Federalism 2
Federalism 2
Federalism 2
Citations:
-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and
Conditions of the license agreement available at
https://heinonline.org/HOL/License
-- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text.
-- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your license, please use:
Copyright Information
I. INTRODUCTION
Why do federal states differ so widely in their economic and political per-
formance? Some federal states, such as the United States, are among the
richest and least corrupt in the world. Others, such as India and Mexico, are
very poor and are mired in slow or negative growth. Mexico has also been
plagued by considerable corruption. China, another de facto federal system,
is very poor but is one of the fastest growing economies in the world. To ad-
dress this question, we develop a comparative theory of federal performance
and apply it to India.
The performance of federal systems differs in part because federalism is
not the only relevant variable influencing a country's economic and political
success. Nonetheless, we argue that differential performance does reflect
systematic differences among federal systems. Federalism is not a single type
of system, but a family of disparate systems. Although all such systems have
a hierarchy of governments, differences in federal architecture help to ac-
count for differential federal performance.
To understand how differences in federal structure affect federal perform-
ance, we begin with the traditional arguments favoring federalism. These fall
into two categories: economic benefits and non-economic benefits. The classic
economic arguments about the benefits of federalism are threefold. First,
Friedrich Hayek argues that the central government can never possess enough
information to tailor policies to specific circumstances.' Because lower gov-
ernments have better information about projects, policies, and citizen prefer-
ences, they will make better decisions about policies with a local impact
Hayek's argument implies that, except for truly national public goods such as
defense, a national, one-size-fits-all policy is not optimal.
1593
1594 VirginiaLaw Review [Vol. 83:1593
- Charles M. Tiebout, A-Pure Theory of Local Expenditures, 64 J. Pol. Econ. 416, 416-24
(1956).
'See, e.g., Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Economics of the Local Public Sector, in II Hand-
book of Public Economics 571 (Alan J. Auerbach & Martin Feldstein eds., 1987).
5 See Tiebout, supra note 3, at 419-20.
6See id.
7Wallace E. Oates, Fiscal Federalism (1972), provides the classic statement.
8
See, e.g., id. at 31-53.
'Truman F. Bewley, A Critique of Tiebout's Theory of Local Public Expenditures, 49
Econometrica 713 (1981). Several models show how intergovernmental competition limits
but may not eliminate inefficiency. See, e.g., Paul N. Courant & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, On
the Welfare Effects of Tax Limitation, 16 J. Pub. Econ. 289 (1981); Dennis Epple & Alan
Zelenitz, The Implications of Competition Among Jurisdictions: Does Tiebout Need Politics?,
89 J. Pol. Econ. 1197 (1981).
See Susan Rose-Ackerman, Corruption: A Study in Political Economy (1978).
"See, e.g., Geoffrey Brennan & James M. Buchanan, The Power to Tax (1980); James
M. Buchanan, Federalism As an Ideal Political Order and an Objective for Constitutional
Reform, Publius, Spring 1995, at 2.
11See Robert P. Inman & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Political Economy of Federalism, in
Perspectives on Public Choice 73 (Dennis C. Mueller ed., 1997).
13See, e.g., Donald L. Horowitz, Ethnic Groups in Conflict 646-48 (1985).
1997] Response 1595
the policies about which they profoundly disagree. In these societies, major-
ity rule in a centralized system could be disastrous as groups fight for power
to promote their conflicting goals. This approach suggests that federalism
and other forms of decentralization can sometimes prevent such fights.
Both the economists' and political scientists' approaches to federalism suf-
fer from a significant problem, however: They ignore the critical issue of how
the rules of federalism are maintained. Consider the problem of assignment
of political authority. This issue does not merely concern technical details of
economic efficiency, as economists suggest. It is about the allocation of po-
liticalpower to political units of jurisdiction. Jurisdictions and interests fight
for power to be assigned where they have some influence; and once allo-
cated, jurisdictions and interests fight to preserve and enhance their power.
