gittings2015
gittings2015
gittings2015
*R. KAJ GITTINGS is an Assistant Professor of Economics at Texas Tech University. IAN M. SCHMUTTE is an
Assistant Professor of Economics in the Terry College of Business, University of Georgia. The research
reported in this article used resources provided by Cornell University’s Social Science Gateway, which
was funded through NSF Grant #0922005. Molly Candon and Isaac Knowles provided excellent research
assistance. We gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments of Chad Cotti, Jed DeVaro, Barry Hirsch,
Julie Hotchkiss, David Mustard, David Neumark, Mike Strain, Ron Warren, and Paul Wolfson. Additional
results and copies of computer programs used to generate the results presented in the article are avail-
able from the authors at kaj.gittings@ttu.edu or schmutte@uga.edu.
1
Nonemployment is distinct from unemployment. Our QWI data track movements of workers into
and out of unemployment insurance (UI) taxable employment. However, the data cannot track whether
workers are out of the labor force, searching for work, or employed in a job not covered by UI.
Related Literature
Drawing in data on market outcomes beyond employment has been effec-
tive for evaluating minimum wage policy. Aaronson, French, and
MacDonald (2008) showed that the relationship between minimum wage
increases and restaurant prices is consistent with a competitive labor market
and not consistent with a model in which employers hold substantial
monopsony power. Neumark, Schweitzer, and Wascher (2004, 2005) found
that the effects of minimum wages on income and poverty are also consis-
tent with the predictions of neoclassical theory. Our findings similarly help
to distinguish competing models of market frictions.
We find that aggregate estimates showing small employment effects of
the minimum wage mask stronger effects across markets when disaggre-
gated by turnover and average nonemployment durations. These findings
are related to other work regarding the importance of treatment effect het-
erogeneity in minimum wage analysis. Neumark and Wascher (2002) and
Yuen (2003) documented variation in the extent to which the minimum
wage binds for teenage workers. Singell and Terborg (2007) and Addison,
Blackburn, and Cotti (2009) provided evidence of heterogeneity in the min-
imum wage effects across industries.
Other articles have directly examined how minimum wage increases
affect worker flows, but ours is the first to directly consider the role of turn-
over in mediating the employment effects of the minimum wage. The basic
of employment and labor market flows (Blanchard and Portugal 2001; Pries
and Rogerson 2005; Gorry 2013). In these models, firms create vacancies
and hire from a pool of unemployed workers. Labor market policies, includ-
ing minimum wages, affect the expected profit from a vacancy but also the
value of remaining in a match for the worker. Evaluating these models in a
cross-country setting is compromised by the difficulty of holding unobserva-
ble institutional features fixed. We avoid this criticism by exploiting varia-
tion across U.S. states in minimum wage policy. Our analysis is therefore
similar in spirit to the work of Autor, Donohue, and Schwab (2006) and
Kugler and Pica (2008) on employment protection legislation. While far
from conclusive, our findings suggest that further efforts to estimate fric-
tional labor market models using panel data on labor market flows, in the
spirit Kiyotaki and Lagos (2007), may be a productive way forward.
Data
We combine data from three sources to study the effect of minimum wages
on employment and labor market flows. From the Quarterly Workforce
Indicators we obtain quarterly measures of teenage worker and job realloca-
tion. We also construct our own panel of state-level minimum wage laws that
include information on the month in which each minimum wage became
effective. Finally, we use state-level aggregates from the Current Population
Survey Outgoing Rotation Groups (CPS-ORG) to generate control variables
at the state level and to establish that the minimum wage is binding for
teenage workers.
2
For a comprehensive overview of the LEHD data and production of the QWI, see Abowd et al.
(2009).
3
We used the R2012Q1 version of the public use Quarterly Workforce Indicators. The raw data are
available for download from http://www.vrdc.cornell.edu/news/data/qwi-public-use-data/.
4
Stable jobs in the QWI are those that last at least one full quarter. Formally, a ‘‘full quarter’’ job is
one in which the worker is employed in that quarter, the quarter before, and the quarter after. The
inference is that the job in question was in progress throughout the entire reference quarter.
5
The variable NH measures periods of nonemployment for new hires as the average number of quar-
ters of nonemployment experienced prior to being hired: average (max [nonemployed quarters of new
hire, 4]). Periods of nonemployment for separations represent the average number of quarters of
nonemployment post separation: average (max [nonemployed quarters of separated worker, 4]).
These accounting identities do not directly affect our analysis, but they
restrict the number of independent sources of variation. Second, the QWI
data are prepared using a novel confidentiality protection procedure of
noise infusion so that small cells can be published rather than suppressed
in the released statistics.
Historical Availability
As illustrated in Figure 1, the historical availability of QWI data varies by
state. Entry dates are determined primarily by the adoption of computer-
ized record-keeping. The earliest states appear in 1990 (MD, IL, WA, and
WI). By 2000 the panel is almost balanced. Since our identification strategy
relies on cross-sectional variation in state minimum wage laws, the entry pat-
tern has some potential to affect our analysis. Our benchmark model uses
all of the available data, but for robustness, we also report estimates
restricted to the post-2000 sample.
Figure 1. Annual State Minimum Wage Laws overlaid with QWI availability
Notes: Cells contain the maximum state minimum wage that exceeds the federal minimum wage in a
given year. The cell contains no entry when the state minimum is never binding. The cells are high-
lighted black if QWI data are available in that year. While the gure is annual, the minimum wage and
QWI data used in our analysis are quarterly. Full data are available from the authors upon request.
measuring employment flows. Given the level of job flows JF, and worker
reallocation, WR, we have
WR + JF
ð1Þ A=
2
WR JF
ð2Þ S=
2
In addition, given job reallocation, JR,
JR + JF
ð3Þ C=
2
JR JF
ð4Þ D=
2
Therefore, we face a choice of whether to directly model worker realloca-
tion (turnover), job reallocation, and job flows, treating accessions, separa-
tions, creations, and destructions as derived, or vice versa. The related
literature models accessions and separations directly, along with creations and
destructions. We focus on turnover and job reallocation, since most of the
movements in hires and separations are highly correlated. For comparability
with existing research, we also report estimates using accessions, separations,
job creation, and job destruction as dependent variables (see Table 5).
