Paper 40
Paper 40
Paper 40
‘Why wasn’t France First?’ The Industrial Revolution in England and France: New
England1 in 1500 was lightly urbanised and predominantly agricultural by the standards of the
more developed regions of Eurasia such as the Low Countries and parts of China. Yet, when
Etienne Perlin, a Parisian medical student, visited England in the early 1550s, he witnessed an
opulent society that compared favourably with the France of Henri II and other European
nations he knew of.2 He describes a very prosperous and mercantile nation boasting large
supplies of precious metals and manufactured goods: leather, woollens, draperies, metalware,
tin and lead, as well as many fisheries.3 Perlin also noticed that living standards were high with
meat-rich diets, especially for artisans such as hatmakers and carpenters who enjoyed much
higher real wages than in other parts of Europe.4 White bread, he added, was superior to that
of the French for a similar price,5 and he was very impressed by the fact that houses even in the
smaller towns had several glassed windows, and that all the inns he visited on his tour were
well furnished and decorated, with embroidered cushions and flowers.6 Perlin’s evidence is
1
This paper concerns not Britain but England and Wales. Scotland has been excluded from the analysis because
at the time of writing, no data are available on the occupational structure of Scotland before the middle of the
nineteenth century. With Scots representing only 10-15 per cent of the population of mainland Britain this
omission is not likely to fundamentally distort the picture of the British economy that emerges on the basis of
data from England and Wales alone.
2
It is not entirely clear what part of England he travelled through, but he seems at least to have travelled from
Dover to London and then to Bristol, Cambridge, and Newcastle on his way to Scotland.
3
Estienne Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin
(1558), 17. ‘il y a force argent, & l’or y est gros, & il y a force cuirs, laines, draps, métaux, bon estain, plomb,
force pescheries, qui leur vallent grand deniers.’
4
Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin, 17–19.
‘Les gens d’iceluy lieu sont de grande chère & ayme fort à bancqueter & vous verries force riches tavernes, &
les taverniers qui ont coustumierement grosses bourses, ou il y a trois ou quatre bourserõs plaine d’argent, par
ce moyen pouvons considerer que le pays est fort argēteux & que les gēs de metier gaignent plus en une
semaine que ceux d’allemaigne ou d’espaigne en un mois. Car vous verris des chappeliers & menuisiers
artisans iouer leu escu à la paume ordinairement, ce que ne voyes pas en un autre lieu ordinairement, &
principalement à un iour ouvrier. Et en une taverne faire grãde chere plus souvent que tous les iours avec
connilz, leveraux, & toutes sortes de viande.’
5
Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin, 22. ‘ils
usent du pain bien plus blanc que en la France, tellement qu’il estoit de mon tēps en aussi bon marché qu’en
France.’
6
Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin, 20.‘Par
tout les maison quasi de toutes les villes quāt est aux gens de mesiter : & sont toutes icelles maisons comme les
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 2
certainly anecdotal, but his account shows that for a sixteenth-century European traveller,
England was already notable for its commercial and industrial development and for its
Comparing mid-eighteenth-century France and England – the two main European powers,
well-endowed geopolitical rivals with similar claims to the hall of fame of the Scientific
Revolution7, and profitable colonial empires8 – has been a regular feature in studies looking at
the causes of the Industrial Revolution. If something as dramatic as the Industrial Revolution
‘happened’ in England during the second half of the eighteenth century, it might seem logical
to wonder why a similar revolution did not take hold in France at the same time, or even earlier?
After all, France was the most populous country in Europe, had more than its fair share of all
European scientists, boasted the iconic vehicle of knowledge diffusion (the Encyclopédie), and
was undeniably a great commercial power whose craftsmen and state-supported Manufactures
Royales produced some of the most sought-after goods across wealthy European households.