Most federal systems diverge considerably from the economists' prescription
for the optimal assignment of powers over public goods and taxes. In contrast,
the first 150 years of the United States remarkably paralleled the economists'
prescription. Consider the Constitution's Commerce Clause. 14 The power of
the federal government to regulate commerce is second nature today; so
much so that, for the past sixty years, the Commerce Clause has imposed few
restrictions on federal power. It is therefore remarkable that the federal
government did not exercise this power during its first hundred years, until
passage of the Interstate Commerce Act"5 in 1887 regulating the railroads. It
is hard to imagine the federal government's activity so constrained in the
modern United States-or anywhere in today's developing world. These ob-
servations raise the question, why do public officials so rarely abide by feder-
alism's rules?
For federalism to survive, political officials must have incentives to abide
by federalism's rules. 6 In other words, the rules and constraints of federalism
must be self-enforcing: Political officials must find it in their interests to abide
by a series of rules and to respect a series of citizen rights. For example, offi-
cials in the national government must refrain from invading the policy do-
All federal systems involve decentralized political authority, though not all
forms of decentralization constitute federal systems. To understand federal-
ism, we must identify its principal characteristics. The first condition is a de-
fining characteristic of any federal system:
22
Jonathan Rodden & Susan Rose-Ackerman, Does Federalism Preserve Markets?, 83
Va. L. Rev. 1521 (1997).
1997] Response 1599
Fl: A hierarchyof governments with a delineated scope of authority
(for example, between the national and subnational governments) ex-
ists so that each government is autonomous within its own sphere of
authority.2Y
Beyond this condition, federal systems differ enormously in their political
and economic performance. To build a theory of how their political and eco-
nomic characteristics differ, we begin with a special type of federalism called
market-preserving federalism.4 Formalized decentralization alone is insuffi-
cient to preserve markets; rather, a system must possess further conditions
concerning the allocation of authorities and responsibilities among different
levels of government. These conditions also prove useful for predicting the
differential performance of particular types of federal systems.
F2: The subnational governments have primary authority over the
economy within their jurisdictions.
F3: The national government has the authority to police the common
market [from encroachments by the states] and to ensure the mobility
of goods and factors across subgovernment jurisdictions.
F4: Revenue sharing among governments is limited and borrowing
by governments is constrained so that all governments face hard budget
constraints.
F5: The allocation of authority and responsibility has an institution-
alized degree of durability so that it cannot be altered by the national
government either unilaterally or under the pressures from subna-
tional governments.-'
These conditions represent an ideal type of institutional arrangement of
market-preserving federalism. From the perspective of preserving market
incentives, the authority of the national government over markets is limited to
policing subgovernmental shirking (here represented as F3: subgovernment
encroachment on the common market) and providing national public goods,
such as defense and a stable macroeconomic regime.
The institutional arrangements of federalism recognize a critical difference
between the national government and the subnational governments: There is
only one of the former, but there are many of the latter. Competition among
jurisdictions induces limits on the discretionary authority of the subnational
governments. A necessary condition for this competition to be beneficial is
the absence of trade barriers, so that the entire nation becomes a common
market as required by F3. Without F3, each subnational government would
26See McKinnon, Market-Preserving Fiscal Federalism, supra note 19, at 37-38; see also
David E. Wildasin, Externalities and Bailouts: Hard and Soft Budget Constraints in Inter-
governmental Fiscal Relations (May 1997) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Vir-
ginia Law Review Association) (discussing soft and hard budget constraints in relation to
the size of localities).
1997] Response 1601
Before turning to the economic implications of market-preserving federal-
ism, we pause for a few observations about the relationship between the mar-
ket-preserving federalism model and various systems of federalism throughout
the world. Our approach shows that whether a nation describes its political
system as federal is irrelevant. What matters for federal performance is the
combination of conditions that hold. Many de jure federalisms are nothing
like market-preserving federalism. For example, in Mexico, Conditions F2,
F4, and F5 fail. In this federal system, the lion's share of state revenue comes
from the national government.8 This raises several problems. First, it breaks
the link between local economic prosperity and fiscal health. Second and
perhaps more importantly, along with the revenue come restrictions, rules,
and regulations from the center. Money from the central government carries
the implicit threat, made explicit in Mexico,2 9 of withdrawing funds if the
lower government chooses to disobey. Local governments in these systems
have neither the incentive nor the ability to differentiate themselves from
their neighbors. More broadly, the failure of F2 and F5 implies that the po-
litical discretion and authority retained by the central government greatly
compromise its market-preserving qualities.