Note that A and S are very highly correlated and have nearly identical
level- and time-series variation within states. Figures 2a and 2c plot the least-
squares residuals in worker reallocation and employment from two repre-
sentative states, California and Illinois, after removing state and period
effects. Figures 2b and 2d plot the least-squares residuals in hires and
separations.6 The series for hires and separations track each other excep-
tionally closely, which reflects that most hiring activity is driven by the need
to replace workers who turn over. These observations support our primary
focus on turnover and job reallocation.
6
We show plots from just two states for brevity. Plots of the data from all states are available from the
authors upon request.
Figure 2. Residual Plots: Employment and Worker Reallocation Rate and Separation and
Hiring Rate for California and Illinois
All cells and all QWI statistics are distorted through this process, but the
upshot is that the QWI data are therefore subject to very little cell suppres-
sion relative to other protection schemes and produce a more representative
sample in the published statistics. The QWI include a flag when cells are ‘‘sig-
nificantly distorted’’—that is, when the published value deviates from the con-
fidential value by a specific (confidential) threshold. To ease the reader’s
mind about potential measurement issues, we drop the flagged significantly
distorted cells as a robustness check.7 Because of the high level of aggrega-
tion, our state-level data have no cells flagged as significantly distorted.
Other Concerns
The QWI data also do not currently include reliable or consistent informa-
tion on public-sector employment or self-employment.8 We restrict our
7
It should be noted, however, that it is not clear whether dropping these cells produces better or worse
estimates. In fact, since it is clear that these cells are small to begin with, dropping them generates a sam-
ple selection issue. Regardless, even when doing so, our results are unchanged.
8
As of this writing, the LEHD program is in the process of incorporating the self-employed and public-
sector employment into the QWI, so the limitation to private-sector employment is not permanent.
analysis to jobs for employers that report being privately owned. We also
have no measure of labor utilization at the intensive margin. Like much of
the minimum wage literature, our analysis is restricted, by virtue of the avail-
able data, to the extensive margin of employment adjustment.
9
Figure 1 conveys that the timing of entry into QWI through the 1990s misses some of the state-level
variation in minimum wages. This observation motivates us to perform robustness checks of our main
results by restricting the sample to the more balanced 2000:Q1–2010:Q4 period. The results are largely
consistent across the sample periods.
10
The Merged Outgoing Rotation Group files are available from NBER at http://www.nber.org/
morg/annual/ or by request from the authors.
aggregate the household-level data using the CPS sampling weights, into
the following state-quarter variables: the employment-to-population ratio of
teenagers, the teenage share of the state population aged 16 to 65, the aver-
age wage rate for teenagers (aged 16 to 18), the average wage of adults aged
25 to 54, and the unemployment rate for men aged 25 to 54.11
Dependent Variables
We focus on the following variables:
Descriptive Statistics
Table 1 reports summaries of the state-level data. The entries are means of
state-quarter observations, weighted by the teenage population. The average
worker reallocation rate for teenage workers in the sample is 1.19. That is,
teenage workers turn over a little more than once per quarter. The average
job reallocation rate is 0.38, which means that a little more than a third of
teenage jobs are reallocated from employers reducing their teen workforce
to those expanding it during a quarter. In the QWI, the average ratio of
worker to job reallocations is approximately three. For every job that is real-
located across firms during the quarter, three workers are reallocated.
11
See the online Appendix (http://ilr.sagepub.com/supplemental) for details.
Notes: Summary statistics for the state-level combined QWI and CPS data. The universe is all state-
quarter observations that appear in the QWI. The source for each variable is indicated in its title. All
reported summary statistics are weighted by the teenage population. Standard deviations in
parentheses.
The variable ‘‘teen fraction of stable hires’’ measures the fraction of total
hires during the quarter that become stable jobs. The reported value of
0.34 means that, on average, a third of jobs that teenagers are hired into
are stable, as opposed to temporary, jobs. We also report the corresponding
statistic for separations. Slightly fewer than a third of the jobs that teenage
workers separate from were stable jobs.
The QWI also report the number of quarters of nonemployment
experienced in the previous year by the worker before being hired. For all
separations, they report the number of quarters of nonemployment experi-
enced by the worker subsequent to leaving employment. Consistent with
the strong seasonality of their employment, teenage workers experience on
average 2.63 quarters of nonemployment after separating from jobs and
have experienced 1.81 quarters of nonemployment before being hired.
Empirical Strategy
In this section, we introduce our main empirical strategy, which is an exten-
sion of the state panel data approach used in much of the related literature.
We discuss the assumptions underlying identification and our approach to
assessing robustness to violations of those assumptions. Also in this section,
we demonstrate that 1) increases in the statutory minimum wage materially
affect the wages earned by teenage workers and 2) minimum wages are
binding within and across states and industries for teenagers.
The variable s indexes the state and t indexes the period (quarter).
Variable yst can be one of many labor market outcomes, including employ-
ment, worker reallocation rate, job reallocation rate, or others. State- and
period-specific effects are denoted ms and lt , and ths is a state-specific lin-
ear time trend. We also include vr ðs Þ, t , which allows for the period-specific
shocks to vary by Census region. The function r(s) maps states to its Census
region. The variable RECESSIONt is equal to 1 in periods of recession, as
dated by the NBER, and zero otherwise. The term ps measures any state-
specific effect on the outcome from being in a recessionary period. State-
specific seasonal fluctuations in the outcome are included as xs, q(t) . The
function q(t) maps period to the quarter of the year (I, II, III, IV). We denote
the natural logarithm of the effective minimum wage in states as of the
beginning of period t (first month of the quarter) as lnMWst, and Xst is a vec-
tor including the log adult wage, the share of teenagers in the adult popula-
tion, and the unemployment rate of prime-age males. The residual, nst,
accounts for unobservables affecting state-level outcomes in period t.
where k indicates the NAICS 3-digit industry, and Idks is an indicator equal to
1 when state-industry pair ks is in decile d and zero otherwise. The para-
meter bd is the effect of interest and measures heterogeneity in the respon-
siveness of markets to the minimum wage with respect to the level of
turnover or tightness. The remaining effects are the same as they were in
Equation (5) but defined at the state-industry level here in this model.12
We compute the within-sample average of turnover and tightness sepa-
rately for each state-NAICS 3-digit industry and pool these measures into
deciles for estimation. We adopt several alternative methods that vary the
rule for decile assignment, as described below in the subsection on estima-
tion details. Each measure has advantages and potential drawbacks. As we
show, both lead us to similar though not identical conclusions, opening
fresh questions about the link between minimum wages, employment, and
the competitive structure of teenage labor markets.