Yet, comparing the two countries between 1700 and 1750 as a way to elucidate the causes of
the Industrial Revolution supposes: i) that the Industrial Revolution was an event whose causal
chain was very short (the first half of the eighteenth century), and ii) that England and France
were at a similar level of development by 1750, which would make it equally likely for either
The first point had almost no intellectual support until after WWII. The early scholarship
on the Industrial Revolution, from Toynbee to Mantoux, and up to Clapham saw it as the
gradual (and in Clapham’s case incomplete) culmination of a long process of Smithian growth
ouvrerois des barbiers de France tāt par hault, que par bas, & verries a leurs ouvreoirs & fenestres tant de ville
que de villages forces fleurs, & aux tavernes forces foin dessus les planchiers de boys, & forces oreillies de
tapisseries sur lesquelz les voyagers se assisent’.
7
Peter (ed ) Mathias, Science & Society 1600 - 1900 (Cambridge, 1972), 81; Joel Mokyr and Professor of
Economics and History Joel Mokyr, The Economics of the Industrial Revolution (1985), 128.
8
Guillaume Daudin, ‘Commerce et prospérité : la France au XVIIIe siècle. 2e éd.’, (2011).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 3
and institutional and structural transformations.9 On this view, by 1750 most of the divergence
between England and the rest of Europe, including France, had already happened, and as
Mantoux put it: ‘the Industrial Revolution was no accident’. Looking at the causes for
England’s primacy necessarily required these leading early historians to turn their scholarly
Yet, in the black and white ideological world of the post war, the wisdom of these earlier
views got lost in the clamour for brash, politically amenable conclusions. In the nascent field
case in point in the (academic) confrontations of the Cold War to prove the superiority and
historical ineluctability of Western capitalism. The origin of this battle for history really got
going with early Modernisation theorists, and especially the publication of W.W. Rostow’s
Backwardness, and the work of economic historians such as David Landes, and Rostow again,
with a more ambitious comparative restatement of his stage theory in How it all began.10
Regardless of the merit of their explanations and the nature of their analyses – which have been
the subject of countless articles and pugnacious debates – all these authors share the assumption
that England and France were at comparable levels of economic development in say 1750,
economists, economic historians and statisticians greatly improved the empirical basis for the
9
Arnold Toynbee, Lectures on the Industrial Revolution in England (London, 1884); Paul Mantoux, La
Révolution Industrielle Au XVIIIe Siècle (Paris, 1906), IX; J. H. Clapham, An Economic History of Modern
Britain : Machines and National Rivalries (1887-1914) with an Epilogue 1914-1929 (1938).
10
W. W. Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth. A Non-Communist Manifesto (pp. x. 178. University Press,
1960); Alexander Gerschenkron, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (1962); David S. Landes,
The Unbound Prometheus : Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to
the Present (Cambridge, 1969); Walt Whitman Rostow, How It All Began: Origins of the Modern Economy
(1975).
11
Charles Poor Kindleberger, Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1851-1950 (1964).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 4
constructed long series of key economic indicators (including GDP) constructed using the
National Accounting framework developed between the 1920s and the 1940s and adopted by
most governments in the 1950s for macroeconomic surveying and forecasting. In order to apply
(Keynesian) macroeconomic models to the past, one only had to re-construct series from
existing statistical data and piecemeal historical records. Following in the footsteps of Nobel-
laureate Simon Kuznets, statisticians and economic historians across the Atlantic started to
produce similar retrospective series for their countries. Phyllis Dean and W.A. Coal published
their monumental British Economic Growth from 1688 to 1959 in 1962, arguing that the British
economy experienced its first sustained growth episode between 1760-1850, the ‘classical
period’ of the Industrial Revolution.12 During these ‘years of miracles’ (Mokyr), major
technological innovations came in a continuous stream and drove economic growth in a way
goods and increased their quality while vastly expanding their supply, from the refining of
coke-smelted iron with coal to the mechanisation of spinning and weaving and the development
of the steam engine. In this approach to development what is taken as the starting point for this
miraculous story is, in fact, the tail end of a much longer technological evolution associated
with using coal for industrial processes in England. This included: lime burning, by 1400,
textile dying, by 1500, salt making, by 1550, brewing, before 1600, glass manufacturing, in
1612, malting, by 1650, firing pottery, in the 1670s, lead smelting, also in the 1670s, copper
smelting, in 1676, iron smelting, in 1709, and finally iron refining, in 1784.14
12
Phyllis Deane and William Alan Cole, British Economic Growth, 1688-1959: Trends and Structure (1962).