In sum, though many forms of political decentralization exist, market-
preserving federalism characterizes only a narrow subset.?
F3. Second, the induced competition among lower jurisdictions places self-
enforcing limits on these governments' ability to act arbitrarily?'
These limits have a number of salutary effects. First, no government has a
monopoly of regulatory authority over the entire economy. The national
government's absence of regulatory authority prevents it from creating mo-
nopolies and other forms of inefficient economic intervention that plague de-
veloping countries. Competition limits the ability of subnational govern-
ments to create monopolies and other policies that cripple markets, because
doing so would place firms in its jurisdiction at a considerable disadvantage.
When a particular jurisdiction imposes an onerous restriction on its firms, the
firms face a competitive disadvantage relative to competing firms from less
restrictive jurisdictions.
A further beneficial effect of market-preserving federalism is that compe-
tition among jurisdictions extends to factors of production, such as capital
and labor. This induces jurisdictions to provide a hospitable environment for
factors, typically through the provision of local public goods such as secure
rights of factor owners, provision of infrastructure, utilities, and access to
markets. Those jurisdictions which fail to provide these goods find that fac-
tors generally move to other jurisdictions. Although old firms may not move
old plant and equipment to new jurisdictions, they will locate new invest-
ments there. In less competitive jurisdictions, local economic activity and tax
revenue therefore decline. For example, the economic rise of the American
South since the 1960s reflects in part firms moving to jurisdictions with fewer
regulatory and labor restrictions. 32
Third, the hard budget constraint (F4) implies that local governments can
go bankrupt. This provides lower governments with incentives for proper fis-
cal management. Local enterprises, politicians, and citizens hardly want their
government to spend more money than is prudent, as bankruptcy would
greatly hinder the ability of local governments to finance necessary public
goods, such as those needed to attract foreign capital and lower business costs.
Finally, market-preserving federalism provides a secure political founda-
tion for markets.33 By resting the regulatory authority over markets with
lower governments, market-preserving federalism induces them to foster lo-
cal economic prosperity. In addition, by limiting national authority over the
economy, it also prevents the national government from causing the massive
3' This Section summarizes an extensive literature in economics, including the classic
work of Tiebout and Oates. See Oates, supra note 7; Tiebout, supra note 3. For a review
of this literature see Rubinfeld, supra note 4.
32See, e.g., Ronald I. McKinnon, Market-Preserving Fiscal Federalism in the American
Monetary Union, in Macroeconomic Dimensions of Public Finance: Essays in Honour of
Vito Tanzi 73, 89 (Mario I. Blejer & Teresa Ter-Minassian eds., 1997).
1 See Weingast, supra note 16.
1997] Response 1603
31For example, the common market in the early 19th century United States could not
have been sustained without the ever-vigilant policing of the Supreme Court. See, e.g.,
Gibbons v. Ogden, 22 U.S. (9 Wheat.) 1 (1824) (striking down New York State's grant of
an exclusive right to operate steamboats). Policing the market against encroachments by
state governments proved a major use of its constitutional powers. These cases reveal the
remarkable diversity and cleverness of the states in their efforts to erect such barriers.
See Barry R. Weingast, The Political Foundations of Antebellum American Growth 20
(Sept. 1, 1993) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Virginia Law Review Associa-
tion). Similarly, such barriers are a major reason underlying the movement for economic
and political union in Europe. See Geoffrey Garrett, International Cooperation and Insti-
tutional Choice: The European Community's Internal Market, 46 Int'l Org. 533 (1992).
1 See Montinola, Qian & Weingast, supra note 16, at 73-79.
31See id. at 77-78.
1997] Response 1605
8Id. at 65-66.
1606 Virginia Law Review [Vol. 83:1593
a market economy, it has the power to prevent lower governments from fos-
tering markets.
D. Does FederalismPreserveMarkets?
We end this Part with the question asked by Rodden/Rose-Ackerman in
the title to their article: Does federalism preserve markets? Although their
title is a clever twist on the phrase "market-preserving federalism," it reflects
a fundamental alteration in the nature of the issue. The theory sketched in
this Part suggests that federal systems differ too considerably to have a uni-
form effect on markets. Indeed, the discussion above implies that many fed-
eral systems are very poor at preserving markets. The answer to Rodden-
/Rose-Ackerman's question must therefore be "no."
