclusion and an armed uprising.
12. With this definition I have tried to be broader than the conventional guaran-
teed posts within the state, yet simpler than Roeder and Rothchild (2005, 30), who
define powersharing institutions as rules that “seek to guarantee . . . inclusive decision-
making, partitioned decisionmaking, predetermined decisions, or some combination
of these.”
What Do We Know about Why Peace Fails? 49
13. Critics like Sriram 2008 and Roeder and Rothchild (2005) also criticize the in-
efficiency, costliness, and perverse policy incentives of powersharing. I consider these
to be less important, partly because alternatives also exhibit such deficiencies.
14. These concepts do not have to compete and may complement one another.
15. Holsti (1996, chap. 5, esp. 84–87) uses this term in a relatively narrow manner,
almost equivalent to regime legitimacy. However, this concept is too narrow to capture
the more embedded and performance elements of state legitimacy that go beyond the
selection of rulers.
2
Is Civil War Recurrence Distinct
from Its Onset?
A Quantitative Analysis and the Limits Thereof
ONE OF THE FIRST QUESTIONS to arise in this inquiry concerned the character
of civil war recurrence. Is the phenomenon of recurrence any different from that
of onset? If not, then it would make more sense not to pursue an inquiry into re-
currence at all but to draw on the more numerous and better-trodden ground of
civil war onset in thinking about recurrence. If recurrence does differ from onset,
then how does it differ? Although recurrence may differ from onset in its mani-
festation, its consequences, or its modes of termination, I am here concerned
with the causes or risk factors associated with recurrence. One can imagine that
societies that have experienced civil war once may be more prone to turn to vio-
lence again, because of the availability of arms, of former militarized networks,
of prior training and capacity among rebel groups, and / or of the socialization
toward war. One can also imagine that war weariness, scars of warfare, social and
individual traumas, the depletion of resources and social capital brought about
by prior warfare, and other aftereffects may make recurrence less likely. Micro-
level violence (Kalyvas 2006) may aggregate or articulate in different ways as
well, with unforeseen consequences.
This chapter seeks to do two things. First, I endeavor to answer this ques-
tion: Do the causes or risk factor of civil war recurrence differ from its onset? I
explore this question through a quantitative exploration of the question drawing
on well-known data sets. I draw on research conducted in collaboration with
the economist John Schmitt (Call and Schmitt 2009), using linear regressions
to determine the extent to which the recurrence of armed conflict differs in its
causes from that of initial onset. If recurrence were not to differ appreciably from
onset, then this inquiry would best be served by analyzing all civil war onsets.
After explaining the pool of cases, I proceed to specification of variables and then
present results.
Second, the chapter demonstrates why one should be deeply skeptical of the
findings of much of the quantitative literature in the absence of other methods
Is Civil War Recurrence Distinct from Its Onset? 51
Table 2.1 Comparing Civil War Onset and Recurrence: A First Cut
Variable or Parameter (1) (2) (3) (4)b
Data sourcea F&L 2003 F&L 2003 by C&S 2009 C&S 2009
C&S 2009
Estimation logit logit logit, mfx logit, mfx
Dependent variable onset onset onset recur1
Mean of dependent 0.017 0.017 0.017 0.040
variable
Prior war (0 / 1) –0.954** –0.954** –0.00587** 0.14375**
GDP per capita (lag) –0.377** –0.344** –0.00288** –0.00028
Log of population (lag) 0.263** 0.263** 0.00220** 0.00254**
% mountainous 0.219** 0.219** 0.00183* 0.00168**
Noncontiguous (0 / 1) 0.443 0.443 0.00430 –0.00125
Oil exporter (0 / 1) 0.858** 0.858** 0.01009* 0.01281**
New state (0 / 1) 1.709** 1.709** 0.03498* —
Instability (0 / 1) 0.618** 0.618** 0.00650* 0.00624**
Democracy (Polity IV) 0.021 0.021 0.00017 –0.00008
Ethnic frac. (ELF) 0.166 0.166 0.00139 –0.00635**
Relig. frac. (RLF) 0.285 0.285 0.00238 0.01225**
Constant –6.731** –6.731** — —
Sample size 6,327 6,327 6,327 6,165
Statistical significance: # at 10% level; * at 5% level; ** at 1% level.
a
F&L = Fearon and Laitin (2003); C&S = Call and Schmitt (2009).
b
New state predicts failure perfectly.
these are correlated with war recurrence in the same direction as onset, and
all have a roughly comparable impact.9 Thus oil exporters have on average a
1-percentage-point greater chance of experiencing civil war than non–oil ex-
porters, but a 1.2-percentage-points greater chance of experiencing recurrence.
Similarly, a doubling of the population (a 1-unit increase in the log of the popula-
tion) increases the chances for civil war onset by 0.22 percentage point and for
recurrence by 0.25 percent.10
Three other variables point to important differences between recurrence and
civil war onset. At the same time, ethnic fractionalization and religious fraction-
alization are statistically significant for civil war recurrence but not for onset. The
absence of significance of these variables was a key factor in the central conclu-
sion of Fearon and Laitin (and Collier and colleagues) that ethnic and religious
grievance did not underlie civil war onset. Instead, they posited that civil wars
reflected opportunity for insurgency provided by poor or weak states, as signified
by the confluence of poverty (GDP per capita) and primary commodity depen-
dence (proxied by the oil exporter variable).
One of the most important substantive findings of this chapter is that per cap-
ita GDP (lagged) is not a significant predictor of civil war recurrence. Although
54 Why Peace Fails: Theory
we confirmed Collier and others’ (2003) and Fearon and Laitin’s findings that
GDP per capita (lagged) is negatively correlated with onset, the coefficient loses
its statistical significance for recurrence. This finding—that poverty makes no
difference in a country’s risk of civil war recurrence—cuts against much of
the current thinking and policy emphasis on the economic conditions of poor
people in the wake of war.11
Ethnic fractionalization also seems to cut against long-standing theoretical
claims about civil war risks. The coefficient is negative, which suggests that an in-
crease in ethnic fractionalization (the chance that two random persons are from
different ethnic groups) by half a unit (say, from 0.25 to 0.75, for a variable rang-
ing from 0.001 to 0.925) lowers the chance of civil war recurrence by 0.3 percent-
age point. Although 0.3 percentage point may sound small, this effect is sizable
compared with other effects considered to be large in the literature on civil war
onset, such as being an oil exporter, which raises the chance of civil war onset by
about 1 percentage point. The average probability of civil war recurrence in the
sample is only 4 percentage points.
Religious fractionalization (RLF) is also highly statistically significant for re-
currence (p < 0.001). RLF (which runs from 0 to 0.783 in the sample) behaves
as theoretically expected, damaging chances for postwar peace. An identical half-
unit increase in the degree of religious fractionalization raises the chances of civil
war recurrence by about 0.6 percentage point. Its impact on recurrence is thus
more than half that of oil dependence and twice that of a doubling of GDP on
Fearon and Laitin’s onset variable. Recall that these last two marginal effects have
sent the field into a tizzy in the past several years.
What import do these findings carry at first glance? Most important, they
suggest that civil war recurrence is worth studying. Its causes seem to be different
from those of onset. These differences are not simply a matter of degree but also
reintroduce into one’s understanding of civil wars variables that have been dis-
missed in recent research on civil war onset. The factors that pointed to poverty
as a central risk factor of civil wars are not, in fact, crucial for whether countries
emerging from war risk relapse into armed conflict. Specifically, our research sug-
gests that the social composition or character of society is an important factor in
whether peace can be consolidated. Our initial findings confirm that some cases
are “hard” for consolidating postwar peace, specifically where religious fraction-
alization is high and where ethnic homogeneity prevails.
findings for onset, societies with many small ethnic groups are not at the apex of
risk for civil war recurrence either. Of course these theories of ethnic diversity are
replete with dated assumptions that ignore transnational influences on identity,
even if empiricists test for a regional risk of conflict generally. Moreover, they are
based on time-invariant and often decades-old measures of ethnic composition
in a given country.
This revised analysis also suggests that large population, oil exporters, and
instability all retain some influence on war recurrence, with comparable influ-
ence as with onset. One important exception is the impact of per capita GDP,
which has only one-fourth the impact on recurrence as it has on onset. Terrain
also loses half its impact relative to onset. In general we find that the same eco-
nomic and geographic variables remain significant in explaining war recurrence,
although some have less impact.
To repeat, the most important finding of the quantitative exercises presented
in this chapter is that ethnic and religious fractionalization have an important
and complex impact on civil war recurrence that they do not have for onset. Thus
it appears worthwhile to study civil war recurrence as a phenomenon in its own
right, especially examining the role of ethnic and religious fractionalization that
should have a lesser impact at the extremes of its values (i.e., very much or very
little fractionalized).
Three considerations—conceptual, theoretical, and empirical—call for
caution in relying too heavily on the findings given here concerning the role of
ethnicity in civil war recurrence. First, at the conceptual level, as with other vari-
ables identified by quantitative research, ethnic fractionalization and religious
fractionalization remain relatively static variables. Fractionalization and diversity
measures of ethnicity fail to identify which ethnic groups matter (Chandra and
Wilkinson 2008) and do not capture the relationship between ethnicity and the
state. The generally static and thus unstrategic conception of these variables rep-
resents one of the biggest obstacles to reliance on this application of Fearon and
Laitin’s data set to the study of war recurrence.
Second, there are important theoretical gaps in relying on quantitative correla-
tions from the quantitative analysis given above. Even if the ethnic structure of a
society constitutes a risk factor, this relationship tells us little about how and why
the ethnic composition of society influences the chances of converting social
intercourse into armed conflict. Statistical analyses in and of themselves offer no
theoretical rationale for the correlations identified. One theoretical rationale for
the causal role of ethnic fractionalization (up to a certain point, but thereafter)
and religious fractionalization playing a role is one of opportunity for political
manipulation. That is, this structure indicates something of the opportunities
that political leaders have to mobilize social divisions and conflict toward politi-
cal ends—possibly toward violent means. This account comports with political
entrepreneurial accounts of ethnic conflict (Gagnon 1994).
58 Why Peace Fails: Theory
ferent causal pathways whereby ethnicity might affect rebellions and infighting
within powersharing arrangements, including those where external events (like
the US civil rights movement for Catholics in Northern Ireland, or the onset of
the North American Free Trade Agreement for the Zapatistas) trigger excluded
populations to mobilize or ethnic groups in power to seek to expand that power.
The study by Wimmer, Cederman, and Min (2009) provides a foundation
for understanding the causal relations examined in the case studies that follow.
For two reasons, however, I have not drawn on their data set or definition of
exclusion. First, their concept restricts exclusion to ethnic identity. Instead, dif-
ferent types of exclusion may be relevant in ways that are not captured in their
data set’s single set of indicators or by other universal measures of exclusion. The
proclaimed basis of exclusion (e.g., religious or ethnolinguistic) or the institu-
tional configuration may vary across societies. Second, the perception of exclu-
sion is pertinent and rests on prior expectations. Although quantitative meth-
ods do not permit such a contextualized understanding, qualitative methods do.
Perceptions provide a more detailed understanding of causal pathways. For this
reason, the concept of exclusion in this book is contextually specific, rooted in
expectations by elites of the main sociopolitical groups.
Before turning to the qualitative analysis, however, it is worth reflecting on
how much one can infer from statistical methods in general. There is good rea-
son to question the reliability and robustness of quantitative findings, both in the
analysis presented above and in research more broadly. Despite the many posi-
tive contributions of such methods, a number of systematic problems tend to be
overlooked. The next section examines both these positive and negative aspects.
into question the reliability and perhaps utility of quantitative analysis based
on numerous observations. The questions raised here go beyond long-standing
general objections to the application of statistical inference in a scientific frame-
work to social phenomena.
Unit Heterogeneity
The small sample size also effectively imposes the uncomfortable requirement
that researchers assume that the underlying data generation process is identical
across all cases of civil war recurrence, which is a strong assumption. To con-
tinue the medical drug analogy, we know that some drugs can affect men and
women, children and adults, or other groups differently, but the small size of our
experiment forces us to assume that the effects are the same across all countries,
religious groups, ethnic groups, and other groups.
How comparable are Russia’s two civil wars (in Chechnya) with Nicaragua’s?
Or Indonesia’s conflicts over Aceh with Rwanda’s society-sweeping war–cum–
genocide? Or Argentina’s insurgency against the military dictatorship with Chi-
na’s? The idea is that control variables are designed precisely to control for dif-
ferences, but these controls may not be effective in complex social environments.
Because regression analysis requires setting aside this limitation and trusting the
controls, I elect to elide this objection. However, it is useful to keep in mind the
potential limits of control variables in comparing such disparate units of analysis.
single variable or the exclusion of a few country cases changes our result in im-
portant ways. A few examples suffice. First, in our regressions on war recurrence,
adding a single variable (viz., the square of ethnic fractionalization) restored the
statistical significance of per capita GDP for recurrence.
Second, perfectly reasonable alternative definitions of some variables lead
to divergent outcomes. Whereas ethnic fractionalization is negatively associ-
ated with war recurrence, introducing its square points to a largely positive, but
concave, relationship. Another example from modeling ethnic diversity under-
scores this point. When we used various definitions of ethnic fragmentation, the
variable proved significant in virtually all versions. However, the sign of the eth-
nic fractionalization variable was not consistent across all specifications! Thus
even with statistical significance, the fundamental causal direction was wholly
unreliable.
We have no a priori reason to presume that one model of ethnicity (e.g., eth-
nic fractionalization squared) or religious structure is better than another. Ana-
lysts have a tendency to conclude that a better fit means a better explanatory
variable. Consequently, concluding that ethnic fragmentation is linearly related
to war recurrence or concluding it is a concave function is somewhat arbitrary,
which relies heavily on the particularities of the variables used to proxy for ethnic
fractionalization, the countries and years in the sample, and the estimation tech-
niques used. Drawing either scholarly or policy implications from such choices
seems ill advised.
A third, simple example comes from the work of Paul Collier and colleagues.
Since 2002, he and various colleagues have produced several publications citing
the rate that armed conflicts recur within five years, statistics that have found
their way into pronouncements by the UN secretary-general. Yet between 2002
and 2006, they reported remarkably divergent rates of armed conflict recurrence,
including 50 percent, 44 percent, 23 percent, and 21 percent (the latter two refer
to recurrence within four years).14 That the same person reports such divergent
figures over a span of four years is another argument for caution against drawing
strong conclusions from statistically based exercises under these conditions.
Poor Proxies
Often, the connection between proxies and the things they purport to measure
is thin or questionable. As Gleditsch and Ruggeri (2010, 299) aver, “Many of the
indicators used in empirical studies of civil war are relatively crude indicators of
the underlying concepts and only loosely related to the theoretical rationale.”
Fearon and Laitin, for example, use per capita GDP and oil export dependence
as proxies for state weakness, whereas Collier and colleagues see these same
62 Why Peace Fails: Theory
variables as proxies for limited economic opportunities. Walter (2004) uses in-
fant mortality rate as a proxy for economic opportunities, and Doyle and Sam-
banis (2000) use electricity consumption as a proxy for local capacity.
Creative use of the available cross-national data is admirable and necessary.
However, scholars should be much more modest in declaring that these imper-
fect proxies confirm or reject the underlying theoretical relationships that the
proxies are meant to represent. For example, infant mortality responds much
more to trends in health provisions in a society, reflecting factors unrelated to
the possibilities of employment. States and international organizations run risks
when they base policies on research that rests upon poorly measured or only
loosely connected proxies.
Policy Applicability
Related to the prior problem are challenges of policy relevance and utility. The
variables for which we have data and that have the most significant impact are
ones over which policymakers typically have little control, especially in the short
run. A handful of variables repeatedly appear in statistical analyses of civil war
onset and recurrence: the level of GDP, infant mortality rates, size of population,
primary commodity dependence, and ethnic or social fractionalization.
At best, these correlations can guide policymakers in identifying and ad-
dressing the long-term risk factors for armed conflict. The most direct logical
Is Civil War Recurrence Distinct from Its Onset? 63
implication of the research findings given above is that peace can be advanced
by reducing poverty, infant mortality rates, and diversified economies. And yet
does anyone really think that reducing infant mortality rates in a specific coun-
try is the ticket to peace, or that national or international actors can reduce in-
fant mortality quickly enough to shape the dynamics of a recent, impending,
or ongoing civil war? Such variables may provide guidance on detecting where
armed conflict may be a few percentage points more likely, but they are not help-
ful for developing policy responses to existing or recently ended conflicts. Some
of these variables—like population, terrain, and the national demographic pro-
file—cannot be effectively manipulated by authorities unless those authorities
engage in mass human rights violations.
In addition, specific steps to reduce these risk factors for civil war onset and
recurrence may themselves cause armed conflict more acutely than the marginal
effect of the risk factor. For example, Collier’s advocacy for adherence to the
World Bank’s neoliberal macroeconomic prescriptions as the best route to devel-
opment may in fact deepen other proximate causes of warfare, because the dislo-
cations of privatization or reducing the state payroll may foster instability. This
is precisely the finding of Hartzell and Hoddie (2010), who show that adoption
of the International Monetary Fund’s structural adjustment programs between
1970 and 1999 made countries more likely to experience civil war onset. As an-
other example, diversifying the economy quickly through expanded agroexports
may leave thousands of peasants landless and may prompt armed uprisings. Even
if one accepts the risk factors identified in statistical analyses of civil wars, these
tools provide little undisputed guidance for nuanced, midlevel policymaking,
much less for country-specific remedies.
Conversely, the variables that policymakers care most about are often diffi-
cult to put into quantitative models. Some scholars have in recent years made
headway in testing quantitative models of international peacebuilding efforts, or
actions designed to reduce war recurrence. Collier and colleagues, for example,
have drawn conclusions about the impact of international aid, the timing of this
aid, and the particular type of aid that helps prevent conflict recurrence.15
Michael Doyle and Nicholas Sambanis have performed the most significant
work in this area, based on Sambanis’s civil war data set. They code UN-authorized
international missions based on their degree of authority and mandates. Namely,
they distinguish among (1) monitoring, (2) consent-based traditional peace-
keeping, (3) multidimensional peacekeeping, and (4) peace enforcement (Doyle
and Sambanis 2000, 781). They examine the impact on peacebuilding success as
measured by both a return to violence and a minimal level of participation or de-
mocracy. Their salient findings regarding international agency are that (1) treaties
have a positive impact; (2) any sort of UN involvement has a positive but limited
impact compared with treaties, with which it is highly correlated; and (3) only
64 Why Peace Fails: Theory
the quality of the peace agreement, which may be the key to success, and thus
they call for case studies (p. 151).
These research findings show the limits of statistical methods for studying
civil war recurrence. These methods have great difficulty providing clear answers
to questions such as these: What elements of a political settlement are most im-
portant? How can external actors foster elections that do not themselves spark
renewed violence? How can exclusionary power arrangements be transformed?
What state institutional reforms are most important? How are their capacity and
legitimacy enhanced? How can countries that are dependent on primary com-
modities reduce their risk of war and its recurrence without provoking conflict?
How important is justice for past atrocities? Although scholars can create prox-
ies for some of the variables relevant to these questions, they are the exception.
Where such variables do exist, the nexus is distant and the cross-national data
are inadequate and usually incomparable. Even Sambanis’s efforts, which go
well beyond most others’, do not go far enough to address these kinds of policy
concerns.
Conclusion
This chapter serves two purposes. First, it determines, based on one of the best
and most appropriate data sets available, whether civil war recurrence differs
from civil war onset. The answer is a muted yes. Onset and recurrence share a
number of risk factors—including having a large population, relying heavily on
oil exports, and political instability—and these factors have a comparable influ-
ence on recurrence as with onset.
However, in contrast to their role in civil war onset, ethnic fractionalization
and its square both appear to represent statistically significant risk factors for civil
war recurrence, as does religious fractionalization. This difference suggests that
these two identity issues are conceived, refracted, or manipulated (perhaps in
conjunction with fears, interests, or desires) so as to enhance the chances of re-
currence once a civil war has been dormant for a short time (one or two years). It
is also important for this book’s claims about grievance as the most salient causal
factor for civil war recurrence, rather than economic factors like poverty, that
GDP per capita is not statistically significant as a risk factor in the application of
linear regression analysis to the Fearon and Laitin data set. However, once ethnic
fractionalization is squared, GDP per capita reappears as a statistically significant
risk factor, but only with one-fourth its earlier influence.
Second, this chapter shows that scholars and policymakers alike should
regard the findings of quantitative research on civil wars with a degree of cau-
tion. Even when used with care and sophistication, they suffer from numerous
flaws, most of which cannot be overcome without an unrealistic investment of
66 Why Peace Fails: Theory
Notes
1. Their complete list is given by Fearon and Laitin (2003, n3).
2. Fearon and Laitin (2003, 5); for additional coding notes, see Fearon and Laitin
(2003, n4).
3. The findings differed only by a thousandth of a point and are available on re-
quest. The table replicated is labeled table 1 in Fearon and Laitin (2003, 84).
4. In replicating the work of Fearon and Laitin, we too use the log of lagged popula-
tion, the log of portion of mountainous terrain, and lagged per capita GDP.
5. They measure ethnic fractionalization (and separately and analogously, religious
fractionalization) using a composite of ethnolinguistic fractionalization (based on the
1964 Soviet Atlas’s measurement of the probability that any two people in a country
are from different ethnolinguistic groups), the share of the largest ethnic group, and the
number of distinct languages spoken by groups exceeding 1 percent of the population.
See Fearon and Laitin (2003, 78).
6. In this Call and Schmitt (2009) diverge slightly from Fearon and Laitin. Our def-
inition of recurrence codes every year of the recurred civil war as a recurrence; Fearon
and Laitin, by contrast, focus on onset and code only the first year of a new civil war as
“one.” We find their coding strange, because it codes identically both every country in
its second (or third) consecutive year of civil war (e.g., Guatemala in 1983) and every
country at peace (e.g., Sweden 1997). We believe that countries at war should be coded
as experiencing recurrence rather than no warfare. However, we also ran a regression
for onset (available from the authors), coding all country-years that civil war occurred
as “one.” We found that neither was statistically significant at the 5 percent level or
Is Civil War Recurrence Distinct from Its Onset? 67
better, though RLF was statistically significant in some cases at the 10 percent level,
reinforcing our earlier findings on the differences between onset and recurrence.
7. This tally diverges from the 73 countries and 127 civil wars cited by Fearon and
Laitin (2003, 75), who counted multiple wars. Because our unit of analysis is country
(not the war, as Sambanis), we did not distinguish among wars in a given country.
8. Marginal effects show what percentage change is associated with a 1 unit change
in continuous variables, and with a change from 0 / 1 in dichotomous variables.
9. Oil exporters and large countries are slightly more likely (by 20 percent and
14 percent, respectively) to experience recurrence than onset. Terrain and instability
are slightly (by 4–8 percent) less important for recurrence than onset.
10. “New states” drops from the regression because it perfectly predicts war recur-
rence. Following Fearon and Laitin, the regression also includes a lagged dependent
variable.
11. Of course the level of GDP per capita says nothing about the national income
distribution.
12. For a more extensive treatment of some of these issues, see Human Security
Report Project, Human Security Report 2009 / 2010, chapter 2, “Peace, War and Num-
bers” (Human Security Report Project 2009), which appeared after Call and Schmitt
(2009).
13. As mentioned above, Fearon and Laitin state their data show 127 civil war on-
sets, including recurrent ones. Our examination of their data yields 97.
14. See, in the order corresponding to the figures cited, Collier and Hoeffler (2002);
Collier et al. (2003); and Collier, Hoeffler, and Söderbom (2006a, 2006b). Also see
Suhrke and Samset (2007, 198).
15. See most recently, Collier (2007, 104–7) and Collier, Hoeffler, and Söderbom
(2006b).
16. Again, we did not use Sambanis’s data set because it captures only civil wars, ex-
cluding data on countries that did not experience civil war, which substantially reduces
the number of observations.
17. Doyle and Sambanis (2006, 102n78).
This page intentionally left blank
Part II
Examining the Cases
This page intentionally left blank
3
Liberia
Exclusion and Civil War Recurrence
of the population. These elites repressed the roughly sixteen main ethnic “up-
country” groups, most of which had been divided by borders from their clans-
men in neighboring Guinea, Sierra Leone, and Côte d’Ivoire. Indigenous tribes,
for instance, only received the right to vote in 1964. In 1980 a coup led by Master
Sergeant Samuel Doe and other low-ranking officers, all from native tribes and
lacking a high school education, toppled American-Liberians from power for the
first time.
Doe’s regime continued the patronage-based, murderous predatory state of
his predecessors. His own ethnic group, the Krahns (who made up only 5 per-
cent of the populace), were overrepresented in the cabinet, and the Gios and
Manos (who constituted 15 percent of the population) suffered discrimination.
In the wake of a failed coup attempt in 1985, Doe’s Krahn-dominated army killed
a reported 3,000 Gios and Manos (Adebajo 2002a).5 As Adebajo (2002a, 46)
notes, “This single episode, more than any other, set the stage for the exploita-
tion of ethnic rivalries that would eventually culminate in Liberia’s civil war.”
On Christmas Eve 1989, Charles Taylor and some 167 other rebels invaded
from Côte d’Ivoire, launching a civil war that would persist through at least
eleven peace agreements and twenty cease-fires. Ethnic grievance played a role
in the conflict. Taylor’s National Patriotic Front of Liberia (NPFL), which was
composed mainly of Gios and Manos, gathered more of these ethnic nationals
as it swept across the country (Adebajo 2002a).6 NPFL rebels killed Krahns and
Mandingos, and Doe’s Armed Forces of Liberia also killed Gios and Mandingos
(Ellis 2001).
Six other rebel groups would emerge to play salient roles in the first civil war.7
Two splinter groups broke away from Taylor’s NPFL. Prince Johnson’s Indepen-
dent NPFL broke away in July 1990, and would later that year capture Presi-
dent Samuel Doe and videotape his grisly killing. Three senior NPFL officials
broke with Taylor in 1994 and formed the Central Revolutionary Council. In
contrast to these groups, other groups emerged that were composed mainly of
Krahns and Mandingos. Refugees from Sierra Leone formed the basis of United
Liberation Movement of Liberia for Democracy (ULIMO) in May 1991. Three
years later it split into two groups: ULIMO-J, led by Roosevelt Johnson, a Krahn,
with 3,800 members; and ULIMO-K, led by Alhaji G. V. Kromah, a Mandingo,
with 6,800 rebels (Adebajo 2002a). The 2,500-strong Liberia Peace Council
emerged in 1993 under the Krahn politician George Boley, who had served as a
minister under presidents William Tolbert and Doe. And the 400-member Lofa
Defense Force emerged in 1993.
At the same time, Liberia’s first civil war seems a good candidate for the eco-
nomic causes of armed conflict. The country is rich in natural resources, includ-
ing diamonds, timber, gold, rubber, and other minerals. In accord with some re-
search, its rebel commanders could enrich themselves and find the independent
74 Examining the Cases
means to sustain their fight. Taylor reportedly collected $75 million per year from
his territorial control of key resources, including $10 million per month from a
consortium of American, European, and Japanese mining interests. ULIMO-J
garnered income from diamond mining in the West, and the Liberia Peace
Council exported rubber. ULIMO-K sought to restore the wartime interruption
of Mandingos’ income from diamond exports. One study estimated that in 1995
alone, Liberia’s warlords exported more than $300 million worth of diamonds,
$53 million in timber, and $27 million worth of rubber (Atkinson 1997).
Fearon and Laitin (2003) argue that weak state structures typical of high
resource dependency provide the opportunity for armed rebellions to emerge.
Certainly the Liberian state was weak, and these huge incomes represented a
serious motive for rebel groups to continue their fight in a country whose gross
domestic product was only $135 million in 1995. Taylor’s use of the state to plun-
der the country’s resources after his 1997 inauguration supports this argument.
However, it is not clear that these resources constituted the main motives for the
start of the war.
Whether one sees ethnic or economic underpinnings of Liberia’s initial war,
ideology was not a driving factor. None of the insurgent groups articulated ideo-
logical motives for taking up arms. Although the anti-NPFL groups claimed to
fight for democracy, Adebajo (2002a, 47) states that these “were essentially ad
hoc ethnic armies led by individuals with dubious democratic credentials.” Com-
mand and control were extremely minimal in these organizations, with their
heavy reliance on spiritual and drug-induced states among a huge number of
child rebels. Horrible atrocities characterized the war.
By late 1990 Taylor’s NPFL had control of 80 percent of Liberia’s territory, all
outside Monrovia. The next five years were characterized by efforts by the anti-
NPFL forces to push back the NPFL’s quick territorial gains, and Taylor’s (un-
successful) efforts to take the capital (Alao, MacKinlay, and Olonisakin 2000).
ECOMOG, whose prompt initial intervention in 1990 had secured Monro-
via, would eventually also come under attack from anti-NPFL forces (Adebajo
2002b). As bloody battles affected tens of thousands of civilians, faction leaders
shuttled to West African capitals in a constant circuit of peace agreements, failure
to fulfill pledges, and renegotiations (Alao, MacKinlay, and Olonisakin 2000).
By 1995, in a crucial strategic shift, the Nigerian government had come to
accept the Ghanaian position of the need to accommodate Taylor and his forces
as part of a settlement of the war. The incorporation of troops from francophone
states into ECOMOG accompanied this shift, opening the way to a regional
consensus on a negotiated settlement that had the support of not only the anti-
NPFL forces but also Taylor’s NPFL. This newfound modus vivendi between
Taylor and Nigeria led to an agreement in the Nigerian capital of Abuja in August
1995. Although that accord foundered amid heavy violence in Monrovia by the
spring, in August 1996 exasperated West African heads of state foisted on the
parties a new, strengthened timetable for Abuja’s implementation, in what came
to be known as the “Abuja II” accord.
Abuja II would govern the end of the first civil war. It revised deadlines for a
cease-fire and concentration of forces; for verification of the same by ECOMOG,
the UN, and a transitional government composed of the factions (“Council of
State”); for disarming and demobilizing the factions; and for national elections.
It also empowered monitors to recommend travel restrictions and the seizure of
assets of recalcitrant warlords, and it authorized ECOWAS to remove any non-
compliant warlords from the Council of State and even from electoral candida-
cies (Pham 2004, 130).
Virtually all experts regard the civil war as concluded by 1996. The peace
agreement that ended the war was signed after Taylor reached a rapprochement
with the regional power, Nigeria, in June 1995, after which the August Abuja
accord was quickly signed (Adebajo 2002b). A cease-fire went into effect that
fall, and fewer than 2 percent of the war’s battle deaths occurred between that
time and early 1997, mainly during the 1996 battle over Monrovia.8 After some
delays, elections were held in August 1997. Taylor left little doubt that his loss
would lead to a return to the horrific warfare of the prior years. Partly due to the
pall of fear and intimidation, Taylor won a large majority. As Lyons (1998, 183)
notes, however, “Postelection powersharing or the need to negotiate the compo-
sition of the new Armed Forces of Liberia, for example, received little attention.
Political leaders preferred to allow the election to settle such contentious issues.”
What followed underscored the perils of using elections and democratization as
a conflict resolution mechanism.
76 Examining the Cases
Sekou Conneh (an ethnic Mandingo), was the son-in-law of Guinea’s presi-
dent. The ebb and flow of the regional conflagration saw LURD pushed back
into Guinea in September 2000 but then boosted, ironically, by Sierra Leone’s
peace process in 2001. Idle combatants from both sides crossed the border to
fight in Liberia. Some five hundred former army soldiers joined LURD, whereas
two thousand former RUF rebels fought alongside Taylor’s government forces
(Pham 2004, 182). Civilians continued to suffer the brunt of indiscriminate at-
tacks, as first one side and then the other would simply invade a town to loot it
and withdraw, and rarely come into direct combat with the opposing forces.
In 2002, LURD advanced to take important towns of Gbargna (home to Tay-
lor’s NPFL-controlled territory in the first war) and Tubmanburg, only to be
pushed back by Liberia’s security forces by October. Taylor’s forces benefited
from internal divisions within LURD, which had no clear political program be-
yond the ouster of Taylor (Human Rights Watch 2002a). Those divisions fell
along the divide between political leaders and military commanders, along with
tensions between Krahns and Mandingos. In early 2003 Liberian Krahns in Côte
d’Ivoire broke from LURD and formed (with Ivorian support) MODEL (Pham
2004, 185). LURD and MODEL constituted the two main rebel groups of the
second civil war.
Conversely, LURD benefited from growing international reprobation of
Taylor due to his continued support for the horrific fighting in Sierra Leone. In
1991, RUF, led by Taylor’s friend Foday Sankoh, launched its insurgency against
Sierra Leone’s government from Liberian soil. Taylor’s NPFL played a key role
in supplying arms. As president, Taylor continued his support of RUF and of the
Armed Forces Revolutionary Council (Olonisakin 2007). That destabilization
of the region undermined support for Taylor during the second war, both from
the big powers and from neighbors in the region.
In June 2003 sitting President Taylor was indicted for war crimes by Sierra
Leone’s Special Court, whose creation had been blessed by the UN Security
Council and the UN General Assembly. This indictment, together with deterio-
rating security and President George W. Bush’s ordering US warships to Liberia
in late July, contributed to Taylor’s resignation and flight to Nigeria. Two weeks
later, on August 18, 2003, a peace accord was signed between the two rebel fac-
tions and Taylor’s successor that led to a transitional government and ended the
second civil war.
Despite widespread corruption among former warlords in that interim gov-
ernment, a peace process enjoyed success seven years later. The warring factions
were demobilized relatively quickly, security sector reforms proceeded, donors
funded extensive reconstruction projects, and the election of President Ellen
Johnson- Sirleaf and a multiparty legislature in 2005 left no renewed warfare
on the horizon in 2010—despite persistent problems of corruption, a lack of
78 Examining the Cases
accountability, weak institutions, and poverty. What explains this second civil
war’s onset, given that end of the prior war and a serious international peace-
building effort? The following sections consider different explanatory factors.
Political Repression
By the end of 1998, however, these steps had proven themselves a chimera. The
most significant exclusionary behavior was Taylor’s repression of political oppo-
nents. By late 1998 Taylor had forced into exile his main political rivals, largely
through his partisan use of loyal security forces engaging in unaccountable ha-
rassment and repression. Sam Dokie, for instance, had become a prominent critic
of Taylor after having once been his ally. On November 28, 1997, Liberian police
detained Dokie and three family members. The next day members of Taylor’s
Special Security Service (SSS) forcibly took the Dokies away, and three days
afterward their mutilated bodies were found (US Department of State 1999, 1).
The SSS members were arrested and released a few months later, and the per-
petrators were never held accountable. The US State Department also reported
that, on several occasions in 1998, “security forces publicly disrobed, flogged,
and humiliated perceived opponents of the administration” (US Department of
State 1999, section 1c).
The most salient act of repression of political opponents targeted former
ULIMO-J leader Johnson and those ex-combatants close to him. On Septem-
ber 18, 1998, hundreds of Liberian security forces and irregulars launched a
planned operation called “Operation Camp Johnson Road” against the follow-
ers of Johnson, allegedly in response to an assassination plot (US Department
of State 1999, 1). Johnson survived the initial attack, and he sought refuge in the
US Embassy, at whose gates the government attacks continued, killing several,
including top deputy Madison Wion (Adebajo 2002a; IRBC 2001; US Depart-
ment of State 1999).11 After seventeen hours and several witnessed extrajudicial
Liberia 79
executions, the US State Department reported more than 300 dead, mostly eth-
nic Krahns (IRBC 2001).
Some observers saw the attack as an attempt to kill Johnson, who was sub-
sequently evacuated from the embassy. His departure ended powersharing in
the Taylor government. Following these seventeen days of unrest in the capi-
tal, some 9,000 persons, mostly ethnic Krahns, fled Liberia (US Department of
State 1999, 1). Two months later, Taylor accused thirty-two people—including
Johnson and his other main rivals, such as Ellen Johnson-Sirleaf, Alhaji Kromah,
and George Boley—of involvement in the plot (Adebajo 2002b). Several were
subsequently convicted in absentia or jailed, which seriously undermined the
possibility of unarmed political opposition.
Media Suppression
Taylor also used his presidential power to stifle media critics. Six months into
his term, his Ministry of Information ordered the country’s only private print-
ing press closed because of “inflammatory” editorials, although it reopened after
an apology. Police flogged the publisher of another twice-weekly newspaper in
January 1998, and Taylor’s security services periodically threatened journalists
and editors, leading to a degree of self-censorship among the most critical media
(US Department of State 1999, 3). Harassment of the media continued through
1999 and until the war ended (Williams 2006). Two radio stations were closed
in March 2000 (Adebajo 2002a).
the Liberian people in general. . . . This was in effect, a political settlement that
was intended to put an end to seven years of a bloody civil war. It was believed
then, that confidence, a necessary element of national reconciliation and lasting
peace, would have to be nurtured, beginning with the intents of the parties in
good faith to make peace. Evidence in this case may be found in the fact that the
first post-war government which is now headed by Mr. Taylor, was mandated
to restructure the Army, Police and the various security agencies with a view to
reflect neutrality. That is, none of the parties to the agreement was to maintain
dominance over the army or any of the security agencies. (LURD 2002)
Alternative Explanations
Having set forth the case for a precipitating role by Charles Taylor’s exclusion-
ary behavior, what can one make of the several widely perceived causal factors
in Liberia’s war recurrence in 1999 and 2000? This section explores the main
alternative explanations for the renewed armed hostilities.
Regional Factors?
What role did regional factors play in Liberia’s civil war recurrence? Certainly
regional factors played a salient role in the onset, duration, character, and recur-
rence of internal armed conflicts throughout West Africa. In some ways Liberia’s
wars, along with those of Sierra Leone and Côte d’Ivoire, are best analyzed as
manifestations of a single regional dynamic from 1989 to 2007. Rebel armies were
formed with the diplomatic support and funding of neighboring states; cross-
border rearguards played important roles in all cases; smuggling networks cut
across borders; refugees became strategic resources in mobilizing combatants;
82 Examining the Cases
International Factors?
What role might international factors more broadly have played in civil war re-
currence? Some analysts, after all, believe that, with the end of the Cold War, the
United States’ neglect and the subsequent aid cutoff were the decisive factors
in the onset of war in Liberia a month after the Berlin Wall fell in 1989 (Pham
2004, 89–91). Did the West topple Taylor? Was the UN mission or its missteps
responsible for the recurrence of armed conflict?
International factors played a role in Liberia’s war recurrence, but they consti-
tuted neither the main cause of war recurrence nor a major factor in Taylor’s vio-
lation of expectations surrounding the peace process. Some initial steps showed
support for the peace process. International actors facilitated the end of a war-
time shipping embargo and the reopening of seaports and airports.
Yet Western governments approached Taylor’s presidency with hesitation.
Although they viewed Taylor as a necessary part of the peace process in the
Liberia 83
mid-1990s, Western diplomats were well aware of his reputation for avarice and
corruption, of his ethnicity-based alliances, and of horrific rights abuses. At the
first donor conference under Taylor’s presidency, donor pledges of $230 million
reached only half the $438 million requested by the government (Eziakonwa
1998, 26).14 In addition, diplomatic sources in Liberia insisted publicly in mid-
1998 “that the government must implement more macroeconomic adjustment,
control its security forces, and attend to human rights as the preconditions for
providing new foreign aid to Liberia.”15 These concerns with democracy, corrup-
tion, and human rights rendered disbursements very slow.
The most significant international actions toward the Taylor administration
stemmed from his role in fostering warfare in the region, especially Sierra Le-
one. As Liberia’s peace process came to fruition, Taylor-backed RUF forces and
disgruntled former soldiers (the Armed Forces Revolutionary Council, AFRC)
took the capital for the first time in May 1997. They ousted that country’s presi-
dent, Ahmed Kabbah, who enjoyed the backing of the West and ECOWAS.
ECOMOG deployed in force to Freetown, becoming the main force confront-
ing the RUF–AFRC alliance (International Crisis Group 2002, 2). The regional
force ousted the rebel regime from the capital in February 1998.
ECOWAS represented the single most important external relationship for
the Taylor administration, and tensions over Sierra Leone intensified. Although
ECOWAS leaders had decided to accommodate rather than continue fighting
Taylor in the Abuja agreements of 1995 and 1996, that decision was rooted in the
hope that peace in Liberia would curb Taylor’s support for RUF in Sierra Leone
(International Crisis Group 2002, 2). Yet as Liberia’s peace process progressed,
Taylor-supported RUF forces surged rather than ebbed, undermining the rap-
prochement with Taylor. RUF rebels had killed dozens of Nigerian ECOMOG
troops in May 1997, and as president, Taylor refused ECOMOG jets access to
Liberian airfields for their Sierra Leonean operations. Upon his election, Taylor
also successfully pressured Nigerian president Sani Abacha to replace ECOMOG
force commander Victor Malu, who had insisted on ECOMOG’s independence
from Taylor’s government and on ECOMOG’s role in restructuring Liberia’s
armed forces (Adebajo 2002b). Boosted by the legitimacy of his election and
by international ambivalence about paying for peacekeepers and reconstruction
activities in a corrupt environment, Taylor weakened ECOMOG’s influence, es-
pecially its ability to restructure the armed forces. Its troops departed Liberia in
late 1998.
Largely because of Taylor’s support for the insurgency in Sierra Leone, do-
nors failed to provide him with resources or diplomatic support. Rather than
attempting to use diplomatic leverage to shape his behavior, they withdrew their
support. In March 2001, the United States sponsored unilateral sanctions, and
the United States and United Kingdom backed UN Security Council resolutions
84 Examining the Cases
Will Reno observed that “the war has been as much a battle over commerce
inside and beyond Liberia’s borders as it has been a war for territory or control
of the government.”20 Once the first war ended, disarmament and demobiliza-
tion occurred to a lesser degree in areas of natural resource concentration. This
pattern suggests that control of those resources underlay that process (Alao,
MacKinlay, and Olonisakin 2000, 100).
Economic motivations must be included in Taylor’s motives for waging a
regional war even once it was apparent he would become president in Liberia.
His own survival and his political power were apparent motives for his regional
aggressiveness. He remained, for example, extremely frightened for his own
personal security. Similarly, ethnic alliances and the training he and ally Foday
Sankoh received in Libya fostered political affinities. Yet no analysts allege any
strong ideological character to Taylor’s platform or his behavior. Taylor’s in-
volvement in smuggling diamonds, timber, and other natural resources was an
important component of the regional dynamic. His involvement in supporting
RUF, despite his protestations, was documented by a panel of experts formed
by the UN Security Council in 2000. Although he tried to forestall sanctions
by grounding his aircraft and inviting international monitoring against diamond
smuggling, the international community was unconvinced (Adebajo 2002b). In
March 2001 the UN Security Council, at the behest of the United States and
the United Kingdom, approved a ban on the sale of Liberian diamonds, an arms
embargo, and a travel ban targeting Liberia’s political leaders and their families
(Pham 2004, 182).
Of course the state is a powerful source of legitimate access to money, as dem-
onstrated by the rapid increase in tax revenues once postwar elections were held.