13
Joel Mokyr, The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress (1992).
14
J. R. Harris, The British Iron Industry 1700-1850 (Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire, 1988); John Hatcher,
The History of the British Coal Industry: Volume 1: Before 1700: Towards the Age of Coal (Oxford, 1993).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 5
In France, too, efforts to produce long series of economic data got going after the war.
Collaborative efforts by historians (Fernand Braudel and Ernest Labrousse) and economists
(Jan Marczewski and Francois Perroux) led to the publications of some series by Perroux and
Marczewski in 1947, but the interdisciplinary cooperation proved rather short-lived, and
historians adopted their own vision of quantitative history – called histoire sérielle - that did
not fit in the National Accounting framework.15 It was from the mid 1960s and until the 1980s
that new national accounts series were finally produced by Tibor Markovitch, Jean-Claude
Toutain and Maurice Lévy-Leboyer.16 Having retrospective series for both France and Britain
suddenly made possible a new quantitative approach to the past performance of the two
economies, and Marczeswki’s ‘Le produit physique de l'économie française de 1789 à 1913:
comparaison avec la Grande-Bretagne’, was the first to engage in this systematic comparative
exercise.17
The subject of the economic performance of France over the long nineteenth century and
the speed and nature of its industrialisation thus briefly became a hot topic for Anglophone
economic historians in the 1980s. The publication of a series of revisionist accounts, which
presented a much more optimistic outlook of the French economy, led to some striking
conclusions regarding its economic performance both in the eighteenth century (seen to be on
par with Britain by Richard Roehl and Rondo Cameron), and in the nineteenth century (over-
15
François Perroux, Pierre Uri, and Jan Marczewski, Le Revenu National (Paris, 1947).
16
Jean Marczewski and Jean-Claude Toutain, ‘Histoire quantitative de l’économie française.’, Cahiers de
l’Institut de science économique appliquée. Série AF, Histoire quantitative de l’économie française, i (1961);
Tihomir J. Markovitch, Histoire quantitative de l’économie française: L’industrie française de 1789 à 1964.
Analyse des faits, 3 vols (Paris, France, 1966); Jean-Claude Toutain, Histoire Quantitative de l’économie
Française. IX, Transports En France 1830-1965 (Paris, 1967); Maurice Lévy-Leboyer and François
Bourguignon, L’Économie Française Au XIXe Siècle (Paris, 1985), 185 F; Jean-Claude Toutain, La Production
Agricole de La France de 1810 à 1990 Croissance, Productivité, Structures (Grenoble, 1993).
17
Jean Marczewski and Tihomir J. Markovitch, ‘Le produit physique de l’économie française de 1789 à 1913
(comparaison avec la Grande-Bretagne)’, Les Cahiers de l’Institut de science économique appliquée, clxiii
(1965).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 6
performing compared to Britain by Patrick O’Brien and Caglar Keyder).18 These positive
interpretations found that France growth trends rather than absolute levels. It is after all easier
to grow faster further from the frontier (catch-up growth), and France experienced an earlier
demographic transition and relatively slower population growth in the nineteenth century,
Since then, however, most economic historians have walked back on these judgments.
Revised occupational and output data have largely undone the positive assessment of French
economic performance both in terms of trend and levels, and following Nick Crafts, François
Crouzet, Maurice Lévy-Leboyer and François Bourguignon, Paul Bairoch, and Jean-Pierre
Dormois, all settled for a moderately pessimistic diagnosis for France in the nineteenth
century.19 One point worth noting is that to date a wide disagreement remains on the
quantification and the performance of the French economy in the late nineteenth century. With
four competing GDP series (Toutain, Lévy-Leboyer and Bourguignon, Dormois, and Ridolfi)
and 50 years of impassioned discussions from which no consensus has emerged among
economic historians, it is important to take any definitive judgement based on any one of these
series with a light pinch of salt.20 In recent years, especially in answer to R.C. Allen’s
18
Rondo Cameron and Charles E. Freedeman, ‘French Economic Growth: A Radical Revision’, Social Science
History, vii (1983); Richard Roehl, ‘French Industrialization: A Reconsideration’, Explorations in Economic
History, xiii (1976); Patrick Karl O’Brien and Caglar Keyder, Economic Growth in Britain and France, 1780-
1914 : Two Paths to the Twentieth Century (London, 1978).Bairoch’s series (1978) also reflect this positive
assessment of French economic growth relative to Britain. His series rely on Toutain’s data (published in 1987),
which is by far the most optimistic industrial output series for France. Lévy-Leboyer and Bourguignon (1985)
and Dormois (1999) have suggested much lower figures for the value of the French industrial output.