Identification
Identification of Equation (5) (and similarly Equation (6)) relies on the
assumption that changes in the minimum wage are not correlated with resi-
dual movements in the outcome. The appropriate model and research
design continues to be the subject of much controversy (Allegretto, Dube,
Reich, and Zipperer 2013; Neumark, Salas, and Wascher 2014). Our bench-
mark specification is highly saturated and controls for many different con-
founding unobservables considered in the recent literature, including state-
specific linear time trends (Addison et al. 2009), region-period shocks
(Meer and West, forthcoming), and state-specific responses to recession
(Allegretto, Dube, and Reich 2011; Neumark et al. 2014). In the empirical
work, we establish that our results are robust to further saturating the model
12
There are 4,269 unique state-NAICS 3-digit industry pairs, and estimating all the effects in Equation
(6) at the NAICS 3-digit level results in a very large number of parameters. Therefore, some of the effects
will be estimated at the state-sector level to ease the computational burden. Those instances are made
explicit in both the text and the tables. Also note that in Equation (6), kd and lt are not identified since
we control for state-industry and region-period effects. The notation is preserved for consistency of pre-
sentation with Equation (5).
13
Note that the number of teenage workers in each state-month cell is relatively small. However, any
measurement error this generates should attenuate our estimates.
Decile
Sample 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Mean
1990–2010 0.32*** 0.43*** 0.33*** 0.22*** 0.17*** 0.10*** 0.04 0.07* 20.00 0.15***
(N = 4,284) (0.055) (0.027) (0.026) (0.024) (0.025) (0.030) (0.033) (0.043) (0.044) (0.039)
1990–2010 (QWI) 0.30*** 0.38*** 0.32*** 0.20*** 0.11*** 0.05 0.01 0.04 20.04 0.11***
(N = 2,754) (0.070) (0.031) (0.037) (0.034) (0.032) (0.040) (0.044) (0.050) (0.051) (0.048)
2000–2010 0.29*** 0.36*** 0.30*** 0.18*** 0.08*** 0.05 20.00 0.06 20.01 0.11**
(N = 2,244) (0.095) (0.031) (0.039) (0.030) (0.033) (0.047) (0.049) (0.040) (0.064) (0.051)
2000–2010 (QWI) 0.27*** 0.35*** 0.29*** 0.17*** 0.08** 0.04 0.01 0.07 20.01 0.10*
(N = 2,058) (0.099) (0.032) (0.040) (0.032) (0.035) (0.050) (0.051) (0.043) (0.067) (0.053)
Notes: Minimum wage elasticities estimated under the state-level panel data model described in the section on employment, turnover, and labor market tightness. The
column lists the dependent variable and the row heading lists the sample restriction. The models are estimated under the benchmark specification that controls for
average adult wage, prime-male unemployment, the share of teenagers in the working-age population, state and period effects, state-specific trends, state-specific season
cycles, state-specific recession effects, and region-period shocks. The models are weighted by the teenage population. The parenthesized values are robust standard errors
clustered at the state level.
*, **, and *** indicate the estimate is statistically different from zero at the 10, 5, and 2.5% level, respectively.
For each industry k, GAPk is the number such that 20% of workers in k
have GAPi GAPk . The first two columns of Table 3 show the distribution
of GAPk across all NAICS 3-digit industries for teenagers and for adult work-
ers. The third and fourth columns show the distribution of GAPsk computed
within state-industry pairs. The fifth and sixth columns, which complement
the state-level bindingness results in Table 2, show the distribution of GAPs
computed by state.14
The entry .04 in the first column indicates that at the third decile of the
industry distribution, 20% of teen workers earn within 4% of the minimum
wage. In the median industry, 20% of teen workers earn within 9% of the
current minimum wage. By contrast, in the median industry, 20% of adult
workers have wages 54% higher than the minimum. At the ninth decile,
14
GAPi is measured in log points and so the entries in Table 3 approximate percentages.
20% of teen workers earn within 22% of the minimum wage. The corre-
sponding figure for adults is 83%. These patterns are nearly identical in the
third and fourth columns, which computed the gap measure for state-
industry pairs. At the state level (which masks the variation in the binding-
ness across industries) at the 90th percentile of the gap distribution across
states, 20% of teens earn within 7% of the minimum wage.
Taken together, the results suggest that while there is indeed more varia-
tion in the bindingness across industries than across states, the minimum
wage has some bite virtually everywhere. The average increase in the mini-
mum wage in our data is 10.2%, with an interquartile range of 4.8–12.0%.
Intuitively, if the true employment elasticity is 0.5, and the minimum wage
increases by 10%, we need at least 5% of the workforce to earn within 10%
of the minimum wage. On the basis of the evidence in the table, this will be
the case in most of the markets in our data. We address any remaining con-
cerns in the subsection below on results and robustness, where we show that
the bindingness of the minimum wage is not correlated with our measures
of turnover and labor market tightness.
Panel A
Panel B
Notes: The dependent variable in each model is listed at the top of the column. The models in every
column also contain state effects, period (quarter of sample) effects, state-specific time trends, effects
for state-specific seasonality, state-specific recession effects, and region-period interactions. The
regressions are estimated by weighted least squares where the weights are the teenage population.
Robust standard errors are clustered by state.