According to the Taylor government, it increased state revenues from a little more
than $1 million in the first seven months of 1997, just before Taylor assumed of-
fice, to $125 million in the subsequent five months (Eziakonwa 1998, 26). This
view is supported also by Taylor’s efforts to expand presidential authority over
strategic natural resource contracts. In 2000 Taylor also got the Assembly to pass
a law granting him the sole power to conclude commercial contracts for strategic
commodities, and thus channel their revenues directly to his control (Thomson
Reuters Foundation 2001). One report asserts that the Taylor / Sankoh split that
led to the capture and holding of more than 500 ECOMOG soldiers in 2000
by RUF was sparked by a dispute over access to Sierra Leone’s diamond fields
(International Crisis Group 2002, 3).
These empirics suggest that natural resources and private gain were crucial in
accounting for the first war and its persistence. Because combatant factions do
not generally acknowledge their economic motives as ends rather than means,
it is impossible to conclude with certainty the role such factors play in warfare.21
Taylor’s exploitation of the state for personal gain is undeniable, and it is difficult
88 Examining the Cases
to determine whether his former allies and enemies took up arms because of
their political, social, or economic exclusion from the spoils of the state, and
whether their individual exclusion or that of their ethnic group was causal.
However, the role of natural resources and private gain seems less persuasive
in understanding why war resumed in 1999 and 2000. Taylor’s exclusionary be-
havior is the indispensable factor in explaining civil war’s recurrence in Liberia.
The factions opposed to Taylor did not immediately challenge his government,
indicating that their treatment by Taylor was relevant in the decision to defect.
At a minimum, their desire for access to the spoils of power was mediated by
the marginalization perceived to stem from Taylor’s repression and exclusion.
Although LURD’s financing proved murky, it was not involved in commercial
logging until very late in the war after it took control of most of the country
(Brabazon 2003, 5). Indeed, some LURD commanders feared that exploiting
diamond mines would lose them the moral high ground against Taylor, even
when they took control of important mining areas in early 2002 (Brabazon 2003,
6): “During LURD’s initial occupation of this area, individual commanders and
fighters reportedly sold stones on a personal basis, a practice which led to one
colonel being ambushed by his own troops. Indeed, it is this fear that diamond
wealth will split the organization with financial jealousy that has so far prevented
any concerted effort to exploit mineral resources.”
The empirics suggest that both “greed” and “grievance” played a role in civil
war recurrence but that the latter was the clearest and most important precipi-
tating factor in a complex interaction process. Natural resources were important
when Taylor excluded even his allies from the spoils of office, and they again
became a factor once LURD had launched the renewed war in funding opera-
tions and attracting combatants. Yet exclusionary behavior seemed to underlie
the motives as seen through both rebel actions and rhetoric during the second
civil war. Moreover, Taylor’s conduct also shows how weak institutions that are
created by exclusionary conduct not only reflected weak institutions but also
helped to reinforce, and even reconstitute anew, the country’s personalized and
weak state institutions (Sawyer 1990, 148–73).
had a budget of more than $781 million for the second year after a new presi-
dent was elected following the second civil war, from July 2007 to June 2008
(Dupuy and Detzel 2007, 17). The decision of the UN Security Council to itself
authorize 15,000 troops in 2003, rather than rely upon ECOWAS to provide
peacekeepers, also reflected greater external commitment. Although US troops
never landed on Liberia’s shores, President George W. Bush’s decision to station
marines just offshore in August 2003 signaled their potential to intervene and a
greater priority than during the 1990s.
More significant was the decision to maintain peacekeepers for a period of
years after the 2005 elections. This decision contrasted starkly with the with-
drawal of UN troops within two months of Taylor’s swearing-in in 1997. Dupuy
and Detzel (2007, 23) conclude that “the success of the CPA [Comprehensive
Peace Agreement] is likely due to the deployment of UNMIL, which has pro-
vided public security and maintained stability in the country.” The difference
between the swift departure of foreign troops after the 1997 election and the sus-
tained peacekeeping presence since 2003 lends support to the findings of Fortna
and of Doyle and Sambanis that peacekeeping troops’ prolonged presence, es-
pecially when part of a multidimensional peace operation, reduces the chance
of war recurrence (Fortna 2008; Doyle and Sambanis 2006; Sambanis 2008).
Another measure of the seriousness of the international commitment were
the sanctions adopted by the UN Security Council on the importing of any
Liberian-produced diamonds, on the exporting of arms into Liberia, and later
on the importing of Liberian timber.24 No such leverage was exercised during
or after the prior war. Crucially for international leverage, the UN considered
and rejected a 2004 Liberian request to list the restrictions, providing continued
leverage over the Liberian government until the revocation of all such targeted
sanctions in 2008. Linked to this effort was the broader, more comprehensive
approach to postwar peacebuilding by external actors. Although the approach
was similar, the breadth of civilian commitment was greater after the second war
ended in 2003, with longer-term and better funded reform projects for the secu-
rity and justice sectors, the financial sector, and the civil service.
Second, in terms of internal economic or political strategic choices, the most
salient factor in the preservation of peace since the 2003 cease-fire ended Li-
beria’s second civil war has been the inclusionary character of governance, eco-
nomic, and security arrangements. The August 2003 Accra Peace Agreement
brought an end to the war, and it enshrined an interim powersharing arrange-
ment. Like the peace accords signed during the first war (including Abuja), this
agreement has continued to reward faction leaders by granting them personal
positions in the Cabinet, and thus permitting them to plunder state resources for
personal gain in keeping with political economy theories.
Liberia 91
Conclusion
What explanations of Liberia’s second civil war are most persuasive? How well
do the circumstances and factors surrounding Liberia’s renewed warfare con-
form to various theories?
Liberia’s experience from 1996 through 2000 provides support for several
theories of civil war and its recurrence. Liberia is a poor society with weak state
institutions, lying among war-torn neighbors, and highly dependent on natural
92 Examining the Cases
resources, where young men constitute a large proportion of the population and
where ethnic divisions are significant. Neighboring states and the international
response to Charles Taylor’s warmongering in Sierra Leone contributed a rear-
guard, resources, and even combatants to LURD and MODEL. However, these
new insurgent groups were not created by external actors nor principally by the
lure of economic rents but by Liberians reacting to Taylor’s policies.
As shown above, natural resources like timber, rubber, and minerals played an
important role as incentives to and resources for civil war. This political economy
explanation represents the most plausible alternative to the role of exclusionary
behavior during the interwar period. Yet Taylor’s exclusion of all his main op-
ponents from the political stage, not to mention his violence and discrimination
against them, was the primary driver of Liberia’s war recurrence. Unprovoked by
any coherent armed opposition, Taylor began to repress his political opponents
and regional rivals soon upon acceding to the presidency. He then reneged on the
international and national expectation surrounding the downsizing, reform, and
curricular revision of the armed forces and stalled on these stipulated changes.
Despite the absence of detailed provisions for inclusion in the peace process of
1996–97, he violated expectations by dismissing his former enemies from the
government after promising them a share of power, he increasingly pushed out
his former enemies from the army and security services, and he used violence
and threats of arrest against some of these dismissed officials.
Taylor’s exclusionary behavior, especially in the security services, involved
patron–client networks that marginalized ethnic Krahns and Mandingos. His
policies led former ULIMO combatants to reorganize and challenge the state.
The competing informal networks characteristic of a weak state fell along the
lines of ethnic difference and grievance, fueled by a lack of resources. Yet nei-
ther weak institutions nor ethnic diversity per se is a sufficient explanation. Tay-
lor’s transparent ethnic manipulation made the difference. His exclusion was so
egregious that many of his senior followers through the end of the first civil war
helped form LURD. In the end, grievance accounts for this “tough” case of civil
war recurrence at least as much as the economic factors prevalent in the contem-
porary literature.
Beyond the substance suggested by this case study, it offers a chance to reflect
on case studies as a method of researching civil wars and their recurrence. This
case study, though based principally on secondary sources, offers some clear
advantages over the quantitative methods examined in chapter 1. Quantitative
methods can identify and confirm the likely causal impact of variables that can be
measured comparably across many cases, including institutional arrangements
like powersharing and risk factors like poverty or dependence on oil exports.
Unless they find a 100 percent correlation, such methods are obviously unable to
specify whether such variables are operative in any given case. Moreover, quan-
Liberia 93
titative methods cannot capture the strategic choices made by elites, even when
these are conditioned by risk factors or institutional arrangements.
This Liberia case study shows the value of qualitative methods for under-
standing the role of elite choices in postwar societies. Taylor’s decision to renege
on the arrangements agreed upon is crucial for explaining Liberia’s war recur-
rence. Despite the deliberate self-interested misrepresentation of motives, how
rebels frame their motives is relevant for understanding causes of civil wars and
the lines along which mobilization does or does not occur.
Case studies also hold heuristic value. Even a relatively structured and fo-
cused case study such as this one reveals empirics that suggest new lines of in-
quiry and potential causal factors that may require greater attention. This case
study has revealed the salience of regional and international levels of analysis.
Quantitative analysis has addressed these factors by retaining country-level units
of analysis but also including variables for “regional” impact or neighbors at war;
however, these efforts do not entirely capture the insights provided by shifting
levels of analysis. This shift, though not executed in this study (e.g., I did not
examine West Africa’s conflict cluster, the Great Lakes conflict cluster, or the
Central American conflict cluster), can nevertheless be identified and explored
in a case study. The case would be strengthened by more detailed process tracing
of the various factors that shaped Taylor’s decision making, including access to
advice he received and the pressures of various domestic constituencies, as well
as the application of psychological methods.
Qualitative methods, and this case study specifically, also carry liabilities.
Aside from its execution, a case study of Liberia cannot wholly sift through the
economic versus the power-based political motives of Charles Taylor or his asso-
ciates once in office. That difficulty undermines the effectiveness of the method
and the persuasiveness of the argument. Even more empirical detail would prob-
ably not produce a definitive finding.
Moreover, the robustness of a particular variable is not verifiable based on a
single case study. Those who execute case studies perceive their findings to apply
more broadly, at least to similarly situated cases. However, a variable that seems
consequential may be irrelevant in all other cases. Only through an examination
of other cases (whether similar or not) can one determine whether a particular
factor is relevant for the entire pool of cases. It is to such a method that I subse-
quently turn by conducting briefer, more structured, and more focused “mini”
or abbreviated case studies.
94 Examining the Cases
Notes
1. Several sources cite the 150,000 estimate of total deaths; e.g., see Stedman (1996,
252 n36).
2. Although the government did not verify the identity of the rebels as Liberian,
Reuters reported that locals alleged them to be members of ULIMO-K and ULIMO-J.
3. LURD was formed in February 2000 by former Taylor allies, consisted mainly of
former ULIMO-K members, but included also former members of prior rebel groups
ULIMO-J, the Liberia Peace Council, and former government soldiers.
4. Peace Research Institute Oslo (PRIO) Conflict Summaries, 2003a. Available
from the author.
5. The coup attempt was led by General Thomas Quiwonkpa, the founder of the
National Patriotic Front of Liberia, which Taylor would eventually command.
6. The NPFL also included Burkinabe, Gambian, and Sierra Leonean mercenaries.
7. This paragraph draws on Adebajo (2002a, 46–47).
8. PRIO Conflict Summaries for Africa, 2003a.
9. Statement released April 25, 1999, from the Global Security Organization web-
site on military factions, www.globalsecurity.org / military / world / para / lurd.htm.
10. Peter Dennis, “A Brief History of Liberia,” paper for the International Center for
Transitional Justice, May 2006, author’s files, 14.
11. Wion had allegedly confessed to involvement in the assassination plot (IRBC
2001).
12. Taylor cited the wording of the Akosombo Agreement, which stipulated that
planning for the restructuring and training of the military would be the responsibil-
ity of the Liberian Transitional National Government, with support from interna-
tional actors. See Akosombo Agreement, September 12, 1994, Section H, Article 9,
Count 4.
13. Nicole Itano emphasizes the tactical consequences of this divisive style, as a
weakened military proved unable to defend Monrovia against the rebels’ advance. See
Itano (2003, 3).
14. The donor conference was held in Paris in April 1998.
15. “Liberian Daily News Bulletin,” Star Radio, July 24, 1998, as quoted by Geepu-
Nah Tiepoh, “The Hubbub over Foreign Aid: Facing the Sobering Reality,” www
.theperspective.org / hubbub.html.
16. Author’s personal interviews, Monrovia and Dakar, August 2004.
17. The company was earlier the Oriental Timber Company, and later the Liberian-
Malaysian Timber Company.
18. One was the December 2000 report of the Sierra Leone Expert Panel, and an-
other was the October 2001 report of the UN Panel of Experts on Liberia.
19. Stephen Ellis, quoted by Pham (2004, 121).
20. William Reno, quoted by Pham (2004, 121n1).
Liberia 95
21. As Collier et al. argue in Breaking the Conflict Trap (2003), rebel leaders have
many incentives to hide their true selfish motives behind rhetoric that instead empha-
sizes legitimate collective grievances.
22. Also from the author’s interviews with officials of UNMIL and Western embas-
sies, Monrovia, August 2004.
23. See UN General Assembly Resolution 51 / 3 C, June 13, 1997. Of course,
ECOWAS played a more prominent and expensive role than the UN in the war as
well as afterward. One scholar estimates that Nigeria spent more than $4 billion on
ECOMOG alone in the 1990s (Coleman 2007, 85); however, Western states’ defer-
ence to the African Union (rather than the UN) itself reflects the low priority given
Liberia’s peace process by those states.
24. See UN Security Council Resolution 1343, March 7, 2001, and UN Security
Council Resolution 1521, December 22, 2003. UNSC Resolution 1343 was revoked
on November 20, 2008, by UN Sanctions Regulations Amendment SR 2008 / 394.
4
Separatist Recurrences of
Civil War
Before embarking on this and the next two chapters on the recurrent cases of
armed conflict, I summarize the six main findings presented in these three chap-
ters, as drawn from the fifteen total cases. First, precipitating exclusionary behavior
is the most evident and cited proximate cause for recurrence in most cases—in nine
of fifteen cases, or 60 percent. Recall that precipitating exclusionary behavior goes
beyond a static condition of exclusion. In these nine cases postwar states adopted
a policy that violated the expectations of the former rebels or their followers and
supporters, and this exclusionary conduct served as the principal precipitating
factor for the recurrence of civil war or internal armed conflict. These nine cases
are the Central African Republic, China / Tibet, East Timor, Georgia, Haiti, Li-
beria, Russia / Chechnya, Sudan, and Zimbabwe.
Four of these cases—those based on secessionist struggles—are the subject
of this chapter. In an additional four cases—Haiti, the Central African Republic,
East Timor, and Zimbabwe—political exclusion was a driving factor in the re-
currence of armed conflict. These cases, whose recurrences were not rooted in se-
cessionist aspirations (even where the original war may have been thus rooted, as
in East Timor), are addressed in chapter 5. Liberia also fits this pattern of exclu-
sion and thus serves as a key trigger for the recurrence of internal armed conflict.
Second, exclusion by the state against its former wartime allies constitutes a sepa-
rate subset of war recurrences. In some cases where a coalition of insurgent armies
emerges victorious, exclusionary behavior by one victorious actor against a war-
time ally constitutes the principal precipitating factor in a relapse into armed
conflict. East Timor and Zimbabwe present cases of triumphant liberation move-
ments whose leaders, once in power, acted in an exclusionary manner toward
their former allies, which sparked renewed armed conflict.
Separatist Recurrences of Civil War 99
Third, a violation of powersharing arrangements was the trigger for war recurrence
in 40 percent of the core cases of recurrence. Precipitating exclusionary conduct may
rest on formal agreements or on unwritten, informal arrangements that create
certain expectations (as in Haiti, Burundi, and East Timor). In six of the fifteen
cases of recurrence—Sudan, Russia (in Chechnya), Georgia (in South Ossetia),
Liberia, the Central African Republic, and Zimbabwe—the state reneged on an
explicit, signed powersharing agreement, either to cede central power over a ter-
ritory or to share institutional power in political offices or military / police posts.
In Chechnya the role of reneging on a powersharing arrangement was an impor-
tant factor, but not the sole trigger.
Fourth, severe, chronic exclusionary conduct, though insufficient to postulate as
a correlated or causal variable, played a role in two war recurrences. In these two
additional cases of Burundi and Rwanda, exclusionary behavior was not the pre-
cipitating factor but is cited by virtually all analysts as a crucial causal factor. In
these interactive recurrences in adjacent, demographically similar states, severe
exclusionary behavior served as the constant backdrop to the eruption of resis-
tance and its harsh repression, which cost hundreds of thousands of lives. These
state policies, following earlier mass violence that had been deemed (perhaps in-
correctly) a civil war, reflect the most severe exclusionary behavior for the cases
observed. I refer to this as severe, “chronic exclusion,” a term that identifies a
risk factor for conflict recurrence but inadequately specifies whether (or when or
how) armed conflict will recur in a given society. The concept of chronic, severe
exclusion is thus useful to understand a subset of recurrent internal armed con-
flicts but not as a trigger of war recurrence. The cases of severe, chronic exclusion
in Burundi and Rwanda are examined in chapter 5.
Fifth, exclusionary conduct is not the only salient factor in these recurrences; how-
ever, it is the most consistently important one. Natural resources and economic fac-
tors were not a primary causal factor in any of the fifteen core cases except Peru
(which is analyzed in chapter 6, along with other nonconforming cases), where
the reemergence of the Shining Path insurgency coincided with its new role not
just in taxing cultivators of coca but also in its trafficking. However, natural re-
sources acted as an interrelated, secondary factor in four other cases of recur-
rence. Thus recurrence was influenced by the interaction of exclusion with oil
production or transportation in the Sudan and Chechnya; and with minerals in
Liberia and the Central African Republic.
Except for four states—Russia, Peru, Lebanon, and Georgia—the core cases
were predominantly poor. These cases also score high on the various indicators
of state institutional weakness. Haiti, East Timor, the Central African Republic,
Sudan, Zimbabwe, and Mali rank among the world’s least institutionalized states.
The qualitative research here indicates that these two factors identified by the
economy-centered literature on civil wars are relevant risk factors. Poverty and
100 Examining the Cases
state weakness enhance the risk of recurrence, but recurrence is most often trig-
gered by state exclusionary behavior.
Sixth, and most important, the points noted above indicate that exclusionary be-
havior was the most important causal factor in eleven of the fifteen cases, or 73 percent,
of recurrence of armed conflicts. Postwar states engaged in exclusionary conduct in
thirteen of the fifteen cases, or 87 percent, although it was not the main cause in
two of these. Again, these six central findings are presented in this and the next
two chapters. I now turn to the first subset of cases whose recurrences reflected
separatist aspirations.
As in Liberia, exclusion by postwar governments served as a trigger for re-
newed conflict in eight other core cases. Exclusion took various forms. I begin by
analyzing the cases of powersharing over separatist territories. Rather than offer
key analytic points prematurely, here I present four mini–case studies: Sudan’s re-
current civil war (1955–72 and 1983–2005), Russia’s two civil wars in Chechnya
(1994–96 and 1999–), South Ossetia’s recurrent armed conflict against Georgia
(1992–94 and 2004; the 2008 war and the Russian invasion were too recent
for this study), and China’s two wars in and over Tibet’s autonomy (1950–51
and 1956–60). Subsequently, I analyze the findings from all four cases.
Sudan is the largest country in Africa, and its northern part is occupied by
the Sahara Desert. A British census in the aftermath of independence in January
1956 showed that 55 percent of the population claimed African descent, and
39 percent claimed Arab ancestry. Most of those African Sudanese lived in the
southern region, but almost half (45 percent) of those African Sudanese lived
with their Arab compatriots in the eastern and other non-southern regions
(Poggo 2009, 15). Because Sudanese “Arabs” are generally descended from a
mixture of Arab, Nubian, and black African races, the term is more cultural than
racial (Suliman 1997, 100). In the nineteenth century, the slavery of some 2 mil-
lion black southerners mainly at the hands of Arabs and Western colonists led to
the assimilation of darker-skinned peoples into Arab ways, Islam, and intermar-
riage (Anderson 1999, 65). Thus the rebel leader John Garang was fond of say-
ing that more Africans lived in the supposedly Arab-dominated North of Sudan
than in the South (Poggo 2009, 19). Ethnic distinctions also characterized the
South, where the most numerous black African tribes were the Dinka and the
Nuer (Poggo 2009, 13).
The roots of the first civil war center on the aspirations for self-government
of the South and perceived northern resistance to this end. This resistance pre-
dated and anticipated Sudan’s independence on January 1, 1956. Northern po-
litical parties, in an effort to preemptively occupy the state posts and political
space that independence would afford, became expansive and more absolute
in their expressions of Sudanese unity (Poggo 2009, 35). Because they were
wrapped up in their negotiations with the colonial occupiers of Egypt and Brit-
ain, the northern parties neglected southern actors. The southerners increas-
ingly saw that their marginal role in decision making during this interim period
foreshadowed their continued exclusion (Poggo 2009, 34). They increasingly
expressed their frustration and eventually withdrew from the transitional ar-
rangements. Thus the dynamics in the years 1954–56 in Sudan reflect a falling
out among the main domestic protagonists in a process of the emergence of a
new country.
On August 18, 1955, soldiers in the town of Torit in Sudan’s southernmost
province of Equatoria received long-rumored orders to report for transporta-
tion to northern postings, which allegedly were aimed at weakening and dividing
southern soldiers within the national army. They attacked their northern officers
and stole arms and ammunition, and the soldiers in other southern towns soon
followed suit, which led to roughly four hundred deaths, mostly of northerners
(Poggo 2009, 42). The mutiny marks the onset of the civil war, which continued
in the following months and accelerated partly in response to severe repression
carried out by the North (Poggo 2009, 52–53).
After the 1955 mutiny, a Commission of Inquiry found that “the Southern
Army revolt was the final outburst after the Southern political claims had been
frustrated” (quoted by Poggo 2009, 56). In a recent detailed study of the origins
of the first war, Poggo (2009) concludes that the 1955 mutiny of the Equatoria
Corps “was the culmination of frustration after many years of discrimination”
against southerners, grievances “compounded by the Sudanese government’s
refusal to grant federal status to the South” (p. 49). She adds that southern de-
mands for a federated system (not even independence) were “totally ignored” by
the northern political leadership (p. 50). Northerners’ exclusion of southerners
continued in the late 1950s: in discrimination in state posts, including their total
exclusion from the Foreign Ministry; in the 1956 formation of a forty-six-person
constitutional drafting commission that contained only three southerners; and
in the composition of the legislature, where southerners chafed at their degree
of underrepresentation (pp. 52–58). Moreover, the repression of any seeming
dissent further deepened southerners’ marginalization and the civil war.
The rebel bands remained inchoate and small between 1955 and 1963, which
partly accounts for the starting dates of the war in the 1960s. The Sudan African
National Union (SANU) was formed in 1962 in Kinshasa, but it was viewed by
Separatist Recurrences of Civil War 103
the rebels as a futile diplomatic forum (O’Ballance 2000, 17–19). But in 1963
the rebels organized, adopted the name the Anya-Nya, and launched more at-
tacks in the mid-1960s while using the Republic of the Congo and Uganda as
refuges (O’Ballance 2000, 21–23). By the mid-1960s, SANU had split to form
new political groups, some tied to the Anya-Nya, that by now demanded inde-
pendence rather than federation.
In contrast to other cases, Sudan’s religious and ethnic dimensions seem more
intertwined, because marginalization and mobilization have occurred along both
lines, and it is impossible to dismiss one or the other. Furthermore, rather than
an entirely Christian composition, the rebels of the South included numerous
Muslims (Iyob and Khadiagala 2006, 32). The parties to conflict utilized these
terms—“Arab,” “African”—explicitly to mobilize greater adherents. Anticolonial
nationalists reappropriated the term “Arab” in the 1920s in resistance to British
colonial discourse. Only later did some adopt “African” as a gesture against their
disenfranchisement under the “hegemonic rule of their Arabized compatriots”
(Iyob and Khadiagala 2006, 31).
External actors also played an important role in this first war, beyond the pre-
independence policies of Egypt and Britain. Between 1960 and 1972, the Soviet
Union, Great Britain, various Arab countries, East Germany, Yugoslavia, and
China all supplied the Sudanese government with sophisticated arms and aircraft
(Poggo 2009, 1). The southern rebels were greatly strengthened in resources
and arms by the Israeli government, which passed on arms captured in the Six-
Day War and sought to undermine the Arab-dominated Sudanese government
(Poggo 2009, 2).
The Peace
Colonel Gaafar Muhammad Nimeiri had come to power initially as a socialist
and secularist, but after a Communist coup was turned back in 1971, he moved
toward the West and away from radical change. The United States responded
warmly to this shift and gave $18 million for refugee resettlement in support of
the peace accord (Anderson 1999, 17). Partly out of a desire to bolster his sup-
port in the South, Nimeiri also sought to negotiate an end to the seventeen-year
civil war. In 1972, the Addis Ababa agreement was signed between the Nimeiri
government and the now more unified political-military insurgency, the South
Sudan Liberation Movement. A cease-fire went into effect with general success
that year. The negotiations were facilitated by the agreement of the Ethiopians
to cease supporting the rebels in exchange for Nimeiri’s commitment to cease
support for the Eritrean rebels. The negotiations process was formally chaired
by the emperor of Ethiopia and was mediated by Liberian canon Burgess Carr
of the All-African Council of Churches (Mitchell 1989, 8; Assefa 1987, 131–43).
104 Examining the Cases
The peace agreement provided for considerable autonomy for the South un-
der a regional government with its own high executive council and a regional as-
sembly—all enacted into law. The regional entity would have legislative author-
ity over education, health, public security, and natural resources (e.g., oil), but
not defense, currency, or foreign affairs (Daly 1993, 19). Mechanisms were also
created to help prevent and resolve tensions between the central government
(where southerners continued to have representation) and the new regional
bodies. Arabic continued as the official language of the whole country, but En-
glish became the “common language” of the South and was taught in schools
(Mitchell 1989, 8). After the most difficult negotiations (Assefa 1987, 131–34),
the parties agreed on the incorporation of an estimated 12,000 rebels into the
state’s armed forces and police. Mitchell (1989, 8) reports: “This force would,
for a transitional term, be under the command of a commission of northerners
and southerners, until the south had set up its own machinery for maintaining
law and order, which was to consist of an armed police force and between 2,000
and 3,000 frontier guards.”
The agreement retained the unity of the country while offering the prom-
ise of substantial autonomy and security guarantees. It is generally considered a
successful peace negotiation, and a crucial factor in both the eleven-year inter-
war peace and the recovery of some stability for the Nimeiri regime (Mitchell
1989, 9).
the Southern politicians themselves.” Related to these actions to roll back the
autonomy that southerners expected in their public security and legal systems,
not to mention religious and cultural life, Nimeiri reneged on other elements of
the accord and thus redrew the South’s internal divisions.
The Anya-Nya II, led by some of the same commanders, joined with other
mutineers in 1983 to form the Sudan People’s Liberation Army, which was con-
nected to its political arm, the Sudan People’s Liberation Movement ( Johnson
and Prunier 1993, 125). Colonel John Garang, who had fought with the rebels
in the first civil war, was sent as an army officer to negotiate with rebels in 1983
when he defected to join them ( Johnson and Prunier 1993, 124).
Overall, academic treatments of the Sudanese recurrence of civil war empha-
size the exclusionary behavior of the Sudanese government. Mitchell (1989, 2),
for instance, says that the Addis Ababa agreement provided the basis for peace
between North and South “until the terms and the spirit of the Agreement were
unilaterally undermined by Nimeiry, one of its main architects, and war broke
out again.” Johnson and Prunier (1993, 124) say that “Nimayri prepared for the
abolition of the Southern region by arresting pro-unionist Southern politicians
and transferring Southern troops to the North.” And Wakoson (1993, 29) says
that “the Northern ruling elite have consistently ignored Southerners’ demand
for federalism. The result of this intransigence has been the continual constitu-
tional crisis and civil wars dominating Sudanese national politics since 1955.”
Although many analysts of the war recurrence stress the North’s efforts to gar-
ner resources from the South, none place economic factors or natural resources
at the center of their explanation. However, natural resources, especially the dis-
covery of larger oil reserves in the 1980s and 1990s mainly in the South, are a
relevant factor in renewed warfare. Suliman’s (1997) neo-Marxist analysis explic-
itly argues that the ethnoreligious divisions that are emphasized by virtually all
analysts of the second civil war are overstated and that economic factors play an
important role, especially as the war wore on. He notes that Chevron announced
the discovery of new oil reserves in the southwest in 1981, amounting to 12 per-
cent of the estimated national reserves of 2 billion barrels at the time. Nimeiri
angered southern elites in 1982 when he announced that the country’s first re-
finery would be constructed south of Port Sudan rather than closer to the South
(Suliman 1997, 115). Among the earliest attacks of the second war in 1984 were
on oil fields in the South, which disrupted production there for several years.
Even so, Suliman (1997, 110–15) and Daly (1993, 21–23) emphasize the ef-
fects of economic crisis and export-led economic and agricultural policies rather
than oil, which receives only a tertiary mention. Indeed, the case lends support
to the thesis, contrary to Collier and his colleagues, that negative World Bank
and International Monetary Fund policies proved more important than any par-
ticular natural resource in facilitating the second war. Those policies undercut
106 Examining the Cases
at this time: Russian political elites hoped that a military victory would give them
political capital, they were concerned about organized crime, and they were wor-
ried about the precedent that Chechen secession might set.3 A Russian missile at-
tack killed Chechen president Dudayev in April 1996, bringing together the sep-
aratist forces. They recaptured the capital on August 6, 1996. That same month,
Russia’s popular general Alexsandr Lebed and then–general Aslan Maskhadov
signed the Khasavyurt Accords, providing for a cease-fire and the withdrawal of
Russian troops. A tenuous period of peace ensued.
Chechnya’s war recurrence in 1999 may seem like it does not meet the stan-
dard of reneging on the part of the state. Kremlinologists, however, viewed the
war in Chechnya as not just potentially destabilizing in Russia but also one
that had a major political impact, sealing the fate of one president and opening
the way for another. In the words of Lieven (1998, 102), “The first week of the
Chechen War marked one of the most critical moments in the history of the
Yeltsin administration and indeed of modern Russia. . . . This is because, for a
few days, there seemed to be a real possibility that the unity of the Russian army
would crack, and with it the obedience of the junior commanders to the Defence
Ministry and the military hierarchy.”
The first war “very nearly led to Boris Yeltsin’s impeachment” (Lieven 1998,
102). The second civil war was also intimately tied to regime stability in Moscow.
Once Vladimir Putin became president upon Yeltsin’s resignation three months
before the March 2000 elections, “renewal of the war against Chechnya . . . se-
cured Putin’s victory” (Evangelista 2002, 6). Putin’s career rose with the specter
of renewed warfare in Chechnya.
Alternative Explanations
Other factors played at most a secondary role. Although state weakness as a factor
is generally assessed with regard to the central state (in which an internal conflict
occurs), the weakness of Chechen pseudo–state institutions by 1999 played a
role in conflict recurrence. Putin and Stepashin (Hoffman 2000) explicitly cited
the inability of Maskhadov’s government, which enjoyed de facto autonomy, to
control dissident factions of the prior insurgent movement by 1999. Although oil
has played a role in the duration of the second conflict and in the intensification
of warlord violence and profiteering, Chechnya’s oil only makes up about 1 per-
cent of the oil in Russia (Baev, Koehler, and Zurcher 2005; Shermatova 2003).
Therefore, it does not seem likely that oil alone has been enough of an incentive
for Russia to continue the conflict and oppose Chechen independence.
International factors played a less prominent role here than in other cases.
One unusual precedent is cited as contributing to Russia’s proclivity to invade
110 Examining the Cases
Chechnya after the Dagestan raids and the Moscow bombings (allegedly by
Chechen separatists, though the authorship remains murky): NATO’s bomb-
ing campaign in Kosovo from March to June 1999. That bombing occurred
despite Russian objections and without UN Security Council consent. More-
over, it showed the value of low-risk, high-altitude aerial bombardment, which
inflicted high enemy military and bystander casualties while subjecting airmen
and ground soldiers to virtually no risk. Consequently the NATO campaign em-
boldened the Russians to invade on political grounds and on tactical grounds,
which increased civilian casualties while reducing Russian troop exposure until
after the aerial bombardment had weakened Grozny tremendously.
that were not recorded as reaching twenty-five deaths in a single year. As with
China’s renewed warfare in Tibet, the Georgian case could have been counted
as a case of multiple and simultaneous internal armed conflicts and thus would
have been omitted from the analysis. Again, however, it is included here out of a
commitment to seek to include those cases from Fearon and Laitin where pos-
sible, and due to the ability to analyze these two wars in South Ossetia in relative
geographic isolation from Abkhazia.
Within six months the OSCE had deployed a civilian mission whose man-
date included promoting negotiations between the parties. The OSCE mission
launched programs of disarmament and weapons collection, as well as confidence
building and dialogue programs that brought together representatives of civil
society from both sides (König 2005, 242–45). But these programs proved futile
in the face of the shift in Georgian policy that triggered the 2004 armed conflict.
The United Nations also deployed an integrated mission in Tbilisi in 1993, but
its mandate was limited to the conflict over Abkhazia. The middle to late 1990s
were marked by increased attempts at cooperation between the South Ossetian
authorities and the Georgian government, including law enforcement coopera-
tion, road reconstruction, and improved electrical supply (Cvetkovski 2001).
Mobilization in both South Ossetian conflicts occurred along ethnic rather
than religious lines. In 1989 Georgia’s ethnic makeup was 70.1 percent Georgian,
1.8 percent Abkhaz, 3.0 percent Ossetian, and 6.3 percent Russian (US Depart-
ment of State 1998). The population of South Ossetia in 1989 was 66.0 percent
Ossetian, 29.3 percent Georgian, and 1.9 percent Russian (Baev, Koehler, and
Zurcher 2005, 265).6 At least an equal number of Ossetians lived within Georgia
outside South Ossetia, where they lived relatively peaceably with Georgians and
others (Dawisha and Parrott 1997). Mobilization for the armed conflict and its
recurrence occurred largely along ethnic lines, with many Georgians displaced
from South Ossetia in the first war.
Religious difference was not a salient point of mobilization in the conflict re-
currence in South Ossetia. In 1993, the religious makeup of Georgia was 65 per-
cent Georgian Orthodox, 11 percent Muslim, 10 percent Russian Orthodox, and
8 percent Armenian Apostolic (Curtis 1995). Both ethnic Ossetians and other
residents of South Ossetia are mostly Orthodox Christian, with a minority of
Sunni Muslims among ethnic Ossetians. Both the Abkhaz and South Ossetia
conflicts manifested ethnic more than religious identities in discourse and mo-
bilization, particularly in South Ossetia, where the majority share the Orthodox
Christian religion. South Ossetia is extremely mountainous, and thus the only
northern passage to Russia is through a single tunnel.
it was new restrictions on trade and movement that Georgia imposed in and
around South Ossetia.” However, in contrast to Charles Taylor’s plunder of the
Liberian state for the gain of his in-group, Saakashvili was willing to take some
inclusionary measures that his government viewed as significant concessions.
Indeed, the 2004 armed conflict was not inevitable: Saakashvili made overtures
to what he considered the “easiest” of the three regions, Ajaria, and thus suc-
cessfully secured its greater integration into Georgia in ways that “unfroze” that
particular conflict (König 2005, 237–38; Welt 2010). Ajarians, unlike Ossetians
and Abkhazians, are ethnic Georgians.
South Ossetia presented more difficulty than expected. Saakashvili entered
office in January 2004 in the culmination of the “Rose Revolution.”7 Upon tak-
ing office, he had already signaled that the “fragmentation” of Georgia would
not be tolerated (König 2005, 238). Tbilisi—recognizing that de facto South
Ossetian president Eduard Kokoity had very little popular support or legiti-
macy—thought that it might shift South Ossetian loyalties to the Georgian
state. It launched a crackdown on smuggling and black markets, hoping to ex-
pose and undercut the corruption of Kokoity’s government before his people. It
also offered social assistance to the population. The Georgian “carrots” included
establishing a free medical service, paying pensions, accepting the term “South
Ossetia,” and reopening the main railway link from Georgia to South Ossetia
(König 2005, 238).
Georgia’s plan, which presumed that Ossetian authorities would lose support
as they were less able to deliver services, backfired (International Crisis Group
2004, 1). Ossetians who earned their living from the black market were angry,
and others saw assistance as an attempt to co-opt the population (PRIO 2003b).
The deployment of around-the-clock police and political volunteers to stop con-
traband was akin to a widening of “occupation” of civilians, which raised the
specter of more widespread incursion and loss of autonomy (Welt 2010, 65).
Georgia also deployed several hundred special forces in the “conflict zone” as
part of the Joint Peacekeeping Force, but in a perceived violation of the Sochi
Agreement. Welt argues that, in a classic security dilemma dynamic, this move
was seen as offensive by South Ossetians, whose counterdeployments with the
Russians were in turn viewed as offensive rather than defensive by the Georgian
government (Welt 2010, 65).
In the summer of 2004 Georgia accused Russia of providing arms to the South
Ossetians and seized two trucks full of missiles. South Ossetia responded by
briefly detaining 50 Georgian police officers, and exchanges of gunfire between
forces commenced for the first time since 1992. Both sides marshaled forces, and
for the first time since 1992 the defined conflict zone was remilitarized by up to
3,000 additional Georgian troops, 2,000 South Ossetian troops, and an influx of
some 1,000 Russia mercenaries (International Crisis Group 2004, 14).
114 Examining the Cases
have set in the 1950s carried broad ramifications for both China’s economy and
its stability.
During the invasion of 1950–51, Chinese sources report an estimated 5,000
persons died, and thousands of Tibetans fled to India. The advance of the Chi-
nese army was also met with the surrender of many Tibetan soldiers. The PLA
forces halted about 200 kilometers from the capital, Lhasa, and sought to negoti-
ate the exercise of its control with the Tibetan authorities and the Dalai Lama,
who was urgently formally installed at the age of sixteen years in light of the inva-
sion. Eventually a negotiations team of Tibetan officials in Beijing signed what
became known as the Seventeen-Point Agreement in May 1951.10 The authority
of the team, and the conditions of freedom or coercion under which they signed
the document, remain in dispute (Shakya 2000, 45–91). To the Dalai Lama’s
surprise (Goldstein 2007, 20), the Seventeen-Point Agreement stated that Ti-
bet was part of China, pledged Tibetan assistance for the presence of Chinese
military troops, and provided for locating military and civilian authorities in
the region.
However, the accord otherwise reaffirmed the political and religious status
quo of Tibet. Points 4 and 5, for instance, stated that the “Central Authorities
will not alter the existing political system in Tibet,” and affirmed the “status, func-
tions and powers” of the Dalai Lama and the Panchen Lama. Point 11 said, “In
matters related to various reforms in Tibet, there will be no compulsion on the
part of the Central Authorities.”
What led to the renewed fighting in 1955 that culminated in 1959 uprisings
in Lhasa that were suppressed? Tibet’s renewed warfare can best be seen as a
reaction against a gradually more invasive and transformative occupation. The
Chinese Communists openly described their agenda of “liberating” Tibet from
imperialist influences. At Mao Zedong’s insistence, they quietly and patiently
began a long-term process of social transformation of the religious, economic,
and political structures of society (Goldstein 2007, 542). Thus diverse Tibetan
Buddhist sects were brought into the polity for the first time (Shakya 2000, 132).
Some lamas received salaries and honorific posts in the Preparatory Committee
appointed to oversee a transition of Tibet into an autonomous region, akin to
the other ethnic minorities in which autonomy was more reduced than in Tibet
(Shakya 2000, 132–33).
The bureaucratic advance of the social policies and tasks of ever more in-
trusive territorial administration provoked rebellion among Tibetans, initially
in the eastern provinces. In 1955 the Chinese government initiated its Major
Socialist Campaign aimed at accelerating the collectivization of the nation’s
agriculture, including the ethnic minority regions so that these would not “fall
behind” (Goldstein 2007, 549). Although Tibet was exempt from this policy,
ethnic Tibetans who lived in the adjacent jurisdictions of Kham and Amdo were
Separatist Recurrences of Civil War 117
not. In contrast to central Tibet, where a feudal system of aristocrats and serfs
and slaves prevailed, many Tibetans in these provinces were nomads or small
landowners. Here the campaign proceeded apace and gave rise to a bloody up-
rising that began in Kham by ethnic Tibetans (called “Khampas”) (Goldstein
2007, 549). Within months, the rebel activities had spread to western Kham and
to central Tibet.
Between 1956 and 1959 thousands, possibly tens of thousands, died.11 The
PLA made significant headway against the rebellion in 1957, leading thousands
to flee to central Tibet. The fighting culminated in uprisings in Lhasa, but the
PLA crushed these and wrought devastation on religious sites (destroying many
Buddhist monasteries and religious sites). In 1959 the gradualist approach to
Tibet ended, and Tibetan autonomy was curtailed. The Dalai Lama fled and es-
tablished a government in exile across the border in India.
Tibetans launched their renewed civil war in response not only to forced col-
lectivization but also to the broader influx of and exercise of control by Chinese
administrative officials, soldiers, and Han Chinese migrants (Grunfeld 1996,
131–35). Mao planned to stimulate massive Han migration to Tibet with the goal
of Hans outnumbering Tibetans five to one (Minahan 1996). That migration in-
creased in the mid-1950s. Another example of the bureaucratic ramping up of au-
thority is the effort to disarm the Tibetan population in accord with national pol-
icies. The Chinese pressed forward their plans, even though Tibetans objected
that weapons were a part of their culture, including inside Buddhist monasteries,
where they formed part of sacred ornamentation. Their initial hesitation in step-
ping up intrusion in social and political life derived partly from the sense of de-
pendence and isolation, because the thousands of occupying PLA soldiers relied
on Tibetans for food and the country was only accessible over land from India.
In addition the Chinese government not only paid their tens of thousands of
soldiers but also paid additional civilian administrators and offered interest-free
loans to Tibetan businessmen and purchased Tibetan wool and other goods at
inflated prices. As a result of the economic costs of these policies (and the Korean
War at the other end of China), the Chinese government “began to take greater
control of the Tibetan economy” (Shakya 2000, 135). Thus the very presence of
ethnic Han Chinese laid the groundwork for the perceived marginalization and
disempowerment of Tibetans under Chinese occupation. “By the middle of 1955,
every Tibetan began to feel the presence of the Chinese” (Shakya 2000, 133).
The exclusion perceived by the Tibetans in the mid-1950s may also derive
from the end of the period required for the Chinese government to complete the
logistical and communications conditions necessary to militarily support full ex-
ercise of its authority over Tibet. No year-round passable roads existed between
Tibet and China until construction projects, deemed a priority in 1951, com-
pleted two roads in 1955. Telecommunications were also difficult, and telegraph
118 Examining the Cases
towers were also constructed in this time frame. As Thomas (1959, 129) says,
“The roads now tied Tibet to China. Immediately the Chinese increased their
pressure on the Dalai Lama and high officials; they wanted no more delay about
the establishment of the administrative committee that would give them formal
control of the country.”
Did the Chinese policies constitute exclusionary behavior? Some argue that
the Chinese never violated the provisions of the Seventeen-Point Agreement.