19
N. F. R. Crafts, ‘Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1830–1910: A Review of the Evidence’, The
Journal of Economic History, xliv (1984); François Crouzet, De la supériorité de l’Angleterre sur la France:
l’économique et l’imaginaire, XVIIe-XXe siècles (Paris, 1985); Lévy-Leboyer and Bourguignon, L’Économie
Française Au XIXe Siècle; Paul Bairoch, Victoires et Déboires. Histoire Économique et Sociale Du Monde Du
XVIe Siècle à Nos Jours (Paris, 1997); Jean-Pierre Dormois, ‘Évaluation et Composition Du Produit Industriel
Français Avant 1914’, Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, (1997); Jean-Pierre Dormois, ‘Tracking the
Elusive French Productivity Lag in Industry’, Hitotsubashi Univ. Research Unit for Statistical Analysis in
Social Sciences, Inst. of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi Univ.
20
A discussion is available in A. Litvine (2020), French Occupational Structure, Industrialisation and Economic
Growth, France, 1695 to the Present, pp.8 ff.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 7
comparative causal explanation of the Industrial Revolution,21 new series for France have
appeared, showing that it fared slightly better than Allen thought in the eighteenth century,
with relatively higher real wages22 and sustained commercial and industrial expansion.23 These
new observations do not change, however, the modest performance of the French economy
over the whole period. First, it is not surprising that wages were higher in the more industrially
and technologically advanced regions like Normandy, and when compared to similar regions
across the Channel the relative difference between the two countries remains significant.
Second, real wages in France on the eve of the Revolution were not desperately low only
insofar as food was also relatively cheap or the average diet less abundant. The French
population had already reached its pre-Black Death level (around twenty million) sometime
between 1600 and 1650 and Malthusian pressures must undoubtedly have been building up
(although not consistently across the country) from the mid seventeenth century, unlike in
England, which did not recover its pre-Black Death population until the late eighteenth century.
England had thus a much more favourable land/labour ratio in the early modern period
compared to much of Europe, which also coincides with the timing of the divergence between
England and France (around 1650) suggested by Ridolfi’s and Nuvolari’s recent GDP figures.24
https://www.campop.geog.cam.ac.uk/research/occupations/outputs/preliminary/france_1695_present_al.pdf. See
also Jean-Claude Toutain, ‘Comparaison entre les différentes évaluations du produit intérieur brut de la France
de 1815 à 1938 ou L’histoire économique quantitative a-t-elle un sens ?’, Revue économique, xlvii (1996). And
for the more recent: Leonardo Ridolfi and Alessandro Nuvolari, ‘L’histoire Immobile? A Reappraisal of French
Economic Growth Using the Demand-Side Approach, 1280–1850’, European Review of Economic History, xxv
(2021).
21
Robert C. Allen, The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective (Cambridge, 2009).
22
Cédric Chambru and Paul Maneuvrier-Hervieu, The Evolution of Wages in Early Modern Normandy (1600–
1850) (University of Zurich, 2021); Leonardo Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée: A Study on
Real Wages, Working Days and Economic Performance from Louis IX to the Revolution (1250–1789)’,
European Review of Economic History, xxi (2017); Vincent Geloso, ‘Were Wages That Low? Real Wages in
the Strasbourg Region Before 1775’, The Journal of Interdisciplinary History, xlviii (2018); Leonardo Ridolfi,
‘Six Centuries of Real Wages in France from Louis IX to Napoleon III: 1250–1860’, The Journal of Economic
History, lxxix (2019).