*, **, and *** indicate the coefficient is statistically different from zero at the 10, 5, and 2.5% level,
respectively.
zero employment effect also cannot rule out labor-labor substitution in the
market for teenage workers (Ahn, Arcidiacono, and Wessels 2011; Giuliano
2013).
Moving to the flow variables, minimum wages reduce the rate of worker
reallocation and do not have any effect on job reallocation. That is, the flow
of teenage workers into and out of jobs is reduced by the minimum wage.
One direct consequence of a reduction in worker reallocation is that the
duration of jobs and of unemployment spells should increase even if there
Alternative Specifications
In Table 5, we evaluate the robustness of our initial results. Each row corre-
sponds to a different empirical specification, and each cell reports the esti-
mated elasticity of the minimum wage (and standard error) with respect to
the variable in the column heading. Row 1 restates our benchmark specifi-
cation from Table 4. To facilitate direct comparison with related research,
we add results for separation, hiring, job creation, and job destruction rates.
Rows 2–4 relax our preferred specification. Row 2 is identical to row 1
but drops state-specific seasonality effects. Row 3 drops the state-specific
recession effects from row 2; row 4 further removes the region-period
effects. That is, row 4 is left with controls for state effects, period effects,
and state-specific time trends. Row 5 then saturates the model by adding a
state-recession-unemployment rate interaction to our benchmark specifica-
tion in row 1, which allows for the effect of unemployment to vary by reces-
sion and by recessions within states.
Across these five specifications, the results are broadly consistent in
terms of sign and significance, although the magnitudes of the elasticities
vary. Effects on job reallocation are sensitive to model specification.
Furthermore, consistent with a fall in worker reallocation, minimum wages
reduce hiring and separation rates with a magnitude that is nearly identical
across all specifications. This is to be expected, as Figures 2b and 2d show
that hiring rates and separation rates are nearly identical in the aggregate.
In all but the most saturated specification (row 5), higher minimum wages
are associated with lower rates of job creation, but the elasticity is sensitive
to model specification.15
Some research suggests that minimum wage effects occur with some lag
(Neumark and Wascher 1992; Baker, Benjamin, and Stanger 1999;
Burkhauser et al. 2000). Row 6 shows the elasticity on the average of the
15
Meer and West (forthcoming) found that minimum wages negatively affect job creation when one
looks across all workers in the QWI. When we estimate across all workers, we get similar results. The
results for job creation seem particularly sensitive to controls for the state-specific seasonal component,
but results for job growth across all workers are robust.
Stable Stable
hires separation
Log Employment / Worker Job Hire Separation Job Job
(earnings) population reallocation reallocation Total hires Total separation rate rate creation rate destruction rate
(1) Benchmark 0.10* .02 –.20*** –.06 0.15*** 0.19*** –.19*** –.20*** –.08* –0.03
(0.054) (.074) (.074) (.040) (.041) (.041) (.073) (.077) (.058) (.043)
(2) No state cycles 0.12** –.01 –.26*** –.13*** 0.20*** 0.20*** –.27*** –.25*** –.19* 0.21
(0.058) (.066) (.079) (.058) (.055) (.045) (.077) (.104) (.097) (.097)
(3) No cycles/rec. 0.13** –.01 –.20*** –.10** 0.24*** 0.21*** –.23*** –.16*** –.20* 0.09
(0.054) (.065) (.065) (.050) (.060) (.046) (.073) (.069) (.108) (.092)
(4) No cyc/rec/regxP 0.07 –.05 –.27*** –.10 0.35*** 0.29*** –.28*** –.26*** –.16* 0.02
(0.058) (.086) (.100) (.063) (.048) (.066) (.096) (.108) (.086) (.060)
(5) Saturated 0.15*** .01 –.18** –.04 0.14*** 0.17*** –.17** –.19** –.05 –.02
(0.042) (.069) (.082) (.045) (.051) (.058) (.083) (.083) (.065) (.053)
(6) Lagged MW 0.10* .01 –.16*** –.06 0.18*** 0.33*** –.17*** –.15*** –.10 –.00
(0.056) (.057) (.065) (.036) (.052) (.079) (.070) (.061) (.066) (.007)
(7) County level 0.16*** 0.02 –.24*** –.06*** 0.14*** 0.18*** –.21*** –.28*** –.05*** –0.08**
(0.019) (.038) (.031) (.021) (.023) (.021) (.029) (.038) (.000) (.039)
(8) County two-stage 0.16*** –0.02 –.16*** –.05 0.14*** 0.24*** –.16 –.16*** –.08 –0.02
(0.046) (.075) (.062) (.034) (.040) (.054) (.064) (.063) (.052) (.034)
(9) Benchmark: 2000 + 0.10* .02 –.15*** –.07 0.15*** 0.23*** –.16*** –.13*** –.13 0.04
(0.056) (.093) (.053) (.051) (.049) (.061) (.058) (.053) (.089) (.068)
16
Specifically, we estimate
where i indexes a county in state s, and Zist are county-level log adult earnings and teen share of adult
population. Xst includes the controls from our state-level models. We estimate in two stages. First, we
regress county-level outcomes on time-varying county-level observables to obtain ^zst . Second, we estimate
the state-level model on ^zst . See Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan (2004); Hansen (2007) for details.
Within-state National
Notes: Table entries are elasticities of employment with respect to the minimum wage evaluated at each
decile of the turnover (worker reallocation rate) distribution. The unit of observation is a state-NAICS3-
quarter combination. All models control for state-NAICS3 and region-period effects as well as state-
sector trends. In columns (1)–(3), each observation is assigned into a decile of the within-state
distribution of turnover across 3-digit NAICS industries. Column (1) reports a benchmark specification.
Column (2) adds state-sector-quarter-of-year and state-sector-recession effects. Column (3) drops
observations that were substantially distorted as part of QWI confidentiality protection (flag = 9).
Column (4) uses the specification from column (2) but controls for state-NAICS3-specific trends.