The Chinese authorities permitted extensive self-rule, and their transformative
social reforms occurred through carrots much more than sticks. However, the
incursion and the prolonged presence of troops, civilian administrators, and
Han migrants led to small changes in governance. Thus the Chinese prohibited
the cross-border trading of the Tibetan silver ingots used as currency because it
was undermining the Chinese currency. Wages were cut after being raised. Small
steps like changing the uniforms of the Tibetan armed forces also signaled that
the Chinese government would, in fact, slowly transform the status quo, even
with the complicity of some Tibetan elites along the way.
Finally, international and regional actors influenced the war recurrence in
Tibet. In the first war, calculations about how much leverage Tibetans had in
negotiating hinged partly on whether the Americans or others would provide
overt aid and recognize them (Shakya 2000). Extensive diplomacy between
the Americans, the British, other powers, and the Tibetan government in exile
persisted (Grunfeld 1996, 151–65). After the Dalai Lama’s trip to Beijing and
embrace of initiating some elements of socialist transformation, his brother and
two other Tibetan government officials sought the support of India and the
United States for a secret resistance group. By early 1956 the US Central Intel-
ligence Agency was recruiting guerrillas, training them in camps in Nepal, and
air-dropping them into Kham and Tibet (Shakya 2000). Many of these (most are
presumed to have been captured and killed) were drawn from the aristocrats of
Tibet’s extremely archaic feudal system.
Even if one accepts that the letter of the Seventeen-Point Agreement was
never violated, the issues of ethnicity and exclusion lie at the core of Tibet’s war
recurrence. Natural resources are absent from the main historical works on Tibet
(Goldstein 2007; Shakya 2000; Richardson 1962; Patterson 1960). Although
outside forces propelled the conflict once it was under way, they did not insti-
gate it.
departures from the expectations held by separatist populations and their lead-
ers, which undermined hopes for continued or expanded autonomy.
The case of Sudan’s North / South civil war recurrence offers perhaps the
starkest case. The decision by the North to impose Sharia law on the South, to
transfer southern soldiers to the North, to arrest southern politicians and to ig-
nore agreed-upon federalism all triggered renewed warfare. Analysts are unam-
biguous about the privileged role of these actions, seeing the resurgence of orga-
nized attacks in the South as a reaction to, rather than precipitator of, the 1983
war. The cases of Chechnya and South Ossetia are similar insofar as separatists
in an earlier contest had fought strongly enough to force a cease-fire agreement
involving de facto autonomy. But after some years, and for different political rea-
sons, central state leaders opted to change the arrangement, which prompted
renewed warfare.
National heads of government in all four cases took action that reflected po-
litical aspirations and / or perceived political constraints. Russian prime minis-
ter Putin and the Russian military saw potential gains in relaunching a second
Chechen war, for political and security reasons. Of all these separatist cases, only
Chechnya’s rebel forces provide serious evidence of proactive defection from
the Khasavyurt Agreement in 1999. However, even Russian officials see the at-
tacks of dissident separatist Chechen groups as serving mainly to accelerate and
complicate Russia’s planned defection from the accord. Georgia’s newly elected
president Saakashvili thought he might consolidate his power and that of Geor-
gia through new provocative policies against illicit trade in South Ossetia, as he
had done swiftly in Ajaria.
In contrast to these two new leaders acting out of perceived and anticipated
strength, Sudan’s president Nimeiri acted out of potential weakness. He was mo-
tivated partly by fear that Islamists were becoming stronger and needed to be
appeased, which he obliged by toppling the South’s autonomy. Because China’s
strategic superiority over Tibetan forces was evident in the early 1950s, the Ti-
bet case shows some differences. Even so, Mao Zedong’s government showed
some restraint until impatient advocates of speedier reform prevailed and im-
plemented land reforms that prompted renewed fighting there. The politics of
handling separatist territorial movements can have its origins in questions of
statehood or regime change in each of these four cases. In three cases initial wars
occurred in tandem with the arrival of statehood and a new government after
external occupation. In the fourth case, Tibet, the initial war took place directly
on the heels of the regime change wrought by revolution in 1949.
What of alternative arguments? Only in the case of Sudan did natural re-
sources play a salient role in war recurrence of these cases, and even so that role
was in tandem with exclusionary dynamics that received more analysis and at-
tention. It was also only one of a handful of other economic issues considered
120 Examining the Cases
important at the time for the South. Conventional measures of state strength for
Georgia and Russia—given the well-developed role of the state in society, the
economy, and security—place them on a considerably higher level of institu-
tionalization than countries such as Burundi, Rwanda, the Central African Re-
public, and Haiti. Except for the presence of a joint Russian-Ossetian-Georgian
peace force in South Ossetia, none of the other cases experienced the presence
of international troops. And in South Ossetia, the Russian presence was not seen
as “neutral.” This factor is revisited subsequently in later chapters, where we can
consider cases of both recurrence and nonrecurrence.
In both Tibet and South Ossetia, one sees examples of secessionist struggles
in the context of military occupations in regions that had enjoyed significant au-
tonomy in prior decades. The dynamics of these struggles contrast sharply with
that of Liberia’s civil war and its recurrence, and with the experiences described
in Haiti, the Central African Republic, and other countries with nonseparatist re-
currences. Although East Timor represented a secessionist struggle, it too differs
from the pattern of Tibet and South Ossetia given the falling out among victors
after a successful armed struggle. I have argued here that Tibet and South Ossetia
represent secessionists who revert to war in the face of initiatives by a perceived
occupier to transform the status quo in ways that would render permanent or
more extensive the exclusionary rule, and thus undermine the possibilities of
self-government. This research does not analyze the factors that lead national
states to initiate such transformational policies, nor does it consider why in some
cases separatist territories do not choose to respond with renewed armed con-
flict. Such questions are important for a fuller understanding of separatist wars
and their recurrence. I now turn to nonseparatist struggles and their recurrence.
Notes
1. In the case of Azerbaijan, the recurrence in Nagorno-Karabakh was excluded be-
cause I could find no analysts except PRIO, which considered the two dozen deaths
from border skirmishes to constitute an internal armed conflict, especially given that
similar such skirmishes with fewer than twenty-five deaths had taken place in several
years between 1994 and 2005.
2. Sambanis (2006), covering 1945–2002, Fearon and Laitin (2003), covering
1945–99, and the Political Instability Task Force (2008), covering 1955–2007, all
score the first civil war from 1963–72, and the onset of the second in 1983, with vary-
ing end dates (especially because the war continued past the dates of publication for
Sambanis and Fearon and Laitin).
3. For more on the origins of the Chechen wars, see Dunlop (1998), Lieven (1998),
Sakwa (2005), Evangelista (2002), Cornell (2001), Gall and de Waal (1998), Russell
(2005), Jean (2000), and Ashour (2004).
Separatist Recurrences of Civil War 121
4. See James Fearon’s (1998) emphasis on the lack of credible commitments created
by the disappearance of central authority upon the dissolution of the Soviet Union and
the Yugoslavian Federation.
5. In 1944–2002 data set, Sambanis codes two civil wars, in 1991–92 and 1992–94.
Walter’s 1946–96 data set does not code any wars in Georgia in the early 1990s, and the
Political Instability Task Force codes two wars, one in 1991–93 and one in 1992–93.
6. The most recent Georgian census in 2002 did not include the autonomous ter-
ritories of Abkhazia and South Ossetia.
7. Saakashvili’s populist, nationalist government replaced that of the more tradi-
tional Communist (and former Soviet foreign minister) Eduard Shevardnadze, who
was forced to resign in the face of mass demonstrations against electoral fraud.
8. The war could, therefore, also be considered interstate.
9. Tibetan army officers, for instance, continued to sport British uniforms (Gold-
stein 2007, 215).
10. This was officially the “Agreement of the Central People’s Government and the
Local Government of Tibet on Measures for the Peaceful Liberation of Tibet,” May 23,
1951.
11. Some scholars estimate that 45,000 Han died and 65,000 Tibetans, but these
are considered high (Grunfeld 1996, 133).
5
Nonseparatist Recurrences of
Civil War
for a period of several years. Usually such exclusion extends beyond access to
state power to also include access to economic power and social opportunities.
Recall that precipitating exclusion can take the form of either formal exclusion
based on laws or written policies (e.g., apartheid) or informal treatment or be-
havior that systematically excludes a group from such positions. In addition, I
argue here that the important aspect of exclusion rests on the dashed expecta-
tions of the aggrieved ethnic or political group rather than an objective or stan-
dard schema.
This chapter argues that exclusionary behavior played a precipitating role
in recurrences not only in Liberia and the four separatist recurrences analyzed
above but also in five additional cases: Haiti, East Timor, Zimbabwe, Burundi,
and Rwanda. In the first three of these additional cases, this behavior was “pre-
cipitating” insofar as it was a trigger causally linked to the recurrence of armed
conflict. In the latter two cases, Burundi and Rwanda, I argue that the exclusion
was “chronic” and was generally considered the most important factor underly-
ing the repeated violent conflict in those two interrelated cases.
These nonseparatist cases also suggest the importance of a second pattern of
precipitating exclusion: the exclusion of former allies or coalition partners after
a successful rebellion. In most cases where newly elected or empowered postwar
governments engage in exclusionary behavior, it is against former enemies or
the social groups associated with them. However, in a small set of cases drawn
from successful insurrections, exclusion may precipitate renewed armed conflict
when postwar governments move to marginalize, exclude, or even persecute
their former rebel partners. The two central cases analyzed here are East Timor
and Zimbabwe, although such behavior contributed to Nicaragua’s postrevolu-
tionary recurrence as well, and has been identified by Atlas and Licklider (1999)
in Sudan and Chad.
As mentioned in the previous chapter, the state’s reneging on an explicit
powersharing deal in the territorial, political, or security realm constituted the
principal trigger of recurrence in six of fifteen core cases. Of these, Liberia, the
Central African Republic, and Zimbabwe represented nonseparatist recurrences.
In the other nonseparatist cases of Haiti and East Timor, recurrence was tied to
a failure to meet informal expectations for participation in postwar governance.
in 2001–2 and again in 2006. The first two conflicts, in the periods 1996–97 and
2001–2, had similar motivations and actors. The Central African Republic has
no ethnic majority but instead conforms to a plurality of groups. The country’s
ethnic breakdown as of March 2009 was Baya, 33 percent; Banda, 27 percent;
Mandjia, 13 percent; Sara, 10 percent; Mboum, 7 percent; M’Baka, 4 percent;
Yakoma, 4 percent; and other, 2 percent. The religious breakdown was 35 per-
cent indigenous beliefs, 25 percent Protestant, 25 percent Roman Catholic, and
15 percent Muslim, although the Christian majority is strongly influenced by
animist beliefs and practices. Like many of the conflict recurrences after 1988,
these repeat armed conflicts reflected not religious division so much as mobiliza-
tion along ethnic lines.
Recurrence in 2001
The presence of UN peacekeeping troops corresponded to a period of relative
stability, because there was little violence between the Bangui Agreements and
the end of the peacekeeping mission in the Central African Republic in April
2000. Violence emerged a year later, again in the form of a coup attempt involv-
ing dissatisfied elites who rallied troops rather than a mass-based civil war. In
May 2001 members of the country’s armed forces, led by former president André
Kolingba (from the Yakoma ethnic group), led a coup attempt against President
Patassé. They alleged that the military’s old grievances from the prior conflict
against Patassé had not been addressed.
The rebellion of mid-2001 was suppressed with the help of Libyan troops
and a neighboring rebel group, the Mouvement pour la Libération du Congo
(MLC). Because the MLC was intent on toppling the Kabila government in
the Democratic Republic of the Congo, it provided troops that supported the
Patassé government, largely because the Central African Republic had allowed
the MLC to operate within its southern territory. The UN denounced the coup
attempt, but it stated that the government should not purposefully target the
Yakoma tribe with violence. Former Malian president Amadou Toumani Touré
was sent as a UN peace envoy to speak with the government, opposition, and
civil society. Patassé accused his army chief of staff, General François Bozizé, of
helping to orchestrate the coup attempt and had him fired. The casualties had
been relatively few up to this point in 2001.
However, additional rebellion against the government occurred within a few
months in 2001. The ousted General Bozizé gathered troops to resist his firing,
dividing the armed forces between Patassé and Bozizé loyalists. In November
2001, as the conflict resurged, the UN stepped up its mediation efforts, sending
Lamine Cisse, a retired Senegalese army general, to lead the mediation effort.
Nonseparatist Recurrences of Civil War 127
leading to small arms proliferation. In 2007, rebels from Sudan fled into the Cen-
tral African Republic, as did units of the Lord’s Resistance Army from Uganda
in 2008 (BBC 2010).
nic group, and the northeastern rebellion prompted anti-Gula sentiment and re-
taliation, leading many Gula to flee their homes. Some of the Ex-Liberators (who
helped Bozizé to power) were also active in the rebellion. The Armée Populaire
pour la Restauration de la République et la Démocratie (APRD) was made up
mainly of former presidential guards of Patassé, who was from the same region.
The APRD claimed that its goal was to engage in dialogue with the government
to address the exclusion of Patassé supporters from elections, as well as the secu-
rity situation in the northwest, where armed bandits attack villagers.
(2010) work on the negative impact for civil wars of the International Monetary
Fund’s structural adjustment packages, but it flies in the face of Collier’s recom-
mendations to adopt such policies for stabilization.
Two pertinent factors seem to be the resurgence of repression by the 1988–90
coup government led by General Prosper Avril that preceded Aristide’s election,
and the diffusion of democratization in the region that raised uncertainty amid
more competitive electoral events. Avril engaged in brutal repression, especially
targeting leftist critics and followers of Aristide, who was then a parish priest and
vocal critic of the government. Violence against the Haitian police and military
also increased. The fall of the Berlin Wall and the spread of electoral regimes in
Latin America and Central and Eastern Europe, which also extended to much
of Africa in the early 1990s, increased pressure on Avril’s regime to permit elec-
tions. Much of the violence in Port-au-Prince centered on the period preceding
the country’s first truly open and competitive elections in December 1990.
To the extent that recurrent political violence among elites, especially coup
attempts and political assassinations, signifies a weak state, then state weakness
is perhaps the single most apparent factor. Yet the mechanisms for how state
weakness is triggered and when and why specific armed conflicts emerge, even if
violence is neither widespread nor in the form of armed combat between formed
armies, remain an open question.
In the case of the initial armed conflict—especially the coup d’état of Septem-
ber 1991—some acts of exclusion by Aristide are apparent; however, these fac-
tors were eclipsed by the broader anti-Aristide (and anti–popular democracy)
sentiments that underlay the support for the coup. Even before president-elect
Aristide was sworn into office the first time on February 7, 1991, he faced a coup
attempt by Duvalier’s former interior minister (and director of the infamous Ma-
coutes), Roger Lafontant. The failed coup attempt was followed by the lynching
of some seventy former Duvalierists by pro-Aristide mobs (Serrill 1991). Ongo-
ing organizing against and demonizing of Aristide persisted, even though the
reforms he launched at this point were of a “moderate social democratic” nature,
neither barring the elite from access to state offices nor jeopardizing the coun-
try’s free market system (Dupuy 2007, 112). Aristide did, however, seem to con-
done or encourage deadly mob violence against those wealthy elites who tried to
thwart the will of the people in seeking to transform the exploitative and unequal
society and economy (Dupuy 2007, 122; 2009, 166–68). As one scholar puts it
(Dupuy 2007, 168–69), “The military, backed by the dominant classes, would
have overthrown Aristide in any case for what he (then) stood for. But he gave
the justifications for their actions that they would not have had otherwise.”
The strength of the popular movement that helped bring Aristide to power also
ensured that the coup would lead to broader violence, both by the poor support-
ers of Aristide and, most especially, against his supporters by the coup-spawned
132 Examining the Cases
government led by General Raoul Cedras. Similar to what I show below in the
cases of Rwanda and Burundi, political exclusion, backed by deadly violence,
underlay the rise in organized violent conflict in the early 1990s in Haiti, but it
was not a precipitating factor in the same way that it would prove to be in the
2003–4 recurrence.
in 1995. His prime minister, René Preval, was elected president for the first time
in a flawed process whose result was widely accepted internally and externally.
Under Preval, relative stability prevailed, facilitated by a large international UN
and OAS presence and UN troops. However, Parliament was not functioning for
much of his tenure, and by 1997 the government had gained a reputation for cor-
ruption (Dailey 2003). In 1996, the Lavalas political movement split as Aristide
formed his Famille Lavalas (Lavalas Family) political party with mass support.
But he left behind many disenchanted members of the intelligentsia and artists
who resisted his personalistic style of leadership.
Political violence began rising in anticipation of the May 2000 parliamentary
and municipal elections and the November 2000 presidential ballot. A number
of factors rendered the elections questionable and fueled instability that year:
postponed balloting, violence against some candidates and campaigns, manipu-
lation of the Senate results, politicization of the Provisional Electoral Commis-
sion, and polarization over the imminent return of Aristide to a second term
(OAS 2000). Referring to the elections of 2000, one journalist (Dailey 2003)
concluded, “Gross electoral fraud by the ruling party has deprived the entire po-
litical apparatus of legitimacy.” Although the breakdown in government under
Preval had prompted the World Bank and others to suspend aid, the inaugura-
tion of Aristide’s second administration led to the suspension of all official inter-
national assistance except humanitarian aid (Dailey 2003).
In 2003, tensions between the Aristide government and leftist and rightist
opponents grew. A former pro-Aristide gang leader, Amiot Metayer, formed
what he called the Cannibal Army to oppose the government. Metayer’s struggle
gained prominence until he was killed, presumably by government forces, in Sep-
tember (Beidas, Granderson, and Neild 2007). In January 2004, as the country
celebrated two hundred years of independence, thousands of people marched
against the government. On February 5, the former Cannibal Army (now re-
named the Artibonite Resistance Front for the Overthrow of Jean-Bertrand
Aristide), stormed the police headquarters in Gonaives and released dozens of
prisoners. The group was led partly by the slain Metayer’s brother, but also by
many former soldiers from the Duvalier period who had fled the country to the
Dominican Republic. In the next few days the uprising spread to a dozen other
cities, often facing little government resistance. On February 22, after the group
took control of the country’s second-largest city, insurgent leader and ex-soldier
Guy Philippe announced that he would take the capital within two weeks unless
Aristide stepped down.
Aristide and the rebel forces both rejected any powersharing arrangement.
The president also rejected the French government’s suggestion that he abandon
power. As forces advanced on the capital, Aristide resigned his post on Leap Day,
and was escorted from his home to the airport and flew into exile (Robinson
134 Examining the Cases
2007; Farmer 2004). Evidence of US tacit, and perhaps financial, support for
the uprising exists, and many analysts have debated whether US officials coerced
Aristide into his resignation and flight. In any case, a new interim government led
by Gerard Latortue was installed with the United States’ blessing. That govern-
ment engaged in continued repression and killings of Aristide’s supporters for
several months. Immediately upon Aristide’s departure, the UN Security Coun-
cil authorized a new UN Stabilization Mission in Haiti, deploying 3,500 troops
initially. In 2006, a new election was held in which former President René Preval
was elected to a second full term.
alty to him and his wife. Political killings escalated, and the police were seen as a
political tool and pervaded by corruption linked to an expanding drug trade. In
June 2003, the head of the Haitian National Police fled the country, fearing for
his life because he had resisted attempts by the president and members of Parlia-
ment from his party to force favoritism in promotions and the hiring of unquali-
fied members for the force (Lynch 2003). In August 2003, the United States–
based Committee to Protect Journalists announced that Haiti had rejoined Cuba
as one of the two most dangerous countries in the Americas for journalists, citing
alleged state complicity in the murder of two journalists and the exile of thirty
others (Regan 2003).
Middle-class Haitians, as well as many from the poorer classes, became disil-
lusioned by the predatory approach to the state and the more overt antidemo-
cratic practices carried out with the electoral machinery and the legislature. As
the journalist Peter Dailey wrote (2004), “Aristide’s growing authoritarianism
has been denounced by virtually every element of the coalition that supported
his rise to the presidency in 1990: the priests and laypersons of the liberation
theology wing of the Haitian church, the network of grassroots organisations,
peasant co-operatives and labour unions, and every single Haitian intellectual or
artist of note. Aristide tried to compensate for the defection of his former sup-
porters by recruiting criminal gangs.”
Ironically, elections became the means by which a popular, populist politician
built a semiauthoritarian regime, over the dissidence of those who represented
peasant organizations, artists, labor unions, and other civil society organizations
(Fatton 2002). In this sense, Aristide’s behavior was exclusionary not only to-
ward his former enemies but also toward his former allies, a pattern that is more
decisive in the recurrences of armed conflict in Zimbabwe and East Timor.
Supporting Collier’s claims, the four years preceding the armed conflict of
2003–4 showed an unusual economic decline. Although GDP per capita rose
from 1996 to 2000, it fell in 2001, 2002, and 2004, before rebounding in 2005
and climbing until 2009 (Fasano 2009, 5). That decline in the early 2000s, like
much in Haiti, was highly conditioned by external factors, primarily the reduc-
tion in international aid and loans from the United States, the international finan-
cial institutions, and eventually Canada and European bilateral donors.
Because of the proximity of Haiti to the United States, it is difficult to distin-
guish the role of the international factors, especially as they reflect great power
interests, from regional factors in Haiti. Although the United States deployed
force to restore Aristide to power, neither the Clinton nor the Bush administra-
tion was ever comfortable with his leftist political platform, especially his resis-
tance to neoliberal economic prescriptions. The Clinton administration initially
conditioned aid and loans, eventually suspending aid to the very police force
that it had created and underwritten (Beidas, Granderson, and Neild 2007). The
136 Examining the Cases
armed resistance for the next twenty-five years, despite that fact that it received
virtually no assistance from abroad (Steele 2002, 77). After the annihilation of
tens of thousands of civilians by Indonesian forces and their allies, it became
apparent by the late 1970s that ending the occupation would require a political
strategy that rested on a broad civilian resistance movement, although the insur-
gent military forces retained symbolic importance (Rees 2004, 2).
As part of the political effort, FALINTIL’s commander, Xanana Gusmao,
sought to diminish long-standing Timorese disunity that would become impor-
tant in the 2006 recurrence. In 1987 he created the National Council of Mau-
bere Resistance (Conselho Nacional de Resistência Maubere, CNRM) to create
a broad, inclusive, and nonpartisan political movement. FALINTIL separated
itself from the political party FRETILIN, Xanana resigned from the party, and
FRETILIN ceased to claim to be the sole legitimate representative of the Ti-
morese people (Simonsen 2006, 579). In 1998 the CNRM reconstituted itself
as the National Council of Timorese Resistance (CNRT), without changing its
nonpartisan, unifying aspirations.
The numerous casualties of the occupation and the resistance lead many to
overlook the internal character of the original armed conflict. The occupation
involved the killing of between 100,000 and 200,000 persons (Niner 2001, 19).
Although the violence, oppression, and social transformation of the occupation
defined the last quarter of the twentieth century in East Timor, the armed con-
flict’s origins lie in internal divisions over independence in the context of Portu-
gal’s decline and withdrawal as a colonial power. Indonesia was a powerful strate-
gic actor that allied with internal factions; however, it would be an exaggeration
to attribute the origins of the original armed conflict primarily to Indonesia.
The war for independence ended with a horrible spike in violence in reaction
to this referendum. A massive and deliberate campaign of violence, carried out
almost entirely by Timorese militias opposed to independence, broke out in Dili
two days after the vote and spread to the countryside. Although serious violence
had occurred in 1999 before the referendum, the scale and scope of this violence
had not been seen in years—it involved widespread rape, looting, and the killing
of some 1,400 persons (Cohen 2006, ii). Some 250,000 refugees fled to West
Timor, many more were displaced, and the great majority of schools and health
facilities were destroyed (Steele 2002, 77). The militias had received training,
organization, and equipment from the Indonesian armed forces, whose troops
also participated in much of the killing and the destruction of many of the main
buildings of the capital and elsewhere (Cohen 2006, ii).
On September 12, 1999, the UN Security Council authorized a Multinational
Force with Indonesian acquiescence, which deployed a week later under Austra-
lian leadership with the name International Force for East Timor (INTERFET).
INTERFET was eventually able to reduce the violence, because many anti-
independence militia members fled among civilians to West Timor. In October
1999, the UN Security Council authorized the UN Transitional Administration
in East Timor (UNTAET), which effectively exercised full sovereignty over the
territory. A special representative of the UN secretary-general was both head of
the UN peacekeeping operation and the administrator over the territory, and his
decrees had the force of law (Chopra 2000). Although there was no peace agree-
ment, the 1999 postreferendum violence and the authorization of INTERFET
marked the demise of Indonesian rule and the inevitability of internationally em-
braced independence for East Timor. Although violent attacks persisted through
late 1999, the war was essentially over.
this shortsighted decision contributed to the CNRT’s breakup into five factions
in 2000. After that time an East Timor Transitional Authority was created that
oversaw some administrative capacities, although only two of thirteen districts
were under Timorese leadership in March 2001 (Suhrke 2001, 13). Some believe
that these tensions later undermined the UN’s standing and thus its ability to
influence the factional tensions leading up to the 2006 violence.
Upon independence in May 2002, UNTAET’s mandate was changed to sup-
port the new Timorese state through the renamed and downsized UN Support
Mission in East Timor (UNMISET).8 Between the withdrawal of Indonesia’s
forces in 1999 and independence in 2002, more than 80 percent of the 250,000
refugees had returned from West Timor (Martin and Mayer-Rieckh 2005, 135),
and thousands of poor and displaced Timorese had converged on Dili. Political
wrangling, including courting former prointegration political factions, prevailed,
but without extensive violence leading up to the election of a Constituent As-
sembly in August 2001 and presidential elections in April 2002. Partly because
of the UN’s eagerness to depart swiftly, insufficient time to hold elections for a
Parliament left the Constituent Assembly converting itself into the Parliament
(Goldstone 2004, 87–90). FRETILIN gained fifty-five of the eighty-eight seats
in the Constituent Assembly in 2001, and no other party received more than
seven seats. Its political dominance was cemented with the Assembly’s vote
to extend the life of the initial election into a five-year Parliament without a
new election.
ordinates, referring to them [as] ‘sons of pro-Indonesia militia,’ a huge insult for
those who sacrificed many years of their lives in service of independence.”
The F-FDTL leadership introduced and perpetuated the east / west discrimi-
nation, ignoring complaints from those inside and outside the army about its
significance. Although Xanana helped foster this distinction, FRETILIN’s own
history also reflected this east / west divide, visible in its demonstrably greater
support from the east in the 2001 elections. FRETILIN’s “top down, non-
inclusive way of doing politics” (Simonsen 2006, 584) coincided with the per-
ception of favoritism over easterners and unwillingness to respond to evident
discrimination. This exclusionary conduct constituted the single most salient
trigger for the renewed conflict in 2006, but others also played a role.
factors of the 2006 violence. However, the low level of state capacity correlates
highly with the problems in East Timor, and this is difficult to discount. The low
level of institutionalization of the army, as well as of the hastily formed and highly
personalized and political police force, made it difficult to control the conduct
of these forces and constituted an absence of channels for dissent (Rees 2004).
and 1990s, the territory remained the poorest in Indonesia in 1996 (Moxham
2008, 9). However, this level of poverty is not considered by Timorese observers
or by international analysts to have been crucial in the outbreak of armed conflict
of 2006. Harrington (2007) emphasizes economic factors more than others, but
he attributes that recurrence to the cultural distinctions between firaku and ka-
ladi, exacerbated by multiple horizontal inequalities, including greater access by
easterners to land, property, and housing after the 1999 referendum. Outbreaks
of violence among youth gangs that mobilized along the east / west divide began
in late 1999 and were suppressed by UN troops and police (Harrington 2007).
In addition, easterners were seen as dominating and as enjoying privileged access
to jobs and control of the markets in Dili after independence. These horizontal
inequalities underlay the exclusion perceived by the western FALINTIL peti-
tioners in 2006. Harrington (2007) argues that UNTAET was ill equipped and
unable to manage the influx of people into the Dili area after 1999 or to manage
land disputes adequately, despite having some recognition of the problems and
having created an office early on to address disputes. In short, economic factors
were not precipitating causes, but they exacerbated the tensions over land and
access to jobs, especially for the demobilized combatants and those people serv-
ing in the army and the police.
Robert Mugabe, the leader of ZANU, was elected prime minister in 1980, and he
subsequently became president and head of the government.
The establishment of a new government in an internationally recognized,
majority-ruled Zimbabwe saw the inclusion by Mugabe of several ZANU of-
ficials in the Cabinet in 1980 (Catholic Commission for Justice and Peace in
Zimbabwe 1997, 7). ZAPU leader Joshua Nkomo (the “Father of Zimbabwe”)
declined the ceremonial post of president but became minister of home affairs.
The latent tensions between the newly empowered ZANU government and the
ZAPU opposition saw isolated attacks in 1981 and 1982, which cost up to 300
lives in 1982. In 1982, after the discovery of an arms cache, which very possibly
had been orchestrated, the government arrested several high-ranking ZIPRA
commanders and ousted ZAPU members from the Cabinet.14 Nkomo later fled
into exile for his life.15
In early 1983, the violence intensified. It took different forms, including ini-
tially attacks by “dissidents” on buses, trains, and stores, mainly against civilians,
with dozens of deaths (Lawyers Committee for Human Rights 1986, 34). Those
active in attacks were mainly former ZAPU guerrillas, and ZAPU leaders helped
organize the rebellion; however, the degree of command and control exercised
by the former guerrilla party over all dissident action is unclear (Lawyers Com-
mittee for Human Rights 1986, 20–22). In a vicious spiral, state military, para-
trooper, and police units stepped up operations against the dissidents alleged to
be members of ZAPU and its ZIPRA armed forces (Catholic Commission for
Justice and Peace in Zimbabwe 1997). In addition, in 1983 government forces
(especially a North Korean–trained unit called the Fifth Brigade, which con-
sisted only of ex-ZANLA members once ZIPRA ex-combatants were marginal-
ized, left, or were ousted) launched widespread attacks against ZAPU civilian
supporters, mainly Ndebele tribe members.16 The government announced in
January 1984 that “dissidents” had in 1983 murdered 120 people, mutilated 25,
and raped 47, and had committed 284 robberies.17
A significant portion of the violence experienced as part of Zimbabwe’s recur-
rent conflict after 1983 consisted of mass atrocities and executions, rather than
combat between uniformed armies. A report by the country’s Catholic Com-
mission for Justice and Peace found that “the presence of the Fifth Brigade in an
area in 1983 meant an initial outburst of intense brutality, usually lasting a few
days, followed by random incidents of beatings, burnings and murders in the
ensuing weeks, months, and years” (Catholic Commission for Justice and Peace
in Zimbabwe 1997, 54).
One extensive study of human rights abuses alleged that about 1,500 Nde-
bele civilians were killed in 1983 alone (Lawyers Committee for Human Rights
1986, 2). Another study based on interviews with former guerrillas stated that
after the war of independence, ZIPRA guerrillas were seen as a “political danger”
148 Examining the Cases
and, “along with ZANU civilians and ‘the Ndebele’ as a whole with whom they
were associated, were hunted down, jailed, tortured and killed” (Alexander and
McGregor 2004, 81–82). Nkomo later claimed that 20,000 Ndebeles were
killed, mostly executed outside combat.
Given the extensive and important role played by other countries in the in-
dependence struggle in Zimbabwe, external actors played a surprisingly reduced
role in the 1983–87 war recurrence. Based on detainee accounts, South Africa’s
government was implicated in providing training and weapons for the rebellious
dissidents (Lawyers Committee for Human Rights 1986, 22–24), which intensi-
fied the strength of the Zimbabwean government’s repressive response (Ohlson
and Stedman 1994, 90). However, third countries played no role in guiding the
strategies of either side. Instead, the resurgent armed conflict was dampened
and then ended by a political deal struck between ZAPU’s Nkomo and Mugabe.
Nkomo was eager to return from exile, and ZAPU gained little through these
violent attacks, especially given the harsh response by the government forces
(Ohlson and Stedman 1994, 91).
Just as the conflict commenced with exclusionary conduct, it ended with in-
clusionary powersharing. In 1987, ZANU-PF and ZAPU concluded a power-
sharing agreement that reinstated posts in the cabinet and made Nkomo the
country’s vice president from 1987 until his death in 1999. Crucial for the power-
sharing deal was the absorption of ZAPU into a renamed ZANU-PF (Patriotic
Forces). Competitive democracy was sacrificed to peace, as Mugabe’s goal of a
one-party state was realized with ZAPU’s incorporation into the ruling party
(Ohlson and Stedman 1994, 91).
Again, exclusionary conduct is central to the recurrence of armed conflict in
Zimbabwe, but it stemmed from a falling out among the victorious allied forces
after one faction went ahead and assumed control of a new state. The dissident
violence, led by former ZIRPA members, stemmed from a perception that for-
mer combatants and Ndebele peoples were being excluded from power by the
new regime. The conflict’s origins, according to Ohlson and Stedman (1994,
90–91), lay in “claims by former ZAPU members that they had been reduced to
political impotence.” ZAPU had “suffered from its exclusion from power.” The
violence differed from that of the East Timor insofar as the targets of the latter
were mainly and initially members of the armed forces and the Timorese police.
However, the dynamics of these recurrences are remarkably similar.
of armed conflict in East Timor, one year after the withdrawal of the peacekeep-
ing operation in favor of a political mission with a handful of unarmed military
observers, reveals the value of the international troops as a dissuasive presence.
Third, regional dynamics and the initiative taken by neighbors in advancing
or mitigating warfare were apparent. In Liberia both the witting and unwitting
involvement of Guinean and Sierra Leonean state armed forces, along with non-
state actors, abetted the recurrence of war, although this was more pronounced
in the organized violence in the territory of Liberia’s neighbors. In Haiti, the US
government played a crucial diplomatic role in signaling support for those who
would undermine Aristide’s government after 2000. Perhaps their support for
the rebels was material as well. In the Central African Republic, the troops of
France and neighboring states (especially Libya) provided a lifeline for Presi-
dent Patassé at crucial moments, and the downgrading of their commitment and
deployments facilitated the slide into recurrent armed conflict. In East Timor,
Indonesia was an important factor in the initial war, even though regional and
external factors played little direct role in the 2006 recurrence.
In the cases of East Timor and Zimbabwe, reneging on presumed commit-
ments by elected postwar governments also triggered renewed armed conflict.
Alongside these two cases, the cases analyzed above—the Central African Re-
public, Liberia, and Haiti—demonstrate the relevance of weak state institutions
as a backdrop for exclusionary behavior and add weight to that alternative expla-
nation. Other explanations, including that of reliance on natural resources, were
not nearly as salient as the decisions surrounding the exclusion of groups from
particular ethnicities or geographic regions.
specified here, given that numerous cases of oppression and discrimination can
coexist with the absence of armed conflict. Nevertheless, in seeking to explain
these two interrelated cases, scholars repeatedly cite exclusion as a central factor.
The succession of internal armed conflicts in Burundi and Rwanda since the
1960s demonstrates the importance of the regional level of analysis. Some of
the most prominent theorists of mass violence in the two countries—including
Lemarchand (2004), Mamdani (2001, 2002), Prunier (1995), and Uvin (1998,
1999)—concur on the important role of cross-border dynamics in understand-
ing the origins of warfare and genocide in the “Great Lakes” area encompassing
and extending beyond Rwanda and Burundi. Consequently, I present both cases
here in a parallel, simultaneous fashion. While acknowledging that the processes
of violence differ in the cases (Uvin 1999, 265), I examine these two case stud-
ies in a single narrative, reflecting a structured-focused analysis of each case and
the interaction between them, presented in a chronological fashion that alter-
nates between each case based on stages of conflict and relative stability. The
structured, focused approach for each case is retained, but I analyze one set of
hypothesized factors for each case before moving on to the next set of factors.
These sets of recurrences of warfare stretch the boundaries of our concepts
of civil war and stable peace. The character of violence often took the form of
mass atrocities, or “selective genocide” (Lemarchand 1975), more than civil war
or even internal armed conflict. In these episodes of mass violence, there have
been “rebels” organized under some command. However, mass civilian violence
has often unfolded alongside these internal armed actions. Moreover, it has of-
ten been difficult to document the coherence, command structure, or even indi-
vidual leadership of insurrectionary forces that have attacked state targets. That
is not to say that such command-and-control mechanisms did not exist, but they
were ephemeral and poorly documented, and they have often been so wholly
annihilated that it is impossible to exhume their specifics. This mass violence
makes it difficult to differentiate genocide from warfare (something genocide
perpetrators count on), and the levels of this mass violence make it difficult to
exclude from data sets of civil wars.
Fearon and Laitin (2003) score civil wars in Burundi in 1972, 1988, and
1993–2002; and in Rwanda in 1962–65 and since 1990. Scholars disagree about
the specific timing of these conflicts. Thus Uvin (1999) and Sambanis (2006)
cite mass atrocities in the 1960s in Burundi, next recurring in 1972, for instance.
Sambanis scores civil wars also in 1972 and 1988, but commences the third civil
war in 1991. As for Rwanda, data sets (Fearon and Laitin 2003; Doyle and Sam-
banis 2006; Political Instability Task Force 2008) concur on a civil war episode
in the 1960s and another in the 1990s, but they disagree on precise starting dates
(1962 or 1963) and ending dates (1964, 1965, or 1966). Because of the con-
tinuity across the 1994 genocide and throughout the 1990s, I score the 1990
152 Examining the Cases
internal war as continuing throughout the 1990s, even though the majority of
war-related deaths occurred outside the borders at times, and even though the
dynamics shifted in the 1990s. It is relatively clear that from war’s onset in 1990,
right through the July 1994 fall of Kigali to the Rwandan Patriotic Front, there
was no period of widely perceived peace followed by a renewed warfare. There-
fore, for our purposes, the 1990 period was the most recent, and only, episode of
civil war recurrence in Rwanda.
Before turning to these wars, what are the relevant demographic and other
characteristics of these societies? The two countries formed a single Belgian
colony from World War I until July 1962, when they split and each received in-
dependence. Belgium had fostered a Tutsi-dominated monarchy, although when
Hutus rose up in mass violence in 1959, it organized elections in which it sup-
ported Hutu rule in that portion of the colony. Tutsis have historically made up
only 10 to 14 percent of the population in both Burundi and Rwanda, with 85 to
90 percent Hutus and 1 percent Twa (Uvin 1999, 253). There is no systematic
religious difference between these ethnic groups, and religion has not been a
source of violent mobilizations.
ing Hutus to target Tutsis still within Rwanda as accomplices. Ethnic violence
would continue through independence in 1962 to 1966. Only the attack of De-
cember 1963 threatened the country’s stability, but roughly 20,000 people died
in these attacks in the early 1960s (Des Forges 1999). Alison Des Forges (1999,
36) reports that “Hutu leaders used them all [the attacks] to bolster the sense of
Hutu solidarity, to solidify their own control and to eradicate the last vestiges of
respect for Tutsi authority.”
Rwanda’s 1959 ethnic violence had transformative consequences for politics
in Burundi, because it deepened Tutsi determination to hold onto power more
tightly (Weinstein 1972). Thus, although a multiparty constitutional monar-
chy was inaugurated upon Burundi’s independence in 1962, fearful Tutsis as-
sassinated the prodemocracy King Rwagasore (who had married a Hutu) and
in 1965 carried out a coup that ushered in one of the most ethnically exclusive
regimes on earth (Ndikumana 1998). Uvin (1999, 256–57) is worth quoting
at length:
Following the events in Rwanda, state control [in Burundi] became the sole
vehicle for Tutsi to retain their privileges, while conversely it was the sole means
of rapid social advancement for Hutu. . . . From 1966 to 1993 political and by
extension economic power in Burundi was tightly held by three military regimes
(Micombero, 1966–82; Bagaza, 1982–87; Buyoya 1987–93) that used their
military might to keep their privileges. All three presidents were Tutsi-Hima
[lower-caste Tutsi] from the same village in the Bururi region, born within
two miles of each other. . . . Almost all positions of importance in Burundi
were monopolized by the Tutsi minority. They included the higher levels of the
single party, . . . the full command structure of the army, the police and security
forces, and the judicial system (even in 1994, only 13 out of 241 magistrates
were Hutu).
Even so, the Tutsi dominance persisted. By the time of the outbreak of violence
in 1988, three-quarters of the Cabinet and the legislature, thirteen of fifteen gov-
ernors, and all army officers and 96 percent of the enlisted soldiers were Tutsis
(Gale Group 2008, 4). Rather than this book’s argued state exclusion, state inclu-
sionary measures presaged the 1988 recurrence. Some allege that Buyoya’s mea-
sures toward inclusion generated heightened expectations among Hutus, whose
frustration fueled conflict (Gale Group 2008, 4). The Burundi case suggests that,
in the context of extreme chronic exclusion, steps to greater exclusion may not
provoke armed conflict. However, it would be a mistake to say that Buyoya’s pre-
violence measures constituted powersharing, because they rested on informal,
inclusionary measures. Indeed, steps toward powersharing only emerged after
the violence. Buyoya then appointed the country’s first Hutu prime minister and
created a commission, composed equally of Hutus and Tutsis, to investigate the
violence and make recommendations for national unity (Gale Group 2008, 4).
The 1988 violence began when Hutu farmers, resentful of corrupt Tutsi local
rule, killed up to 3,000 Tutsi in two northern villages of Burundi (Uvin 1999).
The Tutsi-dominated army responded directly and with heavy force, killing be-
tween 20,000 and 150,000 Hutu and driving out tens of thousands of refugees
(Uvin 1999; US Department of State 2008). Given the mass atrocities in the
government response, violence eventually diminished. Buyoya’s measures of in-
clusion did not amount to powersharing, but they signaled a willingness to grant
Hutus a greater participation in governance that would still be clearly dominated
by Tutsis.
after waves of violence, and the importance of refugee communities as the source
of mobilization of political organization and armies. “Refugees provide the con-
ceptual link among all three forms [political, economic, and social] of exclusion,”
according to Lemarchand (2004, 67). Their role derives not solely as direct pro-
tagonists of violence but also as sources of economic and social stress on the
host society, which provokes scapegoating by host nations’ authorities and fuels
cycles of discrimination if not demonization.
Such was the case of Tutsi refugees who had first fled by the tens of thou-
sands after the 1959 violence, and then had become central actors in the civil
war of 1990. Given the persistent Hutu political domination in Rwanda through-
out the 1960s and 1970s, the Tutsi refugees in Uganda became key recruits and
even commanders of the rebel National Resistance Army (NRA) organized by
Museveni to overthrow Milton Obote. The Obote government expelled thou-
sands of Rwandan refugees, who were subsequently permitted to return in 1985
to NRA-controlled areas. When they took Kampala in 1986, one-fourth of the
16,000 rebels were Banyarwandans. Among these was Paul Kagame, the future
leader of the Rwandan Patriotic Front, who was named acting head of intelli-
gence in Uganda (Mamdani 2001).