23
Daudin, ‘Commerce et prospérité’.
24
Ridolfi and Nuvolari, ‘L’histoire Immobile?’
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 8
Beyond the data and the conclusion regarding economic performance lies one of the most
history. Using the wealth of new data published in the 1960s and 1970s, Nick Crafts penned
an article comparing Britain and France, which claimed that the Industrial Revolution was
fundamentally a stochastic (i.e., an accidental) process.25 His conclusion was that: ‘Put in the
context of England's primacy in achieving the “decisive innovations,” it does not of itself
necessarily imply that Britain ex ante in, say 1740 had the greater probability of achieving the
first industrial revolution or that one should feel obliged to seek reasons for Britain's inevitable
primacy going far back into her history.’ Since then, Crafts has distanced himself from this
interpretation, and most explanations now agree that technological change is endogenous, path-
dependent, gradual and multi-factored, but his methodology in reaching this conclusion
remains a powerful component of many studies in our field.26 ‘As far as economic theory is
concerned’, Crafts argued in the same article, ‘it is in fact difficult using neo-classical
assumptions to derive predictions about the rate of technological progress in general or even to
support the assertions of writers such as Crouzet, Landes and Habakkuk of the beneficial effect
of the “shortages” experienced by the British economy in the first half of the eighteenth
century.’ What conclusion should we derive from this statement? Is it that Crouzet, Landes,
Habakkuk, Allen and Wrigley are wrong? Or rather that neo-classical assumptions and models
based on their work may be problematic for historical knowledge production – especially in
terms of causal inference. Arthur Lewis, himself a Nobel prize winner in economics, would
agree with this: ‘from the point of view of countries with surplus labour [definitely the case of
25
Crafts (1977), ‘Industrial Revolution in England and France: Some Thoughts on the Question, “Why was
England First?”’, The Economic History Review
26
N. F. R. Crafts, British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution (Oxford, 1985); N. F. R. Crafts
and C. K. Harley, ‘Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley
View’, The Economic History Review, xlv (1992); N. F. R. Crafts, ‘Macroinventions, Economic Growth,
and‘Industrial Revolution’in Britain and France’, Economic History Review, xlviii (1995).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 9
all early-modern economies] neoclassicism is not an analytical framework which can relevantly
fit [our] problems’.27 Before trying to determine causality, should we not first apply ourselves
to describing as precisely as possible the nature of the phenomena studied? This fundamental
empiricism would surely spare us the absurdity of concluding that what was, could not have
been. What good is it to use a probabilistic model to show that Britain's industrialisation was
‘partly due to chance’ and that ‘France could have moved out of agriculture and into
manufacturing faster than Britain, but the probability was less than 30 percent’, if we can
As the optimistic accounts of French economic performance were being rejected, and
perhaps as part of the diminishing importance of cold-war mentality, key estimates of economic
growth for Britain were also revised downwards, and the British Industrial Revolution came
again to be seen as a more gradual and protracted process with early modern origins.29 More
recent work by Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley using occupational data has confirmed and extended
Crafts’ revisionism, showing that the growth in manufacturing employment in Britain took
place between 1550 and 1750, not between 1750 and 1850 – long before any other European
country.30 Thus, logically, if both Britain and France fared less well than previously thought
during the classical period of the Industrial Revolution (1760-1850), the divergence between
the two countries must have originated not in the late eighteenth century but much earlier, and
was clearly present in the seventeenth or, perhaps even, the sixteenth century, by the time of
27
W. Arthur Lewis, ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’, The Manchester School, xxii
(1954).
28
Nico Voigtländer and Hans-Joachim Voth, ‘Why England? Demographic Factors, Structural Change and
Physical Capital Accumulation during the Industrial Revolution’, Journal of Economic Growth, xi (2006).
29
Crafts, British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution; Crafts and Harley, ‘Output Growth and the
British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View’.