Our approach suggests further that the analysis cannot stop here. The
point of the theory of market-preserving federalism is to provide an approach
that explains which types of federalism protect markets. Federal systems that
differ from this ideal in predictable ways will have economies that differ from
an ideal market's society in predictable ways. Thus, federal systems that
violate a common market assumption will lose all benefits from competition
among jurisdictions. Lower governments will erect trade barriers and sub-
stantial interventions in their economies. Forms of federalism which violate
Conditions F2 and F5 will have too powerful a center, also compromising
federalism's market-preserving qualities.
2 Arend Lijphart, Democracy in Plural Societies 181 (1977); Riker, supra note 17, at
120-22.
43See B.S. Grewal, Fiscal Federalism in India 15-18 (1974).
See Asok Chanda, Federalism in India: A Study of Union-State Relations 68-72 (1965)
(discussing the historical background of the center's authority over the states).
45See, e.g., Granville Austin, The Indian Constitution: Cornerstone of a Nation 189-91
(1966).
46 See Grewal, supra note 43, at 15-32.
47See K.S. Krishnaswamy, I.S. Gulati & A. Vaidyanathan, Economic Aspects of Feder-
alism in India, in Federalism in India: Origins and Development 180, 188 (Nirmal Mukerji
& Balveer Arora eds., 1992) (suggesting that, "Though States were given the exclusive
right to agricultural taxation, political conditions made its exploitation extremely difficult,
if not virtually impossible.").
1608 Virginia Law Review [Vol. 83:1593
stantial portions of the total revenue transfers from the center to the states.4
These expenditures include those stipulated by central development plans,
state-level plans, and centrally sponsored schemes. This last program has be-
come increasingly important both as a patronage tool and as a way for the
center to dominate investment and distribution decisions.
While the Planning Commission controls Plan expenditures, the Finance
Commission has authority over all non-Plan disbursements. The commission's
main job is to address the gap between committed expenditures and the state's
expected revenues.f It does not rank or evaluate different types of expendi-
tures, however, and its main goal is to avoid deficits in non-Plan areas."
The lack of coordination between the two commissions creates a soft
budget constraint for the states. Because the Finance Commission tends to
provide funds to make up shortfalls, states have an incentive to commit to
expenditures regardless of funds. This behavior by states emerged soon after
independence. In the 1960s, for example, an astute observer remarked that
"states indulge in competitive importuning, putting up scheme after scheme
to attract funds, and then happily run up big deficits by failing to collect their
own share .... .""
In the 1950s and 1960s the two commissions controlled almost all revenue
transfer decisions. 53 But in the last two decades, other central government
agencies have acquired considerable influence over economic policies. Since
all foreign projects must be routed through ministries or central financial in-
stitutions, 4 the recent introduction of economic reforms does not necessarily
mean greater decentralization to the states. Moreover, the bulk of industrial
policy, especially through regulation and licensing, is controlled by centrally
appointed boards and agencies. This system, known in India as License Raj,
means that the center retains control over the distribution of permits and li-
censes for new areas of economic development through the relevant central
ministry.55 Although recent central governments have pledged to loosen the
grip of License Raj,56 the center still reserves the right to decide which changes
will be made.
Apart from the distribution of revenue and returns from investments,
states can potentially increase their total revenue by borrowing. But the states'
53See Chanda, supra note 44, at 188-225,260-94; Grewal, supra note 43, at 25-32.
14Jagdish N. Bhagwati, India in Transition: Freeing the Economy 49-50 (1993).
51See id. at 50-51
16 Id. at 86-87.
1997] Response 1609
ability to borrow is limited. The Constitution mandates that, as long as a
state owes outstanding loans to the center, it cannot raise loans without the
center's consent. 7 Although this rule is not always followed, states do borrow
much more from the center than from the market."8 This has two results: First,
the states have racked up enormous debt to the center, with an increasing
share of their resource transfers to the center taken up by debt service
charges.59 Second, this makes states further reliant on center decisions.