Mamdani (2001) and Prunier (1995) argue that the RPF invasion cannot be
understood outside the context of political events in Uganda. In the words of one
RPF commander, “If the NRM [National Resistance Movement, the political
arm of the NRA] could liberate Uganda, the RPF began to ask why it could not
do the same in Rwanda” (quoted by Mamdani 2001, 173). In addition, Ugandan
political events also pushed the RPF to launch an armed attempt to challenge
the Hutu-led government in Kigali. According to the new Ugandan ambassador
to the United States, two decisions by the new Kampala government pushed the
Uganda-based leadership of the RPF to decide to invade in 1990: the decision to
ban nonindigenous Banyarwandans from owning land in Uganda, and the deci-
sion to ban them from holding state offices there (Mamdani 2001).
The RPF invaded from Ugandan bases on October 1, 1990, with ongoing
combat halted only in July 1992 when a cease-fire was signed amid international
pressure. That cease-fire failed within eight months, leading to renewed fight-
ing and a new cease-fire forced on the government of Juvenal Habyarimana in
August 1993. The downing of the airplane carrying the presidents of Rwanda
and Burundi prompted the genocide in April 1994, and the taking of Kigali by
the RPF three months later. Rwanda’s recurrence is distinctive insofar as it de-
parts from the pattern identified by numerous analysts of the Great Lakes re-
gion of a limited uprising or assassination leading to the murder of one ethnic
group by the hundreds or thousands, followed by massive reprisals costing hun-
dreds of thousands of lives. However, Burundi in 1993 represents a return to
this pattern.
Nonseparatist Recurrences of Civil War 157
Moreover, these cases should not lead one to eschew exclusionary behavior
as a significant factor. On the contrary, the scholarly consensus is that exclu-
sion has played the most important role in the patterns of organized violence in
Rwanda and Burundi during the past four decades. Rather, the cases suggest that
where chronic, extreme exclusion persists, inclusionary efforts may in fact trig-
ger armed uprisings through raised expectations. The experience of Burundi’s
peace process since 2002, though not taken up here, suggests the potential that
inclusionary mechanisms, including powersharing, can have in such a context
with the presence of international guarantors and programs aimed at facilitating
dialogue and mutual understanding.
2009) to disaggregate the study of civil wars. The pattern of mass-based vio-
lence, organized by rebel armies operating across borders in waves of violent
reprisals led by the state, offers one pattern of what are classified as “civil wars”
but that merit separate explanations.
Second, the cases of Burundi, Rwanda, and the entire Great Lakes region
(certainly including Rwandan and Ugandan involvement in postgenocide war-
fare in Zaire) exemplify the importance of a regional level of analysis and the
salience of transnational factors. Third, both cases support claims that democ-
ratization can fuel mass ethnic violence. As Uvin (1999, 267) says, “The most
recent and most extreme rounds of violence are the direct result of processes of
democratization set in motion in large part by pressure from the international
community.” In the absence of coherent prodemocratic political actors, democ-
ratization itself may prompt insecurity and mass violence. And fourth, the role of
chronic, rather than precipitating, exclusion stands out, despite instances where
inclusionary measures seemed to provoke mass violence. These cases point to
the need for further conceptualization of types of exclusion and of the processes
whereby it enervates war and violence.
The cases of nonseparatist recurrence of armed conflict reveal important di-
vergences in the character of recurrence, in the aims of insurgents, and in causal
factors. The levels of violence diverged greatly, ranging from hundreds of thou-
sands dead in Africa’s Great Lakes region to only dozens of combat deaths in
Haiti and East Timor’s recurrences. The rebels’ specific motives also differed in
these cases.
Many hypothesized factors played a role in the recurrence of armed conflict
in these cases. These include state weakness in all the cases examined in this
chapter. Indeed, countries like the Central African Republic, Haiti, and East
Timor have come to embody weak state institutions to such an extent that it is
difficult to distinguish those fragile institutions from the very violence that ac-
companies the frequent political changes of government, often through coups
that may constitute internal armed conflicts. In addition, regional factors play
an important role in recurrences in several countries. Although these countries
are all extremely poor, this poverty was not directly related to the instigation of
war recurrences without regard to the more unusual factors emphasized here—
namely, exclusion.
Exclusion by new postwar governments characterized all these cases of non-
separatist recurrences. These cases reinforce the important role identified in
separatist cases and in Liberia of exclusionary behavior. In every case actors un-
derstood their own renewed violence mainly as a reaction to the exclusionary
positions adopted vis-à-vis state power by postwar elected governments.
In addition the cases of East Timor and Zimbabwe show that the exclusion of
former enemies is not the only dimension along which warfare may recur. The
exclusion of former allies or coalition partners after a successful rebellion also
160 Examining the Cases
can prompt a recurrence of armed conflict. In both Zimbabwe and the recent
case of East Timor, the perceived marginalization from state power represents
the main armed violence experienced subsequent to independence. Thus exclu-
sion may precipitate renewed armed conflict when postwar governments move
to marginalize, exclude, or even persecute their former rebel partners.
Finally, the cases of Rwanda and Burundi broaden our understanding of ex-
clusion to reinforce an argument that has been prevalent for many years: that
chronic oppression involving exclusion from political and economic power can
elicit armed violence on a massive scale. This chronic exclusion constitutes a
standing factor that must be combined with other explanations to fully account
for the recurrence of wars in these cases. In both cases, political competition
in democratization efforts represents an important trigger for ethnicity-based
violence, as did the approaching implementation of the 1993 Arusha agreement
in Rwanda.
However, these five nonseparatist recurrences are not the sole cases of recur-
rence. Chapter 6 examines the causes of war’s recurrence in the four cases that
seem to contradict the book’s central argument.
Notes
1. United Nations Office of Coordination of Humanitarian Affairs, “Central African
Republic: IRIN Background Notes,” June 11, 1998, www.africa.upenn.edu / Hornet /
irin_61198.html.
2. On the “predatory” state, see North (1981); and on its existence in Haiti, see
Maguire (1995).
3. This despite the presence of darker-skinned heads of state, such as Francois Du-
valier and Jean-Bertrand Aristide.
4. National Coalition for Haitian Refugees / Human Rights Watch / Jesuit Refugee
Service, “Fugitives from Injustice: The Crisis of Internal Displacement in Haiti,” Au-
gust 1994 report, Washington, D.C. Also see Perusse (1995, 35).
5. UN Statistics Division, “National Accounts Estimates of Main Aggregates,”
http: // data.un .org / Data .aspx?q=haiti&d=SNAAMA&f=grID percent3A101
percent3BcurrID percent3AUSD percent3BpcFlag percent3A1 percent3BcrID
percent3A332#SNAAMA.
6. International Monetary Fund, “World Economic Outlook Database, October
2010: Nominal GDP List of Countries,” data for 2009.
7. Personal communication to the author from Shepard Forman, October 14, 2004.
8. The successive UN presences are as follows: UNAMET, June–October 1999,
provided electoral assistance for the referendum; UNTAET, October 1999–May
2002, administered the territory until independence; UNMISET, May 2002–May
2005, supported strengthening of the state and security with lower numbers of troops;
UNOTIL, May 2005–August 2006, a political mission with only thirty-four unarmed
Nonseparatist Recurrences of Civil War 161
military observers supporting state building; and UNMIT, August 2006 until this
writing.
9. For the details of the events of April and May 2006, I draw heavily on “UN Spe-
cial Commission 2006” report, officially the “Report of the UN Independent Special
Commission of Inquiry for Timor-Leste.”
10. UN Department of Peacekeeping, “UNMISET Home Page: Facts and Figures,”
www.un.org / en / peacekeeping / missions / past / unmiset / facts.html.
11. Australian Defence Force website on the International Stabilization Force in
East Timor, www.defence.gov.au / op / eastTimor / general.htm.
12. Republica Democratica de Timor-Leste and UN Country Team, “Timor-Leste
Millennium Development Goals Report,” United Nations, Dili, 2004, 15.
13. On the history of the independence struggle, see Stedman (1993), Sibanda
(2005), and Bhebe and Ranger (1995).
14. See Stedman (1993), Sibanda (2005), and Bhebe and Ranger (1995).
15. On Nkomo and ZAPU, see Sibanda (2005).
16. For more details, see Lawyers Committee for Human Rights (1986).
17. Ibid.
18. Lemarchand (2004, 66) defines “political exclusion” in a liberal manner, as “the
denial of political rights to specific ethnic or ethnoregional communities, most notably
the right to vote, organize political parties, freely contest elections.”
6
Recurrences That Defy
the Argument
NO SINGLE ARGUMENT or factor can plausibly lay claim to playing the crucial
causal role in recurrences of internal armed conflict. Despite my making a strong
case for decisions by a state that render it exclusionary and insufficiently legiti-
mate, exclusion is neither sufficient nor necessary for war recurrence. Of the fif-
teen core cases of recurrence, four cases do not support the role of exclusionary
behavior in the recurrence of armed conflict. This chapter examines those four
cases. It first explores Lebanon and Mali, two cases that directly defy the hypoth-
esized role of exclusion. In both cases inclusionary behavior was adopted and
maintained, yet dissident groups among former armed insurrectionary groups
took up arms once again. The chapter identifies which factors these cases suggest
are causally important, and why inclusionary behavior failed.
The chapter then turns to Nicaragua and Peru, two postwar states that en-
gaged in exclusionary behavior, but where other factors seem to trump the
impact of government exclusion. These two cases suggest, respectively, the im-
portance of external actors and of the rents from natural resources (viz., coca
products). Despite the preponderance of evidence that shows the significance of
exclusionary behavior in accounting for postwar recurrences of armed conflict,
these cases represent exceptions. They show that other factors, including those
hypothesized in the literature drawn from quantitative works, can play a salient
role in war recurrence.
Two cases show the limits of an explanation that relies solely on exclusionary
behavior. In the case of Lebanon, a 1943 powersharing arrangement failed in
1958, and it was then restored after that initial civil war. Analysts concur that the
failure of that powersharing arrangement constituted the precipitating factor in
the second civil war of 1975–90. Other factors are explored below in the mini–
case study. Of the entire pool of forty-two countries that experienced either war
recurrence or nonrecurrence, Mali offers the only post-1988 case where power-
sharing failed to prevent recurrence. In both cases dissident groups reverted to
armed conflict, despite the adherence to powersharing by some elements of the
Recurrences That Defy the Argument 163
ing migration to the cities, which benefited Christian and Sunni communities
but not Shia Muslims in the South (Makdisi and Sadaka 2005; 60; Zahar 2005,
229–30). This “created a never-before experienced socioeconomic gap that
closely mapped onto religious affiliation” (Zahar 2005, 229). In light of this dis-
satisfaction with Muslims’ share of state power, they questioned the degree of
power President Chamoun enjoyed to make decisions. Specifically, the Lebanese
National Movement (LNM) objected to Chamoun’s joining the Baghdad Pact
and thereby setting back Arab unification. With urging by radio broadcasts from
Syria and Egypt to rise up and overthrow the government, the LNM launched a
series of attacks. The army chief refused to send the army against the rebels for
fear of mutiny, and American marines waded ashore among sunbathers to back
the government against a feared loss of the country to Syrian control and the
United Arab Republic. Roughly two to four thousand persons died in the fight-
ing (Collelo 1989, 186). The president resigned, but the powersharing arrange-
ment was revived amid new leadership.
In this first crisis of powersharing, external influences were apparent. More
than 140,000 Palestinians, 10 percent of them Christians, became permanent
residents of Lebanon in conjunction with the creation of a Jewish state on Leba-
non’s southern border (Picard 1996, 79). Their presence not only constituted
a haven for armed resistance to Israel, and thus a hostile target of the Israeli
Defense Forces, but also invited Arab and other meddling. Syria persistently
attempted to exercise power in Lebanon, emboldened by the Arab nationalist
movement that was embodied in the United Arab Republic. The West, especially
the United States, also exercised its influence at this time. In contrast to most
cases of civil war recurrence examined here, these divisions fell along religious
rather than ethnic lines. External factors enhanced a sense of marginalization
along religious lines to ignite the 1958 armed conflict. Marginalization was ap-
parent, but not through a deliberate disruption, reversal, or reneging of the in-
clusionary approach taken in the 1943 National Pact.
ing the status quo, including the Kataeb that would become part of the Lebanese
Front (LF) and its allies, the Israeli-influenced Southern Lebanon Front, and the
“Tigers” military wing of Camille Chamoun’s National Liberal Party. The state
army, which initially stayed on the sidelines, would by 1976 break into fragments.
Thus, the LF became the main protagonist defending the status quo.
On the other side lay a less cohesive group led mainly by the Lebanese Na-
tional Movement (LNM), under the Druze Kamal Jumblatt, and its allies in a
rough coalition of Muslims, Palestinians refugees, and leftists (including roughly
10,000 Palestinians from the Rejectionist Front drawn partly from the Popular
Front for the Liberation of Palestine, plus the pro-Iraq Arab Liberation Front, the
Independent Nasserite Movement, the Syrian National Socialist Party, and the
Communist Party). Although some Christian leftists belonged to the progressive
coalition led by Jumblatt, very few Muslims were able to stay in the conservative
forces led by the LF.
After the attacks of April 13, 1975, led to a series of mutual recriminatory at-
tacks against civilians, Jamblatt refused to participate in a government to which
the Kataeb belonged. No Sunni political leaders would cross him, but neither
would any Christian-dominated groups concede to form a government without
the Kataeb. Hence a stalemate led to the formation of a Christian-favored mili-
tary cabinet by Maronite president Suleiman Frangieh, leading to a summer of
relative calm, aided by Palestine Liberation Organization (PLO) chairman Yas-
ser Arafat’s success in keeping PLO factions out of the fighting through the end
of the year (Cobban 1987, 128). However, continued wrangling and maneuver-
ing led to renewed and massive fighting among militias. By the fall of 1975, most
of Beirut’s port and the city itself were destroyed, and within two years roughly
600,000 to 900,000 Lebanese had fled the country. The war would eventually
result in the death of some 130,000 persons and cost $100 billion in damage
(Collelo 1989, 181).
The government became largely dysfunctional in early 1976, at which point
many Palestinians joined in the warfare on the side of the LNM. Ostensibly to
quell the violence, Syria launched a full-scale invasion in May 1976. At that point,
the LNM and its Palestinian and other allies occupied 70 percent of the coun-
try. The fighting continued, however, with Israel and Syria tacitly cooperating to
prevent the Palestinian groups and their LNM allies from gaining control of the
country (Winslow 1996, 208–10). With Syrian advances, the Lebanese Forces
made gains, taking back territory from the LNM and convening the Parliament
to install a new government in September. Throughout 1976, Syria and other
Arab states had engaged in dialogue, and after its invasion, Syria sought to legiti-
mize its presence through the Arab League, which deployed troops (Winslow
1996, 210–12). A peace conference in Riyadh in October 1976 led to a significant
166 Examining the Cases
The conflict reflects exclusionary behavior at the outset, including chronic ex-
clusion from before independence through the first civil war of the early 1990s.
Exclusion and inclusion were based not on religion but on ethnic, regional, and
other distinctions involving the pastoral, nomadic Tuaregs who inhabit mainly
the northern, desertified portion of Mali and the western area of Niger. Recur-
rent armed conflict in the period 2006–9 reflects not exclusion so much as the
initiative of a minority of former rebels pressing for more rights, power, and state
benefits. Regional factors were important both because a Tuareg rebellion in Ni-
ger preceded that of Mali in the early 1990s, and interaction continued between
Tuaregs in both countries. In addition, Libyan and Algerian governments both
deployed troops and became active, along with other African states, in seeking
to mediate a resolution. Control of smuggling routes played a role in the 2006
recurrence but was not the primary factor, and natural resources did not figure
prominently.
Despite its reputation as a peaceful West African country, Mali has experi-
enced internal armed conflicts, mostly concentrated in what is generally called
northern Mali, comprising the three (out of eight) regions of Tombouctou, Gao,
and Kidal. These three remote, desert regions constitute 59 percent of Mali, a
portion larger than Afghanistan or Texas. Uprisings against French rule were put
down, as was an uprising by Tuaregs and Moors after independence in 1960.
Tuaregs and Moors make up 5 to 10 percent of the population of Mali, and differ
from other ethnic groups in the country as they generally have lighter skin and
are considered to be related to North African Berbers.1 They numbered 621,000
of Mali’s 12.5 million inhabitants in the 1990s (Keita 1998, 6).
Tuaregs (the term sometimes includes Moors) have episodically sought
greater autonomy from empires and states during the past several decades. The
former commander of a key base in the counterinsurgency of the 1990s described
“a conviction among the Tuaregs” after independence in 1960 that “they were
singled out for particular discrimination, and were more neglected than others in
the distribution of state benefits” (Keita 1998, 10). From 1962 to 1964, Tuaregs
carried out a number of hit-and-run raids that did not constitute a civil war and
that were suppressed by the state. Keita (1998, 10) describes how Tuaregs at the
time felt threatened by land reforms aimed at modernization by southern Mali-
ans unsympathetic to the northern tribes’ migratory pastoral lifestyle. As a result
of the uprising, the government placed Tuaregs under a “repressive” military ap-
paratus (Keita 1998, 10).
in Eastern Europe and Africa also led to pressures in Mali for greater political
and press freedoms, but then–president Moussa Traoré rejected calls for multi-
party electoral system. In 1991 Traoré was ousted and arrested. A transitional
government headed by Lieutenant Colonel Amadou Toumani Touré organized
a constitutional reform process that led to the approval of a new charter in 1992
that provided for multiparty elections and the freedom of political parties except
where based on ethnicity, religion, region, or gender (US Department of State
2010c). Alpha Oumar Konaré of the Alliance for Democracy became the coun-
try’s first democratically elected president in 1992, which ended eighteen years
of one-party rule.
In June 1990 the Popular Movement for the Liberation of the Azaouad
(Mouvement Populaire de Libération de l’Azaouad, MPLA, “Azaouad” being the
Tuareg term for Northern Mali) carried out attacks on two towns in Kidal that
marked the beginning of the war, almost simultaneously with the onset of armed
conflict by Tuaregs in Niger (Dillon 2007, 28; Vinding 2002, 355). These rebels
sought greater autonomy and resources from the state. In contrast to the smaller
rebellion of the early 1960s, the attacks spread across the northern regions and
intensified in 1990–92. One factor here was the harsh repression that the Ma-
lian army visited upon not just the communities in areas of conflict but also on
lighter-skinned peoples throughout the northern areas, which prompted more to
flee and an intensification of the warfare (Poulton and ag Youssouf 1998). Other
rebel groups emerged, some of which splintered. Under Algerian pressure four
of these groups united as the Unified Movements and Fronts of the Azaouad
(Mouvements et Fronts Unifiés de l’Azaouad, MFUA).
Virtually every analysis of the Tuareg Rebellion of the early 1990s refers to
social marginalization, exclusion, and cultural and political suppression. Krings
(1995, 57) argues, for instance, that among the decisive factors for the “margin-
alisation and deprivation of the Tuareg” that led to war were the “negation of the
existence of the Tuareg ethnic community” by black African leaders in Mali and
Niger, along with “exclusion of the Tuareg from political participation.” Dillon
(2007, 2) cites as a “root cause” of the war the “social exclusion of Touaregs from
military and civil service positions.”
Some have argued that severe drought in the North was a major factor in the
Tuareg rebellion. Severe droughts struck the region in the years 1973–74 and
1983–84 (Poulton and ag Youssef 1998, 33; Somerville 1986). These droughts
reduced grasslands and animal herds, made livelihoods more difficult for no-
mads, and forced mass migration (Dillon 2007, 47–49). One detailed study of
the effects of drought concluded that this was not the main cause of the war
(Benjaminsen 2008). In addition, these droughts cannot explain the timing of
the onset of the 1989–96 war. The uncertainties unleashed by democratization
better account for this timing.
170 Examining the Cases
International factors played a role in the initial conflict. The onset of conflict
came in June 1990, one month after rebel attacks began in adjacent Niger af-
ter 18,000 Tuareg refugees returned from Algeria. The Nigerian attacks, which
were related but not coordinated, forced the MPLA’s leader, Iyad ag Ghali, to
launch attacks earlier than he had hoped (Krings 1995). Libya also played a role.
Although Libya’s Qaddafi in 1980 declared his country as the “homeland” for all
Tuaregs and offered them citizenship, one researcher who interviewed Tuareg
leaders found that they dismissed these claims, seeing Libya instead as having
“abandoned” Tuaregs during the first civil war (Dillon 2007, 55). Vinding (2002,
355–56) emphasizes the role of unemployed youth who, affected by the drought
and poverty in the 1980s, joined Qaddafi’s Islamic Legion and received military
training, and then returned to Mali or Niger to fight.
with the blessing of the Malian army, which fueled society-based warfare. In ad-
dition, some distrustful Tuaregs in the army mutinied and killed several of their
colleagues (Keita 1998, 18).
Violence continued through 1996, and it then dissipated to such an extent
that the war was considered over. Ag Ghani’s group (split off from the MPLA and
renamed first the FPLA and then the MPA) did not abandon the National Pact
and helped defeat two other MFUA groups, the ARLA and the FIAA (Hum-
phreys and ag Mohamed 2003, 21). The money of another group, the FPLA,
dried up. Foreign states pressed for implementation of the National Pact dur-
ing this time, and the United Nations Development Program funded a program
working with local chiefs to reinforce peace. In 1996, a “Flame of Peace” cer-
emony in Timbuktu marked an official end to the war, because roughly 3,000
rebel weapons were destroyed. In October 1996 1,620 additional ex-combatants
were integrated into the army, the various police and customs forces, and the civil
service, including 77 at the officer level or equivalent (Dillon 2007, 100, based
on Keita 1998).2
continued attacks from the Tigharghar Mountains, and he took refuge in Algeria,
from where he persisted in his struggle through 2009, even though the Malian
army made important gains and won massive defections of the rebels.
These splinter groups, mainly ex-combatant army deserters, claimed that the
poverty and neglect of the Kidal region underlay their struggle, so it would be
erroneous to see the recurrence as reflecting a reneging on the National Pact,
certainly not its core elements. Instead, Mali’s recurrent armed conflict, albeit a
small-scale recurrence, defies the argument of this book. What factors does this
case suggest are important for the failure of peace? Mali points to the role that
splintered groups and incohesion among insurgent forces pose for the consoli-
dation of peace.3 The increasing involvement of these groups in smuggling also
suggests an economic opportunity that fueled the recurrence. Smuggling had in-
tensified in northern Mali over the previous years, ironically helped by the reduc-
tion of the state’s coercive forces there as part of the National Pact (Dillon 2007).
The integration of ex-combatants was seen as both significant and successful,
despite the problems that developed among some ex-combatants. Dillon (2007,
99–102), in 2006 interviews with Tuareg leaders and ex-combatants about the
stability of peace, found that most Tuaregs brought up integration, citing it as ei-
ther well implemented, helpful to peace, or beneficial to Tuaregs, or all the above:
“Several [interviewees] saw the endeavor as the key factor that helped end the
fighting and ‘establish peace’ in northern Mali. . . . By granting Touaregs access
to these jobs, the integrations went a long way towards addressing the social ex-
clusion that had contributed to the start of the rebellion” (Dillon 2007, 99, 101).
In addition, economic aid to the North and greater power for the newly de-
centralized structures were functioning within a few years. That aid was less than
hoped for and expected, partly due to economic downturn.
Mali’s armed conflict recurrence resembles that of Peru in that many former
combatants abandoned their struggle. However, in Mali, a series of negotiations
played the crucial role, whereas in Peru intelligence feats that led to the capture
or killing of crucial commanders played a key role. Moreover, the Malian state
adopted inclusionary measures that were largely implemented and were not re-
versed by the Malian state. This case offers the most serious challenge to the
argument that exclusionary behavior underlies war recurrence, and that the in-
corporation of combatants into the state army and police forces is a crucial ele-
ment of consolidating peace.
Most analysts cite the attacks of 1981 in their accounts as significant open-
ings to the counterrevolutionary war (Booth 1985; Padro-Maurer 1990; Dil-
lon 1991). Sam Dillon (1991, 54), for instance, describes an initial attack led by
Commander Tigrillo on June 13, 1981, in which six people died in an attack on
a Sandinista jeep with civilians aboard. He describes one rebel’s sentiment that
they had finally attacked and captured weapons “after starving in the hills for a
year.” Prevost (1987, 8) reports that bands of former guardsmen and business-
men formed two groups, the Fifteenth of September Legion and the National
Democratic Union, along the Honduran border, although these resulted only in
“a few isolated attacks” on literacy workers in 1980.
eventually commanded a unit based in Costa Rica with funding from the CIA
and the US Army (Dillon 1991, 86).
Political exclusion played an important role. The Sandinistas made no effort
to include their former enemies in the new government. People from the prior
government who posed a potential threat (including National Guard officers)
were pursued and assassinated rather than integrated into the government or
armed forces (Dillon 1991). Moreover, the Sandinistas quickly showed intol-
erance for those who were former commanders of impeccable revolutionary
credentials but who sought a less radical approach to both land reform and po-
litical life. Once land reform moved beyond taking the large haciendas of the
wealthiest to taking private medium-sized farms, these Sandinistas objected,
which led to their marginalization, to their treatment as potential subversives,
and ultimately to their joining the opposition and even the armed resistance
(Brown 2001, 15). The departure of many Sandinistas echoes, on a less influen-
tial scale, the split of insurgent coalitions in the proindependence movements in
East Timor and Zimbabwe.
Nevertheless, it would be misleading to say that exclusionary policies consti-
tuted the primary explanation for recurrence. Exclusionary behavior drove many
Sandinista supporters to support the insurgency, including objections to their
political and economic policies. Ideological concerns and fear for their lives led
many National Guardsmen to flee and join the rebels. The foreign policy de-
cision by the Reagan administration to contest the Sandinistas on ideological
grounds was a key factor in elevating these disparate elements into an organized
fighting force capable of any serious military operations. The causes of war recur-
rence in Nicaragua lie with an “invasive neighbor” as much as Sandinista exclu-
sionary policies or the objections to them.
Natural resources played no role whatsoever in the origins of the civil war or
its recurrence, except insofar as the banana and coffee export-oriented economy
is seen by some scholars as associated with the one-man dictatorship that So-
moza represented (Robinson 1996; Paige 1997).
In summary, once in power, the Sandinistas set about consolidating their grip
on control of the state. Even though they would later engage in limited inclu-
sionary measures, including competitive elections, their policies excluded both
former enemies and former commanders who criticized government policies or
behavior. Nevertheless, that exclusionary conduct was not the principal trigger
for the recurrence of 1981. The United States’ decision to provide funding and
other support for organizing the remnants of the National Guard was the prin-
cipal factor in recurrence.
Conclusion
What do these four cases tell us about the causes of recurrence of internal armed
conflicts? They first underline the lack of a single factor or approach that can fully
account for war recurrence. The presence of exclusionary behavior by postwar
180 Examining the Cases
states is neither necessary nor sufficient to elicit renewed warfare. It is worth not-
ing the extenuating circumstances that help account for the failure, in particular,
of powersharing in Lebanon and Mali. The massive influx of Palestinians into
southern Lebanon transformed the demographic foundation upon which power-
sharing was based. It also aggravated political tensions, both in the expressed
preferences of this refugee population and by drawing in regional interests and
actors to a greater degree whose policies shifted accordingly. The postwar Ma-
lian government did not deliver on many of its promises of inclusion of Tuaregs,
paving the way for complaints of persistent exclusion. This experience should
serve as a cautionary lesson for cases (see Nepal and Bangladesh in chapter 7)
where authorities are not moving to fulfill pledges made as part of powersharing
arrangements. These cases nevertheless show the vulnerability of powersharing
arrangements to changing circumstances and to perceptions of exclusion.
These two cases of failed powersharing also suggest a new hypothesis that
draws on the theoretical claim that rebel cohesion is important for peacebuilding
success. They specifically point to the importance of rebel cohesion as a factor in
the success of powersharing arrangements. One can also see the element of rebel
cohesion in the Timorese and Zimbabwean recurrences, where victorious armies
experienced divisions and then exclusion, which led to relapse into conflict. Atlas
and Licklider (2005) point to the presence of a similar process of postindepen-
dence violence in Chad and Sudan.
The cases of Nicaragua and Peru illustrate show that exclusion can exist but
also be eclipsed by other factors in recurrence of armed conflict. The Peruvian
case especially lends support to theories that emphasize natural resources as a
central factor in civil wars and their recurrence. Coca products clearly helped
provide the fuel for a resurgence of the Shining Path, much as they have given
oxygen to the growth and persistence of the FARC. Nicaragua’s recurrence calls
into question the level of analysis common to civil war studies: the state. The role
of external states or other actors in not just abetting but also constituting civil wars
and their recurrence requires reconceptualizing civil wars, armed conflicts, and
their analysis. In particular, regional actors and dynamics, as well as extraregional
actors and dynamics, merit systematic and integrated analysis when seeking to
understand today’s armed conflicts.
The three prior cases have utilized a particular method that bears reflection
at this point. The method of “structured, focused” case comparison is not new.
Numerous books and articles have utilized the method, which was initially de-
veloped by the insightful and personable Alex George (Bennett 2008). What
is unusual is the degree to which these have been condensed, considering only
those factors identified in the qualitative and quantitative literature reviewed
initially. These “mini–case studies” constitute one of the contributions of this
Recurrences That Defy the Argument 181
Notes
1. Some 52 percent of Mali’s national population is of the Mande ethnicity (Bam-
bara or Malinke), 11 percent are Fulani, 7 percent are Songhai, 7 percent are Saracolé,
5 percent are Moor and Tuareg, 4 percent are Mianka, and 14 percent are other ethnici-
ties (US Department of State 2010c). The Songhai, Moors, and Tuaregs predominate
in the North, where Tuaregs numbered about 621,000 in the 1990s (Keita 1998, 6).
2. This brought total integration of ex-combatants to 2,230, including 1,311 in the
army, 348 in the National Guard, 301 in the gendarmerie and police, 100 in the customs
service, 50 in the water / forest service, and 120 in the civil service (Dillon 2007, 100).
3. Doyle (2002) and Doyle and Sambanis (2006) emphasize this variable as one of
several that influence successful peacebuilding.
182 Examining the Cases
4. After debate among Peruvian officials, members of Shining Path were permitted
to run for office for the first time in the October 2010 elections (Briceño 2010). See
also Longmire (2009).
5. Brown (2001, 1–19) offers an account of the origins of anti-Sandinista actions
that begins with disgruntled peasants, many former Sandinistas, that fled to hills in the
face of land confiscations. His interviews with former rebels date the earliest attack as
November 1979, when a group of “Milpistas” (People’s Anti-Sandinista Militias, for-
merly a component of the Sandinista army called the People’s Anti-Somoza Militias)
attacked a Sandinista base with only five deaths among the attackers (Brown 2001, 14).
6. On the context of the war and the Shining Path, see McClintock (1998), Fumer-
ton (2003), Fox and Starn (1997), Gorriti (1999), Campbell (1973), Taylor (2006).
In the highlands, poverty correlated heavily with indigenous identity; see Arnson
(2005).
7. See Ploughshares’ “Armed Conflict Reports: Peru,” www.ploughshares.ca /
libraries / ACRText / ACR-Peru.html, which relies in part on data from Peruvian non-
governmental organizations, US State Department estimates, and data from Human
Rights Watch, and was updated in February 2002,.
8. “Minister: Shining Path Remains a Threat in Peru’s Jungles,” Latin American Her-
ald Tribune, August 6, 2009.
7
Making Peace Stick
Inclusionary Politics and Twenty-Seven Nonrecurrent
Civil Wars
Table 7.1 Mode of Civil War Termination by Historical Period, All Nonrecurrent Civil Wars,
1944–2007
Period Victory Negotiated Settlement
Ended before 1988 Bolivia, 1952 Cyprus, 1974
Costa Rica, 1948 Laos, 1960–73
Cuba, 1958–59
Greece, 1945–49
Jordan, 1970
South Korea, 1949–50
Paraguay, 1947
South Vietnam, 1960–75
N=8 N=2
Ended in or after 1988 Angola, 1975–2002 Bangladesh, 1976–97
Bosnia, 1992–95
Croatia, 1992–95
Djibouti, 1993–94
El Salvador, 1979–92
Guatemala, 1968–96
Moldova, 1992
Morocco, 1975–88
Mozambique, 1976–95
Nepal, 1997–2006
Papua New Guinea, 1988–98
Sierra Leone, 1991–2000
South Africa, 1983–94
Tajikistan, 1992–97
United Kingdom / Northern
Ireland, 1969–99
N=1 N = 15
Sources: Table I.1, drawn from Fearon and Laitin (2003), augmented by data from the Peace Research
Institute Oslo, as described in the introduction to the present volume. Determinations of the mode of war
termination (victory vs. negotiated) are the author’s.
Table 7.2 Powersharing by Type, All Cases of Recurrence and Nonrecurrence, 1944–2007
Country (relevant years) Political Military Territorial Economic
Angola (2002–) Yes Yes
Azerbaijan (1994–2005) Yes Yes Yes
Bangladesh (1997–) Yes Yes Yes
Bosnia (1995–) Yes Yes Yes
Burundi (1988–93) Yes ®
Central African Republic (1997–2001) Yes ® Yes ®
China / Tibet (1951–56) Yes
Croatia (1995–) Yes
Djibouti (1994–) Yes Yes
El Salvador (1992–) Yes Yes
Georgia / South Ossetia (1994–2004) Yes Yes
Guatemala (1996–) Yes Yes
Laos (1973–) Yes ®
Lebanon (1958–75) Yes Yes
Liberia (1996–99) Yes Yes
Mali (1994–2007) Yes Yes
Moldova (1992–) Yes Yes Yes
Mozambique (1995–) Yes Yes Yes Yes
Nepal (2006–) Yes Yes Yes
Papua New Guinea (1998–) Yes
Russia / Chechnya (1996–99) Yes ® Yes Yes ®
Sierra Leone (2000–) Yes Yes Yes
South Africa (1994–) Yes Yes Yes Yes
Tajikistan (1997–) Yes Yes
United Kingdom (1998–) Yes Yes
Zimbabwe (1979–83) Yes ® Yes Yes
N = 26
Note: Where power sharing failed, the “Yes” is followed by “®” for “reversal.”
Source: Author’s determinations, based initially and largely on Hoddie and Hartzell (2005).
cases of each of the four types of powersharing to illustrate its role in successfully
consolidating peace.
Political Powersharing
In several cases, political powersharing was deemed indispensable to the success
of a peace process. Powersharing was crucial in ending Djibouti’s civil war, for in-
stance, which began in late 1991 when disgruntled members of the minority Afar
ethnic group launched attacks as the Front for the Restoration of Unity and De-
mocracy (FRUD). The government and the FRUD signed a peace accord in De-
cember 1994, ending the conflict, although a splinter group persisted in fighting.
188 Examining the Cases
As part of the deal, several Afars and two FRUD members were appointed to the
cabinet. In 1999 the FRUD campaigned in support of the governing People’s
Rally for Progress party. This political powersharing was bolstered by security
powersharing that led to seven hundred ex-FRUD being incorporated into the
army by 1996.2 As one analyst put it, “Opting for an inclusive approach to tack-
ling political differences seems to have helped in bringing an end to the Djibouti
civil war” (Yoh 2003, 86).
Tajikistan offers another example of a country where political powersharing
has proven important to making peace stick. As per the 1997 agreement that
ended the war, 30 percent of cabinet posts went to the rebel United Tajik Op-
position (UTO). Although the elections of 2000 and 2005 yielded only two of
the sixty-three lower house seats for either of the two parties to emerge from the
rebel movements, the access to the system for UTO leaders seemed to make a
difference. Again, security powersharing bolstered the political arrangement.3 By
2000, 4,498 UTO combatants had been integrated into the armed forces, mainly
in stand-alone units with their own officers.
Other cases of political powersharing also bear mention. Liberia’s recurrent
civil war, from 1999 to 2003, ended in a powersharing accord that brought the
main armed factions together in cabinet posts and other ministerial appoint-
ments during the Transitional National Government before elections in 2005.
Despite serious corruption among senior officials, the political outcome of this
more inclusionary experience has proven much more successful than the exclu-
sionary Charles Taylor administration. Cases such as Bosnia, Northern Ireland,
South Africa, Mozambique, and Sierra Leone provide better-known examples of
political powersharing that have been successful to date.
Conversely, some cases of political powersharing have resulted in failure and
war recurrence. Lebanon was widely considered to have been a success for many
years between its adoption of powersharing in 1958 through the renewed civil
war in 1975. As mentioned in the discussion of powersharing’s weaknesses, most
analysts point to the inflexibility of that particular arrangement in the face of
shifting demographics that left Muslims, especially poorer Shiite Muslims, feel-
ing disenfranchised as their numbers grew. The arrival of thousands of Palestin-
ians in southern Lebanon also placed stress on the system. After 1989 Lebanon
adopted a revised formula of powersharing for the executive based on revised
population estimates.
In addition, powersharing agreements have sometimes not been imple-
mented, but the ongoing negotiations and / or promise of reaching an agreement
seems to hold recurrence at bay. Such are the cases of Bangladesh (1997) and
Nepal (2006), where some elements have been adopted but many others have
not. Most important in these cases, outright violation, rejection, or reversal of
inclusionary powersharing arrangements has not occurred.
Making Peace Stick 189
Security Powersharing
As mentioned above, exclusion from the military and police forces seems to be a
very provocative factor in prompting war recurrence. Conversely, the incorpora-
tion of former enemies is especially important because it provides concrete, and
usually persistent (at least through several years), guarantees to rebels that sacri-
fice their military organization and weapons. It signifies a curb on the exercise of
the arbitrary or deliberate targeting of former enemies by the state. As discussed
above, a recent study shows that military integration is a statistically significant
factor in the consolidation of peace.
Security powersharing proved vital to consolidating peace in several cases.
Although several contextual variables favored the successful peace process in
Mozambique in 1992, the incorporation of former RENAMO rebels into the
Mozambican armed forces was crucial. By 1995, three years after the negotiated
agreement and cease-fire, 3,662 of 12,195 soldiers (30 percent) in the Mozambi-
can armed forces were former RENAMO combatants (Young 1994, 2).5 As is ex-
plained above, several cases of political powersharing (e.g., Djibouti, Tajikistan)
were accompanied by crucial security powersharing as well.
El Salvador shows that security powersharing can also prove important
within police rather than military forces. Although the majority of the members
Making Peace Stick 191
of the newly created civilian-run national civilian police were not former com-
batants, up to 20 percent of the force could be former guerrillas along with an
equal number of members of the former military-controlled national police (Call
1999, chap. 4). The rebel participation in the new force, along with its participa-
tion in electoral processes, gave important security guarantees to the Farabundo
Marti National Liberation Front.6 Similarly, the creation of a new police service
to replace the Royal Ulster Constabulary in Northern Ireland via the 1998 Good
Friday Agreement proved important in alleviating both sides’ fears about poten-
tial armed actions by spoilers. As part of the reform process, 50 percent of all new
recruits for the Police Service of Northern Ireland have been Catholics.
At the same time, security powersharing at times seems epiphenomenal, not
essential to the maintenance of peace. Angola’s 2002 peace accord, for instance,
included the incorporation of ex-UNITA combatants into the armed forces, but
the killing of UNITA leader Jonas Savimbi only weeks earlier is seen as the single
biggest factor in drawing the bulk of the rebels to lay down their weapons. The
unification of the three armies in the new Bosnian state encountered numerous
obstacles and remains incomplete at the operational level. However, the politi-
cal unification, intertwined with territorial autonomy, served as the foundation
for the successful cease-fire, not the slow and partial unification of armed forces
between the two entities.
Territorial Powersharing
Conflicts over territorial autonomy or secession merit special attention. Despite
the prevailing sense that such territorial conflicts are very difficult to resolve, the
data are unclear. Eight of the twenty-seven cases of nonrecurrence involved sa-
lient issues of territorial autonomy or secession. Of these eight successfully re-
solved armed conflicts, five (Bangladesh, Bosnia, Papua New Guinea, and North-
ern Ireland) included powersharing provisions regarding territorial governance.
Territorial powersharing also may lead to war recurrence. Of the fifteen cases
of recurrence, territorial autonomy or secession was salient in six. Of these six,
five countries reached some sort of powersharing involving territory (usually in
conjunction with other types of powersharing) before experiencing war recur-
rence. In such cases, powersharing was not a panacea. Cases such as Chechnya,
Azerbaijan, Tibet / China, and South Ossetia / Georgia show that providing some
measure of autonomy may help secure a cease-fire, but it does not ensure consoli-
dated peace. In most such cases, an autonomy arrangement only kicked the can
of final status down the road, permitting other factors to reignite warfare. In some
cases inactivity on the part of a powerful state whose sovereignty is recognized
over the territory seems common and may well have occurred before other trig-
gers renew the armed conflict.
192 Examining the Cases
Economic Powersharing
The definition of economic powersharing is wide-ranging, sweeping from mini-
mal consultations with former rebel parties on economic development deci-
sions to property guarantees to specified shares of oil or other high-rent natural
resources. In South Africa, for instance, the guarantees of private property re-
sponded to a key insecurity among whites, given the apparent dominance that
black South Africans would exercise politically. In Guatemala guarantees in the
1996 peace accords provided for land reform and for expanded recognition of
social and economic rights among indigenous populations. The 2006 Nepalese
peace accord also contained measures to reform the feudal land tenure system,
to provide remedial development to the landless, and to protect private property.
Unfortunately, these provisions lay dormant for the transitional period, and thus
were neither abrogated nor fulfilled. At the same time, economic powersharing
may have a relatively small impact on whether or not peace sticks. In Lebanon,
for instance, the disenchantment over political offices far outweighed the rela-
tively minimal influence of the stipulation that all religious communities would
benefit equally from development aid.
In addition, the sharing of natural resources as a means of conflict resolution
can perversely aggravate civil wars. Such was the case with Sierra Leone’s 1999
Lomé powersharing accord. The agreement made Foday Sankoh, the leader of
the Revolutionary United Front, a vice president and chair of a commission over-
seeing the country’s diamonds and other natural resources, a position he used
to fortify his rebel group’s capabilities and attack peacekeeping forces in 2000.
Ironically his participation in the government via the powersharing arrangement
had brought him into the capital and made him more vulnerable.7 Government
troops and intervening British forces were consequently better able to locate and
capture him and his lieutenants, and thus bring a more decisive end to the civil
war by 2002. Nevertheless, Sierra Leone’s 1996 Abidjan and 1999 Lomé power-
sharing agreements show that powersharing is not always successful, and can in
the midst of war portend continued waves of violent warfare.
Table 7.3 Incidence of Powersharing among All Recurrences and Nonrecurrences, 1944–2007
Status of
Powersharing Nonrecurrence Recurrence
Abrogated Laos, 1973 Burundi, 1972, 1988, 1993–2006
Central African Republic, 1996–97, 2001–2
China / Tibet, 1950–51, 1956–59
Liberia, 1989–96, 1999–2003
Russia / Chechnya, 1994–96, 1999
Zimbabwe, 1972–79, 1983–87
N=1 N=6
Not abrogated Angola, 1975–2002 Azerbaijan, 1992–94, 2005
Bangladesh, 1976–97 Lebanon, 1958, 1975–90
Bosnia, 1992–95 Mali, 1989–94, 2007
Croatia, 1992–95
Djibouti, 1993–94
El Salvador, 1979–92
Guatemala, 1968–96
Moldova, 1992
Mozambique, 1976–95
Nepal, 1997–2006
Papua New Guinea, 1988–98
Sierra Leone, 1991–2000
South Africa, 1983–94
Tajikistan, 1992–97
UK / Northern Ireland, 1969–99
N = 15 N=3
Source: Author’s case-by-case determinations.