Column (5) uses the specification from column (2) but assigns observations to deciles based on the
position of the 3-digit NAICS code in the national distribution of turnover across industries over the
sample period. The parenthesized values are robust standard errors clustered at the state level.
*, **, and *** indicate the coefficient is statistically different from zero at the 10, 5, and 2.5% level,
respectively.
Within-state National
Notes: Table entries are elasticities of employment with respect to the minimum wage evaluated at each
decile of the average nonemployment duration distribution. The unit of observation is a state-NAICS3-
quarter combination. All models control for state-NAICS3 and region-period effects as well as state-
sector trends. In columns (1)–(3), each observation is assigned into a decile of the within-state
distribution of turnover across 3-digit NAICS industries. Column (1) reports a benchmark specification.
Column (2) adds state-sector quarter-of-year and state-sector recession effects. Column (3) drops
observations that were substantially distorted as part of QWI confidentiality protection (flag=9). Column
(4) uses the specification from column (2) but controls for state-NAICS3-specific trends. Column (5)
uses the specification from column (2) but assigns observations to deciles based on the position of the
3-digit NAICS code in the national distribution of average nonemployment durations across industries
over the sample period. The parenthesized values are robust standard errors clustered at the state level.
*, **, and *** indicate the coefficient is statistically different from zero at the 10, 5, and 2.5% level,
respectively.
minimum wage has a large negative effect. The remainder of this section
details the motivation, estimation, and interpretation of these results.
Motivational Framework
Our investigation is motivated by search-theoretic wage-posting models pop-
ular in the analysis of minimum wage policy (Manning 2003, 2006). Markets
Estimation Details
To estimate Equation (6), we begin with QWI data that are disaggregated by
state and NAICS 3-digit industry. For the period 1990 to 2010, this yields
244,332 unique state-industry-quarter observations. For each of the 4,269
state-industry combinations that appear in the data, we measure the average
level of turnover and the average nonemployment duration of separations
throughout the sample. For each state separately, we compute deciles from
the state-specific distribution of average industry turnover (or average non-
employment duration) and assign each state-industry-quarter observation in
the original data set to the corresponding (time-invariant) decile. This
method emphasizes variation across industry in our proxy measures for labor
market conditions but is flexible enough to allow, say, the food service indus-
try in New Jersey to occupy a different position in the turnover distribution
than in California (should that be the case). Furthermore, it captures the
fact that workers are more likely to turn over and reallocate within markets
that are geographically close together. Last, these decile assignments are
constant over time. To the extent that turnover may be endogenous to inno-
vations in the minimum wage and employment, our non-time-varying decile
assignments mechanically break that relationship in these data.
This procedure coarsens the data on two dimensions and is effective in
eliminating the part of variation in our measures of turnover and tightness
that is associated with the minimum wage—the pairwise correlation
between the state-industry average turnover and the contemporary mini-
mum wage is 20.0013 and statistically insignificant. However, we show addi-
tional results that coarsen the data even further and assign deciles based on
the national industry distribution of turnover. Here, each industry is
assigned a decile based on the average turnover in that industry over time
and across states. This second method should further mitigate concerns
about endogeneity, but it also has drawbacks. Specifically, it combines geo-
graphic variation in turnover across states with variation across industries
within a state. Also, each particular industry is forced to have the same dec-
ile assignment in every state. If the oil and gas industry in Texas has a differ-
ent level of turnover (or duration of nonemployment) than the oil and gas
industry in Oregon, then this decile assignment rule imposes measurement
error into our estimates. Our qualitative result remains the same when we
use this coarser measure, though the monotonicity in the estimated employ-
ment effect of the minimum wage across deciles is weaker, which would be
consistent with measurement error associated with pooling state-industry
pairs with different levels of turnover.
We have also used two alternative methods to assign deciles that yield the
same pattern of results. One assigns each state-industry a time-invariant dec-
ile based on the average turnover distribution over all state-industry pairs
(not just over industries within the same state as in our primary measure
described above). We have also performed estimates using deciles that vary
over time based on current period turnover. This design is more flexible
but raises concerns about endogeneity, since Table 4 shows that minimum
wages affect both the contemporaneous level of turnover and periods of
nonemployment for separations.17
Estimating Equation (6) where all of the unobserved heterogeneity is spe-
cific to each state-3-digit NAICS industry is computationally demanding.
The NAICS collapses 3-digit industries into a set of 20 major sectors, and
most of the time-series within-state variation is common to these major sec-
tors. Our main results fit trends, seasonality, and recession effects for each
state-sector (NAICS major sector) effects rather than state-industry (NAICS
3-digit industries). For robustness, we also estimate a specification with state-
3-digit industry trends with seasonality and recession effects that are state-
sector specific.
17
The results described in this paragraph are available upon request. We considered assigning deciles
based on measures of turnover and tightness for non-teenage workers as well. However, the non-teen or
adult measures are poor proxies for their teen counterparts for two reasons: 1) adult and teen turnover
are weakly correlated, and 2) non-teen turnover is correlated with the employment of teenage workers,
which generates the same endogeneity concerns as if one would use teen turnover to begin with.
and positive employment effects where turnover is high. Table 7 shows the
same pattern for the duration of nonemployment for separations. When
durations of nonemployment are short, higher minimum wages yield lower
employment; but when durations of nonemployment are high, there are
positive employment effects.
Column (4) of Table 6 controls for trends at the state-industry level. We
find the negative employment effects in the lower two deciles are attenu-
ated relative to the first three columns that control for state-sector trends.
However, the estimated elasticities at deciles 3 and 4 become more negative,
at 2.425 and 2.497, and statistically significant at the 5 and 10% level. The
results in the upper deciles remain roughly the same, and, if anything,
increase in magnitude.
Nearly identical changes occur in column (4) of Table 7, which adds
state-industry trends (rather than state-sector trends) to our model with het-
erogeneity by decile of nonemployment duration. The employment effect
in decile 1 becomes smaller and insignificant. However, the effect in deciles
2 and 4 becomes more negative (20.791 and 20.977) and significant at the
5 and 2.5% level. In this model the estimated positive effects at higher dec-
iles become larger and increase in statistical significance.