30
Leigh Shaw-Taylor and E. A. Wrigley, ‘Occupational Structure and Population Change’, in Roderick Floud,
Jane Humphries, and Paul Johnson (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain (2014).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 10
Recent work by Broadberry et al. suggests that British GDP per capita stagnated from 1350
to 1650 and then grew at around 0.5% per year from 1650 to 1830.31 Regardless of the merit of
these figures, their findings do not contradict this early divergence hypothesis. Firstly, the
phase of slow economic maturation, 1500-1650, that enabled more rapid ‘modern’ economic
growth thereafter was not accompanied by large increase in GDP per capita, and in the context
of a population at least doubling between 1500 and 1650, the fact that living standards did not
that GDP estimates are controlled conjectures with significant margins of error, even if this is
only too rarely acknowledged by their producers.33 This article suggests that a key feature
in England and that it is this precocity which explains the different paths taken by the two
countries before 1750. Using new occupational data at the sub-sectoral level, we conclude that
it is time to rehabilitate the older, long-term view of the Industrial Revolution and pay more
attention to suggestions made by Nef for the period 1540-1640, and by both Crouzet and
Wrigley and Schofield on the longer period 1550-1750 regarding the early modern roots of the
Nef had shown that the shift to energy-intensive forms of production in the sixteenth
century meant that England had a decisive comparative advantage when it came to industrial
products like saltpetre, glass, salt, dyes, alum, and in the ship building industry; but above all
31
Stephen Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’, Cambridge Core, (2015).
32
We do not accept Broadberry et al’s suggestion that economic development is reducible to GDP per capita
growth. Achieving the same GDP per capita at double the population over the same area clearly requires
considerable economic development.
33
Charles Hilliard Feinstein and Mark Thomas, ‘Making History Count: A Primer in Quantitative Methods for
Historians’, (2012).
34
John U. Nef, ‘A Comparison of Industrial Growth in France and England from 1540 to 1640’, Journal of
Political Economy, xliv (1936); François Crouzet, ‘Angleterre et France au XVIIIe siècle : essai d’analyse
comparée de deux croissances économiques’, Annales, xxi (1966); François M. Crouzet, Britain Ascendant :
Comparative Studies in Franco-British Economic History (1990); E. A. Wrigley, The Population History of
England 1541-1871 : A Reconstruction (Cambridge, 1981).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 11
in coal, metal and textiles, which all helped Britain vastly expand her trade across the world
between 1540 and 1640.35 By 1700, Britain was already an exception in Europe, while France,
despite episodic growth in the sixteenth and early seventeenth century, remained a relatively
poor performer. Growth picked up after 1715 accompanied by population growth but limited
structural change at the national level. In the word of Crouzet, ‘on the eve of the Revolution
the French economy was the same it had been under Louis XIV [1643-1715]. It was simply
producing more.’36 The following revolutionary decade left the French economy in tatters but
laid the bases for subsequent (modest but steady) growth in the nineteenth century.37
countries during the period in which they industrialised and made the transition to modern
economic growth. The fruits of this research will be published as Saito and Shaw-Taylor,
The present authors contributed chapters on England and Wales, and on France; a much fuller
For England and Wales (henceforward E&W), the published population censuses of 1851,
1861, 1871, 1881, 1891, 1901 and 1911 provided detailed enumerations of occupations by both
age and sex in over 400 categories and are the source of all our occupational data for the period
35
What has been sometime called the ‘Nef thesis’, his argument for dubbing this period a first industrial
revolution, has been rejected, but in part – and unhelpfully we believe – for the mislabelling of early-modern
economic development as a revolution. It is also true that Nef stopped his analysis in 1640 and sometimes
argued that little change happened afterwards. We now know that development carried on right through, which
fits very nicely with the gradualist interpretation that came out of the work of Crafts and Harley.
36
Crouzet, Britain Ascendant : Comparative Studies in Franco-British Economic History, 26.
37
Crafts, ‘Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1830–1910’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 12
1851-1911. The 1841 census also recorded male and female occupations in considerable detail.