Table 7.3 includes twenty-five of these cases, based on whether or not these
powersharing arrangements were abrogated in the key few years after conflict
termination (Georgia is an ambiguous case, and so I have set it aside). The as-
sessment of whether a powersharing arrangement is violated is based on whether
any of the four types of powersharing was perceived to have been reneged upon
or withdrawn by the state. Delays in meeting targets to incorporate former rebels
into the armed forces, as has occurred in Nepal, for instance, is not sufficient to
be deemed “abrogation.” Conversely, the ouster of hundreds of former rebels
from the army’s ranks would be considered “abrogation.” Table 7.3 draws directly
on table 7.2.
Table 7.3 shows the high correlation between the abrogation of powersharing
arrangements, on the one hand, and civil war recurrence, on the other hand.
Fifteen cases of preserved powersharing did not experience a recurrence, and
only three such cases (Azerbaijan in 2004, Lebanon in 1975, and Mali in 2007)
did experience recurrence of internal armed conflict. As such, 87 percent of
194 Examining the Cases
of nonrecurrence that show how powersharing is not only insufficient but not
necessary for peace.
elections, and his party gained five of twenty-seven Senate seats and twenty-six
House seats in 1966 (Maríñez 1990). His party continued to compete in subse-
quent elections and elected presidents in 1978, 1982, and 2000. This form of de-
mocracy was illiberal and curtailed; it reflected the anticommunist foreign policy
of the United States and its allies, and it thus inhibited participation by those who
had risen up against a military government in 1965. Yet it was not exclusionary.
Former combatants had the chance to participate in governance and did so, even
though the inclusionary character of political authority was not benevolent nor
perhaps even voluntary in this case or that of Northern Cyprus. If it were not for
external powers and / or intergovernmental bodies using, and then threatening to
use, force, then exclusionary behavior could well have ensued.
instance, the point of the internal conflict was precisely to keep leftists and Com-
munists out of power, which the regime successfully did for decades until 1989.
The Greek Civil War similarly ended with the Communist Party being outlawed
(until 1974), many of its leaders tried and executed, and the remainder jailed or
in exile (Samatas 1986). Even Costa Rica, which had been peaceful since 1948,
represents exclusionary politics because victorious center-right rebels reneged
on their pledge to permit the Communist Party to compete electorally and jailed
some of its leaders.
South Korea’s civil war offers another instance of postwar anticommunist
exclusionary behavior technically followed by no recurrent internal armed con-
flict. Its civil war is not the major war that divided North Korea and South Ko-
rea, which were already separated by 1948 (and thus were considered to have
fought an interstate war, one that has also not recurred amid heavy international
troop presence). Instead, the South Korean nonrecurrent civil war that appears
in the Fearon and Laitin data set is the insurrection of outraged residents of Jeju,
an island where up to 30,000 were killed in the period 1948–50. Months after
police fired on a demonstration commemorating Korea’s struggle against Japa-
nese occupation in 1947, increasingly frustrated residents attacked twelve gov-
ernment police posts. Because many Koreans considered the government and
police to have collaborated with the Japanese occupiers, the socialist South Ko-
rean Workers Party found fertile ground in organizing resistance on Jeju, joined
(and armed) by several hundred defectors in mutinied units of the Korean armed
forces. In this place, the lingering effects of World War II occupation politics
coupled with Cold War ideological competition to fuel protests that grew into
organized armed actions and deadly reprisal massacres by government troops
and anticommunist youth volunteers. The rebels, who eventually received exten-
sive material support from North Korea and began flying its flag, were brutally
suppressed by anticommunist government forces.11
Exclusion followed the war. In 1948 the South Korean legislature banned the
South Korean Workers Party and made it a crime to even mention the Jeju upris-
ing and subsequent massacres. An official truth commission into the Jeju upris-
ing found that, rather than any sort of inclusion of those who had arisen against
the government, at least 14,373 had been killed, mostly amid the “wanton de-
struction” of 95 percent of the villages on a central mountain and the elimination
of most of their inhabitants.12 In April 2006 President Roh Moo-hyun officially
apologized for the massacres associated with the Jeju uprisings and granted the
island’s long-standing wish for greater autonomy, denominating it “Jeju Special
Self-Governing Province.”13
These cases of exclusionary postwar regimes that successfully averted sub-
sequent civil wars reveal that excluding former enemies is compatible with sus-
tained negative peace. However, they also reveal other insights. They show that
198 Examining the Cases
historically specific and normative contexts shape the ideas and patterns of war-
fare, peace, regime type, and governance structures and behavior. Seven of these
nine cases (77 percent) are best seen through a Cold War ideological prism, even
where local power struggles and identity politics underlay wars exhibiting East /
West ideological divides. Admittedly, locally specific contests were subjected to
the manipulation of images, fears, and symbols to fuel the fears or interests of
transnational movements for or against Communism.
Nevertheless, transnational norms in historical moments worked to render
acceptable and even laudable the abrogation of liberal democratic politics and
the adoption of Communist or socialist one-party models. Those historical mo-
ments were global—the end of World War II, the delegitimation of fascism, and
the rise of two models of democratic capitalism and Soviet-style Communism—
as well as regional in nature—the wave of Communist regimes that swept South-
east Asia, the insurgencies that swept from Cuba to South and Central America,
and the legitimation of military institutional authoritarian regimes in South
America. These geographic contexts and historical moments are not determi-
nate, but they are overlooked by both large-N quantitative methods that treat
only countries as the unit of analysis and by qualitative studies that have a depth
of only one or two cases.
Inherent in the philosophical, political, and economic thought underlying
these regimes was not just the marginalization of formerly dominant bour-
geois political parties and economic elites but also their active suppression
through physical elimination, incarceration, reeducation, and / or exile. Con-
versely, anticommunist governments dehumanized Communists and sought to
destroy their organizations. For both Communists and anticommunists, torture
and abuse were at times used as a public display of official rejection, humiliation,
and terror.
Analyzing the cases of exclusionary behavior among countries that experi-
enced one civil war but no recurrence reveals the importance of historical con-
text. Roughly two-thirds of the twenty-seven cases exhibited inclusionary be-
havior, and one-third showed exclusionary conduct. At first glance, exclusionary
politics is not incompatible with sustained peace.
However, every single case of nonrecurrence under exclusionary behavior oc-
curred before 1989. Conversely, inclusionary behavior characterizes successful
terminations of wars after 1988 (see table 7.4). Fifteen of seventeen cases (88 per-
cent) of nonrecurrent wars that ended with inclusionary behavior occurred after
the Cold War’s conclusion in 1989. Only two cases of nonrecurrence with inclu-
sionary behavior occurred before 1989. In both those cases, Cyprus in 1974 and
the Dominican Republic in 1965, external armies intervened to stop fighting on
behalf of an ally, which led to the forging of a political transition that precluded a
victory against the status quo ante but forestalled outright exclusionary behavior
by the state’s armed forces.
Making Peace Stick 199
Table 7.4 Inclusion and Peace after the Cold War: All Cases of Recurrence and Nonrecurrence, by
Political Behavior, 1988–2007
Type of Behavior Nonrecurrence Recurrence
Exclusionary Burundi, 1988, 1993–2006
Central African Republic, 1996–97, 2001–2
East Timor (Indonesia), 1975–99, 2006
Haiti, 1991–95, 2004
Liberia, 1989–96, 1999–2003
Peru, 1981–95, 2007
Russia, 1994–96, 1999–
Rwanda, 1962–65, 1990–2002
N=0 N=8
Inclusionary Angola, 1975–2002 Azerbaijan, 1992–94, 2005
Bangladesh, 1976–97 Mali, 1989–94, 2007
Bosnia, 1992–95
Croatia, 1992–95
Djibouti, 1993–94
El Salvador, 1979–92
Guatemala, 1968–96
Moldova, 1992
Mozambique, 1976–95
Nepal, 1997–2006
Papua New Guinea, 1988–98
Sierra Leone, 1991–2000
South Africa, 1983–94
Tajikistan, 1992–97
UK / Northern Ireland, 1969–99
N = 15 N=2
Source: Author’s case-by-case determinations.
These cases suggest that the end of the Cold War marks a historic shift in
historical contexts that dramatically shape the chances and character of sustain-
able peace in three important ways. First, ideology was the mobilizing principle
and point of reference for most of the conflicts during the Cold War, but not
afterward. Of the nine cases of exclusionary cases that did not recur, ideological
battles over Communism were central to all of them except Jordan in 1970. Com-
munist rebellions or anticommunist counterrevolutionary efforts lay at the core
of efforts to mobilize support and articulate stances, whether it was Paraguay or
Bolivia (with ethnic overtones) in South America; the Caribbean Basin cases of
Costa Rica and the Dominican Republic; the Asian cases of Vietnam, Laos, and
South Korea; or Europe’s Greece. And although several cases of postwar inclu-
sionary behavior occurred in tandem with conflicts that began as ideologically
centered wars during the Cold War, only one armed conflict of the nonrecur-
rences commenced after 1988 (Nepal in 1997).
200 Examining the Cases
Second, global norms of war termination also shifted. As noted earlier in the
chapter, outright victory had been the most common form of war termination
during (and before) the Cold War. However, negotiated settlements became far
more prevalent in conjunction with the end of the Cold War. We know this from
other research on civil war settlements (Fortna 2004a). This shift reflected at-
titudes among armed factions as well as neighboring powerful states and inter-
national organizations.14
Third, just as international actors have played a more important role in fa-
cilitating and mediating peace agreements among warring parties since the Cold
War, foreign troops have also played a notably more prominent role since 1988.
In none of the pre-1989 exclusionary cases of nonrecurrence did international
peacekeeping troops appear. Certainly foreign armed forces arrived and played
combat roles in several cases. These include the assistance from US armed forces
in putting down rebellions in Greece and South Korea. In addition, neighboring
states such as Nicaragua and North Korea helped one or both sides in the civil
wars of Costa Rica, Laos, Vietnam, and South Korea. The closest thing to inter-
national intervention in preserving peace in these cases of exclusion is the role
of teams of diplomats and military experts from the Organization of American
States in facilitating the resolution of conflicts launched by exiles from Nicara-
guan soil against the government of “Pepe” Figueres in late 1948 and again in
1955. However, those were small missions with no combat component (Herz
2008, 6, 13). They also occurred after Figueres had dissolved the country’s
standing army, failing not because of international deployments but because
Costa Rica’s former insurgent combatants regrouped and joined civilians in tak-
ing up arms.
Among cases after 1988, international troop deployments played a salient role
in several. External combat troops helped reach and / or maintain cease-fires in
Bosnia, Croatia, Cyprus, Mozambique, and Sierra Leone. In the first three of
these cases, many observers maintained for years that a withdrawal of foreign
troops would result in war recurrence. In addition, unarmed UN military observ-
ers (usually no more than three hundred) were deployed to strengthen peace
processes in El Salvador, Guatemala, Tajikistan, and Nepal. Still others—such
as South Africa, Bangladesh, and Djibouti—showed that external troops are not
necessary at all to advance. Interestingly, the two cases of inclusionary behavior
before 1989 are also the only two pre-1989 cases in the pool being considered
here in which international troops deployed. These include the US and Orga-
nization of American States deployments to the Dominican Republic and the
involvement of Turkey’s armed forces in forcing an end to hostilities in Cyprus
in 1974. The latter two cases suggest that foreign troop deployments helped avert
the normal outcome of exclusionary behavior during the Cold War. We will re-
turn to the issue of foreign troop presence and “frozen” conflicts.
Making Peace Stick 201
after war and expect to be able to enjoy stability. Inclusionary behavior toward
former enemies is the surest path to nonrecurrence; exclusionary behavior is
the route to renewed armed conflict. Inclusionary behavior need not be power-
sharing, certainly not in the inflexible, timeless formula that facilitated the return
to warfare in Lebanon in 1975. Yet former rebels and their supporters require
some hope of exercising control over their own lives through institutions of au-
thority, especially the state, either nationally or locally. Providing them with ei-
ther a guaranteed share of that power or a regular guaranteed opportunity to seek
it through elections with sufficient guarantees is the sine qua non of sustainable
peace in the contemporary era.
Several components of the international context are important here. Among
them are new transnational norms of elections as legitimating mechanisms and
global human rights standards. A form of authoritarianism that leaves large eth-
nic or religious groups with no hope of inclusion in the polity is likely to confront
armed challenges. Even elected, formally democratic regimes that limit contes-
tation for formerly mobilized populations can expect to face renewed armed
conflict. This is precisely what occurred with governments that were elected in
Liberia, Haiti, and East Timor.
In addition, these cases suggest that postconflict societies are especially sus-
ceptible to the impact of transnational norms, institutions, and international in-
fluence in ways that render exclusionary politics unsustainable. The international
peacebuilding “industry” emphasizes the importance of inclusion, competitive
electoral systems, powersharing, and certainly some measure of responsiveness
to former enemies. Governments that engage in outright exclusion can expect to
receive a colder international reception and even a drop in international aid, as
occurred in both Liberia under Charles Taylor and Haiti under President Aris-
tide. Excluded groups and former combatants perceive these incentive structures
and norms. Once they see that their political or physical fate is threatened, the
international environment encourages rejection and justifies protest in the face
of such injustice. In some cases external assistance for renewed armed conflict in
the face of exclusion is more direct.
ment. The term was applied principally to the several wars and secondary civil
wars related to the breakup of the Soviet Union: Moldova (Transnistria), Geor-
gia (Abkhazia and South Ossetia), Azerbaijan (Nagorno-Karabakh), and the
Caucasus (Chechnya). The moniker has been extended to a number of other
conflicts, including Bosnia from 1995 to the present, Kosovo since its 1999 war,
and Cyprus since 1963. The “frozen” character of these conflicts corresponds in
all cases to the presence or threats of invasion by international troops stationed
specifically to deter renewed combat. In Transnistria, for instance, some 1,300
troops (mainly Russian) of the Commonwealth of Independent States form part
of a Joint Control Commission designed to prevent flare-ups of attacks. Even
where the numbers of foreign troops have been reduced significantly (as in the
Balkans), their value derives from their deterrent effect and the promise that
more forces could be deployed if necessary.
Scholars have still not fully fleshed out our understanding of the concept or
the wars to which it refers. Lynch (2004, 41) has written that these wars are
“events [that] have developed dynamically” in these conflicts, changing the ob-
jective conditions and subjective perceptions of these conflicts (Lynch 2004;
2005, 192–95). Most important, he suggests that the empirical administration
of territory by de facto states has increased the practice, perception, and expecta-
tion of sovereignty among elites of contested separatist territories.
An examination of the cases of recurrence and nonrecurrence of civil wars
here suggests three important findings with regard to frozen conflicts. First, the
concept of “frozen conflicts” calls into question whether “peace” can be said to
prevail in these societies. I have counted most such societies as “peaceful” given
a widespread perception that armed conflict is over, at least for the time being
and the near future. It is not clear that all such societies conform to this defini-
tion, which again raises the question about my definition of “peace” and its op-
erationalization. By including these cases, I have sought to cast a wide net on the
diversity of manifestations of “peace.” However, one must acknowledge that the
quality of perceived peace is less deep and sure in such frozen conflicts than in
other postwar societies. Episodic skirmishes in Georgia, Moldova, and Azerbai-
jan, for instance, show that peace was fragile even as no internal armed conflict
was recorded.
Second, these cases confirm a prominent, oft-cited claim in the literature on
civil wars and peacebuilding: the importance of third-party forces in deterring
renewed armed conflict. Of the twenty-seven conflicts that did not recur, five
had such external troops serving in a deterrent peacekeeping role: Cyprus (af-
ter 1964), the Dominican Republic (1965), Moldova (1992–), and Bosnia and
Croatia (1995–). In some cases that force was more welcome (e.g., South Ko-
rea) than others (the Dominican Republic). In several of these cases, observers
widely believe that renewed armed conflict would recur if not for the presence of
204 Examining the Cases
bias in treatment of Yakoma soldiers, which led to clashes throughout that year
and 2002. However, the presence of international troops corresponds to rela-
tive stability. First, deployments by the Mosques and Imams National Advisory
Board helped prevent violent attacks (including on the board’s forces) from
growing into broader civil war. The subsequent deployment of peacekeeping
troops by the UN Mission in the Central African Republic saw little violence
between the 1997 Bangui Agreements and the end of the peacekeeping mission
and the withdrawal of French forces from the Central African Republic in 2000.
Second, however, violence emerged in early 2001, roughly one year after these
troops withdrew.16 The Central African Republic, Liberia, Haiti, and East Timor
all show the susceptibility of postconflict countries—especially poor countries
with weakly institutionalized polities—to recurrent conflict in the early years
after international peacekeeping deployments are withdrawn. They affirm the
findings of research cited above by Fortna (2008), Walter (2004), Doyle and
Sambanis (2006), and Sambanis (2008) that the presence of peacekeeping
troops correlates with a longer duration of stability.
Third, territorial powersharing may not be fruitful in the absence of political
or military powersharing in more integrated, permanent arrangements. Indeed,
territorial powersharing can create frozen conflicts with perverse incentives to
achieve more sustainable, long-term solutions. Ultimately, once territorial de
facto administration commences, the population looks to the de facto authority
for services, shifts its expectations, and confers greater legitimacy on that de facto
state and away from the de jure state. In this way, territorial powersharing is the
most divisive form of powersharing, given that it does not require the separate
pieces of a whole to communicate, much less cooperate. Minority members and
even units within the armed forces or police must at least communicate and tac-
itly cooperate in order for the institution to function effectively and the leaders to
receive accolades. Cabinets divvied up according to powersharing arrangements
still must work together under the guidance of national leaders to function. In
contrast, the incentives for cooperation between separatist regions that have
won some degree of autonomy generally use it to institutionalize that autonomy.
Moreover, their inhabitants become more accustomed to and influenced by the
discourse of sovereignty and independence—making it extremely hard to re-
verse de facto quasi-statehood. Given these dynamics, unless powerful economic
or symbolic capital is available to sway inhabitants of a separatist region not to
separate, then consistent pressure for independence will probably persist, leaving
armed action as more necessary to alter the status quo on the ground.
To recap, “frozen” conflicts represent an important subset of nonrecurrent
civil wars. The absence of recurrence in these cases may be due to the inclu-
sionary behavior of the state and elites, but it may also (or instead) stem from
the altered incentives that derive from third-party armed guarantors. Frozen
206 Examining the Cases
conflicts also offer a number of hypotheses, some of which have been advanced
and even explored by researchers. But one important and novel finding regarding
these cases is the strong suggestion that the presence of international military
forces—acting as a buffer, deterrent, or enforcer of a cease-fire—is a powerful
factor in the prevention of recurrence of internal armed conflict. The cases ex-
amined, admittedly without systematic controls, in this book affirm the recent
scholarly emphasis on the presence of international peacekeepers in preventing
armed conflicts.
Indeed, the cases of “frozen” conflicts may share an important trait with the
Cold War–era cases of repressive authoritarian regimes that have been able to
prevent recurrence. They both point to the dissuasive power of coercive force
in the calculation of regime opponents about whether to contest state power
through the force of arms. I would not wish to carry this comparison too far,
because there are many instances of repressive, authoritarian regimes that insur-
gents have successfully challenged. However, the socialist cases of nonrecurrence
suggest that the mobilizing, all-encompassing, society-penetrating projection of
state power may have had some success in precluding the emergence of armed
challenge. As suggested above, unless non-Western alternatives gain new promi-
nence, the normative contemporary global environment seems very intolerant
of such stifling and suppressing behavior, rendering this option null—as the em-
pirics of this chapter testify.
Conclusion
What can one conclude from having extended this analysis of the failure of peace
to the full pool of cases of civil wars that seem to have ended? As noted, exclu-
sionary behavior played a central role not only in Liberia and the other two cases
where peacekeeping troops had to be reintroduced, Haiti and East Timor, but
also in several armed conflicts over the pool of civil wars since 1944. However,
this is neither a necessary nor sufficient condition for recurrence. Exclusion can
lead to decades without civil war, just as it is often the trigger for conflict.
When examining the cases of nonrecurrence, however, exclusion assumes
new significance. After 1989 exclusion never produces stability, but it always
leads to the recurrence of internal armed conflict. The cases of nonrecurrence
also reveal the importance of inclusionary political behavior for sustaining peace.
Among the pool of core cases examined here of war recurrence or nonrecur-
rence, 85 percent of instances of inclusionary behavior are associated with sus-
tained peace, in some cases lasting for decades. In only three cases (Azerbaijan,
Mali, and Lebanon) does inclusionary behavior result in the recurrence of inter-
nal armed conflict. This finding also contrasts with a prevalent claim that victory
Making Peace Stick 207
These points are intended to clarify the findings of a complex and lengthy
attempt to extrapolate from the findings of the three main case studies. By exam-
ining the full pool of cases, I hope to provide a more substantive picture of the
causal mechanisms at work than large-N quantitative studies yield. I also seek to
provide something more comprehensive and wide-ranging than detailed case
studies that often show too little awareness of and relation to the broader range
of cases of civil wars and internal armed conflicts.
Making Peace Stick 209
The findings of this study draw on and advance theories of civil war recur-
rence. They offer a critique of the prevalent views that emphasize economic
factors and natural resources in civil war occurrence and recurrence. What are
the full implications of these findings for peacebuilding theory? The following
chapter takes up this question.
Notes
1. I have drawn initially here on the data of Hoddie and Hartzell (2005), excluding
only the Dominican Republic, where cease-fires and demobilization seemed the sole
criterion for qualifying it as “security” powersharing. I then conducted my own catego-
rization of powersharing types for all other cases.
2. Office of the UN High Commissioner for Refugees, “Chronology for Afars in
Djibouti,” RefWorld, www.unhcr.org / refworld / country,,,CHRON,DJI,,469f3882c,0
.html.
3. International Federation of Electoral Systems, “Election Guide,” www.electionguide
.org / election.php?ID=100. Ex-rebel parties gained none of the upper house seats in
2000.
4. World Directory of Minorities, “Hutu and Tutsi of Burundi,” www.faqs.org /
minorities / Sub-Saharan-Africa / Hutu-and-Tutsi-of-Burundi.html.
5. Anthropologists have highlighted the role of tribal rituals for cleansing and rec-
onciliation of ex-fighters; see Honwana (2006).
6. Personal interviews with Farabundo Marti National Liberation Front com-
mander Shafick Handal, 1996, San Salvador; and with Farabundo Marti National Lib-
eration Front political adviser Salvador Samayoa, 1996, San Salvador.
7. See Dupuy and Benningsbo (2008, 2).
8. Note that one case of war recurrence enjoyed peace under powersharing for more
than ten years: Lebanon from 1958 to 1975.
9. On these events, see Atkins and Wilson (1998) and Torrijos (2008).
10. Jordan’s war was essentially King Hussein’s reestablishing control over the mo-
nopoly of coercive force in the territory after tens of thousands of Palestinian refugees
entered the country and carried weapons openly and began exercising some degree of
self-rule. Upon the defeat of the Palestinian forces, no powersharing was contemplated
or adopted with these noncitizens.
11. “National Committee for Investigation of the Truth about the Jeju April 3 Inci-
dent,” report released by the government on December 15, 2003, www.jeju43.go.kr /
english / sub05.html.
12. Ibid.
13. See “Special Act for a ‘Jeju Special Self-Governing Province’ Enacted,” on the
website of the Korean Ministry of Public Administration and Security, www.mopas
.go.kr / gpms / ns / mogaha / . Also see the entry on the Jeju uprising, in The New World
Encyclopedia, www.newworldencyclopedia.org / entry / Jeju_Uprising.
210 Examining the Cases
HAVING EXAMINED THE POOL of the clearest cases of both successful and failed
postwar peacebuilding, what can one say about the implications of these findings
for the theory of civil wars and their recurrence, and for theories of postconflict
peacebuilding? This chapter revisits the initial analysis of what scholars have
found about the causes of civil wars and of consolidated postconflict peace. It
first recaps the central findings of the five previous, empirical chapters (part II)
of the book. Here the focus is on synthesizing the findings of the case studies,
tempered by an examination of the range of cases of war recurrence and non-
recurrence that have informed the study. I then turn to theory, focusing on the
principal overarching approaches to peacebuilding that dominate contempo-
rary debate on postwar peacebuilding. The next section sets forth the concept of
“legitimacy-focused peacebuilding” and its potential to address shortcomings of
the four extant approaches. Then, informed by the perils of extrapolating policy
implications from the theoretical findings, the subsequent chapter turns to what,
if anything, these findings mean for the ability of internal and external actors to
shape peacebuilding outcomes.
rent armed conflict. The robust quantitative correlation between poverty and
the onset of civil war is not disconfirmed in these cases.
The causal import of natural resource dependency is less persuasive based
on the universe of cases, although this factor seems quite important in a subset
of cases of civil war recurrences and especially in a subset of countries that have
experienced long-standing, nonrecurrent internal warfare. For instance, specific
export commodities play a salient role in the persistence of civil wars in Afghani-
stan, Colombia, and the Democratic Republic of the Congo. Conversely, such
export dependency is not apparent in other long-lasting wars in Burma, Pakistan,
Sri Lanka, and the Philippines. Liberia shows how the availability of high-rent
exports under a weakly institutionalized state facilitated the organization of in-
surgency and defections from government military forces. Yet even in this case,
only in combination with exclusionary behavior did natural resources or low ca-
pacity contribute to war recurrence.
Admittedly, the definition of “peace” used here is a narrow one focused on
the nonrecurrence of internal armed conflict. This definition omits the dignity
of life of a society, and the presence or absence of justice for its individuals and
social groups. It falls well short of the preferred content of peacebuilding that
has emerged in the scholarly literature and even policy statements by interna-
tional organizations working on peace and development. Setting aside the lack of
shared conception and measurement of “positive peace,” some substantive rea-
sons warrant a study of negative peace. It has been the main operational indicator
of failure for international peacekeeping and peacebuilding efforts, and the main
yardstick for the success of the UN Peacebuilding Commission. Without nega-
tive peace, positive peace is only a fleeting hope. And discerning how to achieve
negative peace is a necessary first step in determining the steps to advance posi-
tive peace. Surprisingly little consensus exists about the causes of consolidated
peace in international scholarship.
Turning to the cases of nonrecurrence, this study reinforces, to an unexpected
degree, the correlation between negative peace and inclusionary behavior, prin-
cipally by the state toward its former enemies. Powersharing is the most preva-
lent form of inclusionary behavior. It takes many forms beyond allocation of the
presidency or the cabinet to former warring parties, although such guaranteed
quotas remain very prevalent. Especially important among alternative types of
powersharing is the provision of security posts in the military or police forces,
which provides crucial guarantees to alleviate fears of physical violence against
demobilized fighters. This issue constituted a trigger for war recurrence in Li-
beria, the Central African Republic, and East Timor, and to a lesser extent in
Zimbabwe, Rwanda, and Haiti. Although powersharing is neither necessary nor
sufficient to prevent war recurrence, its presence corresponds greatly to peace
consolidation, whereas its abrogation correlates with failure.
216 Implications for Theory and Practice
Yet powersharing is not the only form of inclusionary conduct that helps
peace to “stick.” The vanquished parties’ expectations of being included in po-
litical life can be met via the realistic hope of electoral representation, whether at
the local, provincial, national, or supranational level. To the extent that electoral
results are not rendered meaningless through either vacating the authority of
public office or an outright reversal of voting outcomes, then such democratic
processes constitute inclusionary politics. Yet democratic political forms can
also coexist with exclusionary political behavior, as we saw in Liberia, Rwanda,
Burundi, the Central African Republic, East Timor, and Haiti. These cases dem-
onstrate precisely the limits of liberal peacebuilding models, to which I return
just below.
What are the implications of this book for the civil war literature, with its
quantitative tendencies and its focus on onset rather than the prevention of re-
currence? This study strongly suggests that the substantive significance of exclu-
sionary or inclusionary behavior exceeds that of poverty, resource dependency,
or state capacity in war recurrence. This research calls into question the strong
focus by policymaking entities and scholars on fighting poverty as the most ur-
gent means to advance peace, and it raises questions about our excessive heed to
quantitative methods rather than drawing on some more contextualized analysis.
Poor countries are at a greater risk of civil war and its recurrence, but inclusionary
conduct seems to have much more analytic power in accounting for recurrence.
One illustration of the limits of quantitative methods is what the cases revealed
about the salience of religious fractionalization. Although this variable emerged
as highly statistically significant for the recurrence of civil wars, it figured in only
a few of the clearest cases of recurrence, represented by the fifteen core cases.
Ethnic fractionalization also figured in several, but not in several others. Those
findings are difficult to interpret, but they suggest that the way such social divi-
sions are drawn on by elites or masses is complex. The interplay of these variables
warrants more consideration.
The picture here of war recurrence is one where risk factors elevate the likeli-
hood of exclusionary behavior, often by elected governments reneging on the
perceived commitments to losing factions or groups. It ratifies the findings of
those who find that powersharing can play a positive role for peace, specifically
in the sustainability of postwar peace. It suggests that elite agency is the locus for
examining the chances of recurrence of internal armed conflict after civil war.
The findings call into question a prevailing view that victory in warfare facili-
tates postwar stability, because how postwar polities—shaped by their own po-
litical contests, civil society organizations, and international actors—respond
to power after warfare is more commonly the crucial factor. Including one’s en-
emies, rather than killing them, is the most frequent path to peace.
But it is also vital to reconsider the nature of scholarship on civil wars and
their occurrence and recurrence in light of the historically contextual nature of
Conclusions for Theory 217
environment and how norms constrain the choices available to individual or col-
lective agents within a particular country or specific war. In this study I have not
sought to specify which norms are at work in these cases or to formalize their
role in outcomes—work that has begun elsewhere. Nor do I analyze or seek to
anticipate what sort of normative changes are afoot in the international system. A
number of potential trends regarding human rights, transnational activism, truth
and justice, and peace itself suggest possible future norms, but these are beyond
the scope of the study.
Authoritarianism—and Repression
Let us quickly dispense with the most obvious alternative to liberal peacebuild-
ing: authoritarian or nondemocratic regimes or exclusionary state structures.1
Stepping away from “democratization” as an end or means of state legitimation
would seem to require that international actors be open to some authoritarian
strains of governance. Paris (2004, 180) explicitly considers this alternative, and
he rejects authoritarianism because “it would rely on the permanent, forcible
suppression of contestation” that would engender resistance. In fact, we saw in
chapter 6 that many authoritarian states offer some of the most durable instances
of nonrecurrence. The use of demonstrably violent repression against politi-
cal dissidents can both eliminate armed opponents and remove the incentive
to rebel, in some cases for decades. Authoritarianism is unappealing because it
embodies a lack of even the possibility of fulfilling either individual (liberal) or
group (communitarian) aspirations.
Embracing authoritarian governance is not appealing for another reason: It
requires repression. It suppresses contestation and breeds resentment and alien-
ation. Obviously, these sentiments erode legitimacy, but they may not lead to
armed rebellion in the short or medium run. Many empirical experiences of
postwar authoritarianism—consider Vietnam and Syria—involve the repres-
sion and exclusion of wartime foes. Only through repression did these regimes
survive and avoid war recurrence. It is both unrealistic and objectionable on
humanitarian grounds to expect international actors to embrace severe repres-
sion as the route to avoiding renewed warfare. It is one thing to downplay the
authoritarian traits of elected postconflict regimes, as donors have done in places
like Cambodia and Guatemala. It is quite another to openly embrace severe re-
pression in authoritarian regimes as a path to stability. Such policies fly in the
face of the long-standing normative commitments of donors and international
220 Implications for Theory and Practice
organizations, and would open Western states adopting them to scathing inter-
nal criticism.
service without some sense that one is safe and that such “service” will not lead
to personal danger, group peril, or enhanced social conflict?
The republican worldview emphasizes the dangers of factions, but its solu-
tions seem blind to the ever-present possibility of armed violence and a perilous
aggravation of social hatreds. Thus Barnett’s call for constitutionalism rests on an
assumption of highly formalized institutions that constrain actors. It fallaciously
presumes, rather than helps constitute, the requisite consensus on the rules of
the game by society’s main groups. Madison and Hamilton emphasize the need
for checks and balances (mechanisms that can certainly enhance internal state le-
gitimacy and may reflect power dividing) to curb authoritarian tendencies. Nev-
ertheless, the assumed milieu does not correspond to a fragile cease-fire amid
intense identity conflict. Republican theory fails to recognize the intensity of
group affiliation and loyalty. As Patten (1996, 26) says, “By assuming that there is
some single good—such as civic friendship or self-government—that is a good
for everyone, republicans seem insensitive to difference.”
In this sense Barnett’s proposals for extended debates to reach shared under-
standings and views seem somewhat archaic, oddly reminiscent of the security
enjoyed by eighteenth-century diplomacy. They appear incognizant of the sim-
mering, hate-laced social relations among so many postwar societies. The no-
tion of convening a series of conversations whereby shared understandings may
emerge is attractive, and one that critical theorists like Richmond and Franks
(2009, 212) also seem to favor. However, without some attention to security—
to who will ensure safety against roving and (almost always) still-armed fac-
tions—such conversations are likely to lead to assassinations, threats, circum-
scribed debate, or mass violence in the extreme.
Legitimacy-Focused Peacebuilding
Two central findings of this book are that exclusion is highly correlated with civil
war recurrence, and that inclusion is very highly correlated with the absence of
recurrence, or “negative” peace. This finding suggests that national elites and
international actors can foster sustained peace if they seek to meet the parties’
expectations about their role in governance even after initial elections and into
the future. Various sorts of inclusionary behavior can meet this expectation.
Powersharing in its various guises may do so, but so also may access to power
by holding mayorships or a few posts in cabinet ministries or on local councils
as a result of elections rather than fixed arrangements. In short, inclusion can
include powersharing, power dividing, or simply access to compete in elections
if poor results do not violate expectations concerning representation in the state.
Once spoilers have been mollified in the early stages of war termination, then
medium-term stability requires managing those spoilers by including some of
them in accord with their expectations.
However, minimal inclusion in government represents a highly mechanistic
view of participation and the state. Although the cases point to inclusion as a
Conclusions for Theory 225
Table 8.1 Key Contributions and Shortcomings of the Main Theoretical Approaches to
Peacebuilding
Approach Contributions Shortcomings
Liberal Focus on political nature of Overemphasis on vertical legitimacy,
peacebuilding peacebuilding especially democracy and
Focus on rights as basis for stable elections, versus horizontal
polity legitimacy
Too little concern with quality of
elected governments
Overly individualistic, insufficient
focus on group interests and
insecurities
Republican Focus on finding common ground Presumes single common “good”
peacebuilding among factions Too blind to group identities and
Focus on tolerance loyalties
Focus on intergroup dialogue Neglects possibility of “virtuous”
inclusionary policies in the
absence of dialogue or interaction
State building as Focus on state arena Overemphasis on state capacity over
peacebuilding Offers framework of state legitimacy legitimacy
for addressing inclusion Overemphasis on state rather than
legitimate authority at substate
and suprastate levels
Critical Emphasis on long-term sustainable Undervalues elite politics and deal
peacebuilding legitimacy making
theorists Eschews one-size-fits-all formulae Neglects threat posed by spoilers
Focus on civil society participation Rejects statism, conflating it with
liberalism
crucial element, the historical context and linked factors in these cases suggest
that a broader understanding of how new postwar governments relate to the main
groups of the population is necessary. If stability requires inclusion of the main
social factions in the state, it is because state institutions require internal legiti-
macy. To be sustained, that inclusion must be understood as part of state–society
relations that are minimally institutionalized and accepted—that is, legitimate.
State legitimacy, especially horizontal legitimacy, offers the conceptual mecha-
nism for a more holistic understanding of the relationship for which inclusion
serves as the most visible manifestation. Consequently, a concept of peacebuild-
ing that encompasses not just inclusion of elites but also focuses more broadly
on legitimation is appropriate. This book’s findings suggest a greater focus on
legitimacy in peacebuilding.
I have here used the cases examined in a heuristic manner to formulate an ap-
proach called “legitimacy-focused peacebuilding.” This term constitutes neither
226 Implications for Theory and Practice
peacebuilding. The march of thinking has expanded from including armed fac-
tions to including economic elite interests to including civil society and the
broader population in postwar governance.
As for the second problem of “embracing the reviled,” regimes governing in-
ternational human rights and transnational crime make it somewhat more diffi-
cult for war criminals and alleged perpetrators of atrocities to become part of the
political order in internationally supported transitions. The universal jurisdic-
tion of the International Criminal Court and the increased codification of major
violations of human rights help constitute a much stronger and broader web for
catching the most egregious transgressors. Of course this regime and the trans-
national crime regime remain highly selective, inconsistent, and politicized in
practice. For example, the persistence in the Afghan Cabinet of warlords accused
of war crimes, such as those involved in transnational crime there and elsewhere,
demonstrates the limits of this norm. As seen in chapter 9, candidate selection is
one window whereby international actors can influence the inclusion of political
leaders who may undermine the overall legitimacy of a transition or a postwar
state; however, such action may well be seen as outside interference and prompt
political backlash.
Genuine trade-offs sometimes arise where inclusionary behavior may result
in the accession to power of a faction or individual whose presence undermines
state legitimacy. Under such circumstances, external and internal actors may
perforce accept the temporary inclusion of these unsavory and delegitimizing
leaders with the hope that criminal sanctions or popular sentiment may eventu-
ally politically incapacitate them. Human rights and criminal justice mechanisms
that have shown their reach and tenacity well after transitions have involved se-
nior state offices for the accused, as shown by the cases of Liberia’s Charles Tay-
lor, Serbia’s Slobodan Miloševic, and Kosovo’s Ramush Haradinaj. Whereas one
segment of the population usually intensely supports such individuals, another
reviles them, which leads to a conundrum for horizontal legitimacy. Even with
strengthened mechanisms of global criminal justice, however, they generally take
time and do not adequately or consistently address the problem of embracing
reviled leaders.
Here I present legitimacy-focused peacebuilding as a skeletal framework for
orienting postwar peacebuilding activities. The following statements are in-
tended to clarify the main traits of this admittedly underdeveloped approach:
These last questions are important in light of the disjuncture and even con-
tradictions that have come to light between certain scholarly causal claims and
policy responses. More simply put, the discovery or claim in the social sciences
that factor A is correlated with outcome B does not necessarily mean that policy
230 Implications for Theory and Practice
Addressing Limitations
The study makes ambitious claims about theory, method, and policy approaches
to postwar peacebuilding. At the same time, the study exhibits several short-
comings, including the limits of the methodology, the concepts used, the em-
pirics, and the argument. These limitations simultaneously suggest further lines
of inquiry and thinking. This section addresses three of these weaknesses and
some of their implications for the study of war and peacebuilding. Broadly speak-
ing, I present each of these lines of inquiry in the order of its potential scope
and significance.
The Argument
First, the argument advanced here—that sustained peace depends upon the in-
clusion of former enemies and the social groups associated with them—is not
new. Others have pointed to the concept of exclusion as well as the main mecha-
nism of inclusion, powersharing, in accounting for civil war outcomes, if not the
Conclusions for Theory 231
The Method
Second, this study seeks to do something novel methodologically. It uses both
quantitative methods and a more in-depth case study, but it combines these with
mini–case studies of the entire pool of civil wars that experience recurrent armed
conflict. It also draws heuristically on the pool of civil wars that do not recur.
This tripartite method—seeking not only quantitative methods and case studies
but also a middle ground of extremely short, focused case studies—has some
deficiencies in both concept and execution.
Conceptually, it is impossible for anyone to perform numerous mini–case
studies with the degree of contextual vibrancy and fullness that in-depth case
studies offer. Case specialists will always find themselves dissatisfied with the
omission of key elements and causal relationships that did not make the cut. By
drawing on a structured, focused tablet of hypothesized independent variables,
any researcher will omit the unique or case-specific explanatory factors that have
not been proposed or hypothesized. Using primary source material on such a
large pool of cases is impossible except in large, well-funded collective research
projects—which are discouraged by academic career incentives. Furthermore,
comparativists (among whom I count myself) may find the comparison of
widely disparate cases like Russia, East Timor, and Sudan excessively ahistorical
and decontextualized, especially in the absence of regional similarities that act as
controls. Although these sorts of disparate comparisons are at the core of quan-
titative work, such methods purport to control for potentially relevant variables,
which renders the causal relationship more reliable than when such controls are
not able to be exercised.
In terms of execution here, the linear regressions presented would have
been more robust and persuasive if they had included more complex methods.
They could also have utilized armed conflicts themselves as the unit of analy-
sis, rather than a country whose inclusion is clouded by multiple or unrelated
armed conflicts, which unduly reduced the data set. In addition, the single case
study of Liberia relies on secondary sources for judgments about things such as
the quality if interwar peace and the role of various factors in recurrence. And
experts may criticize the analyses contained in the mini–case studies, even in
condensed form.
Conclusions for Theory 233
Despite these flaws, the method of short, focused case studies also shows
promise for future research on related topics. The presentation of such case stud-
ies, especially where the entire universe of cases can be covered, addresses the
main deficiencies of the two most prevalent methodological approaches: large-N
quantitative studies and a few in-depth case studies. As described in chapter 1,
large-N quantitative studies cannot address variables that do not lend themselves
to useful proxies or measurement. Case studies, including mini–case studies, can
address such hypothesized factors. Furthermore, covering the full scope of cases
gives the reader a sense of understanding of the dynamics at work for all the
cases, which permits the identification of patterns and an understanding of inter-
action among different variables as well as the role of different levels of analysis.
In-depth case studies, of course, offer all these advantages, but it is simply not
possible to construct a dozen or two dozen such in-depth case studies in a way
that is either feasible for researchers or digestible for the general reader.
and resources, often ensnaring other states as enemies. Conversely, states can
constitute rebel organizations in other countries or inside their own borders to
attack other states and to feed, arm, train, advise, and provide legitimacy and
other communications support to such proxies. The relationship between state
sponsors and their proxies requires much more research, and it falls through the
cracks of most of our conceptual maps.
Second, if civil wars are wars between two formed armies, then what happens
when one side is not an army at all? Scholars must increasingly recognize the var-
ious and increasingly important roles played by civilians—as agents of violence,
as victims, or as active supporters—in relation to armed combatants. There are
various dimensions to this relationship. One is that scholars need to devote more
attention to analyzing “one-sided violence” and its relation to more conventional
notions of warfare. Andrew Mack and the Human Security Research Group have
made pathbreaking progress in emphasizing this form of violence as distinct from
warfare and going beyond genocide (Human Security Research Group 2005,
2009). It is clear that one-sided violence is a salient subject in its own right. What
is not clear is how one-sided violence interacts with more conventional warfare.
Many of the cases included in the Fearon and Laitin (2003) data set would not
be counted as “civil wars” by many observers. Some, like the Central African
Republic, come closer to coups involving dozens of deaths, whereas others rep-
resent high levels of one-sided violence. The cases of Rwanda, Burundi, Haiti,
and others demonstrate the need for more discriminating concepts of what have
been called “civil wars.” They also show the importance of analyzing how “one-
sided violence” interacts over territory and across borders with organized armed
factions (civil, interstate, or proxy war). When does one-sided violence breed
insurgent movements or trigger their attacks? Does one-sided violence draw in
third-party armies / peacekeepers more often than what are seen to be civil wars?