Column (5) in Table 6 reports estimates using the national distribution of
average industry turnover. The overall pattern of elasticity estimates is similar
to the corresponding specification in column (2) but less monotonic, and
some statistical significance is lost. As discussed above, this measure likely
introduces additional measurement error in the decile assignments. Two of
the bottom three deciles in this column are negative and statistically signifi-
cant; deciles 4, 5, and 6 are not statistically different from zero; and the esti-
mated elasticities for deciles 7, 8, 9, and 10 are all positive, three of which are
statistically different from zero. One interpretation is that the noise in this
pattern relative to the results in column (2) arises because column (5) pools
state-industry pairs with different levels of turnover. Column (5) in Table 7
similarly shows that using the national distribution of average industry dura-
tions of nonemployment for separations yields slightly noisier estimates but
does not meaningfully change the results or main conclusions.
Earnings Effects
Table 8 reports estimates of the effect of minimum wage increases on aver-
age earnings of workers employed at the end of the quarter. The model in
Table 8 is analogous to column (2) in Tables 6 and 7. In panel A, higher
minimum wages do not appear to have any differential effect on earnings
across markets exhibiting different levels of turnover. However, panel B
shows that increases in the minimum wage reduce earnings in markets with
low average duration on nonemployment and increase earnings in markets
with high durations of nonemployment.
The expected effect on earnings for retained workers is not straightfor-
ward. If a reduction in hours worked (intensive margin) dominates the
Panel A Panel B
1 0.018 1 20.168***
(.0824) (.0616)
2 0.032 2 20.125***
(.0790) (.0612)
3 0.015 3 20.074
(.0758) (.0603)
4 0.035 4 20.032
(.0699) (.0619)
5 0.043 5 0.048
(.0786) (.0697)
6 0.078 6 0.072
(.0646) (.0825)
7 0.048 7 0.104
(.0780) (.0646)
8 0.052 8 0.161**
(.0906) (.0910)
9 0.023 9 0.191***
(.0724) (.0710)
10 20.107 10 0.113
(.0800) (.0863)
No. of observations 237,415 No. of observations 237,415
Notes: Table entries are earnings elasticities with respect to the minimum wage. In Panel A, the
elasticities are evaluated at each decile of the turnover (worker reallocation rate) distribution. In Panel
B, the elasticities are evaluated at deciles of the distribution of average nonemployment duration for
separations. The unit of observation is a state-NAICS3-quarter combination. Parenthesized values are
robust standard errors clustered at the state level. Both models include state-industry and region-period
effects and state-sector trends.
*, **, and *** indicate the coefficient is statistically different from zero at the 10, 5, and 2.5% level,
respectively.
extent to which the higher minimum wages increase wages, then we would
expect a reduction in average earnings when minimum wages rise. If the
wage increase due to an increase in the minimum wage dominates any
reduction in hours worked, then we would expect average earnings to
increase. Of course, employers can also keep their wage bill constant by
reducing hours to offset the higher unit labor costs, and there would be no
effect on earnings due to higher minimum wages.
Within-state National
Notes: Table entries are employment elasticities with respect to the minimum wage evaluated at cross-
classifications of turnover by duration of nonemployment for separations. For example, Low WRR/Low
NSEP indicates a state-NAICS3 combination that has average turnover and periods of nonemployment
for separating workers below their state-specific or national medians. The unit of observation is a state-
NAICS3-quarter combination. All models include state-NAICS3 and region-period effects.
Parenthesized values are robust standard errors clustered at the state level. The columns are organized
as in Tables 6 and 7.
*, **, and *** indicate the coefficient is statistically different from zero at the 10, 5, and 2.5% level,
respectively.
proxies do not necessarily group the same industries and that a low turn-
over subsector does not necessarily also have short periods of nonemploy-
ment. The two mediating variables we construct measure complementary,
but distinct, facets of the labor market.
We can push our proxy measures of labor market conditions a little fur-
ther to get at these questions. We do so by jointly classifying markets based
on both the level of turnover and the duration of nonemployment. In doing
so, we classify a given state industry across two dimensions of heterogeneity
rather than one. Specifically, we group state-industry pairs into ‘‘low’’ and
‘‘high’’ turnover and ‘‘low’’ and ‘‘high’’ nonemployment duration, by com-
bining the bottom five deciles and top five deciles. This yields a four-way
classification of state industries into 1) low turnover and low durations of
nonemployment, 2) low turnover and high durations of nonemployment,
3) high turnover and low duration of nonemployment, and 4) high turn-
over and high duration of nonemployment.
Table 9 presents the results of estimating heterogeneity in the response
of employment to the minimum wage according to our two-dimensional
classification. The models are otherwise identical to those reported in
Tables 6 and 7. We observe that minimum wages are associated with nega-
tive employment effects only in markets where turnover is low and
durations of nonemployment are short, consistent with the results for both
proxies separately. Minimum wages have no statistically or quantitatively
meaningful employment effect in markets with both low turnover and long
durations of nonemployment. However, high-turnover markets with short
durations of nonemployment exhibit positive employment effects, perhaps
indicating that positive employment effects associated with high turnover
dominate negative effects associated with low employment duration.
Markets with high turnover and long durations of nonemployment have
positive employment effects (also consistent with the results for both proxies
separately).
Within state industries that have low turnover (low WRR), the employ-
ment effect of the minimum wage is more negative where nonemployment
durations are low (20.490 in low nonemployment duration markets versus
0.021 in high-duration markets). Conditional on short average nonemploy-
ment durations (low NSEP), the employment effect of the minimum wage
is higher where turnover is higher. The one case in which the basic pattern
fails to hold is in high-turnover markets. Conditional on high turnover, the
employment effect is positive and statistically significant in low NSEP mar-
kets (0.311) but slightly lower in high NSEP markets (0.236).