However, while the male data are reliable, female occupations are systematically under-
enumerated compared with the later censuses. We also have male data for c.1710 and c.1817,
but of very different provenance. From the 1st of January 1813 it became a legal requirement
to record the occupations of fathers in Anglican baptism registers. Since 90 per cent of all men
married in this period and other denominations widely used Anglican baptisms, counts of the
occupations of the fathers provides a quasi-census of male occupations.38 Data were collected
from virtually all 11,400 Anglican baptism registers, generating 2.5m observations over an
eight-year period centred on 1817. Comparison with other sources shows that this generates a
Comprehensive data on female occupations do not exist before 1851. We have instead
calculated sub-sectoral sex ratios from the 1851 population census and applied these ratios to
the male occupational data for earlier periods. Of course, these would not necessarily have been
the same c.1710, c.1817 and in 1851. The approach followed here is to use the 1851 sex ratios
where we have no reason to believe they would have differed from those prevailing in that
year. For certain sectors (textiles, agriculture and the making of clothes) the existing secondary
literature strongly suggests that the ratios would have been different, and we have drawn on
The results of this work have already proved transformative for the national history of the
British Industrial Revolution. Deane and Cole believed that as late as 1760 between 60 and 80
per cent of the labour force was employed in agriculture and that this figure had fallen to 25
38
P M Kitson et al., ‘The Creation of a Census of Adult Male Employment for England and Wales for 1817’;
Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley, ‘Occupational Structure and Population Change’.
39
The methodology and results are described in: Leigh Shaw-Taylor, Keith Sudgen, and Xuesheng You, ‘A
Preliminary Estimate of the Female Occupational Structure of England and Wales 1700–1911’, (2021).
Available at: https://www.campop.geog.cam.ac.uk/research/occupations/outputs/preliminary/
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 13
per cent by 1851.40 They thus saw the Industrial Revolution as characterised by a massive
change in the structure of employment. Crafts, drawing on work by Lindert and Williamson,
accounted for 56 per cent of the labour force in 1688.41 Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley confirmed
the size of the primary sector as 50 per cent of the labour force c.1710 but present a very
In France, as in England, regular census-taking began in 1801 but occupational data were
only compiled in the published returns after 1851, which means that for the first half of the
nineteenth century little occupational data is readily available.43 Unfortunately, until 1896 (or
perhaps even 1901) the unadjusted occupational data collected during quinquennial censuses
and industrial (1839-47 and 1860-65) and agricultural (1840, 1852, 1862, 1882, 1892) surveys
were, generally, of poor quality, especially for female and child labour, which were both
dramatically under-recorded, if at all. The data presented in this chapter are based on: i) new
capitation tax-based estimates for the period 1695-1790 using an expanded sample from
Ostroot and Snyder,44 ii) new estimates based on burial, marriages and baptism records for the
period 1740-1819 from the Enquête Henry-Biraben, iii) revised sectoral estimates from
Marchand and Thélot for 1811-1896,45 and iv) adjusted census returns from 1851 onwards.46
40
Deane and Cole, British Economic Growth, 1688-1959.
41
Peter H. Lindert and Jeffrey G. Williamson, ‘English Workers’ Living Standards During the Industrial
Revolution : A New Look’, Economic History Review, xxxvi (1983); Crafts, British Economic Growth during
the Industrial Revolution.
42
Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley, ‘Occupational Structure and Population Change’.
43
The authors are currently collecting and compiling these data from the nominative census lists, but it will be
many years until a national coverage is achieved.
44
Nathalie Ostroot and Wayne Snyder, ‘The Quality of Life in Historical Perspective France: 1695?1990’,
Social Indicators Research, xxxviii (1996); Wayne Snyder, ‘Occupational Evolution in XVIIIth and XIXth-
Century France’, The Journal of European Economic History, xxxv (2006).
45
O. Marchand and Claude Thélot, Deux Siècles de Travail En France: Population Active et Structure Sociale,
Durée et Productivité Du Travail (Paris, 1991), 140 FRF.