Do external states react differently once a civil war becomes one-sided violence?
In addition to one-sided violence, the role of civilians further challenges our
understanding of war. The most obvious is that civilians frequently comprise the
bulk of both “combatants” and casualties. Attacks are often carried out by “civil-
ians” who take on combat roles for only a few hours. Personally, for instance, I
recall my experience in the late 1980s living in a village in El Salvador, where the
guerrillas sadly pressured children to participate in brief nighttime excursions
to burn buses in neighboring villages. And civilians conduct training and indoc-
trination for warfare, not to mention financing. The Human Security Research
Group (2009) has also drawn attention to the role of civilians as the principal,
often uncounted, victims of warfare in places like the Democratic Republic of
the Congo, where their flight from combat leads to disease and hunger-related
deaths. Because these are not combat-related deaths, they are not convention-
ally counted as casualties of war. As the events in Libya of 2011 illustrate, civil-
Conclusions for Theory 235
ian demonstrators and protesters can also spark internal armed conflicts, and
even civil wars, if armies split and states militarize such contests. More broadly,
other nonstate civilian actors—including members of diasporas, multinational
corporations, nongovernmental organizations, and regional intergovernmental
organizations—also play increasing roles in armed conflicts. These multifaceted
roles of civilians and how they relate to combat have received increased atten-
tion in recent years, but this scholarship has been poorly integrated into broader
understandings of civil wars and their recurrence.
In summary, the study of civil wars, their recurrence, and warfare more gen-
erally requires more nuanced concepts for the contemporary world. By delving
into the specifics of the cases that are captured by some of the best data sets,
data that are used to draw high-profile and widely read scholarly works on civil
wars, this book reveals the diversity of these cases. Rather than assuming that
more numerous and discriminating control variables can ensure that comparable
events are being compared, scholars should press to develop more discriminat-
ing concepts that differentiate these kinds of violence in ways that might lead to
better understandings, enhanced theory, and improved policy. The implications
for this last arena—policy and practice—are especially important in a field so
intertwined with those who actively seek to advance peace, justice, and develop-
ment. The final chapter turns to these implications.
Notes
1. Paris (2004, 181–82) also addresses partition as an alternative. However, parti-
tion is one solution that parties may reach through dialogue, and renegotiating state
borders is not incompatible with liberal traditions.
2. See the 2005 Paris Declaration and the 2008 Accra Agenda for Action, both at
www.oecd.org / document / 18 / 0,3343,en_2649_3236398_35401554_1_1_1_1,00&
&en-USS_01DBC.html.
3. Zartman’s works are useful to consult—see Zartman (1977, 1995a, 1995b,
1995c) and Zartman and Berman (1982).
4. On “doing no harm” in postconflict state building and peacebuilding, see Call
(2008a); DAC-OECD (2007).
9
Conclusions for Policy
and Practice
Can External Actors Build Legitimacy after War?
PAST EXPERIENCE INDICATES THAT the enterprise of consolidating peace
fails in a high percentage of cases, often within the first few years of a cease-fire.
Transforming states and their relationships with societies is even more chal-
lenging, and the role of external actors is complex and fraught with risks. The
previous chapter explains how postwar inclusion of elites is tied to theoretical
notions of state legitimacy, and advocates a “legitimacy-focused peacebuilding”
that contains elements of, but differs from, liberal, democratizing, republican,
state-capacity-focused, and critical approaches to peacebuilding. Given how dif-
ficult it seems for outside actors to foster inclusionary behavior and the state
legitimacy that seems so central to making peace stick, is there a role for external
legitimacy building? What role, if any, can outsiders play in fostering inclusion
and legitimacy?
The behavior of elites toward different ethnic or religious groups is shaped
by numerous factors that are historically rooted, economically driven, and resis-
tant to outside pressures. National elites and their own leadership (Machiavelli’s
virtu) have historically proven decisive in the process of laying the foundation for
a legitimate state in a war-torn society, one in which divided groups eventually
consent to conform to the political order and acknowledge, albeit begrudgingly,
the authority of political structures, rules, norms, and governments. Exclusion-
ary behavior occurs foremost through the agency of national elites, especially of-
fice holders. The ability of international actors to influence such behavior is not
straightforward. A less politically engaged role for donors and the UN system—
focusing on state capacity, basic needs like health and education, social dialogue,
or verifying peace agreements—might seem to make more sense than trying to
engage the complex and perilous process of enhancing horizontal legitimacy in
war-torn societies.
This final chapter argues the contrary. I contend that there is a positive role
for external actors in enhancing inclusionary behavior and legitimacy-focused
peacebuilding, despite the limits and perils of their influence. Those perils are
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 237
extraordinary. External actors face systematic and, in most ways, growing con-
straints in their ability to shape the legitimacy of postwar states through delib-
erate efforts. The chapter begins with the formidable obstacles facing external
actors to engage in the tasks of enhancing inclusionary governance and building
legitimate authority. It then returns to the earlier point that no single formula
or model of inclusionary governance will guarantee legitimacy. However, I do
find a set of persistent challenges, trade-offs, or decision points common to most
postwar societies.
The chapter then breaks down the process of transition from warfare into
four “moments,” or temporal junctures, whose dynamics differ from one another,
but that hold some common challenges across most postconflict societies. These
four moments are (1) the decision on what structures and which individuals
will rule for an interim period, (2) the long-term “design” of the state, (3) elec-
tions and the end of an interim administration, and (4) the postelectoral period.
Although the first three phases are important, it is the “postelection moment”
where exclusionary behavior has led to recurrence in the case studies examined
here, and the phase that has been neglected in research. The chapter outlines
the particular challenges and possible steps to overcome them for each of these
phases in a postconflict environment. In doing so, it advances several principles
for peacebuilders that maximize the chances to overcome the obstacles to inclu-
sion and state legitimacy described in the previous chapter.
heeding national elites’ wishes and deferring to their judgments, they could still
undermine the latters’ legitimacy solely by virtue of their external character. This
“legitimacy-building conundrum” presents especially difficult hurdle in contem-
porary international relations in the wake of intensification of global Southern
rhetorical resentment of Western dominance, especially in the Arab world.
leverage by threatening to cut things like travel privileges, trade preferences, and
diplomatic relations. Yet such steps are disproportionate for trying to stimulate
political will to reform the judiciary or to seat a representative on an electoral
tribunal. Of course, the aid for specific programs themselves can be threatened
(or offered as incentives), but all too often sovereign states can enjoy the benefits
of aid without in the end complying with the strings attached. And donors are
reluctant to follow through on such threats, because it leaves them with no le-
verage and little to show to their constituents back home. As mentioned above,
some poor states are also expressing a clearer rejection of political conditionality
because they have been encouraged by competing nontraditional donors.
In addition, development actors tend to see themselves as providing resources
even to illegitimate regimes, emphasizing “getting along” with the government in
order not to be cut off or kicked out of the country by sovereign states. They have
historically been reluctant to threaten to withhold resources over “politics” (e.g.,
exclusionary behavior or a lack of transparency) that lie at the heart of legitimacy.
Many development officials also resent the idea that peacekeeping organizations
or diplomats might leverage their “neutral” development aid for political ends
such as incentivizing spoilers or bolstering powersharing.
here. Although elections have come to epitomize the institution whereby rulers
can supplant one another nonviolently, they can also spark social division and
conflict, especially where uncertainty due to past authoritarianism or warfare
reigns. As Kumar and Ottaway (1998, 230) admit in a volume that advocates
the positive impact of elections for postconflict societies, “In the absence of a
tradition of democratic contestation, elections in the aftermath of civil war can
be highly divisive.”
Multiparty democracy injects a chance at power, but also a chance for oth-
ers to gain unfairly. Societies experiencing fair and competitive elections for the
first time also face uncertainty about who might cheat and how, especially in the
absence of an effective third-party arbiter of election behavior (be it the courts,
a trusted electoral tribunal, or even an international third party). Unfortunately,
international actors are often not authorized or are ill prepared to confront the
worst cheating and election-related violence. Therefore, much like the situation
in which a commitment problem can lead to violence between two parties whose
relationship undergoes a transition once an overarching authority is weakened
(Fearon 1998), so also a transition from a single-party regime to a multiparty
one can spark violence centered on the electoral timetable. For external actors,
promoting elections may channel attention and resources away from inclusion.
As Carothers (2009, 10) says, “A narrow focus on the basic institutions of politi-
cal competition, especially elections, may not help aid providers to arrive at ways
of broadening inclusion, representation, and participation.”
Most notable here is the role of elections in sparking mass violence. Mans-
field and Snyder (2005, chap. 5) find that in countries undergoing transitions
to democracy, the risk of interstate warfare goes up by a factor of four to fifteen.
Snyder (2000) documents a number of instances where democratization, and
specifically the introduction of competitive, multiparty elections, played a lead-
ing role in the onset of civil war. Prominent cases include the internal wars that
became cross-border wars in Yugoslavia after 1991, Rwanda in 1990, Burundi in
1993, Nagorno-Karabakh in 1992, and Georgia in 1992 (Snyder 2000; Mansfield
and Snyder 2005). Mansfield and Snyder (2005) describe the polarizing effect
of elections via the stirring up of nationalism.
The poster child for the violent potential of postwar national elections is An-
gola in 1991. During peace negotiations, UNITA rebel leader Jonas Savimbi used
the international fascination with a presidential election as a means to regroup,
buy time, and test the opportunity to gain legitimate access to state power, with-
out a commitment to abide by the results. Once his loss was apparent, he resumed
warfare. Whereas the war before the elections had cost 100,000 to 350,000 in
battle deaths, with hundreds of thousands displaced, the postelectoral violence
was by most accounts even more deadly (Tvedten 1997, 111; also see Duke 1998;
Stedman 2002). Between 300,000 and 500,000 people died just between the
242 Implications for Theory and Practice
1992 elections and 1994, which illustrates the dangers of an ill-conceived rush
to national-level winner-take-all elections.3
Since that tragedy, most policymakers and scholars have aggressively dis-
avowed prompt presidential elections as a sufficient marker for democracy (US
Agency for International Development 2005; United Nations Development Pro-
gram 2007). They have instead championed the demobilization of insurgents
before national elections (e.g., Liberia after 2003); the delay of elections until
state institutions are sufficiently in place to manage potential instability (e.g.,
Kosovo); and the holding of municipal and / or legislative elections before presi-
dential elections, a point to which I return below (Paris 2004). Each of these
modifications of the crudest form of postwar democracy promotion signals a
greater flexibility and context-specific approach to postconflict assistance.
Even with these alterations to the “liberal” or “democratic” peacebuilding
model (see Paris 2004; Ottaway 2000; Richmond and Franks 2009), however,
elections continue to serve as the focal point for international legitimation ef-
forts in postconflict settings. Thus the holding of a procedurally free and fair
election is deemed to settle the question of internal and external legitimacy. Ex-
ternal actors are understandably reluctant to broach indicators of broader illegiti-
macy, because these might be interpreted as stepping back from the principles
of democracy. Within the “democratization” framework, national actors have no
clear alternative framework within with which to challenge exclusionary behav-
ior. The presumptive answer, aside from resort to violence, is to wait until the
next election. And the international community is unlikely in the medium term
to agree on an alternative regime type as preferable to some form of competi-
tive multiparty electoral system (on democracy assistance, see Carothers 1999,
2009; McFaul 2004).4 In posttransition states that are even minimally reliant on
external assistance, some form of electoral regime remains the sine qua non of
interstate legitimacy.
If democracy promotion can be harmful, why is legitimacy building any less
perilous? Given that state legitimacy inevitably involves some form of electoral
democracy, it would be deceptive and naive to pretend that it is possible to con-
ceptualize “legitimacy building” or to engage in it in a way that is wholly indepen-
dent of many of the challenges posed by democratization. The inherent contra-
diction of using outside influence to empower “rule by the people” applies to both
“legitimacy building” and democracy promotion. The tensions between elite-
driven bargains and popular inclusion and participation also afflict both these
enterprises. And the greater a state’s legitimacy, the less influence or leverage en-
joyed by outsiders, whether elected in a shallow democracy or selected through
a nonelectoral form of consultation or participation.
Nevertheless, the concept of legitimacy building offers some advantages of
democracy promotion. As discussed in chapter 2, state legitimation is distinct
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 243
from a particular regime type, although some form of popular consultation and
participation constitutes a minimal foundation for broader state legitimacy. First,
state legitimacy encompasses more multivalent political relationships than the
rules of the political game and their procedures connoted by democracy. Among
those political relationships, “legitimacy” more explicitly includes broader elite
bargains than the more formal constitutional or other pacted agreements that
appear in the democratization literature and are connoted by democracy pro-
motion (Karl 1990; Mainwaring, O’Donnell, and Valenzuela 1992; O’Donnell,
Schmitter, and Whitehead 1986; Przeworski 1991; Hagopian 1991). The politi-
cal relationships connoted by “legitimacy” also encompass a broader array of
forms of participation for society, including various social sectors or the “masses.”
Furthermore, state legitimacy derives not solely from the representational
element of society in the state, although this is one core element. The “legiti-
macy” of a state and its authorities may derive from forms of consultation or
participation that differ from formal party-based elections that are the hallmark
of democracy. In this sense, legitimacy is more difficult to define, to measure, and
to influence. But it is also more flexible than the specific features or structures
associated with democratic regimes.
Second, the terms “state legitimacy” and “strengthening legitimacy” do not
raise the hackles of the global South nearly as much as the language of “democ-
racy” and “democracy promotion.” Thomas Carothers (2009, 6) speaks of a
“growing backlash against both democracy promotion and democracy more
generally.” The spread of elective, one-party regimes in parts of Africa (Ottaway
2000), together with a renewed wave of coups and coup attempts (LeVan 2011),
calls into question the unbridled march of multiparty competitive regimes and
liberal rights (Carothers 2006). In addition, China and other nontraditional do-
nors now deliberately seek to offer an alternative to conditions related to human
rights and democratic governance placed by Western donors on their foreign
aid. These trends, coupled with the backlash against US hegemony surround-
ing the aftermath of the September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks and the perceived
entanglement of the United Nations and other international organizations with
Western power, deepen the mixed reception of much of the world to Western
democracy-promotion efforts. Although the global South does not embrace the
concept of state legitimacy, it remains more amenable to the concept than to
democratization.
Legitimacy has the advantage of including a crucial element of state–society
relations: the ability of the state to meet social expectations about delivering ba-
sic services. These basic services at a minimum include ensuring security from
external and internal threats, minimal regulation for the economy, and minimal
public goods such as infrastructure, education, and health. One study, by the
economist Philip Keefer (2008), finds that the ability of leaders to make credible
244 Implications for Theory and Practice
someone must decide who the deciders will be. Actors who exercise control by
virtue of contested sovereign claims or because they can deploy military force
(including external actors like neighboring states, African Union forces, or UN
peacekeepers) will influence at some initial point the determination of who are
the “genuine” spokespersons for society and for major social groups. Someone
must decide which social groups merit a place at the table to begin with.
Such decisions will of course vary from society to society, and national ac-
tors usually fulfill that determining role. In exceptional cases (e.g., Bangladesh in
1997 and Djibouti in 1994), international actors will play no direct or influential
role in such decisions. Where international actors play such a role, it may well be
possible for the major international and national stakeholders to agree virtually
unanimously on the composition of a consultative process, even where no elec-
tions validate the composition. Yet the power of the groups with guns will always
play an oversized role in the constitution of the earliest foundations of a process
of determining who is a legitimate representative of a particular ethnic group
or of society as a whole. External actors perforce shape such a decision where
their armed forces are involved. This is certainly true of processes without elec-
toral validation (speaking here of processes in the earliest stages of consultation
to determine when, whether, and what sort of transitional or political process
should be adopted), but also true even where elections are held in the immediate
aftermath of warfare.
Here I turn away from specific formulas for enhancing legitimate authority
and from given processes that should be followed in postconflict societies. In-
stead, I suggest that thinking about particular decision “moments” in the evolu-
tion of postwar political processes offer clusters of decisions that will shape the
incentives for exclusionary behavior by national actors during and after a transi-
tion from war. Rather than suggest processes to be followed, I suggest that com-
mon choices confront international and national actors at specific moments in
most transitions from armed conflict. Thinking sequentially about possibilities
should supplant thinking mechanistically about implanting a particular form of
governance-like powersharing.
When addressing the ability of international actors to make enhanced legiti-
macy a cornerstone of peacebuilding policy, it is useful to focus on four moments
or phases. International actors face different challenges in each of these phases.
There is no formula to help international actors address legitimation challenges
in any of these moments. However, it is possible to provide midlevel generaliza-
tions (George and Bennett 2005) about what has tended to produce problem-
atic—or positive—outcomes. These points of guidance can serve as cautionary
tales or encouraging tales for possible lessons to be adapted. These moments are
intended to help organize our thinking (i.e., conceptual approaches) to postcon-
flict international efforts. In particular, some of these moments have received
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 247
prerogatives but a high degree of informal external influence (e.g., Sierra Leone,
Liberia, Burundi, Haiti, and Afghanistan). In most of the latter cases (e.g., Haiti
and Afghanistan), external control is high in the immediate aftermath of war but
becomes more circumscribed once a national interim government is formed.
Less common are cases (e.g., Bosnia) where international prerogatives grow af-
ter an initial period.
One of the most striking bifurcations among the staff members of bilateral
actors and international organizations (and some academics) is between those
whose experience lies in cases where international actors exercised intrusive, ro-
bust prerogatives and those where they did not. The former group exhibits a
striking tendency in postconflict peacebuilding discussions to presume as their
starting point that international actors will or should exercise such heavy author-
ity. Conversely, those analysts shaped by the latter experiences tend to assume a
norm that national actors will remain the primary transitional agents. The reality
is that most transitional arrangements are chosen and led by national actors, even
where international troops, aid agencies, and diplomats exercise important influ-
ence on the selection of rules and / or individuals. In the next subsections I dis-
tinguish between transitions from war where international actors had a decisive
influence on decisions about interim authority and those where they did not.
They do so for both principled beliefs in their enhanced ability to foster peace,
prosperity, and justice and for self-interested goals of power and profit.
Despite the allure of greater prerogatives and powers, external actors should
resist this temptation unless it is absolutely necessary. The starting assumption
and the preferred option for external actors’ optimal role should always be mini-
mal unless circumstances dictate otherwise. If legitimation of internal state au-
thority is the linchpin for success in peace consolidation, then it makes no sense
to usurp this authority unless compelled by circumstances. And even where cir-
cumstances do seem to dictate a heavier hand for international actors, the long-
term formation of legitimate authority in a territory may suffer. Such a scenario
unfolded in Bosnia, where the Office of the High Representative accrued greater
powers to disempower spoilers but in the process undermined the emergence
of an unmediated relationship between the Bosnian state and the population
(Cox 2008).
ipate in the determination of a participatory process. At the end of the day, peace
tends to trump justice, participation, accountability, and “good governance.”
Here external actors are generally supporting a more inclusionary peace pro-
cess of former combatants. Because peace agreements tend to privilege the secu-
rity and interests of the warring parties, promoting adherence to them generally
helps alleviate any uncertainty and insecurity that the armed parties may have.
International privileging of the warring parties’ interests over broader social de-
mands is understandable, given that concern in the first few years about rever-
sion to conflict is paramount.
Unfortunately, such privileging has a downside. Negotiated settlements often
do not include sufficient incorporation of civil society and the broader public,
not just in their preparation but also in their substantive terms. Third parties
need to balance the concerns of the potential spoilers in decisions about interim
authority against those of the broader population. One might think of this as
balancing horizontal legitimacy (to the extent that this derives from the interests
of the parties to an accord) with vertical legitimacy. From another angle, priori-
tizing the demands of the warring parties may be good for short-term stability
but may work against the long-term legitimation of state authority. Many peace
processes reflect a marginalization of civil society participation and demands,
such as Liberia’s peace agreements of 1996 and 2003, as well as Bosnia’s Day-
ton Accords.
One example of a peace agreement that successfully incorporated civil soci-
ety into the negotiations process and pacts was Guatemala. The multiple agree-
ments of 1995–96 included many of the issues and demands of civil society. The
weakness of the Guatemalan insurgents, who had been strategically defeated by
the mid-1980s, provided the permissive condition for civil society to have such a
weighty role in the negotiations with the government. Many civil society actors
enjoyed greater internal and external legitimacy than the rebels.
Unfortunately, the peace process in Guatemala is regarded as flawed in the
extent to which civil society’s interests actually were met (Stanley and Holiday
2002). Most of the important elements of the peace agreements went unful-
filled. However, the flaw was not in a failure to emphasize the interests of the
parties sufficiently vis-à-vis the vertical legitimacy. Instead, the problem lay in
the unwillingness or inability of external actors to extract from Guatemalan en-
trenched interests enough concessions to put teeth into the peace agreement and
its implementation (Stanley and Holiday 2002; Prado 1998; Alvarez and Prado
2002). This case reflects the problem identified above of how difficult it is to
wrest concessions from undefeated factions and how military reality constrains
the range of options.
The other situation of selecting interim arrangements is where one side
emerges victorious. Here again the victorious domestic faction holds the cards
254 Implications for Theory and Practice
(Tulchin and Bland 1992). Once the peace process concluded in 1994, the leftist
guerrillas initially enjoyed electoral success only at the local level and as a mi-
nority party in the legislature, through proportional representation. Given that
the former guerrilla parties only won the presidency in 2009, seventeen long
years after laying down their arms, some analysts believe that decentralization in
El Salvador was crucial to keeping the former insurgents from resuming armed
conflict (Tulchin and Bland 1992). Lyons (2002, 222) laments that too many
countries concentrate power and resources in the presidency rather than decen-
tralized systems. Because of the potential for patronage and abuse, mechanisms
of accountability and transparency at lower levels of governance are just as ur-
gent as at the national level.
To the extent that governance may be distributed at different levels above the
state, including allocating functions to the suprastate level, then dividing power
may also help prevent war recurrence. The most salient success of such measures
has been achieved in Europe. The allure of accession to the European Union not
only elicited the institutionalization of improved human rights mechanisms in
the Balkans and parts of Eastern Europe but also served as an incentive for more
inclusionary state design and behavior. The Organization of American States and
the African Union, as well as subregional African organizations, offer the most
promising avenues for the creative design of legitimate authority at the supra-
state level.
However, as indicated above, the willingness of armed factions to diffuse
power and create checks on state power may be limited. The guarantees afforded
by powersharing may be the best (or only) option for convincing armed factions
to cease their armed struggle. Similarly, electoral systems that seem to smooth
the path to stability may be necessary not just to bridge a transition but also to ex-
ist into the future in order to alleviate uncertainties in the short term. Two skep-
tics of proportional representation for its reifying effects in the long term, Reilly
and Reynolds (1999, 29–31), nevertheless acknowledge that “large-scale [pub-
lic relations] appears to be an effective instrument” for smoothing democratic
transitions. To the extent that those deciding on both interim and permanent
structures can build in mechanisms to alleviate the weaknesses of powersharing,
then all the better. South Africa, El Salvador, Liberia, and other countries have
placed sunset provisions on their powersharing mechanisms with some success
thus far. However, there have been too few cases to draw firm conclusions about
adopting interim mechanisms of powersharing that end in winner-take-all sys-
tems or decision points. For instance, once the ten-year phase before a vote on
independence takes place in Southern Sudan, armed conflict may well resume,
just as the protracted negotiations on Kosovo’s final status have not resulted in a
resolution embraced by all parties.
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 257
policy in specific functional areas of the state, such as health, education, security,
hunger response, disaster preparedness, and justice.
Before turning to some of the salient experiences and their implications for
the electoral process in transitioning to a long-term new political authority, it
is important to recall that election day itself is usually a small piece of the elec-
toral process. Because of heightened domestic scrutiny, security presence, and
international presence, violence is often much less than in the preparatory or the
postelection period. One study of electoral violence in East Timor, for instance,
showed that election day was the least violent phase of the electoral cycle, from
preparation to the campaign through to the counting and immediate postcount-
ing periods (Timor-Leste Armed Violence Assessment 2009).
As with all electoral processes, the preparation and campaign season is crucial
in whether the process will be seen as a free, fair, and accurate indicator of popu-
lar preference. The politics of that preparation, including the electoral tribunal
or commission tasked with overseeing the processing and tabulation of results,
will reflect the most divisive and serious threats to political coexistence among
the main parties. Too often, transitional governments have monopolized control
over electoral tribunals, undermining the credibility of the process, not to men-
tion the institutionalization, of open competitive elections.
nus. Third, and on the downside, elections offer the possibility of definitively
excluding losing parties. The tenure of elected officials marks a period of cer-
tainty about who shall rule, clarifying who has lost and for how long. The end of
uncertainty here offers disincentives for engagement with the political process
in the short term after elections.
Finally, elections also offer flash points for international engagement. Most
saliently, they offer external actors the chance, in the name of newfound sov-
ereignty rooted in the popular will, to defer to legitimately elected national au-
thorities by reducing their financial, troop, and other commitments. Insofar as
elections become the exit strategy for international actors, they earn the resent-
ment of many internal and external actors that believe the continued engage-
ment and resources are necessary to conclude a positive transition from war. In
addition, they offer a somewhat arbitrary, and often misleading, marker for the
end of “transitional” economic, security, political, or humanitarian processes. As
such, elections figure into timetables, often in ways that distort context-based
assessments of how well internationally supported internal processes have met
needs and expectations.
to warfare and to send a signal of commitment to the other side and to one’s
own militants that political contestation is replacing the battlefield as the locus
of struggle. International actors have sought to infuse peace agreements with this
sequencing, with a good degree of success.
Delayed elections: the Bosnian experience. A second generalization is central
to the state-building approach to peacebuilding, especially Paris’s “institutional-
ization before liberalization”: delaying national elections until the institutional
skeleton is strong enough to ensure their validity, acceptance, and translation
into effective governance. Here the Angolan experience was also informed by
that of Bosnia, where the outcome of national elections surprised international
actors by dealing a blow to their peacebuilding project.
Bosnia’s Dayton Agreement of 1995 “put the first round of elections on an
exceptionally tight schedule,” sparking heated debate (Cousens 2002, 554). It
provided for national elections within nine months of the accord, permitting but
not requiring local elections. The Bosnian experience elicited a critique of quick
elections not only for the technical difficulties but also for the security and politi-
cal problems posed by such a rushed timetable. Despite the insecurity perceived
by many voters and the technical challenges in mounting registration and bal-
loting, the elections took place in September 1996. As many feared, they served
only to legitimate the nationalist wartime leaders of their respective ethnic con-
stituencies. Elites who consented to Dayton under duress and amid warfare now
could impede its implementation with the imprimatur of being democratically
elected. The nationalist parties triumphed not just at the presidential level but
also in all three entity-level parliamentary bodies (Cousens 2002, n57). The
moderates made slight gains in four subsequent elections before winning sub-
stantial power in the 2000 elections, which opened the door to progress on more
provisions of the Dayton Agreements. Although the nationalists made gains in
the 2002 elections, the moderates once again surged in the 2006 voting.
One factor in the critique of prompt elections is the widespread perception
in the 1990s that quick timetables were driven not by context-specific factors
on the ground but by political and financial factors in Western capitals. In the
United States, which mediated the Dayton Agreements, President Bill Clinton
faced a reelection campaign in 1996 and pledged to withdraw troops by Decem-
ber. Thus the September elections became an urgent exit strategy for US troops.
Moreover, financial concerns about extended peacekeeping operations and their
costs have historically driven members of the UN Security Council to seek to
conclude operations promptly. Here again, elections became the sine qua non
not of democracy (as put by Huntington 1991, 9), but of a swift exit.
What are the problems of early elections? First and foremost, demobilization
and disarmament (or whatever degree of disarmament occurs, which is never
100 percent) require enough time to proceed. Schedules for demobilization and
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 261
This process was followed in Kosovo, but with a relatively quick sequence of
elections. Under Kosovo’s constitutional framework, municipal elections were
held in 2000, only a year after Serb forces capitulated and withdrew in June 1999,
followed by territory-wide legislative elections in 2001. These elections were
organized by the Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe under
the UN’s authority.14 The Kosovan Assembly’s 200 members are elected for a
three-year term, and half of them are elected by proportional representation and
20 are reserved for ethnic minorities, including 10 for Kosovan Serbs. Under the
framework, the Assembly names a president and prime minister, which it first did
in early 2002. Municipal elections and legislative elections have been held every
three years since then, without being interrupted by the declaration of indepen-
dence by the Assembly in February 2008. Kosovo’s Albanian community has ex-
perienced relative stability under this system that encourages a plethora of politi-
cal parties. However, the process has not satisfied the members of Serb and other
minority groups, who have been divided between participating and abstaining
from participation in elections, pending their desire for unification with Serbia.15
In East Timor, presidential elections were not seen to hold the potential
for destabilizing violence, because support for the revolutionary leadership of
Xanana Gusmao was widespread and evident. Nevertheless, elections for a con-
stituent assembly that would become a parliament preceded presidential elec-
tions. Elections of the eighty-eight-member body, seventy-five of whose seats
were by national proportional representation and the remaining in single-seat
districts, took place in August 2001, two years after Indonesia’s withdrawal.16 In
April 2002, Xanana Gusmao won 87 percent of the territory-wide direct vote
as president, the new Constitution was then finalized, and independence was
declared and internationally recognized in May 2002.
Local-level elections were also held. In 2000, a World Bank project organized
the very first electoral processes under the authority of the UN Transitional Ad-
ministration in East Timor, with the election of 6,400 hamlet-level village de-
velopment councils composed of a dozen or more men and women (equally
divided; see Ospina and Hohe 2001, chap. 4). Those councils were apart from
traditional councils of elders that had largely survived the violence. They were
given decision making over how to spend tens of thousands of dollars in grant
monies for local projects, and they operated in consultation with both the CNRT
informal administrators across the territory and the traditional elders. Then, af-
ter the first parliamentary and presidential elections, during a ten-month period
from 2004 to 2005, village (suco) leaders and councils were elected and exer-
cised control over some development resources. There were few violent inci-
dents, and these were isolated in the 2001, 2002, and 2004–5 elections, but the
parliamentary elections of 2007 resulted in two deaths, dozens wounded, and
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 263
7,000 families displaced.17 President Jose Ramos-Horta was also elected in a run-
off second-round election in 2007.
As in Kosovo, despite the swift holding of elections, analysts consider the
fact that parliamentary elections preceded presidential elections helpful in East
Timor’s political transition. Holding parliamentary elections is a way to distrib-
ute power early, to emphasize centers of power other than the presidency, and
to offer representation to multiple and minority parties. In each of these cases,
both a president and a prime minister held important executive powers, and pro-
portional representation served as the main basis for parliamentary elections to
a single chamber. Decentralization, largely at the instance of international actors,
resulted in some important gains in control over resources at the local level, fur-
ther lowering the stakes of a presidential victory. This approach seems promis-
ing for fostering legitimacy without a recurrence to warfare; however, in some
contexts, local elections could well aggravate tensions, threaten a peace process,
or spark violence.
Maneuvering to favor the “right” candidate: Liberia in 1997. One controversial
aspect of international strategies in postwar elections is their role in shaping
which candidates compete and which ones emerge victorious in postwar elec-
tions. What reasonable conclusions, rooted in past experiences, can one draw
about such an external role? From the perspective of the long-term legitimation
of elections as instruments of domestic legitimation, external interference would
seem self-defeating. This is true as it relates to a specific country and in terms of
the general utility of elections. Nothing crushes the ideals of young supporters
of self-determination and democratic processes like seeing powerful countries
manipulate such processes in ways that pervert the will of the populace, espe-
cially when they get away with it. Such external manipulation applies not just to
self-interested foreign countries (like former colonial powers) but also to inter-
national organizations that claim the mantle of neutrality and popular empower-
ment yet still favor certain candidates.
Even where a candidate may enjoy popular support, the perception that his or
her power derives from external support or endorsement may be self-defeating.
Because of the inherent contradiction discussed above, external support as an
instrument of legitimation can backfire and thus undermine internal support or
legitimacy. The American experience in Iraq exemplifies the backlash against
the leadership proposed initially by the George W. Bush administration. That
group of exiles, whose highest-profile member was the controversial Ahmed
Chalabi, enjoyed little support among Sunnis or Shiites who had endured the
regime of Saddam Hussein (Diamond 2005, 28–33). The growing resentment
during 2003 of the extended American-led occupation further eroded support
for this group.
264 Implications for Theory and Practice
At the same time, it is tempting and sometimes sensible for external actors,
whether they are states or international organizations, to seek to influence the
selection or performance of particular candidates. Most obviously, when candi-
dates widely known for their human rights abuses or atrocities run for office in
the wake of warfare, international organizations have a principled obligation to
withhold their support. The United Nations now is precluded from lending its
support for the candidacy of persons accused of war crimes, and most interna-
tional organizations now shy away from lending support to such candidates, even
where these candidates benefit from externally funded peace processes involv-
ing elections.
Nevertheless, from Cambodia to Afghanistan to Bosnia to Liberia and be-
yond, the United Nations and regional bodies have supported both transi-
tional and permanent governments that have included those implicated in war
crimes. That is because peace processes so frequently include commanders or
warlords accused of international war crimes in interim powersharing or gov-
ernance roles.18 The justification of diplomats who negotiate and support such
peace agreements is that an outright ban on dealing with thugs and human rights
violators would preclude the possibility of a cease-fire and peace. With a peace
process, the mechanisms of justice—whether domestic, third-party, or interna-
tional—can begin to function and bring abusers to account for their crimes.
Even in peace processes, international actors may have good reason to sup-
port one candidate over another. Liberia offers an example. As was discussed in
chapter 3, international actors felt compelled to support a peace agreement that
offered a chance for success after more than a dozen failures in 1996. Charles
Taylor was the leading candidate in opinion polls, and no other candidate ap-
peared to enjoy much electoral support. And yet by supporting that process,
rather than delaying elections and seeking avenues to undermine Taylor’s repu-
tation, the international community implicitly endorsed his candidacy and was
implicated in his administration after the 1997 election. Taylor’s past record and
subsequent corrupt and exclusionary rule, which led to renewed warfare, suggest
that international actors might in some circumstances want to seek to weigh in
against a candidate, especially one accused of war crimes.
Powerful countries have long sought to influence electoral processes in less
powerful countries, even as the former profess commitment to open, democratic
processes as expressions of the will of the people of the latter. Of course, how
international actors express their favoritism shapes the extent to which it is ef-
fective. Where external favoritism takes the form of recruiting candidates who
might otherwise appear reluctant, and where much of the campaign appears
overtly funded by external actors, the outcome can be the opposite of the desired
effect. This is especially true for candidates who are perceived to be solely the na-
tive tool of a military occupation, as emblemized by Russia-occupied Chechnya’s
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 265
cial institutions, and donors tend to return to a mode of treating the state as its
sole and most important partner, the legitimate voice and representative of the
territory’s entire society. The “development” moment has arrived, closing the
“peacekeeping” (and “peacebuilding”) moment for too many actors. And devel-
opment agencies and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) are loath to jeop-
ardize their good relations with the host government, which they now can em-
brace as their crucial partner and counterpart. Even where international actors
embrace development projects aimed at easing tensions between former warring
groups, at enhancing the sense of belonging of those marginalized groups, and
at dissuading the state from behaving in an exclusionary manner, the mentality
underlying the planning and consultation by external actors prioritizes the state
to the detriment of those marginalized sectors.
In postwar Sierra Leone, for instance, leaders of the opposition party ex-
pressed their surprise that after their electoral loss in 2002, international embas-
sies’ contacts and invitations to meetings dropped off precipitously. They were
left in the cold in terms not only of domestic governance but also of shaping
the views and business of the United Nations, bilateral actors, and international
NGOs. These external actors concentrated on their counterpart—the state—
and organized their strategies, planning processes, and implementation regimens
with the state, leaving the political parties that emerged from the conflict to sort
out their own relations with one another. When the opposition gained power in
the 2007 elections, its leaders felt once again besieged by the flood of attention
from international organizations.
Of course external actors confront a dicey challenge in seeking to engage op-
position or minority parties after a recognized national election has occurred.
There is no set template or protocol for international actors to maintain rela-
tions, dialogue, or involvement with opposition or minority parties. After all, the
former insurgent forces (or state armies) are no longer armies that merit atten-
tion as security threats from international forces. Instead, they have presumably
become political parties subordinating themselves to the rules of the political
regime, not above the power of the state. Elected governments are likely to be
uneasy or threatened when external actors try to involve former warring parties
or other, third parties in governance—whether in dialogue over state priorities,
budgetary questions, planning processes, sector specifics, implementation, or
the creation or modification of mechanisms for accountability and transparency.
They will quickly decry outside interference and hark back to state sovereignty.
But it is precisely in this phase when external actors must seek to retain a
peace-oriented engagement and thus prioritize the prevention of exclusion-
ary policies and practices. Speaking of postconflict societies, Peter Wallensteen
(2008, 238) argues for “long-term readiness for the international community to
remain engaged, for the benefit of democracy and peace.” As described above,
268 Implications for Theory and Practice
this is extremely challenging, especially once elected governments can claim the
mantle of sovereignty and legitimation via elections. However, there are a num-
ber of means to overcome the barriers to emphasis on legitimation via inclusion-
ary processes.
The groundwork for such a role to be played by international actors must
be laid before an election is held for a posttransition head of state. Where UN
Security Council mandates for verification and monitoring of a peace agreement
exist, an extension of this mandate through the tenure of the first elected head of
state is one means of providing the legal and political basis for continued interna-
tional verification and monitoring. Because external monitoring roles generally
offer informal leverage over the parties to the accord, some means for influencing
elite and governmental behavior persist, especially where foreign troops remain
present. The practice of extended peace operations with a gradually reduced
peacekeeping troop presence seems to have provided useful leverage to the UN
missions in Sierra Leone and Liberia, as well as to international efforts in Bosnia
and Kosovo.
In addition, a newly elected government can extend transitional powersharing
or other co-governance mechanisms past the swearing-in of a government to
continue providing voice to those who potentially could be marginalized. Such
groups may include the armed groups that did not emerge triumphant; the eth-
nic, religious, or social groups associated with those armed groups; and vulner-
able minority groups that were not represented by armed groups or in a peace
deal. The inclusion of other marginalized groups (e.g., representing women,
moderate third parties, and ethnic groups that no army claimed to represent) can
help extend horizontal legitimacy. Extended built-in consultation and voice (one
can think of them as “extended transitional” measures) may, of course, be embed-
ded in a political or electoral system in one of the powersharing mechanisms
described above. Powersharing brings the attendant benefits and limitations of
an institutionalized role for particular social groups in the state and governance.
Conversely, extended consultation mechanisms could be fashioned which
represent temporary or ad hoc arrangements that expire either on a specific date
or after certain predetermined events have occurred (e.g., the transfer of power
from one party to another). Here, I call such arrangements that extend past the
swearing-in of a nontransitional elected government “extended transitional”
measures. Rather than the result of renegotiation processes or Pierre DuToit’s
(2003) “postsettlement settlements,” these are negotiated earlier and persist
beyond elections. Because elected governments are generally reluctant to cede
power immediately after having won it at the polls, extended transitional mea-
sures are unlikely to emerge unless a prior agreement has been reached on them.
One of the most promising areas for external actors to support inclusionary
peacebuilding is in fostering such agreements before the beginning of the cam-
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 269
Civil Society
Beyond the inclusion of political parties and former insurgents, civil society or-
ganizations offer the possibility of advancing broad participation and shunting
exclusion. Here the concerns of critical peacebuilding theorists converge with a
legitimacy-focused approach that includes both elite inclusion and broader mass
inclusionary practices. Civil society is already incorporated into the formulation
of the main national economic planning document used by the World Bank,
the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper. Projects undertaken by the international
financial institutions also routinely consult with NGOs and other civil society
elements. Donors channel many of their funds through national-level NGOs,
although more pass through UN agencies and international NGOs.
However, consultation of civil society tends to be project centered and not
provide the sort of broad participation and accountability that are useful to re-
duce exclusionary governance. Haitian NGOs, for instance, complained even
after participating in consultations all over the country that their views were
largely ignored when the government and international technocrats drafted the
Interim Cooperation Framework in 2004.19 It is rare that civil society groups
are formally part of state decision making about funding priorities or about re-
source management and allocation in ways that affect specific regions and eth-
nic groups. Externally supported state reforms in specific sectors, such as justice
reform and education reform, have increasingly included civil society represen-
tatives. Yet civil society has not generally substituted for the sense of participa-
tion and ownership that comes with powersharing arrangements. Furthermore,
270 Implications for Theory and Practice
building, that will enhance efforts to build legitimacy. The first of these layers is
enhanced coherence among bilateral donors. Even the most unilateral aid efforts
engage in coordination exercises and proclaim a commitment to coordinated
development assistance. The Organization for Economic Cooperation and De-
velopment’s Development Assistance Committee (OECD-DAC) was erected by
the main donors to help coordinate and harmonize aid efforts, and to develop
and advance their conformity with broadly agreed-on standards. In the area of
postconflict countries and fragile states, the OECD-DAC has developed a good
number of standards to enhance not just coherent development efforts among its
members but also mutual accountability with the host country.20
In terms of military action, unilateral interventions or wars remain the excep-
tion rather than the norm. Most international deployments of troops are under-
taken not by a sole power but in multilateral form. For example, even the epitome
of recent “going-it-alone” wars—the US war in Iraq—involved not just the United
States but also an assortment of ancillary coalition partners. Of course, greater co-
herence within each donor country in “whole-of-government” approaches (en-
compassing development, diplomacy, defense, and more) is also important for
the coherence of external efforts.
The second “layer” of legitimacy building is the United Nations system. Most
obviously, military efforts to end (or start) wars can conform to the UN Charter’s
demand that military actions beyond self-defense must be authorized by the UN
Security Council. Although most UN member states saw the 2003 US war on
Iraq as a violation of this legally enshrined principle, the US experience in that
country seems to have ironically produced a backlash in favor of the wisdom of
this international standard. Beyond providing authorization for military inter-
ventions into unconsenting countries, the UN Security Council also approves
political missions and postconflict peacebuilding support missions. Individual
countries can coordinate their diplomacy with these missions, can provide ma-
terial support to them, and can coordinate their funding priorities in concert
with other regional actors. When elected governments tend toward exclusion-
ary policies and practices, the most influential states can help curb this behavior
by coordinating conditionality and leverage with one another, with neighboring
states, and with the senior representatives of the United Nations and other re-
gional organizations.
The third and final layer of legitimacy building is composed of regional and
subregional organizations. The most important of these bodies are the African
Union, the Organization of American States, and the European Union, but other
groups like the Association of Southeast Asian Nations and the Organization of
the Islamic Conference also have potentially important roles. Regional organi-
zations are playing an increasingly important role in peace operations, includ-
ing postconflict peacebuilding. One reason is the desire of Western powers and
272 Implications for Theory and Practice
donors to foist off the financial and diplomatic responsibilities for international
support for these processes to others, especially in Africa. The African Union’s
deployment of troops to Burundi in 2003 and 7,000 troops to Darfur by 2005
reflects this trend as well as the union’s distrust of the UN and its interest in en-
hancing its stature and impact (Bah 2009).