Why would provincial leaders agree to such an asymmetric division of
economic control in a heterogeneous, federal country? A number of expla-
nations emerge from the debates that took place during the drafting of the
new Indian Constitution. It should be emphasized that the Constituent As-
sembly distinguished between economic and political decentralization. While
political decentralization was seen as inevitable, economic decentralization
was never seriously contemplated given the differences in language, ethnicity,
and previous forms of government (e.g., between the British colonial prov-
inces and the princely states).
Nehru and the socialist wing sought to implement central economic plan-
ning because they believed it would more quickly create a strong industrial
base. Leaders more receptive to capitalist theories went along because they
were afraid that open markets, especially those that were permeable by in-
ternational investments, would wipe out nascent local industries that had al-
ready been damaged by centuries of colonial domination. 6' They accepted
central government control as the lesser of the possible evils that could befall
Indian capitalism.
In addition, many feared that without central control, the disparities be-
tween rich and poor states would increase. Both types of states were well
represented in the Constituent Assembly, and their divergent interests were
apparent from the outset. At one point the governments of the rich states of
West Bengal and Bombay suggested that they receive tax shares that re-
flected their contributions.? Their proposal would have given these states,
which represent a mere seventeen percent of the total population, sixty-two
percent of all income tax revenues.? Although these suggestions were never
adopted, they revealed the potential problems that could arise if states were
given greater economic powers. Central dominance was thus considered to
be a way to avoid destructive interstate disputes and increase equality across
disparate regions. These deliberations did result in a system in which the na-
tional government makes all the important economic decisions. But it is far
from clear that centralization led to greater equality.
The data reveal important differences in the resources transferred to rich
and poor states; these differences are the greatest in those areas in which the
central government has the greatest discretion. Between 1956 and 1981, in
discretionary transfers made by central ministries, per capita transfers to low
income states were only seventy-seven percent of those to high income states;
middle income states did somewhat better at eighty-six percent. 4 Non-
discretionary expenditure decisions were slightly more equitable but revealed
the same type of disparity: Statutory transfers were twenty percent higher for
middle income than low income states, and plan transfers were ten percent
higher. '
The distribution of revenue surpluses reveals similar disparities. Because of
the division of responsibilities between the Financial and Planning Commis-
sions, a few states, primarily those with higher per capita income, have regularly
been left with substantial revenue surpluses.66 For example, in the 1980s,
poor Bihar's non-Plan surplus was only ten percent of that of rich Punjab.
These surpluses are important because they can they be plowed back into
further development schemes, creating even wider disparities in the future.
Finally, in violation of Condition F5, the Indian Constitution enhances the
central government's economic control over the states still further. 6 Specifi-
cally, the central government has unilateral control over federal provisions in
several important ways. For example, state boundaries can be redrawn by a
simple majority in Parliament.4 Even more importantly, the Indian Constitu-
tion provides that the President of India may dissolve state governments in
three circumstances: threats to national security by external aggressors, a
breakdown of a state's constitution, and financial crisis. 69 This power was en-
visaged for use in infrequent and extreme cases, and it was never invoked be-
tween 1950 and 1960.70 Since 1962, however, its usage has increased, and it
has become highly politicized. Although the financial crisis provision is
rarely invoked (the most common is the second case, breakdown of the Con-
stitution)," greater economic autonomy for states could change this pattern.
64
Krishnaswamy, Gulati & Vaidyanathan, supra note 47, at 195-96.
64
Id. at 195.
6
67 Id.
For a discussion of the Indian federalist system in comparison with those of other
countries, see Durga Das Basu, Introduction to the Constitution of India 49-63 (9th ed.
1982).
61 India Const. pt. I, art. 3.
69See India Const. pt. XVIII, arts. 352, 356, 360.
10Austin, supra note 45, at 216.
71Basu, supra note 67, at 302-16 (discussing emergency powers generally).
1997] Response 1611
If economic strategies in a state ran counter to the interests of the parties in
power at the center, the financial crisis provision could become as politicized
as the breakdown provision.
Despite Rodden/Rose-Ackerman's contention that India provides a good
case with which to assess market-preserving federalism, India's failure to
meet the approach's criteria makes it an inappropriate test for the theory.