Our previous results suggest turnover may primarily represent a cost
channel for firms in a particular sector, whereas average nonemployment
duration is a measure of labor market conditions facing the industry in a
particular state. This analysis, which jointly classifies markets based on both
turnover and nonemployment duration, indicates that negative employ-
ment effects most likely occur when the outside market is extremely com-
petitive and adjustment costs are low. That is, minimum wages induce
unemployment where labor market conditions are most like a ‘‘spot mar-
ket.’’ Conversely, minimum wages appear to generate positive employment
effects only when turnover is high, re-emphasizing our interpretation of that
measure as reflecting the costs of adjusting labor.
18
Specifically, the leads and lags are added to the model represented by column (2) in Table 7.
19
Sorkin (forthcoming) argued that true long-run effects are hard to identify using U.S. data.
20
Controlling for state-sector quadratic trends does not substantially change our results relative to the
benchmark specification with state-sector linear trends.
21
We choose 10% because it is the size of the average minimum wage increase in our sample.
minimum wage still binds in 84.6% of these markets. The results are simi-
larly strong for deciles of nonemployment duration.
Columns (2) and (4) report the average share of teens for whom the
minimum wage binds in each state industry. This is a measure of the num-
ber of teenagers we expect to be affected by a minimum wage increase of
10%. For turnover (column 2), these estimates range from 26.4 to 46.8% of
teenagers. For nonemployment duration, they range from 28.4 to 47.8%.
While there is variation in these numbers, economically speaking they illus-
trate that minimum wage increases will have a bite in all deciles.
Furthermore, what variation exists in bindingness across our measures of
tightness is not strongly associated with the pattern of employment effects
we observe in the previous tables.
Finally, some caution is required in interpreting Table 10. The number
of teens in the CPS in a particular state and a particular industry is very
small from month to month and year to year. To construct Table 10, we
must pool information across years. Hence, our statistics may conflate peri-
ods in which the minimum wage is very binding and those in which it is not
binding at all.
Conclusions
A troubling gap exists between theoretical models of the effects of the mini-
mum wage and empirical evidence. We suspect this is because many aspects
of the labor market response have been hidden from view. New data from
the Census Bureau’s Quarterly Workforce Indicators combine geographic,
industry, and demographic detail on the stock and flow of employment and
earnings. The detail in these data facilitates a much finer analysis of the
many margins along which labor markets respond to changes in the mini-
mum wage. The primary contributions of this article have been to use the
QWI 1) to further characterize the effect of minimum wage policy on labor
market dynamics, particularly turnover and job reallocation, and 2) to docu-
ment heterogeneity in the effects of the minimum wage across industries
characterized by different labor market conditions.
Theoretically, the effect of the minimum wage on employment is a func-
tion of the degree of competition in the market and the ability of the firm
to easily adjust its labor input. We use two variables in the QWI that proxy
for these market and employer characteristics: turnover and the average
duration of nonemployment for separating workers. Both measures capture
heterogeneity across industries in the response of employment to the mini-
mum wage. The employment effects of an increase in the minimum wage
are strong and negative in markets with low turnover and in markets with
short durations of nonemployment for workers who separate from their
jobs. Conversely, increases in the minimum wage are associated with
increases in employment in high-turnover markets and in markets with high
nonemployment durations. These results are robust to various specifications
and are not driven by variation in bindingness of the minimum wage.
Our results are consistent with the view that shorter durations of non-
employment correspond to more competitive markets. In the most competi-
tive markets, we expect the data to behave similarly to the way the
neoclassical demand model predicts—increases in the minimum wage bring
decreased employment. In the least competitive markets, conditions may be
closer to dynamic oligopsony, in which it is possible that higher minimum
wages may increase employment. Our results that estimate the effect of the
minimum wage on employment, conditional on the duration of nonemploy-
ment, conform to these stylized predictions.
The mechanism by which turnover mediates the effect of the minimum
wage on employment is less clear. The pattern we observe—negative
employment effects in low-turnover markets—runs counter to a wage-
posting model in which high-turnover firms are at the bottom of the job lad-
der. However, our results by turnover are consistent with a model in which
turnover represents a cost channel for firms. If turnover is very costly, then
minimum wages hikes can ‘‘pay for themselves’’ by reducing turnover. This
implication emerges from a simple model of adjustment costs based on
Manning (2006). In this environment, our observed pattern would be
expected—negative employment effects where turnover is low and positive
effects where turnover is high.
Additional work is needed to better explain the link between turnover,
nonemployment durations, minimum wage policy, and employment. Our
results indicate that heterogeneity in the effects of the minimum wage are
meaningfully summarized by turnover and durations of nonemployment,
but it remains an open question whether these variables proxy for variation
in conditions within, or across, local labor markets, and whether they proxy
for variation in market frictions, supply conditions, or production
technology.
References
Aaronson, Daniel, Eric French, and James MacDonald. 2008. The minimum wage, restaurant
prices, and labor market structure. Journal of Human Resources 43(3): 688–720.
Abowd, John M., Kaj Gittings, Kevin L. McKinney, Bryce Stephens, Lars Vilhuber, and Simon
Woodcock. 2012. Dynamically consistent noise infusion and partially synthetic data as con-
fidentiality protection measures for related time-series. 2012 Research Conference Papers.
Federal Committee on Statistical Methodology, Office of Management and Budget.
Abowd, John M., Bryce E. Stephens, Lars Vilhuber, Fredrik Andersson, Kevin L. McKinney,
Marc Roemer, and Simon Woodcock. 2009. The LEHD infrastructure files and the cre-
ation of the Quarterly Workforce Indicators. In Timothy Dunne, J. Bradford Jensen, and
Mark J. Robers (Eds.), Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data, pp. 149–230. Chi-
cago: University of Chicago Press.
Abraham, Katharine G., John Haltiwanger, Kristin Sandusky, and James Spletzer. 2009.
Exploring differences in employment between household and establishment data. Work-
ing Paper No. 09-09. Center for Economic Studies, U.S. Census Bureau.
Addison, John T., McKinley L. Blackburn, and Chad D. Cotti. 2009. Do minimum wages raise
employment? Evidence from the U.S. retail-trade sector. Labour Economics 16(4): 397–408.