A factor favoring the increased activities of regional and subregional organiza-
tions is the notion that these states can provide technical civilian assistance that
is more culturally appropriate than that provided by civilian staff members from
other regions. Judicial advisers, security advisers, and advisers for institutional
capacity building and demobilization, disarmament, and reintegration programs
will be more effective if they speak common languages and share common his-
tories. In places like Africa, such regional civilian assistance will presumably cost
less than if deployed from a wide range of wealthier UN countries.
However, a more compelling reason for providing an enhanced place for
regional organizations (and subregional ones like the Economic Community
of West African States, ECOWAS; the Intergovernmental Authority on Devel-
opment; and the Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa) is the le-
gitimating function they can play. World Development Report 2011 (World Bank
2011, 288) urges “better aligning international assistance behind regional gover-
nance efforts” and thus points to the crucial legitimating role those organizations
can play. If curbing exclusionary behavior by elected governments is crucial for
peacebuilding success, then diplomatic leverage remains a key tool for discourag-
ing such behavior. The ability of Western governments to exercise this leverage
without sparking a backlash against outside interference is limited to the extent
that it smacks of either unilateralism or Western self-interest. Working with and
through the United Nations system, and its various organs and agencies, helps
mute this sort of objection. In early March 2011, the European Union and the
Obama administration both followed this approach to regional organizations’
role in legitimating international actions. In stating a position also embraced by
the United States, a European diplomat stated: “The position even of European
countries who theoretically support a no-fly zone is clear that it would require
the full support of the Arab League or African Union, and a UN Security Coun-
cil Resolution.”21
Of course, regional organizations themselves or their most influential mem-
bers are often contributors to the causes or persistence of warfare. In virtually all
the civil wars examined in this book—from the Central American wars of the
1980s to the Central African wars of the 1990s, and from the West African wars to
the Southeast Asian wars of the 2000s—meddlesome neighbors have spawned
or abetted war. Powerful regional states have a self-interested and perverse influ-
ence not only on what happens in neighboring states but also on the decisions
of regional and subregional organizations, which often act in pathological ways
Conclusions for Policy and Practice 273
(Barnett and Finnemore 2004). The dominant role of the United States in the Or-
ganization of American States and NATO, of Nigeria in ECOWAS, and of South
Africa in the Southern African Development Community emblemize this ten-
dency. Nigeria’s leadership of the Economic Community of West African States
in Liberia, for instance, was seen in the region as corrupt and advancing both the
strategic interests of Nigeria and the personal interests of the troops it deployed.
Nevertheless, nothing blunts the charges of Western interference more than
a regional or subregional organization taking the lead in diplomatic steps or even
adopting certain sanctions to lean on governments to eschew exclusionary prac-
tices. In this sense, regional and subregional organizations represent the gold
standard for the legitimate exercise of outside leverage. Regional institutions can
also embrace regional-level norms of good governance that signal the need to
conform to standards of inclusionary conduct. As the World Bank (2011, 288)
claims, “supporting regional platforms to discuss the application of governance
norms is an effective way to increase ownership.” The legitimacy given to such
measures does not ensure that they will achieve their aims, especially in Africa,
where states are notoriously reluctant to lean on one another. But it does remove
one of the principal shields behind which national governments hide when they
flout international standards of conduct: sovereignty. For these reasons, both
regional and subregional organizations are likely to play a much more salient role
in international affairs in the coming decades.
Conclusion
National-level leaders and organizations hold responsibility for making deci-
sions that can alienate and exclude salient groups from power. They can also cre-
ate state structures and adhere to them in practice so that these groups, including
potential spoilers, feel that their expectations of participation are being met. I
have offered here four different “moments” in which national leaders confront
different points in a postconflict transition to make such decisions. Many others
have written on specific aspects of these moments, including the design and con-
tent of interim administrations; the different constitutional, powersharing, and
other options in state design; strategies about the timing and systems of elections
that bring transitional periods to an end; and the postelection period that proved
so harmful for peace in Liberia, Haiti, East Timor, and other cases. In this chapter
I hope to have structured the contingent choices that confront both national and
international actors in these processes.
It is difficult for outside actors to respond to the imperative to enhance inclu-
sionary behavior and horizontal legitimacy. However, in this chapter I have set
forth some ways in which international actors can engage these processes con-
structively. Engaging processes that strengthen inclusion is more productive than
274 Implications for Theory and Practice
and ultimately a legitimate and sustainable state. Peace and good governance
depend on numerous factors, but they are likely to depend heavily on sound
judgment and sustained engagement.
Notes
1. See Krasner (2001). Even so, the international system reflected greater coher-
ence, coverage, and comparability of states in the late 1800s and early 1900s than be-
fore or after.
2. Hegre et al. (2001) found that countries experiencing regime transitions of any
sort are more inclined to civil wars than stable democracies or autocracies.
3. See Tvedten (1997, 111); also see Duke (1998); Stedman (2002), plus UN esti-
mates of 450,000 to 500,000 dead between October 1992 and December 1993, includ-
ing secondary deaths due to starvation, given by SIPRI (1994).
4. Most regimes considered among the less democratic (e.g., Cuba, North Korea,
Turkmenistan, and Burma) hold elections, and some (e.g., Uzbekistan and Iran) in-
clude multiple parties. Two potential alternatives, Chinese-style single-party open
economy and Islamic republics, may attract additional adherents.
5. NATO’s continued alliance with warlords who had overseen the worst atrocities,
along with its refusal to risk its forces to detain alleged perpetrators, assured that transi-
tional justice would be on the back burner for many months, which became many long
years (and still pending as of mid-2010). In his departure speech as special representa-
tive of the secretary-general in January 2004, Brahimi rued this decision.
6. See “Iraq Body Count,” www.iraqbodycount.org.
7. Where human rights violators are part of an agreement and interim arrangement,
external actors may also seek prosecution for atrocities, or at least exclusion of said
violators from power. Outside powers also may seek to favor one side over another in
a peace process.
8. For various perspectives on what is here called state design and its relation to war
termination, see Elazar (1994), Burton and Higley (1998), Horowitz (1985), Bermeo
(2003), and Fukuyama (2004).
9. Fukuyama (2004, 6–14) refers to this as “scope” of the state.
10. See Call (2002). For an analogous view at the interstate systemic level, see Iken-
berry (2000).
11. On the well-trodden distinction between states, regimes, and governments, see
Lawson (1993); Eagles, Holoman, and Johnston (2004); O’Donnell, Schmitter, and
Whitehead (1986); and Fishman (1990).
12. See, e.g., Kumar (1998); Lyons (2002, 2004, 2005); Ottaway and Carothers
(2000); Jarstad and Sisk (2008); Diamond (2005); Doyle and Sambanis (2006); and
Paris and Sisk (2009).
13. The elections literature also addresses technical challenges of electoral observa-
tion and monitoring, which I do not take up here.
276 Implications for Theory and Practice
14. Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe, “Kosovo Municipal Elec-
tions 2000–Final Results,” 2000. Reports from the Organization for Security and Co-
operation in Europe for municipal and assembly elections for these and other years can
be found at www.osce.org / kosovo / 13208.html.
15. See Kosovar Institute for Policy Research and Development (2009).
16. On the parliamentary process and results, see International Foundation for
Electoral Systems (2005).
17. Timor-Leste Armed Violence Assessment, “Elections Violence in Timor-Leste:
Mapping Incidents and Responses,” Issue Brief 3, June 2009.
18. Sometimes the most prominent candidates to emerge from the populace associ-
ated with the former rebels have not been military commanders but instead political
opposition figures not associated with armed action. Examples include the election of
Ibrahim Rugova as Kosovo’s first president in 2002 and Violeta Chamorro in Nicara-
gua in 1990.
19. See open letter from sixteen Haitian nongovernmental organizations, “Haitian
Civil Society Organisations’ Declaration on the Interim Cooperation Framework,”
June 14, 2004, stating that “the process of drafting the ICF is controlled by external ac-
tors with the complicity of the current government in the framework of a technocratic
approach. This excludes all real participation of the majority and vulnerable sectors of
our country” (para 1.3), www.grassrootsonline.org / node / 723.
20. See the 2005 Paris Declaration and the 2008 Accra Agenda for Action, both at
www.oecd.org / document / 18 / 0,3343,en_2649_3236398_35401554_1_1_1_1,00&
&en-USS_01DBC.html.
21. Anonymous quotation from a European “knowledgeable diplomat,” given
by James Kitfield, “The Libyan Crisis: Grounding No-Fly Talk,” National Journal,
March 10, 2011, www.cnas.org / node / 5963.
References
Adebajo, Adekeye. 2002a. Building Peace in West Africa: Liberia, Sierra Leone, and
Guinea-Bissau. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
———. 2002b. Liberia’s Civil War: Nigeria, ECOMOG, and Regional Security in West
Africa. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Alao, Abiodun, John MacKinlay, and Funmi Olonisakin. 2000. Peacekeepers, Politicians,
and Warlords: The Liberian Peace Process. Tokyo: United Nations University Press.
Alexander, Jocelyn, and JoAnn McGregor. 2004. “War Stories: Guerrilla Narratives of
Zimbabwe’s Liberation War.” History Workshop Journal 57 (1): 79–100.
Ali-Dinar, Ali B. 1999. IRIN Update 448. Abdijan: United Nations Office for the Coor-
dination of Humanitarian Affairs Integrated Regional Information Network for West
Africa. www.africa.upenn.edu / Newsletters / irinw448.html.
Alvarez, Enrique, and Tania Palencia Prado. 2002. “Guatemala’s Peace Process: Context,
Analysis and Evaluation.” Accord 13:38–43.
Anderson, G. Norman. 1999. Sudan in Crisis: The Failure of Democracy. Gainesville: Uni-
versity Press of Florida.
Arnson, Cynthia J. 2005. “The Evolution of Internal War in Peru: The Conjunction of
Need, Creed and Organizational Finance.” In Rethinking the Economics of War, edited
by Cynthia J. Arnson and I. William Zartman. Baltimore: John Hopkins University
Press.
Ashour, Omar. 2004. “Security, Oil, Internal Politics: The Causes of the Russo-Chechen
Conflicts.” Studies in Conflict and Terrorism 27 (2): 127.
Assefa, Hizkias. 1987. Mediation of Civil Wars: Approaches and Strategies—The Sudan
Conflict. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Atkins, G. Pope, and Larman Wilson. 1998. The Dominican Republic and the United States
Athens: University of Georgia Press.
Atkinson, Philippa. 1997. The War Economy in Liberia: A Political Analysis. London:
Overseas Development Institute.
Atlas, Pierre M., and Roy Licklider. 1999. “Conflict among Former Allies after Civil War
Settlement: Sudan, Zimbabwe, Chad, and Lebanon.” Journal of Peace Research 36 (1):
35–54.
Autesserre, Severine. 2010. The Trouble with the Congo: Local Violence and the Failure of
International Peacebuilding. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
278 References
Baev, Pavel K. 2005. “Chechnya and the Russian Military: A War Too Far?” In Chechnya:
From Past to Future, edited by Richard Sakwa. London: Anthem.
Baev, Pavel, Jan Koehler, and Christoph Zurcher. 2005. “Civil Wars in the Caucasus.” In
Understanding Civil War: Evidence and Analysis, Volume 2: Europe, Central Asia, and
Other Regions, edited by Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Bah, A. Sarjoh. 2009. “The Evolution of Regional and Subregional Collective Security
Mechanisms in the Post-Cold War World.” In Cooperating for Peace and Security, ed-
ited by Bruce Jones, Shepard Forman, and Richard Gowan. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Ballentine, Karen, and Jake Sherman. 2003. The Political Economy of Armed Conflict: Be-
yond Greed and Grievance. Illustrated ed. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Barnett, Michael N. 2006. “Building a Republican Peace: Stabilizing States after War.”
International Security 30:87–112.
Barnett, Michael N., and Martha Finnemore. 2004. Rules for the World: International Or-
ganizations in Global Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
BBC. 2010. “Central African Republic Timeline.” May 10. www.bbc.co.uk / news /
world-africa-13150044.
Beauvais, Joel C. 2000. “Benevolent Despotism: A Critique of U.N. State-Building in
East Timor.” New York University Journal of International Law and Politics 33:1101.
Beidas, Sandra, Colin Granderson, and Rachel Neild. 2007. “Haiti.” In Constructing Jus-
tice and Security after War, edited by Charles T. Call. Washington, DC: US Institute of
Peace Press.
Benjaminsen, Tor A. 2008. “Does Supply-Induced Scarcity Drive Violent Conflicts in
the African Sahel? The Case of the Tuareg Rebellion in Northern Mali.” Journal of
Peace Research 45 (6): 819–36.
Bennett, Andrew. 2008. “Building Communities, Bridging Gaps: Alexander George’s
Contributions to Research Methods.” Political Psychology 29 (4): 489–507.
Berdal, Mats. 2009. Building Peace after War. London: Routledge.
Berdal, Mats, and Richard Caplan. 2004. “The Politics of International Administration.”
Global Governance 10:1.
Bergquist, Charles W., Ricardo Peñaranda, and Gonzalo Sánchez G., eds. 1992. Violence
in Colombia: The Contemporary Crisis in Historical Perspective. Wilmington, DE: SR
Books.
Bermeo, Nancy. 2003. “What the Democratization Literature Says, and Doesn’t Say,
about Post-War Democratization.” Global Governance 9 (2): 159–77.
Bhebe, Ngwabi, and Terrence Ranger, eds. 1995. Soldiers in Zimbabwe’s Liberation War.
London: James Currey.
Binningsbø, Helga Malmin. 2006. “Consociational Democracy and Postconflict Peace:
Will Power-Sharing Institutions Increase the Probability of Lasting Peace after Civil
War?” Paper presented at annual meeting of International Studies Association, Town
and Country Resort and Convention Center, San Diego, March.
References 279
Bjornlund, Eric, Glenn Cowan, and William Gallery. 2006. “Elections Systems and Par-
ties.” In Governance in Post-Conflict Societies: Rebuilding Fragile States, edited by Der-
ick W. Brinkeroff. London: Routledge.
Booth, John A. 1985. The End and the Beginning: The Nicaraguan Revolution. Boulder,
CO: Westview Press.
Boutros Ghali, Boutros. 1992. An Agenda for Peace. New York: United Nations.
Bowers, Stephen. 1994. “Tibet since Mao Zedong.” Journal of Social, Political, and Eco-
nomic Studies 19 (4): 409.
Bowles, Edith, and Tanja Chopra. 2008. “East Timor: Statebuilding Revisited.” In Build-
ing States to Build Peace, edited by Charles T. Call with Vanessa Wyeth. Boulder, CO:
Lynne Rienner.
Brabazon, James. 2003. Liberia: Liberians United for Reconciliation and Democracy. Lon-
don: Royal Institute of International Affairs, www.chathamhouse.org / publications /
papers / view / 107611.
Brahimi, Lakhdar. 2007. “State Building in Crisis and Post-Conflict Countries.” http: //
unpan1.un.org / intradoc / groups / public / documents / un / unpan026305.pdf.
Briceño, Franklin. 2010. “Ex-Peru Rebels, Out of Prison, Run for Elected Office.” San
Francisco Examiner, September 30.
Brinkerhoff, Derick W., ed. 2007. Governance in Post-Conflict Societies: Rebuilding Fragile
States. London: Routledge.
Bromley, Mark. 2007. UN Arms Embargoes, Their Impact on Arms Flows and Target Behav-
ior: Case Study Haiti 1993–94. Stockholm: Stockholm Peace and Research Institute.
Brown, Timothy C. 2001. The Real Contra War, Highlander Peasant Resistance in Nicara-
gua. Oklahoma City: University of Oklahoma Press.
Brubaker, Rogers, and David Laitin. 1998. “Ethnic and Nationalist Violence.” Annual Re-
view of Sociology 24:423–52.
Bull, Hedley. 1977. The Anarchical Society: A Study of Order in World Politics. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Burton, Michael, and John Higley. 1998. “Political Crises and Elite Settlements.” In Elites,
Crises, and the Origins of Regimes, edited by Mattei Dogan and John Higley. Lanham,
MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
Call, Charles T. 1995. “The U.S. Military.” In U.S.–Latin American Policymaking: A Refer-
ence Handbook, edited by David W. Dent.
———. 1999. “From Soldiers to Cops: ‘War Transitions’ and the Demilitarization of
Public Security in Latin America and the Caribbean.” PhD diss., Stanford University.
———. 2002. “War Transitions and the New Civilian Security in Latin America.” Com-
parative Politics 35 (1).
———, ed., with Vanessa Wyeth. 2008a. Building States to Build Peace. Boulder, CO:
Lynne Rienner.
———. 2008b. “The Fallacy of the ‘Failed State.’” Third World Quarterly 29:1491–1507.
———. 2008c. “Knowing Peace When You See It: Setting Standards for Peacebuilding
Success.” Civil Wars 10 (2): 173–94.
280 References
———. 2011. “Beyond the Failed State: Some Conceptual Alternatives.” European Jour-
nal of International Relations 17 (2): 302–26.
Call, Charles T., and Susan E. Cook. 2003. “On Democracy and Peacebuilding.” Global
Governance 9 (2).
Call, Charles T., and Elizabeth Cousens. 2008. “Ending Wars and Building Peace.” Inter-
national Studies Perspectives 9 (1): 1–21.
Call, Charles T., and John Schmitt. 2009. “Why Peace Fails: Explaining Civil War Re-
currence.” Paper presented at annual conference of International Studies Association,
New York.
Campbell, Leon G. 1973. “The Historiography of the Peruvian Guerrilla Movement,
1960–1965.” Latin American Research Review 8 (1): 45–70.
Caplan, Richard. 2004a. “International Authority and State Building: The Case of Bos-
nia and Herzegovina.” Global Governance 10:53.
———. 2004b. “Partner or Patron? International Civil Administration and Local
Capacity-Building.” International Peacekeeping 11 (2): 229–47.
———. 2005. International Governance of War-Torn Territories. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sity Press.
Carothers, Thomas. 1999. Aiding Democracy Abroad. Washington, DC: Carnegie En-
dowment for International Peace.
———. 2006. “The Backlash against Democracy Promotion.” Foreign Affairs 85 (March–
April): 55–68.
———. 2009. “Democracy Assistance: Political versus Developmental.” Journal of De-
mocracy 20 (1): 5–19.
Catholic Commission for Justice and Peace in Zimbabwe. 1997. Report on the 1980s Dis-
turbances in Matabeland and the Midlands. Harare: Catholic Commission for Justice
and Peace in Zimbabwe.
Cederman, Lars-Erik, and Kristian Skrede Gleditsch. 2009. “Introduction to Special
Issue on ‘Disaggregating Civil Wars.’ ” Journal of Conflict Resolution 53 (4): 487–95.
Chandler, David. 2006. Empire in Denial: The Politics of State-Building. London: Pluto.
Chandra, Kanchan, and Steven Wilkinson. 2008. “Measuring the Effect of ‘Ethnicity.’”
Comparative Political Studies 41:515–63.
Chatterjee, Partha. 1993. The Nation and Its Fragments: Colonial and Postcolonial Histories.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Chesterman, Simon. 2001. Kosovo in Limbo: Statebuilding and “Substantial Autonomy”.
New York: Transitional Administrations Project at International Peace Institute. www
.ipinst.org / media / pdf / publications / kosovo_in_limbo.pdf.
———. 2002a. “Ownership in Theory and in Practice: Transfer of Authority in UN
Statebuilding Operations.” Journal of Intervention and Statebuilding 1 (1): 3–26.
———. 2002b. “Walking Softly in Afghanistan: The Future of UN State-Building.” Sur-
vival 44 (3): 37–45.
———. 2004. You, the People: The United Nations, Transitional Administration, and State-
Building. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
References 281
———. 2004. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War.” Oxford Economic Papers 56:563–95.
———. 2006. “Military Expenditure in Post-Conflict Societies.” Economics of Gover-
nance 7 (1): 89–107.
Collier, Paul, Anke Hoeffler, and Måns Söderbom. 2006a. Aid, Policies and Risks in Post-
Conflict Societies. Working paper for Oxford Centre for the Study of African Econo-
mies. Oxford: Oxford University.
———. 2006b. Post-Conflict Societies. Working paper for the Oxford Centre for the
Study of African Economies. Oxford: Oxford University.
Collier, Paul, V. L. Elliott, Håvard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol, and
Nicholas Sambanis. 2003. Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development
Policy. Washington, DC: World Bank. www-wds.worldbank .org / external / default /
WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB/2003/06/30/000094946_0306190405396/Rendered/
PDF / multi0page.pdf.
Cook, Nicholas. 2003. Liberia: 1989–1997 Civil War, Post-War Developments, and US
Relations. Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.
———. 2004. Liberia: Transition to Peace. Washington, DC: Congressional Research
Service.
Cornell, Svante E. 2001. Small Nations and Great Powers: A Study of Ethnopolitical Conflict
in the Caucasus. London: Curzon.
Cousens, Elizabeth. 2002. “From Missed Opportunities to Overcompensation: Imple-
menting the Dayton Agreement on Bosnia.” In Ending Civil Wars: The Implementation
of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, Donald S. Rothchild, and Eliza-
beth M. Cousens. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Cox, Marcus. 2008. “Bosnia and Herzegovina: The Limits of Liberal Imperialism.”
In Building States to Build Peace, edited by Charles T. Call. Boulder, CO: Lynne
Rienner.
Craig, Dylan. 2011. “The Wars in the Walls: Sovereign Interstices and African Conflict.”
Paper presented at International Studies Association conference, Montreal, March.
Curtis, Glenn E., ed. 1995. Armenia, Azerbaijan, and Georgia. Washington, DC: Federal
Research Division, Library of Congress.
Cvetkovski, Nikola. 2001. The Georgian–South Ossetian Conflict. Copenhagen: Danish
Association for Research on the Caucasus. www.caucasus.dk / publication5.htm.
DAC-OECD (Development Assistance Committee of Organization for Economic Co-
operation and Development). 2007. Principles for Good International Engagement in
Fragile States and Situations. Paris: OECD.
Dailey, Peter. 2003. “Haiti: The Fall of the House of Aristide.” New York Review of Books
50 (4).
———. 2004. “Who Got Rid of Aristide?” Letter printed in London Review of Books,
May 20.
Daly, M. W. 1993. “Broken Bridge and Empty Basket: The Political and Economic Back-
ground of the Sudanese Civil War.” In Civil War in the Sudan, edited by M. W. Daly and
Ahmad Alawad Sikainga. London: British Academic Press.
References 283
Dunlop, John B. 1998. Russia Confronts Chechnya: Roots of a Separatist Conflict. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dunning, Thad. 2005. “Resource Dependence, Economic Performance, and Political
Stability.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49:451–82.
Dupuy, Alex. 2007. The Prophet and Power: Jean-Bertrand Aristide, the International Com-
munity, and Haiti. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
———. 2009. “Indefensible: On Aristide, Violence, and Democracy.” Small Axe 13 (3):
161–73.
Dupuy, Kendra, and Helga Malmin Binningsbø. 2008. Power-Sharing and Peace-
Building in Sierra Leone: Power-Sharing Agreements, Negotiations and Peace Processes.
Oslo: Peace Research Institute Oslo / Centre for the Study of Civil War. www.prio
.no / sptrans / -42188479 / Sierra_Leone_full_report.pdf.
Dupuy, Kendra, and Julian Detzel. 2007. Peace-Building and Powersharing in Liberia.
Oslo: Centre for the Study of Civil War.
Durch, William J., ed. 1996. UN Peacekeeping, American Politics, and the Uncivil Wars of
the 1990s. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
———. 2006. Twenty-First-Century Peacekeeping Operations. Washington, DC: US In-
stitute of Peace Press.
DuToit, Pierre. 2003. “Why Post- Settlement Settlements?” Journal of Democracy 14
(3):104–18.
Eagles, Munroe, Christopher Holoman, and Larry Johnston. 2004. Politics, Introduction
to Democratic Government, 2nd ed. Peterborough, Ont.: Broadview.
Eckstein, Harry. 1975. “Case Study and Theory in Political Science.” In Handbook of Po-
litical Science, edited by Fred Greenstein and Neslon Polsby. Reading, MA: Addison-
Wesley.
Elazar, Daniel J. 1994. Federalism and the Way to Peace. Kingston, Ont.: Institute of Inter-
governmental Relations.
Elkins, Zachary, and John Sides. 2007. “Can Institutions Build Unity in Multi-Ethnic
States?” American Political Science Review 101:693–708.
Elliott, Paul D. 1978. “The East Timor Dispute.” International and Comparative Law
Quarterly 27 (1): 238–49.
Ellis, Stephen. 2001. The Mask of Anarchy: The Destruction of Liberia and the Religious
Dimension of an African Civil War. New York: New York University Press.
Englebert, Pierre. 2000. State Legitimacy and Development in Africa. Boulder, CO: Lynne
Rienner.
Esty, Daniel C., Jack A. Goldstone, Ted Robert Gurr, Pamela T. Surko, and Alan N. Unger.
1995. “Working Papers: State Failure Task Force Report.” Prepared on contract for the
US Central Intelligence Agency’s Directorate of Intelligence.
Evangelista, Matthew. 2002. The Chechen Wars: Could Russia Go the Way of the Soviet
Union? Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Eziakonwa, Ahunna. 1998. “Donors Back Liberia’s Reconstruction.” Africa Recovery 12.
Farmer, Paul. 2004. “Who Removed Aristide?” London Review of Books 26 (8): 28–31.
References 285
Fasano, Ugo. 2009. “Haiti’s Economic Development since 2004 / 05 and Macroeco-
nomic Outlook.” PowerPoint presentation by former resident representative for In-
ternational Monetary Fund, Port-au-Prince, July 1.
Fatton, Robert. 2002. Haiti’s Predatory Republic: The Unending Transition to Democracy.
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Fayemi, J. ‘Kayode. 2004. “Governing Insecurity in Post-Conflict States: The Case of
Sierra Leone and Liberia.” In Reform and Reconstruction of the Security Sector, edited by
Alan Bryden and Heiner Hänggi. Geneva: Geneva Center for the Democratic Control
of Armed Forces.
Fearon, James D. 1998. “Commitment Problems and the Spread of Ethnic Conflict.” In
The International Spread of Ethnic Conflict, edited by David Lake and Donald Roth-
child. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 2005. “Primary Commodity Exports and Civil War.” Journal of Conflict Resolu-
tion 49:483–507.
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. 2003. “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War.”
American Political Science Review 97:75–90.
Feigon, Lee. 1996. Demystifying Tibet. Chicago: Ivan R. Dee.
Fishman, Robert M. 1990. “Rethinking State and Regime: Southern Europe’s Transition
to Democracy.” World Politics 42 (3): 422–40.
Forman, Shepard. 2005. “Working Better Together: Implementing the High Level Pan-
el’s Recommendations on Peacebuilding.” Presentation at conference on “New Multi-
lateralism” sponsored by L20 Forum, Brussels, May 12.
Fortna, Virginia Page. 2004a. Peace Time: Cease-Fire Agreements and the Durability of
Peace. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 2004b. “Where Have All the Victories Gone?” Paper presented at conference on
order, conflict and violence, Yale University, New Haven, CT, April.
———. 2008. Does Peacekeeping Work? Shaping Belligerents’ Choices after Civil War.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Fox, Richard G., and Orin Starn, eds. 1997. Between Resistance and Revolution: Cultural
Politics and Social Protest. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.
Fukuyama, Francis. 2004. State-Building: Governance and World Order in the 21st Century.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Fumerton, Mario. 2003. From Victims to Heroes: Peasant Counter-Rebellion and Civil War
in Ayacucho, Peru, 1980–2000. West Lafayette, IN: Purdue University Press.
Gagnon, V. P. 1994. “Ethnic Nationalism and International Conflict: The Case of Serbia.”
International Security 19 (3): 130–66.
Gale Group. 2008. “Hutu and Tutsi of Burundi.” In The World Directory of Minori-
ties. www.faqs .org / minorities / Sub- Saharan-Africa / Hutu-and-Tutsi-of-Burundi
.html.
Gall, Carlotta, and Thomas de Waal. 1998. Chechnya: Calamity in the Caucasus. New
York: New York University Press.
Galtung, Johan. 1964. “An Editorial.” Journal of Peace Research 1 (1).
286 References
Gates, Scott, and Kaare Strøm. 2007. Power-sharing, Agency and Civil Conflict: Power-
sharing Agreements, Negotiations and Peace Processes. Centre for the Study of Civil Wars
Policy Brief. Oslo: Peace Research Institute Olso.
Geertz, Clifford. 1963. Old Societies and New States: The Quest for Modernity in Asia and
Africa. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Gellner, Ernest. 1991. “Nationalism and Politics in Eastern Europe.” New Left Review
189:127–43.
George, Alexander, and Andrew Bennett, 2005. Case Studies and Theory Development in
the Social Sciences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
German, Tracey. 2003. Russia’s Chechen War. New York: Routledge.
Ghani, Ashraf, and Clare Lockhart. 2008. Fixing Failed States: A Framework for Rebuilding
a Fractured World. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ghani, Ashraf, Clare Lockhart, and Michael Carnahan. 2005. Closing the Sovereignty
Gap: An Approach to State-Building. London: Overseas Development Institute.
Gleason, Gregory. 2001. “Power Sharing in Tajikistan: Political Compromise and Re-
gional Instability.” Conflict, Security & Development 1:125.
Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede, and Andrea Ruggeri. 2010. “Political Opportunity Structures,
Democracy, and Civil War.” Journal of Peace Research 47 (3): 299–310.
Goldsmith, Andrew. 2009. “‘It Wasn’t Like Normal Policing’: Voices of Australian Po-
lice Peacekeepers in Operation Serene, Timor-Leste 2006.” Policing & Society 19 (2):
119–33.
Goldstein, Melvyn C. 2007. A History of Modern Tibet, 1951–1955: The Calm before the
Storm. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Goldstone, Anthony. 2004. “UNTAET with Hindsight: The Peculiarities of Politics in
an Incomplete State.” Global Governance 10 (1): 83–98.
Gorjao, Paolo. 2008. “UNMISET’s Hasty Replacement by UNOTIL in East Timor.”
www.etan.org / et2005 / may / 08 / 00unmiset.htm.
Gorriti, Gustavo. 1999. The Shining Path: A History of the Millenarian War in Peru. Chapel
Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Orig. pub. in Spanish in 1990.
Greenfeld, Liah. 1992. Nationalism: Five Roads to Modernity. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Grunfeld, A. Tom. 1996. The Making of Modern Tibet. Armonk, NY: East Gate Books.
Gurr, Ted Robert. 1970. Why Men Rebel. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 1993. Minorities at Risk. Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.
———. 2000. Peoples versus States: Minorities at Risk in the New Century. Washington,
DC: US Institute of Peace Press.
Gurses, Mehmet, Nicolas Rost, and Patrick McLeod. 2008. “Mediating Civil War Settle-
ments and the Duration of Peace.” International Interactions 34 (2): 129–55.
Hagopian, Frances. 1991. “Democracy by Undemocratic Means? Elites, Political Pacts,
and Regime Transition in Brazil.” Comparative Political Studies 23 (2): 147–70.
Hampson, Fen Osler. 1996. Nurturing Peace: Why Peace Settlements Succeed or Fail. Wash-
ington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.
References 287
Harbom, Lotta, Stina Högbladh, and Peter Wallentsteen. 2006. “Armed Conflict and
Peace Agreements.” Journal of Peace Research 43 (5): 617–31.
Harrington, Andrew. 2007. “Ethnicity, Violence and Land and Property Disputes in East
Timor.” East Timor Law Journal 4 (1).
Hartlyn, Jonathan. 1988. The Politics of Coalition Rule in Colombia. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Hartzell, Caroline, and Matthew Hoddie. 2003. “Institutionalizing Peace: Power Shar-
ing and Post–Civil War Conflict Management.” American Journal of Political Science
47:318–32.
———. 2007. Crafting Peace: Power-Sharing Institutions and the Negotiated Settlement of
Civil Wars. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.
———. 2010. “Economic Liberalization via IMF Structural Adjustment: Sowing the
Seeds of Civil War?” International Organization 64:339–56.
Havermans, Jos. 2000. “Central African Republic: Ethnic Strife in a Democratic Setting.”
www.conflict-prevention.net/page.php?id=40&formid=73&action=show&surveyid=61.
Hegre, Håvard, Tanja Ellingsen, Scott Gates, and Nils Petter Gleditsch. 2001. “Toward
a Democratic Civil Peace? Democracy, Political Change, and Civil War, 1816–1992.”
American Political Science Review 95 (1): 33–48.
Hegre, Håvard, and Nicholas Sambanis. 2004. “Sensitivity Analysis of the Empirical Lit-
erature on Civil War Onset.” Paper presented at meeting of Polarization and Conflict
Network, Voksenåsen, Oslo, July 2–4.
Henderson, Errol, and Singer, J. David. 2000. “Civil War in the Postcolonial World,
1946–92.” Journal of Peace Research 37 (3): 275–99.
Herbst, Jeffrey. 2000. States and Power in Africa. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Herz, Monica. 2008. Does the Organisation of American States Matter? Crisis States Work-
ing Paper Series 2, no. 34. London: Crisis States Research Centre.
Hill, Fiona. 1995. Russia’s Tinderbox: Conflict in the North Caucasus and Its Implications for
the Future of the Russian Federation. Report for the Strengthening Democratic Institu-
tions Project. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Hoadley, J. Stephen. 1975. The Future of Portuguese Timor: Dilemmas and Opportunities.
Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Hoddie, Matthew, and Caroline Hartzell. 2005. “Power Sharing in Peace Agreements.”
In Sustainable Peace: Power and Democracy after Civil Wars, edited by Philip G. Roeder
and Donald Rothchild. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Hoffman, David. 2000. “Miscalculations Paved Path to Chechen War.” Washington Post,
March 20.
Hohe, Tanja. 2002. “The Clash of Paradigms: International Administration and
Local Political Legitimacy in East Timor.” Contemporary Southeast Asia 24 (3):
569–89.
Holsti, Kalevi J. 1996. The State, War, and the State of War. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press.
288 References
International Crisis Group. 2002. Liberia: The Key to Ending Regional Instability. Wash-
ington, DC: International Crisis Group.
———. 2004. Georgia: Avoiding War in South Ossetia. Europe Report 59. Brussels: In-
ternational Crisis Group.
———. 2006a. Managing Tensions on the Timor Leste / Indonesian Border. Asia Briefing
50. Brussels: International Crisis Group.
International Foundation for Electoral Systems. 2005. “Electoral System for East Timor.”
www.electionguide.org / country.php?ID=63.
International Monetary Fund. 2010. World Economic Outlook Database, September 2011.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
IRBC (Immigration and Refugee Board of Canada). 2001. “Liberia: Madison Wion
and Treatment of His Relatives by Liberian Authorities.” www.unhcr.org / refworld /
docid / 3df4be5d20.html.
IRIN. 2004. “Liberia: LURD Leader Drops Demand for Bryant to Go.” http: // www
.irinnews.org / report.aspx?reportid=48466.
Itano, Nicole. 2003. Liberating Liberia: Charles Taylor and the Rebels Who Unseated Him.
ISS Paper 82. Johannesburg: Institute for Security Studies.
Iyob, Ruth, and Gilbert Khadiagala. 2006. Sudan: The Elusive Quest for Peace. Boulder,
CO: Lynne Rienner.
Jackson, Robert H. 1990. Quasi-States, Sovereignty, International Relations, and the Third
World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jackson, Robert H., and Carl G. Rosberg. 1986. “Sovereignty and Underdevelopment: Ju-
ridical Statehood in the African Crisis.” Journal of Modern African Studies 24 (1): 1–31.
Jardine, Matthew, and Constancio Pinto. 1997. East Timor’s Unfinished Struggle. Boston:
South End Press.
Jarstad, Anna. 2008. “Post-Accord Elections, Power Sharing and Conflict.” Paper presented
at 49th Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, San Francisco.
———. 2009. “The Prevaslence of Power- Sharing: Exploring the Patterns of Post-
Election Peace.” Africa Spectrum 44 (3): 41–62.
Jarstad, Anna, and Timothy Sisk. 2008. From War to Democracy: Dilemmas of Peacebuild-
ing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jean, François. 2000. “Chechnya: Moscow’s Revenge.” Harvard International Review 22
(3): 16–21.
Johnson, Chris, William Maley, Alex Their, and Ali Wardak. 2003. “Afghanistan’s Politi-
cal and Constitutional Development.” Report for UK Department for International
Development and Humanitarian Policy Group at Overseas Development Institute,
London.
Johnson, Douglas H., and Gerard Prunier. 1993. “The Foundation and Expansion of the
Sudan People’s Liberation Army.” In Civil War in the Sudan, edited by M. W. Daly and
Ahmad Alawad Sikainga. London: British Academic Press.
Jones, Bruce, Rahul Chandran, Elizabeth Cousens, Jenna Slotin, and Jake Sherman.
2008. Concepts and Dilemmas in State Building in Fragile Situations. Report based on
290 References
Krueger, Robert, and Kathleen T. Krueger. 2007. From Bloodshed to Hope in Burundi: Our
Embassy Years during Genocide. Austin: University of Texas Press.
Kumar, Krishna. ed. 1998. Postconflict Elections, Democratization and International Assis-
tance. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Kumar, Krishna, and Marina Ottaway. 1998. “General Conclusions and Priorities for
Policy Research.” In Postconflict Elections, Democratization and International Assistance,
edited by Krishna Kumar. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Lawson, Stephanie. 1993. “Conceptual Issues in the Comparative Study of Regime
Change and Democratization.” Comparative Politics 25 (2): 183–206.
Lawyers Committee for Human Rights. 1986. Zimbabwe: Wages of War. New York: Law-
yers Committee for Human Rights.
Layne, Christopher. 1994. “Kant or Cant: The Myth of the Democratic Peace.” Interna-
tional Security 19 (2): 5–49.
Lemarchand, René. 1975. “Ethnic Genocide.” Issue: A Journal of Opinion 5 (2): 9–16.
———. 1994. “Managing Transition Anarchies: Rwanda, Burundi, and South Africa in
Comparative Perspective.” Journal of Modern African Studies 32 (4): 581–604.
———. 2004. “Exclusion, Marginalization and Political Mobilization: The Road to Hell
in the Great Lakes.” In Facing Ethnic Conflicts: Toward a New Realism, edited by An-
dreas Wimmer, Richard J. Goldstone, Donald Horowitz, Ulrike Joras, and Conrad
Schetter. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
———. 2008. “The Killings of 1972.” In Online Encyclopedia of Mass Violence. Paris:
SciencesPo.
LeVan, Carl. 2011. “Power Sharing and Inclusive Politics in Africa’s Uncertain Democra-
cies.” Governance 24 (1).
Levitas, Ruth. 2005. The Inclusive Society?: Social Exclusion and New Labour, 2nd ed. New
York: Palgrave.
Licklider, Roy. 1995. “The Consequences of Negotiated Settlements in Civil Wars,
1945–1993.” American Political Science Review 89:681–90.
Lieven, Anatol. 1998. Chechnya: Tombstone of Russian Power. New Haven, CT: Yale Uni-
versity Press.
Lijphart, Arend. 1977. Democracy in Plural Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press.
Longmire, Sylvia. 2009. “Peru: Controversy over Potential for Shining Path Terror-
ists to Participate in Elections.” South American Policy Examiner, October 28. www
.examiner.com/south-america-policy-in-national/peru-controversy-over-potential-for
-shining-path-terrorists-to-participate-elections.
LURD (Liberians United for Reconciliation and Democracy). 2002. “Blue Print for Sta-
bility in Liberia.” The Perspective, October 4. www.theperspective.org / lurdblueprint
.html.
Lynch, Dov. 2004. Engaging Eurasia’s Separatist States: Unresolved Conflicts and De Facto
States. Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.
———. 2005. “New Thinking about Frozen Conflicts.” Helsinki Monitor 16 (3).
292 References
Lynch, Marika. 2003. “Haiti’s Ex-Chief of Police Cites Corruption.” Miami Herald,
June 28.
Lyons, Terrence. 1998. “Peace and Elections in Liberia.” In Postconflict Elections, Democ-
ratization, and International Assistance, edited by Krishna Kumar. Boulder, CO: Lynne
Rienner.
———. 2002. “The Role of Postsettlement Elections.” In Ending Civil Wars: The Imple-
mentation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, Donald Rothchild,
and Elizabeth M. Cousens. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
———. 2004. “Post-Conflict Elections and the Process of Demilitarizing Politics: The
Role of Electoral Administration.” Democratization 11 (3): 36–62.
———. 2005. Demilitarizing Politics: Elections on the Uncertain Road to Peace. Boulder,
CO: Lynne Rienner.
———. 2006. “Diasporas and Homeland Conflict” In Globalization, Territoriality, and
Conflict in an Era of Globalization, edited by Miles Kahler and Barbara Walter. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Maguire, Robert E. 1995. “Defanging the Predatory State.” Hemisphere 7 (1):14–16.
Mahdavy, Hossein. 1970. “The Patterns and Problems of Economic Development in
Rentier States: The Case of Iran.” In Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East:
From the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, edited by M. A. Cook. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Mainwaring, Scott, Guillermo O’Donnell, and J. Samuel Valenzuela. 1992. Issues in Dem-
ocratic Consolidation: The New South American Democracies in Comparative Perspective.
Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press.
Makdisi, Samir, and Richard Sadaka. 2005. “The Lebanese Civil War, 1975–90.” In Un-
derstanding Civil War: Evidence and Analysis, vol. 2, edited by Paul Collier and Nicholas
Sambanis. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Malan, Mark. 2008. Security Sector Reform in Liberia. Carlisle Barracks, PA: Strategic Stud-
ies Institute, US Army War College. www.strategicstudiesinstitute.army.mil / pdffiles /
pub855.pdf.
Malone, David. 1998. Decision-Making in the UN Security Council: The Case of Haiti. Ox-
ford: Clarendon Press.
Mamdani, Mahmoud. 1996. Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy of
Late Colonialism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 2001. When Victims Become Killers: Colonialism, Nativism and the Genocide in
Rwanda. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 2002. When Victims Become Killers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Mann, Michael. 1993. The Sources of Social Power, Volume II: The Rise of Classes and
Nation-States, 1760–1914. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mansfield, Edward, and Jack Snyder. 2005. Electing to Fight: Why Emerging Democracies
Go to War. Cambridge: Belfer Center for International Science and Affairs.
Maoz, Z., and N. Abdolali. 1989. “Regime Types and International Conflict, 1816–1976.”
Journal of Conflict Resolution 33:3–35.
References 293
Maríñez, Pablo A. 1990. “El proceso electoral dominicano: difícil camino hacia la de-
mocracia.” Secuencia 18:57–82.
Martin, Ian, and Alexander Mayer-Rieckh. 2005. “The United Nations and East Timor:
From Self-Determination to State-Building.” International Peacekeeping 12 (1):
125–45.
Martinetti, Irene. 2007. “The Peacebuilding Commission: A Year in Review.” Center for
UN Reform Education. www.globalpolicy.org / component / content / article / 228 /
32578.html.
McClintock, Cynthia. 1998. Revolutionary Movements in Latin America: El Salvador’s
FMLN and Peru’s Shining Path. Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.