The Indian case far better illustrates what occurs in the absence of market-
preserving federalism. The ways in which India has failed to develop are
consistent with the predictions of our theory about federal performance when
the various conditions of market-preserving federalism are not present. To
summarize, India's federalism departs considerably from market-preserving
federalism, failing to meet criteria F2, F4, and F5. Violating F2 grants the
central government sufficient power over the economy to prevent competi-
tion among the states, which results in an absence of state policy experimen-
tation and innovation. It also prohibits the natural matching of policies to lo-
cal conditions, which in turn inhibits specialization and exchange. The
absence of F4 means that states have no financial incentive to be concerned
about the effects of their policies. Finally, India's violation of F5 provides the
national government with additional leverage over the states. In short, In-
dia's federalism retains the hierarchy of federalism but eliminates the main
mechanisms that sustain strong markets. States are not free to set their own
economic policies. Nor can they capture the gains from policies that foster
economic growth.
Although Roddeh/Rose-Ackerman overstate the extent to which India can
be considered a fair current or future example of market-preserving federalism,
they are correct to point out that a certain amount of economic decentralization
and state innovation is taking place there. 2 From this evidence they conclude
that market-preserving federalism cannot succeed in India. Although we be-
lieve that it remains too early to tell, considerable evidence indicates other-
wise. For example, Gujarat and Karnataka are two states that have taken
greatest advantage of economic liberalization. As market-preserving feder-
alism predicts, the provision of local public goods, such as infrastructure and
utilities, has increased in these states, 3 and it can be argued that their advan-
tages over other states, such as an educated labor force and a history of in-
digenous capital, have helped them attract foreign investment.
Rodden/Rose-Ackerman emphasize the importance of political corruption
in distorting prospects for economic growth. They argue that, contrary to the
predictions of market-protecting federalism, corruption is likely to increase in
72
Rodden & Rose-Ackerman, supra note 22, at 1524-25.
"See Charan D. Wadhva, Economic Reforms in India and the Market Economy 127-29
(1994); Energy: Need for a Comprehensive Policy, DATA india, Sept. 24, 1995, at 764,
765; Lukewarm Response to Telecom Tenders, DATA india, July 9,1995, at 556,557.
1612 Virginia Law Review [Vol. 83:1593
developing democracies if economic decentralization occurs, and they use
evidence on civil service transfers to support their claim. 4 Unfortunately for
their argument, the evidence runs counter to their position: Despite high lev-
els of civil service transfers in Gujarat, economic growth is increasing there."
In order to attribute properly the effect of corruption on economic growth,
it is necessary to have a theory of corruption and its effects. Although some
forms of corruption, such as pervasive and widespread rent-seeking, clearly
inhibit investment and growth, others become accepted as another cost of
doing business. In successful Indian states such as Gujarat and Karnataka,
corruption exists, but it is routinized and predictable, and it is not sufficiently
high to deter capital that desires to locate in India.
In conclusion, although the rhetoric of decentralization in India has in-
creased, it remains to be seen whether state autonomy will increase in prac-
tice. In the 1997 budget announcement, the Finance Minister recommended
that central government resources be consolidated into a single fund and
twenty-nine percent be set aside for the states. 7 6 Although this would increase
their current share, it is still far from parity. In addition, the central govern-
ment is clearly moving toward market reform and away from socialist plan-
ning. Nonetheless, it is far from apparent that the central government will
yield primacy to the states.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
74
Rodden & Rose-Ackerman, supra note 22, at 1538.
75
Wadhva, supra note 73, at 127-28. In addition, Rodden/Rose-Ackerman do not distin-
guish between preexisting corruption and the increased corruption they hypothesize would
occur with economic decontrol. Corruption is widespread in Indian politics and admini-
stration, Paul R. Brass, The Politics of India Since Independence 53 (1990), and there may
well be a correlation between the central government's decision to initiate investment and
a state's level of corruption. But the mere existence of high levels of civil service transfers
cannot be used to conclude that corruption is increasing or is presenting a threat to eco-
nomic development and social welfare. The politicization of civil service transfers is not in
question; what remains to be determined is the extent to which these postings systemati-
cally inhibit economic and social welfare across diverse states.
76Finance Minister P. Chidambaram, 1997-1998 Union Budget Speech before the Lok
Sabha (March 1997), available in India on Internet, Budget '97 (visited Sept. 18, 1997)
<http://budget.allindia.comlbudgetlspeechlndLhtm>.
1997] Response 1613