Ahn, Tom, Peter Arcidiacono, and Walter Wessels. 2011. The distributional impacts of mini-
mum wage increases when both labor supply and labor demand are endogenous. Journal
of Business & Economic Statistics 29(1): 12–23.
Allegretto, Sylvia, Arindrajit Dube, and Michael Reich. 2011. Do minimum wages really
reduce teen employment? Accounting for heterogeneity and selectivity in state panel
data. Industrial Relations 50(2): 205–40.
Allegretto, Sylvia, Arindrajit Dube, Michael Reich, and Ben Zipperer. 2013. Credible research
designs for minimum wage studies. Working Paper. Institute for Research on Labor and
Employment, Institute of Industrial Relations, University of California Berkeley.
Autor, David H., John J. Donohue III, and Stewart J. Schwab. 2006. The costs of wrongful-
discharge laws. Review of Economics and Statistics 88(2): 211–31.
Baily, Martin N. 1982. Comment on ‘‘The minimum wage and job turnover in markets for
young workers.’’ In Richard B. Freeman and David A. Wise (Eds.), The Youth Labor Market
Problem: Its Nature, Causes, and Consequences, pp. 494–97. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Baker, Michael, Dwayne Benjamin, and Shuchita Stanger. 1999. The highs and lows of the
minimum wage effect: A time-series cross-section study of the Canadian law. Journal of
Labor Economics 17(2): 318–50.
Bertrand, Marianne, Esther Duflo, and Sendhil Mullainathan. 2004. How much should we
trust differences-in-differences estimates? Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(1): 249–75.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Pedro Portugal. 2001. What hides behind an unemployment rate:
Comparing Portuguese and U.S. labor markets. American Economic Review 91(1): 187–207.
Brochu, Pierre, and David A. Green. 2013. The impact of minimum wages on labour market
transitions. Economic Journal 123(573): 1203–35.
Burkhauser, Richard V., Kenneth A. Couch, and David C. Wittenburg. 2000. A reassessment
of the new economics of the minimum wage literature with monthly data from the Cur-
rent Population Survey. Journal of Labor Economics 18(4): 653–80.
Dube, Arindrajit, T. William Lester, and Michael Reich. 2010. Minimum wage effects across
state borders: Estimates using contiguous counties. Review of Economics and Statistics 92(4):
945–64.
——. 2016. Minimum wage shocks, employment flows and labor market frictions. Journal of
Labor Economics 34(3).
Giuliano, Laura. 2013. Minimum wage effects on employment, substitution, and the teenage
labor supply: Evidence from personnel data. Journal of Labor Economics 31(1): 155–94.
Gorry, Aspen. 2013. Minimum wages and youth unemployment. European Economic Review 64:
57–75.
Hansen, Christian B. 2007. Generalized least squares inference in panel and multilevel mod-
els with serial correlation and fixed effects. Journal of Econometrics 140(2): 670–94.
Hirsch, Barry T., Bruce Kaufman, and Tetyana Zelenska. 2015. Channels of labor market
adjustment: Analysis of the 2007–2009 federal minimum wage increases. Industrial Rela-
tions: A Journal of Economy and Society 54(2): 199–239.
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and Ricardo Lagos. 2007. A model of job and worker flows. Journal of
Political Economy 115(5): 770–819.
Kugler, Adriana, and Giovanni Pica. 2008. Effects of employment protection on worker and
job flows: Evidence from the 1990 Italian reform. Labour Economics 15(1): 78–95.
Lazear, Edward P., and James R. Spletzer. 2012. Hiring, churn, and the business cycle. Ameri-
can Economic Review 102(3): 575–79.
Manning, Alan. 2003. Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
——. 2006. A generalised model of monopsony. Economic Journal 116(508): 84–100.
Meer, Jonathan, and Jeremy West. Forthcoming. Effects of the minimum wage on employ-
ment dynamics. Journal of Human Resources.
Mortensen, Dale T., and Christopher A. Pissarides. 1994. Job creation and job destruction in
the theory of unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 61(3): 397–415.
Neumark, David, J. M. Ian Salas, and William Wascher. 2014. Revisiting the minimum wage-
employment debate: Throwing out the baby with the bathwater? ILR Review 67: 608–48.
Neumark, David, Mark Schweitzer, and William Wascher. 2004. Minimum wage effects
throughout the wage distribution. Journal of Human Resources 39(2).
——. 2005. The effects of minimum wages on the distribution of family incomes: A nonpara-
metric analysis. Journal of Human Resources 40(4): 867–94.
Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 1992. Employment effects of minimum and submini-
mum wages: Panel data on state minimum wage laws. Industrial and Labor Relations Review
46(1): 55–81.
——. 2002. State-level estimates of minimum wage effects: New evidence and interpretations
from disequilibrium methods. Journal of Human Resources 37(1): 35–62.
Portugal, Pedro, and Ana R. Cardoso. 2006. Disentangling the minimum wage puzzle: An
analysis of worker accessions and separations from a longitudinal matched employer-
employee data set. Journal of the European Economic Association 4(5): 988–1013.
Pries, Michael, and Richard Rogerson. 2005. Hiring policies, labor market institutions, and
labor market flows. Journal of Political Economy 113(41): 811–39.
Sabia, Joseph J. 2009. The effects of minimum wage increases on retail employment and
hours: New evidence from monthly CPS data. Journal of Labor Research 30(1): 75–97.
Singell, Larry D., and James R. Terborg. 2007. Employment effects of two Northwest mini-
mum wage initiatives. Economic Inquiry 45(1): 40–55.
Sorkin, Isaac. 2015. Are there long-run effects of the minimum wage? Review of Economic
Dynamics 18(2): 306–33.
Thompson, Jeffrey P. 2009. Using local labor market data to re-examine the employment
effects of the minimum wage. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 62(3): 343–66.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2006. Current Population Survey: Design and methodology. Technical
Paper No. 66. U.S. Census Bureau.
Yuen, Terence. 2003. The effect of minimum wages on youth employment in Canada: A
panel study. Journal of Human Resources 38(3): 647–72.