McFaul, Michael. 2004. “Democracy Promotion as a World Value.” Washington Quarterly
28 (1): 147–63.
McGarry, John, and Breandan O’Leary. 2003. The Politics of Conflict Regulation. London:
Routledge.
———. 2004. The Northern Ireland Conflict: Consociational Engagement. London: Ox-
ford University Press.
Meyer, John W., John Boli, George M. Thomas, and Francisco O. Ramirez. 1997. “World
Society and the Nation-State.” American Journal of Sociology 103 (1): 144–81.
Milante, Gary, and Stergios Skaperdas. 2009. “Powersharing under the Threat of Con-
flict.” http: // siteresources.worldbank .org / INTCONFLICT / Resources / Milante
Skaperdas090517.pdf.
Minahan, James. 1996. Nations without States: A Historical Dictionary of Contemporary
National Movements. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.
Mitchell, Christopher R. 1989. Conflict Resolution and Civil War: Reflections on the Su-
danese Settlement of 1972. Working Paper 3 Fairfax, VA: Center for Conflict Analysis
and Resolution, George Mason University. http: // icar.gmu.edu / wp_3_mitchell.pdf.
Mitchell, Paul, Geoffrey Evans, and Brendan O’Leary. 2009. “Extremist Outbidding in
Ethnic Party Systems Is Not Inevitable: Tribune Parties in Northern Ireland.” Political
Studies 57 (2): 397–421.
Moxham, Ben. 2008. State Making and the Post-Conflict City: Integration in Dili, Disinte-
gration in Timor-Leste. Crisis States Working Paper Series 2, no. 32. London: Crisis
States Research Centre.
Mukherjee, Bumba. 2006. “Why Political Power- Sharing Agreements Lead to Endur-
ing Peaceful Resolution of Some Civil Wars, But Not Others.” International Studies
Quarterly 50 (2): 479–504.
Murithi, Tim. 2008. “Peacebuilding or ‘UN-Building’? African Institutional Responses
to the Peacebuilding Commission.” Journal of Peacebuilding and Development 4 (2):
89–94.
Ndikumana, Léonce. 1998. “Institutional Failure and Ethnic Conflicts in Burundi.” Afri-
can Studies Review 41 (1): 29–47.
Newman, Edward, Roland Paris, and Oliver P. Richmond, eds. 2009. New Perspectives on
Liberal Peacebuilding. Tokyo: United Nations University Press.
294 References
Nilsson, Desirée. 2008. “Partial Peace: Rebel Groups Inside and Outside of Civil War
Settlements.” Journal of Peace Research 45 (4): 479–95.
Niner, Sarah. 2001. “A Long Journey of Resistance: The Origins and Struggle of CNRT.”
In Bitter Flowers, Sweet Flowers: East Timor, Indonesia, and the World Community, edited
by Richard Tanter, Mark Selden, Stephen R. Shalom. London: Pluto Press.
Nixon, Hamish, and Richard Ponzio. 2007. “Building Democracy in Afghanistan: The
Statebuilding Agenda and International Engagement.” International Peacekeeping 14
(1): 26–40.
Norris, Pippa. 2008. Driving Democracy: Do Power-Sharing Institutions Work? Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W. W.
Norton.
Norton, Augustus Richard, 1991. “Lebanon after Ta’if: Is the Civil War Over?” Middle
East Journal 40 (3): 457–73.
OAS (Organization of American States). 2000. “Chief of Mission Report to the OAS
Permanent Council.” July 13, Washington, DC.
O’Ballance, Edgar. 2000. Sudan, Civil War, and Terrorism. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
O’Donnell, Guillermo, Philippe C. Schmitter, and and Laurence Whitehead. 1986. Tran-
sitions from Authoritarian Rule. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Ohlson, Thomas, and Stephen John Stedman. 1994. The New Is Not Yet Born: Conflict
Resolution in Southern Africa. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Olonisakin, Funmi. 2007. Peacekeeping in Sierra Leone: The Story of Unamsil. Boulder,
CO: Lynne Rienner.
Oquist, Paul H. 1980. Violence, Conflict, and Politics in Columbia. New York: Academic
Press.
Orleans, Leo A. 1966. “A Note on Tibet’s Population.” China Quarterly 27:120–22.
Ospina, Sofi, and Tanja Hohe. 2001. “Traditional Power Structures and the Community
Empowerment and Local Governance Project: Final Report.” Report to the World
Bank, September, Dili.
Ottaway, Marina. 2000. Africa’s New Leaders: Democracy or State Reconstruction? Wash-
ington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
Ottaway, Marina, and Thomas Carothers. 2000. Funding Virtue: Civil Society Aid and
Democracy Promotion. Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace.
Outram, Quentin. 2004. “Economy.” In Regional Surveys of the World: Africa South of the
Sahara 2004. London: Europa Publications.
Padro-Maurer, Rogelio. 1990. The Contras 1980–1989: A Special Kind of Politics. New
York: Praeger.
Paige, Jeffrey. 1997. Coffee and Power: Revolution and the Rise of Democracy in Central
America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Palmer, Robin. 1990. “Land Reform in Zimbabwe, 1980–1990.” African Affairs 89:
163–81.
References 295
Paris, Roland. 2004. At War’s End: Building Peace after Civil Conflict. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Paris, Roland, and Timothy Sisk. 2009. The Dilemmas of Statebuilding: Confronting the
Contradictions of Postwar Peace Operations. New York: Routledge.
Patten, Alan. 1996. “The Republican Critique of Liberalism.” British Journal of Political
Science 26 (1): 25–44.
Patterson, George N. 1960. Tibet in Revolt. London: Faber & Faber.
Perez- Stable, Marifeli. 1999. The Cuban Revolution: Origins, Course, and Legacy. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Perusse, Roland I. 1995. Haitian Democracy Restored. Lanham, MD: University Press of
America.
Pham, John-Peter. 2004. Liberia: Portrait of a Failed State. New York: Reed Press.
Picard, Elizabeth, 1996. Lebanon: A Shattered Country—Myths and Realities of the Wars
in Lebanon. New York: Holmes & Meier.
Poggo, Scopas S. 2009. The First Sudanese Civil War: Africans, Arabs and Israelis in the
Southern Sudan, 1955–1972. New York: Palgrave.
Political Instability Task Force. 2008. PITF Dataset. http: // globalpolicy.gmu.edu / pitf / .
Ponzio, Richard J. 2010. Democratic Peacebuilding: Aiding Afghanistan and Other Fragile
States. New York: Oxford University Press.
Posen, Barry R. 1993. “The Security Dilemma and Ethnic Conflict.” Survival 35 (1):
27–47.
Poulton, Robin-Edward, and Ibrahim ag Youssouf. 1998. A Peace of Timbuktu: Demo-
cratic Governance, Development and African Peacemaking. New York: United Nations
Publications.
Powell, Walter W., and Paul J. DiMaggio, eds. 1991. New Institutionalism in Organizational
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Prado, Tania Palencia. 1998. “Advocates and Guarantors: Establishing Participative De-
mocracy in Post-war Guatemala.” Accord: An International Review of Peace Initiatives:
Negotiating Rights: The Guatemalan Peace Process. www.c-r.org / cr / acc_guat / prado
.htm.
Prevost, Gary. 1987. “The ‘Contra’ War in Nicaragua.” Conflict Quarterly 7 (3): 5–21.
PRIO (Peace Research Institute Oslo). 2003a. “Conflict Summaries: Central African
Republic.” Available from the author.
———. 2003b. “Conflict Summaries: Europe, Georgia (Abkhazia) and Georgia (South
Ossetia).” Available from the author.
———. 2003c. “Conflict Summaries: Peru.” Available from the author.
Prunier, Gerard. 1995. The Rwanda Crisis: History of a Genocide. New York: Colombia
University Press.
Przeworski, Adam. 1991. Democracy and the Market. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Quinn, Jason M., T. David Mason, and Mehmet Gurses. 2007. “Sustaining the Peace:
Determinants of Civil War Recurrence.” International Interactions 33:167–93.
296 References
Ramos-Horta, Jose. 1987. Funu: The Unfinished Saga of East Timor. Trenton, NJ: Red
Sea Press.
Ray, James Lee. 1998. “Does Democracy Cause Peace?” Annual Review of Political Science
1:27–46.
Rees, Edward. 2004. Under Pressure FALANTIL: Three Decades of Security Force Develop-
ment in Timor Leste: 1975–2004. Working Paper 139. Geneva: Geneva Centre for the
Democratic Control of Armed Forces.
Regan, Jane. 2003. “Haiti No. 2 on Danger List for Media.” Miami Herald, August 16.
Reilly, Ben, and Andrew Reynolds.1999. Electoral Systems and Conflict in Divided Societies.
Washington, DC: National Academies Press.
Reno, William. 1999. Warlord Politics and African States. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
———. 2008. “Anti-Corruption Efforts in Liberia: Are They Aimed at the Right Tar-
gets?” International Peacekeeping 15 (3): 387–404.
Reynal-Querol, Marta. 2002. “Ethnicity, Political Systems, and Civil Wars.” Journal of
Conflict Resolution 46 (1): 29–54.
Richardson, H. E. 1962. Tibet and Its History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Richmond, Oliver P., and Jason Franks, eds. 2009. Liberal Peace Transitions: Between
Statebuilding and Peacebuilding. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
Robinson, Randall. 2007. An Unbroken Agony: From Revolution to the Kidnapping of a
President. Basic Civitas.
Robinson, William I. 1996. Promoting Polyarchy: Globalization, US Intervention and He-
gemony. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Roeder, Philip G. 2005. “Power Dividing as an Alternative to Ethnic Power Sharing.” In
Sustainable Peace: Power and Democracy after Civil Wars, edited by Philip G. Roeder
and Donald Rothchild. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Roeder, Philip G., and Donald S. Rothchild, eds. 2005. Sustainable Peace: Power and De-
mocracy after Civil Wars. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Romero, Simon. 2009. “Cocaine Trade Helps Rebels Reignite War in Peru.” New York
Times, March 18.
Ron, J. 2005. “Paradigm in Distress? Primary Commodities and Civil War.” Journal of
Conflict Resolution 49:443–50.
Rosecrance, Richard. 2000. The Rise of the Virtual State: Wealth and Power in the Coming
Century. New York: Basic Books.
Ross, Michael L. 1999. “Review: The Political Economy of the Resource Curse.” World
Politics 51:297–322.
Rothchild, Donald, and Philip G. Roeder. 2005. “Power Sharing as an Impediment to
Peace and Democracy.” In Sustainable Peace: Power and Democracy after Civil Wars,
edited by Philip G. Roeder and Donald Rothchild. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
Press.
Ruane, Christopher. 2003. “Central African Republic: There May Be Trouble Ahead.”
Africa Today 417 (April).
Rubin, Barnett R. 2006. “Peace Building and State-Building in Afghanistan: Construct-
ing Sovereignty for Whose Security?” Third World Quarterly 27:175.
References 297
Stoll, David. 2005. “The Nicaraguan Contras: Were They Indios?” Latin American Poli-
tics and Society 45 (3): 145–57.
Street, Anne M., Howard Mollet, and Jennifer Smith. 2008. “Experiences of the United
Nations Peacebuilding Commission in Sierra Leone and Burundi.” Journal of Peace-
building and Development 4 (2): 33–46.
Strohmeyer, Hansjörg. 2001. “Collapse and Reconstruction of a Judicial System: The
United Nations Missions in Kosovo and East Timor.” American Journal of International
Law 95 (1): 46–63.
Suchman, Mark C. 1995. “Managing Legitimacy: Strategic and Institutional Approaches.”
Academy of Management Review 20 (3): 571–609.
Suhrke, Astri. 2001. “Peacekeepers as Nation-Builders: Dilemmas of the UN in East
Timor.” International Peacekeeping 8 (4): 1–20.
Suhrke, Astri, and Ingrid Samset. 2007. “What’s in a Figure? Estimating Recurrence of
Civil War.” International Peacekeeping 14 (2):195–203.
Suliman, Mohamed. 1997. “Civil War in Sudan: The Impact of Ecological Degrada-
tion.” Contributions in Black Studies 15:99–121. http: // scholarworks.umass.edu / cgi /
viewcontent.cgi?article=1100&context=cibs.
Taylor, Ian. 2010. “Liberal Peace, Liberal Imperialism: A Gramscian Critique.” In Palgrave
Advances in Peacebuilding, edited by Oliver P. Richmond. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Taylor, Lewis. 2006. The Shining Path: Guerrilla War in Peru’s Northern Highlands. Liver-
pool: Liverpool University Press.
Thier, Alex. 2002. “The Road Ahead: Political and Institutional Reconstruction in Af-
ghanistan.” Third World Quarterly 23 (5): 893–907.
Thomas, Lowell. 1959. The Silent War in Tibet. Garden City, NY: Doubleday.
Thomson Reuters Foundation. 2001. “Lucrative Timber Trade Fuels Liberian War Mis-
ery.” http: // reliefweb.int / node / 86035.
Tilly, Charles. 1975. “Reflections on the History of European State-Making.” In The For-
mation of National States in Western Europe, edited by Charles Tilly. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Timor-Leste Armed Violence Assessment. 2009. Elections Violence in Timor-Leste:
Mapping Incidents and Responses. Issue Brief 3. www.timor-leste-violence.org / pdfs /
Timor-Leste-Violence-IB3-ENGLISH.pdf.
Tishkov, Valery. 1999. “Ethnic Conflicts in the Former USSR: The Use and Misuse of
Typologies and Data.” Journal of Peace Research 36 (5): 571–91.
Torrijos, Giancarlo Soler. 2008. Under the Shadow of the United States: Democracy and
Regional Order in the Latin Caribbean. Boca Raton, FL: Brown Walker Press.
Trimberger, Ellen Kay. 1978. Revolution from Above. Piscataway, NJ: Transaction.
Trouillot, Michel-Rolph. 1989. Haiti: State against Nation: The Origins and Legacy of
Duvalierism. New York: Monthly Review Press.
———. 1994. “Culture, Color and Politics in Haiti.” In Race, edited by Steven Gregory
and Roger Sanjek. Piscataway, NJ: Rutgers University Press.
Tuck, Christopher. 2000. ““Every Car or Moving Object Gone”: The ECOMOG Inter-
vention in Liberia.” African Studies Quarterly 4 (1): 1–16.
300 References
Tulchin, Joseph, and Gary Bland. 1992. Is There a Transition to Democracy in El Salvador?
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Tvedten, Inge. 1997. Angola: Struggle for Peace and Reconciliation. Boulder, CO: West-
view.
United Nations Department of Public Information. N.d. “Liberia: UNOMIL, Back-
ground.” Section on “December 1995–November 1996.” www.un.org/Depts/DPKO/
Missions / unomil_b.htm.
United Nations Development Program. 2000. Human Development Report 2000. New
York: United Nations.
———. 2007. Democratization and Civil Society Empowerment Programme. New York:
United Nations Development Program.
United Nations Secretary-General, Office of. 1997a. Final Report of the Secretary General
on the UN Mission to Liberia. New York: United Nations. http: // daccess-ods.un.org /
TMP / 287225.9.html.
———. 1997b. Twenty-Second Report on the UN Observer Mission in Liberia. New York:
United Nations. www.undemocracy.com / S-1997-237.
———. 2007. Fifteenth Progress Report of the Secretary-General on the UN Mission in Libe-
ria. New York: United Nations.
United Nations Special Commission of Inquiry for Timor-Leste. 2006. “Report of the
United Nations Independent Special Commission of Inquiry for Timor-Leste.” Ge-
neva: Office the UN High Commissioner for Human Rights.
US Agency for International Development. 2005. At Freedom’s Frontiers: A Democracy
and Governance Strategic Framework. Report PD-ACF-99. Washington, DC: US
Agency for International Development.
US Department of Defense. 2009. Progress toward Security and Stability in Afghanistan.
Report to the Congress. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.
US Department of State. 1998. Background Notes: Georgia. Washington, DC: US Govern-
ment Printing Office.
———. 1999. Liberia: Country Report on Human Rights Practices for 1998. Washington,
DC: US Department of State. www.state.gov / g / drl / rls / hrrpt / 1999 / 254.htm.
———.2002. Patterns of Global Terrorism, 2002. Washington, DC: US Department of
State. www.state.gov / s / ct / rls / crt / 2002 / .
———. 2008. “Background Note: Burundi.” www.state.gov / r / pa / ei / bgn / 2821.htm.
———. 2010a. “Background Note: Central African Republic.” www.state.gov / r / pa / ei /
bgn / 4007.htm.
———. 2010b. “Background Note: Mali.” www.state.gov / r / pa / ei / bgn / 2828.htm.
Utas, Mats. 2005. “The Reintegration and Remarginalization of Youth in Liberia.” In No
Peace, No War, edited by Paul Richards. Athens: Ohio University Press.
Uvin, Peter. 1998. Aiding Violence: The Development Enterprise in Rwanda. West Hartford,
CT: Kumarian Press.
———. 1999. “Ethnicity and Power in Burundi and Rwanda: Different Paths to Mass
Violence.” Comparative Politics 31 (3): 253–71.
References 301
Van den Brande, K., with S. Happaerts and H. Bruyninckx. 2008. “The Role of the Sub-
national Level of Government in Decision-Making for Sustainable Development.”
Institute for International and European Policy.
Vinding, Diana. 2002. The Indigenous World, 2001–2002. Copenhagen: International
Work Group for Indigenous Affairs.
Wakoson, Elias Nyamlell. 1993. “The Politics of Southern Self-Government.” In Civil
War in the Sudan, edited by M. W. Daly and Ahmad Alawad Sikainga. London: British
Academic Press.
Wallensteen, Peter. 2008. “International Responses to Crises of Democratization in War-
Torn Societies.” In From War to Democracy, edited by Anna K. Jarstad and Timothy D.
Sisk. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Wallensteen, Peter, and Margareta Sollenberg. 1997. “Armed Conflicts Conflict Termi-
nation, and Peace Agreements, 1989–96.” Journal of Peace Research 34 (3): 339–58.
Walter, Barbara F. 1997. “The Critical Barrier to Civil War Settlement.” International Or-
ganization 51:335–64.
———. 2002. Committing to Peace: The Successful Settlement of Civil Wars. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
———. 2004. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” Journal
of Peace Research 41 (3): 371–88.
Walter, Barbara F., and Jack L Snyder, eds. 1999. Civil Wars, Insecurity, and Intervention.
New York: Columbia University Press.
Weinstein, Warren. 1972. “Conflict and Confrontation in Central Africa: The Revolt in
Burundi.” Africa Today 19 (4): 17–37.
Welt, Cory. 2010. “The Thawing of a Frozen Conflict: The Internal Security Dilemma
and the 2004 Prelude to the Russo-Georgian War.” Europe-Asia Studies 62 (1):
63–97.
West, Ronald. 2007. “Lawyers, Guns, and Money: Justice and Security Reform in East
Timor.” In Constructing Justice and Security after War, edited by Charles T. Call. Wash-
ington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.
Whitman, Jim. 1999. Peacekeeping and the UN Agencies. Portland: Frank Cass.
Williams, Gabriel I. H. 2006. Liberia: The Heart of Darkness. Victoria: Trafford Publishing.
Wimmer, Andreas. 2002. Nationalist Exclusion and Ethnic Conflict. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Wimmer, Andreas, Lars-Erik Cederman, and Brian Min. 2009. “Ethnic Politics and
Armed Conflict: A Configurational Analysis of a New Global Data Set.” American So-
ciological Review 74 (2): 316–37.
Winslow, Charles. 1996. Lebanon: War and Politics in a Fragmented Society. London:
Routledge.
Wolff, Stefan. 2009. “Complex Power- Sharing and the Centrality of Territorial Self-
Governance in Contemporary Conflict Settlements.” Ethnopolitics 8 (1): 27–45.
Wood, Elizabeth Jean. 2003. Insurgent Collective Action and Civil War in El Salvador. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
302 References
World Bank. 2002. Haiti: Country Assistance Evaluation. Operations Evaluation Depart-
ment Report 23637. Washington, DC: World Bank.
———. 2011. World Development Report 2011: Conflict, Security and Development. Wash-
ington, DC: World Bank.
Yoh, John G. Nyuot. 2003. “Peace Processes and Conflict Resolution in the Horn of
Africa.” African Security Review 12 (3).
Young, Crawford. 1965. Politics in the Congo: Decolonization and Independence. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 1994. The African Colonial State in Comparative Perspective. New Haven, CT:
Yale University Press.
Zahar, Marie-Jöelle. 2003. “Reframing the Spoiler Debate in Peace Processes.” In Con-
temporary Peacemaking: Conflict, Violence and Peace Processes. New York: Palgrave
Macmillan.
———. 2005. “Power Sharing in Lebanon: Foreign Protectors, Domestic Peace, and
Democratic Failure.” In Sustainable Peace: Power and Democracy after Civil Wars, edited
by Philip G. Roeder and Donald Rothchild. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Zartman, I. William. 1977. “Negotiation as a Joint Decision-Making Process.” Journal of
Conflict Resolution 21:619–38.
Zartman, I. William, ed. 1995a. Collapsed States. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
———. 1995b. Collapsed States: Disintegration and Restoration of Legitimate Authority.
Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.
———. 1995c. Elusive Peace: Negotiating an End to Civil Wars. Washington, DC: Brook-
ings Institution Press.
Zartman, I. William, and Maureen R. Berman. 1982. The Practical Negotiator. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Index
Tables are indicated by t following page numbers. Arabic surnames starting with “al-” are alphabetized by the fol-
lowing part of the name.
civil wars: defined, 11; devastation of, 2; extrastate Contras (Nicaragua), 174, 175–76
aspects of, 233; new civil war in same country Correlates of War Project, 9, 21n11, 27
or territory, 14t; number of battle-related deaths Costa Rica: regional assistance in civil war in, 200;
for internal armed conflict to qualify as, 12; victorious anticommunist regime in, 197
scholarship on, 59–65, 233–35; theories about, Côte d’Ivoire and Liberian unrest, 71, 73, 81, 82
26–30. See also nonrecurrence; onset of civil war; coups, 10, 128–29. See also specific countries
recurrences critical peacebuilding theorists, 35–36, 44, 223–24,
classification of conflicts, 13–15, 14–15t, 21n14, 51 225t, 227
Clinton, Bill, 132, 135, 260 Croatia, international troop deployments to, 200,
CNRT. See National Council of Timorese Resis- 203
tance Cuba: nonrecurrence in, 19; victorious Communist
coercion, 28, 130 regime in, 196
Cold War: and anticommunist regimes, 196–202; Cyprus: international troop deployments to, 200,
breakup of Soviet Union, wars related to, 203; 203; negotiated settlement in, 184; no power-
and ideology as mobilizing principle, 199; nego- sharing, but inclusionary behavior in, 195–96,
tiated settlements during, 184, 200; post–Cold 198
War era vs., 5, 184, 201, 207; and regime types,
183; and victorious Communist regime in Cuba, Dailey, Peter, 135
196 Dalai Lama, 116–18
Collier, Paul: adhering to neoliberal macroeconom- Daly, M. W., 104, 105, 106
ics, 63; on “conflict trap,” 124, 127; on economic Dayton Accords (1995, Bosnia), 253, 260
factors, 6, 72, 105, 130–31, 135; on ethnicity DDR. See disarmament, demobilization, and
factor, 48n2; on postwar countries’ risk level for reintegration
recurrence, 266; on rate that armed conflicts decision “moments” in postwar political processes,
recur, 61; on rebel leaders hiding their true mo- 246–73; elections and end of interim gover-
tives, 95n21; on religious factor, 167; on resource nance, 257–66; interim governance, decisive
curse and civil war, 26–28, 127; on variables and role of domestic actors in, 252–54; interim gov-
regressions, 52–54 ernance, decisive role of international actors in,
Colombia: natural resources in, 27, 215; renewal of 248–52; state design, 254–56; state legitimacy
offensive actions in, 48n7; successful powershar- after elections, 266–73
ing in, 194 Defense Forces of Timor-Leste (FDTL), 140–43
colonialism, effect of, 45 Del Castillo, Graciana, 32
Commission of Inquiry (Sudan), 102 demobilization. See disarmament, demobilization,
Committee to Protect Journalists, 135 and reintegration (DDR)
Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa, “democracy promotion” and democratization:
272 consociational democracy, 40; negative effects of,
Community of Sahel-Saharan States, 127 7, 240–44; and prevention of recurrence, 28. See
comparativists, 232 also specific countries
Condominium Agreement (Sudan), 101 democratic peace thesis, 230
conflict diamonds, 84, 87, 90 Democratic Republic of the Congo: civilian victims
conflict resolution. See negotiated settlements; in, 223; failed powersharing in, 194; multiple
peace agreements; peacebuilding armed conflicts in, 201; natural resources in,
Congo, Democratic Republic of. See Democratic 215
Republic of the Congo Des Forges, Alison, 153
Conneh, Sekou, 77 De Soto, Alvaro, 32
Conselho Nacional de Resistência Maubere Detzel, Julian, 90
(CNRM; East Timor), 138 Development Assistance Committee (OECD-DAC),
consociational democracy, 40 221–22, 271
consolidation of peace, 3, 4, 207, 226. See also Development Research Group (World Bank), 26
peacebuilding De Waal, Alex, 106
constitutionalism, 221 diffusion, 183–84
constructivist theory, 217 Dillon, Karin, 169, 172
Contract and Monopolies Commission (Liberia), 91 Dillon, Sam, 175
306 Index
external actors’ role, 236–37; deciding on transi- Garang, John, 101, 105
tional arrangements and rulers, 247–54, 273–74; Gemayel, Pierre, 164
and elections, 259; shaping legitimacy from genocide, 48n10, 150, 151, 154, 239
without, 45–47, 237–38, 270–73; strategy of, George, Alexander, 16, 180
245–47. See also peacekeeping operations Georgia and South Ossetia, 110–14; abrogation of
powersharing arrangements in, 99; coding in
“failed peace,” 1, 25–49; civil wars and ethnic data bases for, 110–11; economic factors in, 114;
conflict, 26–30; defined, 8, 11; exclusion, inclu- ethnic factors in, 112; failed powersharing in,
sion, and legitimacy, 36–47; reasons for, 25; 194; first conflict (1991–93), 111; fragile peace
recurrence as universally accepted indicator of, 8; in, 203; international factors in, 46, 233; recur-
standards for, 8–9 rence precipitated by exclusion in, 98; second
failed states, 6 conflict (2004), 18, 112–13, 210n15; separatist
FALINTIL. See Armed Forces for the Liberation of recurrences in, 97; territorial autonomy, reneging
East Timor on, 119, 120, 191
Famille Lavalas party (Haiti), 133–34 German, Tracey, 109
F&L. See Fearon and Laitin data sets Ghani, Ashraf, 7, 35, 222
Farabundo Marti National Liberation Front (El Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede, 61
Salvador), 191 globalization and state legitimacy, 244–45
Fearon and Laitin data sets, 74; on Burundi and Goldstein, Melvyn, 115
Rwanda, 151; on Central African Republic, 124; governance: interim governance, decisive role of
civil war at end for at least one year, 12–13; civil domestic actors in, 252–54; interim gover-
wars data set of, 9–10, 20n1, 51, 66nn1–6, 67n7, nance, decisive role of international actors in,
67n13; classification of civil wars not always 248–52; as key to peace, 33–35, 233. See also
clear, 234; collapse of Soviet Union, effect of, state building
121n4; colonial wars for independence included, Governance Reform Commission (Liberia), 91
21n16; conditions favoring insurgency, 27; ethnic Great Lakes region (Africa). See Burundi; Rwanda
fractionalization, 29, 54–56, 55–56t; GDP as greed / grievance debate, 26–27, 58
factor, 53–54; proxies in, 61–62; and religious Greek Civil War, 197, 200
fractionalization, 54–56; and resource curse, 74; grievance-based approaches: and civil wars’ onset,
on South Korea’s nonrecurrent civil war, 197; on 26–27; in recurrence, 72
South Ossetia and Abkhazia, 110, 111; variables gross domestic product (GDP). See economic factors
and regressions in, 52–54, 53t Guatemala: civil societies, involvement in peace ne-
Fifteenth of September Legion (Nicaragua), 175 gotiations, 253; economic powersharing, 192; in-
Fifth Brigade (Zimbabwe), 147 terim governance, role of domestic actors in, 252;
Figueres, “Pepe,” 200 negotiated settlement in, 184; nonrecurrence,
Firaku (Timorese people), 136–37 19; organized criminal violence, 20n7; postwar
FOMUC (Central African Republic), 128 repression, 219; UN military observers, 200
foreign troops. See international troops; peacekeep- Guinea and Liberian unrest, 71, 76, 82, 150
ing operations Gurr, Ted Robert, 26, 37, 41
Forman, Shepard, 139–40 Gurses, Mehmet, 64
Fortna, Virginia Page, 28, 30, 48n5, 64, 90, 205 Gusmao, Xanana, 138–41, 143, 251, 262, 265
France: aid to Central African Republic, 128, 150; Guzman, Abimael, 177, 179
role in Haiti, 133
Frangieh, Suleiman, 165 Habibie, B. J., 138
Franks, Jason, 35, 36, 218, 221, 223 Habyarimana, Juvenal, 155–56
FRETILIN (Revolutionary Front of East Timor), Haiti, 1, 129–36; abrogation of powersharing
137–38, 140–43, 146 arrangements in, 99, 215; background of, 129;
Front for the Advancement and Progress of Haiti, coup attempts in, 131; economic factors in,
132 130–31; elections of Aristide, 135–36; exclusion
Front for the Restoration of Unity and Democracy precipitating recurrence in, 98, 122, 123, 129,
(FRUD; Djibouti), 187–88 134, 135, 202; explanatory factors for recurrence
“frozen conflicts,” 6, 202–6, 214 in, 130, 134–36; first armed conflict (1990–95),
Fukuyama, Francis, 3, 35, 222 130–32; informal external influence on, 248;
308 Index
Koehler, Jan, 106–7 Lemarchand, René, 151, 153–54, 156, 157, 158,
Kokoity, Eduard, 113 161n18, 189
Kolingba, André, 125–26, 149 liberal peacebuilding, 19, 31–33, 44, 47, 218–19,
Konaré, Alpha Oumar, 169–70 224, 225t
König, Marietta, 111 Liberia, 71–95; abrogation of powersharing
Kosovo: international factors and separatist struggle arrangements in, 99, 194, 215; constitutional
in, 46; international transitional authority order, preservation of, 252; demobilization and
in, 247; local and legislative elections before reintegration process in, 84–86, 89; election
presidential elections in, 261–63; national candidates in, 263–66; exclusionary behavior
ground forces in, 249; NATO bombing of, 13, of Taylor regime, 72, 78–81, 98, 100, 123–24,
110; NATO in decision-making role for, 248; no 202; first civil war, 72–74; “greed” and natural
peace agreement in, 2; withdrawal of peacekeep- resources in, 73–74, 86–88, 214, 215; informal
ing troops from, 33–34 external influence on, 248; international factors
Kosovo Liberation Army, 13, 249 in, 82–84; marginalization of civil society in,
Krahns (Liberia), 73, 77, 79, 80, 92 253; media suppression by Taylor, 79; onset of
Krain, Matthew, 149 peace (1996), 1, 12, 74–75; peacekeeping con-
Krasner, Stephen D., 222 sidered successful, yet conflict recurred in, 2, 9,
Krings, Thomas, 169 204; political powersharing in, 188, 256; political
Kromah, Alhaji G. V., 73, 76, 78–79, 85 repression under Taylor, 78–79; regional factors
Krueger, Robert, 190 in, 81–82, 150; second civil war, 1, 16, 71, 76–78,
Kumar, Krishna, 241 188; second postwar peace process (2003–pres-
ent), 88–91; security forces, exclusion in, 79–81;
Lafontant, Roger, 131 UN peacekeeping in, 3, 16, 204
Laitin. See Fearon and Laitin data sets Liberia Coalition for Reconciliation and Democ-
Laos: negotiated settlement in, 184; nonrecurrence racy, 76, 88
in, 194; regime change without warfare in, 189; Liberian Forest Development Company, 86
regional assistance in civil war, 200 Liberian Peace Council, 74, 76, 86
Latortue, Gerard, 134 Liberians United for Reconciliation and Democracy
Lavalas Family (Haiti), 133–34 (LURD), 71, 76–77, 80, 86, 88, 92, 94n3
Lebanese Front (LF), 165 Liberia Peace Council, 73–74, 76, 94n3
Lebanese National Movement (LNM), 164–65 Libya: civilian participants in uprising (2011),
Lebanon, 1, 163–67; analysis as anomaly to 234–35; and Mali, 168, 170, 173
study’s generalizations, 162, 166–67; economic Licklider, Roy, 123, 149, 180
powersharing in, 192; failed powersharing in, Lieven, Anatol, 107
162, 164, 166, 167, 172–73, 180, 188, 202, 231; Lijphart, Arendt, 40
institutional weakness in, 173; international Lobato, Rogelio, 141
troops to maintain stability in, 166, 233; multiple Locke, John, 36
recurrences in, 21n19; National Pact (1943) and Lockhart, Clare, 7, 35, 222
civil war (1958), 163–64; recurrence (1975), 18, Lofa Defense Force (Liberia), 73, 76
164–66; religious factors and marginalization in, Lord’s Resistance Army (Uganda), 128
163–64; Ta’if Accord (1989), 166, 167 Loya Jirga, 249
Lebed, Alexsandr, 107, 109 LURD. See Liberians United for Reconciliation and
legitimacy building, 36–37, 237–45; and democ- Democracy
ratization, 240, 242; external actors enhancing, Lynch, Dov, 203
237–38, 270–73; importance of, 222–23; Lyons, Terrence, 75, 256
increased resistance to Western manipulation,
238–39; “layered,” 270–73; and negative ef- Machiavelli, Niccolò, 33, 220, 236
fects of “democracy promotion,” 240–44; and Mack, Andrew, 234
sovereignty norm, 239–40. See also horizontal Madison, James, 33, 220–21
legitimacy; state legitimacy al-Mahdi, Sadiq, 104
legitimacy-focused peacebuilding, 6–7, 19, 213, Makdisi, Samir, 167
224–30; and blanket formulas, 245; framework Making War and Building Peace (Doyle & Samba-
for, 228–29; and policy questions, 229–30 nis), 32
310 Index
Mali, 167–73; analysis of, 162; background of, 168; National Council of Timorese Resistance (CNRT),
droughts in, 169; economic factors, 214; ethnic 138–40, 142, 262
factors in, 163, 168, 181n1; exclusionary behavior National Democratic Union (Nicaragua), 175
in, 168; failed powersharing in, 162, 172–73, 180; National Liberal Party (Lebanon), 165
inclusionary behavior, yet recurrence in, 172–73, National Patriotic Front of Liberia (NPFL), 73–77,
201; initial civil war, 168–70; institutional weak- 80, 85–86, 94nn5–6
ness in, 99, 173, 214; peace agreements and pow- National Police of Timor-Leste (PNTL), 141
ersharing in, 170–71, 180; recurrence (2006–08), National Reconciliation (Sudan), 104
18, 171–72; reintegration of ex-combatants in, 172 National Reconciliation Commission (Liberia), 78
Malu, Victor, 83 National Resistance Army (NRA ; Uganda), 156
Mamdani, Mahmoud, 151, 156 NATO, 13, 34, 110, 248–49, 273, 275n5
Mandingos (Liberia), 73, 74, 77, 92 NATO-commanded Implementation Force
Mansfield, Edward, 230, 241 (IFOR), 204
Mao Zedong, 18, 116–17, 119 natural resources: high-rent exports of, 179; leverage
Maskhadov, Aslan, 107, 108–9 of resource-rich states, 239; precipitating warfare,
Massaquoi, François, 76 26–27; sharing as means of conflict resolution,
mass violence: classification as civil war, 158–59; 192; significance as factor, 180, 215. See also
failed powersharing resulting in, 231; genocide specific countries
vs., 151 Ndadaye, Melchior, 190
McLeod, Patrick, 64 N’dayen, Didace, 125
mediation. See negotiated settlements; peace negotiated settlements, 184–86, 185t, 200, 207, 253
agreements Nepal: economic powersharing, 192; ongoing nego-
Metayer, Amiot, 133 tiations in, 188; UN military observers, 200
methodology, 6, 15–16; limitations of, 230, 232–33 NGOs (nongovernmental organizations). See civil
Miloševic, Slobodan, 228 society organizations
Min, Brian, 58–59 Nicaragua, 173–77; Communist revolution in,
Minorities at Risk data set, 37 174; constitutional order, preservation of, 252;
Mitchell, Christopher R., 104, 105 economic factors in, 177, 214; ethnic factors in,
MODEL (Liberia), 71, 77, 92 176; exclusionary behavior in, 123, 162, 173, 176;
Mosques and Imams National Advisory Board international intervention in, 200, 233; invasive
(Central African Republic), 205 US role in, 175–76; negotiated settlement in,
Mouvement Populaire de Libération de l’Azaouad 184; powersharing pact in, 186; recurrence in,
(MPLA), 169–70 1, 12, 18, 174–75; religious and ethnic factors
Mouvement pour la Libération du Congo (MLC; in, 174
Central African Republic), 126 Nicaraguan Democratic Force, 175
Mouvements et Fronts Unifiés de l’Azaouad Niger, role in Mali unrest, 168, 169–70, 171, 173, 201
(MFUA; Mali), 169–71 Nigeria, relationship with Taylor in Liberia, 75
Movement for Democracy in Liberia (MODEL), Nimeiri, Gaafar Muhammad, 103–5, 119
71, 77, 92 Nkomo, Joshua, 147–48
Mozambique: end of war in, 184; interim gover- nonrecurrence, 19, 183–210; and economic
nance, role of domestic actors in, 252; interna- powersharing, 192; and exclusionary behavior,
tional troop deployments in, 200; nonrecurrence 199, 199t; and inclusionary behavior, 186–92,
in, 19; political powersharing in, 188; security 199t; paths to, 207; and political powersharing,
powersharing in, 190; sovereignty maintained 187–90; pool of cases, 14t; and security power-
in, 247 sharing, 190–91; and territorial powersharing, 5,
Mugabe, Robert, 147–48 191. See also inclusion; peacebuilding
multiparty democracy, 241 nonseparatist recurrences, 18, 122–61; Burundi,
150–58; Central African Republic, 124–29;
Nagorno-Karabakh: elections sparking mass vio- East Timor, 136–46; exclusionary behavior pre-
lence in, 241; ethnicity and recurrence in, 48n7; cipitating, 123–24; Haiti, 129–36; reneging on
exclusion from study, 120n1 inclusion, 148–50; Rwanda, 150–58; Zimbabwe,
National Council of Maubere Resistance (Timor), 146–48
138 norms, creation after termination of wars, 217–18
Index 311
maintaining stability, 205; proxy use by, 62; on Somoza, Anastasio, 174, 177
rebel cohesion, 173, 181n3; shortcomings of re- South Africa: constitutional order, preservation of,
search of, 63–64; on South Ossetia, 110, 121n5; 252; economic powersharing in, 192; end of war
on sustainability of peacebuilding, 64; on UN in, 184; nonrecurrence in, 19; organized criminal
peace efforts’ effectiveness, 30, 90; on variables violence in, 20n7; political powersharing in, 188,
leading to recurrence, 28–30 256; sovereignty of, 247
Sandinistas. See Nicaragua Southern African Development Community, 273
Sankoh, Foday, 87, 192 Southern Lebanon Front, 165
Savimbi, Jonas, 85, 184, 191, 241, 259 Southern Party (Sudan), 101
Schevardnadze, Eduard, 110 South Korea: nonrecurrent civil war in, 197;
Schmitt, John, 15, 50, 66n6 regional assistance in civil war in, 200; US role
“security dilemma” approach to internal armed in, 200
conflict, 26 South Korean Workers Party, 197
security powersharing, 4, 188, 190–91, 215 South Ossetia. See Georgia and South Ossetia
Sendero Luminoso. See Shining Path (Peru) South Ossetian Popular Front, 111
Senegal: exclusionary behavior in, 214; interwar South Ossetian Supreme Soviet, 111
peace in, 12, 97 South Sudan Liberation Movement, 103
separatist recurrences, 96–121; Chechyna, 106–10; sovereignty norm, 239–40
China and Tibet, 115–18; exclusionary behavior Special Security Service (Liberia), 78, 80–81
precipitating, 98; Georgia and South Ossetia, Sriram, Chandra Lekha, 41, 49n13
110–14; and political exclusion, 4; pool of cases, stability of postwar societies: and deepening divi-
97–98, 98t; Sudan, 100–106 sions among former allies, 149; and inclusion of
Seventeen-Point Agreement (Tibet, 1951), 116, 118 state’s main social factions, 225; and third-party
“shadow” states, 237 military troops, 6
Shevardnadze, Eduard, 111, 121n7 state building, 6–7; to consolidate peace, 3; insti-
Shining Path (Peru), 99, 173, 177–78, 180, 182n4 tutional weakness, 58, 99–100, 109, 120, 149,
Shoesmith, Dennis, 140 159, 214–15; as more conservative than liberal,
Sierra Leone: conflict resolution and sharing of 36; peacebuilding as, 33–35, 221–23, 225t;
natural resources in, 192, 194; constitutional shortcomings of, 224
order, preservation of, 252; informal external State Department. See US State Department
influence on, 248; international troop deploy- state design, 254–56
ments to, 200; and Liberian unrest, 71, 76, 77, 81, state legitimacy, 41–47, 226, 243–44; after elec-
82, 83, 150; Lomé powersharing accord (1999), tions, 266–73; bases of, 243; defined, 41–43;
192, 194; political powersharing in, 188; resource and democratization, 243; embedded, 45, 226;
curse in, 27, 87; state legitimacy after elections and globalization, 244–45; international sources
in, 267; withdrawal of peacekeeping troops from, of, 45–47; performance legitimacy, 45; prag-
33–34 matic, 42; process legitimacy, 45, 226; and social
Sierra Leone Expert Panel, 94n18 expectations, 243–44; vertical, 43–45, 49n15,
Simonsen, Sven Gunnar, 142 245; Western efforts to build, 239–40. See also
Singer, David J., 9, 21n11, 51 horizontal legitimacy; legitimacy building
al-Sistani, Ali, 261 Stedman, Stephen John, 148
Small, Melvin, 9, 21n11, 51 Stepashin, Sergei, 109
Smith, Ian, 146 “structured, focused” case comparison, 180–81
smuggling, 172 Suchman, Mark, 41–42
Snyder, Jack L., 28, 230, 241 Sudan, 100–106; abrogation of powersharing ar-
Sochi Agreement (1992, South Ossetia), 111–12 rangements in, 99; background of, 101; exclusion
social exclusion, 37, 48n8 precipitating recurrence in, 98, 105, 123; failed
social expectations and state legitimacy, 243–44, powersharing in, 194; first civil war (1955–72),
254–55 100, 101–3; institutional weakness in, 99, 214;
socialist regimes, 196 international factors in recurrence in, 106, 233;
Somalia: interwar peace, perception of, 12, 15, 97; natural resources in, 105–6, 119, 214; peace
multiple armed conflicts in, 201; peacekeeping in, 103–4; powersharing after 2005 involving
troops withdrawn amid failure, 9 elections after 4 years and South Sudanese inde-
314 Index