46
Alexis Litvine, ‘French Occupational Structure, Industrialisation and Economic Growth France, 1695 to the
Present.’, in Leigh Shaw-Taylor and Osamu Saito (eds.), Occupational Structure, Industrialization and
Economic Growth in a Comparative Perspective.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 14
Four striking features emerge from a simple glance at the data presented in tables 1a-b
and fig.1 below: i) the radical difference in the level of employment in the primary sector from
the early eighteenth century between the two countries (around 70 per cent of the total labour
force in France, below 40 per cent in E&W). ii) The industrial divergence between France and
E&W (measured in the relative share of employment in the secondary sector) happened well
before the Industrial Revolution. By 1710, E&W had already 43 per cent of its active male
labour force working in the secondary sector (as opposed to Crafts’ previous estimate of 19 per
cent in 1688), while only 16 per cent of working age males were employed in industry in France
by 1725. As a consequence, the secondary sector was already by this date three times larger in
E&W than in France. iii) The flatness of the share of the secondary sector throughout the
classical period of the Industrial Revolution in E&W, and the steady growth in employment in
the tertiary sector during the eighteenth and early nineteenth century, a development which has
not been a feature of the dominant historical national accounts view of the Industrial Revolution
so far. Inversely, the stagnation of tertiary sector employment in France until the mid-
nineteenth century, which suggests a much more limited commercial integration and slower
urbanisation. These points confirm the observations made by Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley, while
indications of output levels in 1750 can be taken from Broadberry and O’Rourke.47 According
to these figures, British industrial output per capita was twice as large as that of France by
1750. Given that French industrial output for the period 1700-1750 grew by an estimate of 52
47
Figures from: Paul Bairoch, ‘International Insutrialisation Levels from 1750 to 1980’, Journal of European
Economic History, II, ii (1982); Crafts and Harley, ‘Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A
Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View’; Stephen Broadberry and Kevin H. O’Rourke, The Cambridge
Economic History of Modern Europe: Volume 1: 1700–1870 (Cambridge, 2010), i.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 15
per cent,48 and that British output grew by 34 per cent over the same period,49 we can safely
assume that French industrial output per capita was at least 60 per cent smaller than that of the
British by 1700. And not only was British industrial output per capita larger, but its composition
reveals a much deeper and longer structural transformation of the economy. Judging by the
relative weight of sectors in the total output circa 1800 (table 1), the most striking feature is
that the share of the food and drink industry in both the total industrial output and the industrial
labour force was respectively three and eight times lower than in France. A likely explanation
of the difference is that in E&W the share of food production had already shrunk with the
growth of other industries, especially manufacturing, chemicals and heavy industry. Even
accounting for the specialised and export-oriented wine and spirit production in France, this
clearly suggests – not unlike Engel’s Law (which posits that the share of income spent on food
decreases as total income grows) – a much less diverse and mature industrial sector. Using the
same data, we can also have an indication of relative intra-sectoral productivity gaps by looking
at the ratio of the share of the labour force to their respective share in the total industrial value
added by sector. This gives an idea of how much one per cent of the labour force in each sector
contributed to the total industrial output by 1800. Obviously, these ratios (table 1, columns 3
and 6) are only meaningful indications within countries and not between them – it is worth
remembering that by 1800 the industrial output per capita was 2.14 times bigger in E&W.
In the following pages we will use our new sub-sectoral data to examine: 1) the evolution
economy, 3) productivity growth and the textile industries, 4) the role of consumer demand
48
Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée’.
49
Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 16
Fig. 1a-b Sectoral distribution of the male and female labour force (in %)
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
c1720 c1810 1851 1881 1911
P_FR S_FR T_FR P_EW S_EW T_EW
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
c1720 c1810 1851 1881 1911
P_FR S_FR T_FR P_EW S_EW T_EW
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 17
Table 1 Share of total industrial value added and share of the industrial labour force per
FRANCE E&W
VA IndLF VA IndLF
(1) (2) (1)/(2) (4) (5) (4)/(5) (4)/(5)*2.14
Mining & fuel 0.2 0.2 1.0 4.0 4 1.0 2.1
Metals 6 2.5 2.4 7.0 8.5 0.8 1.8
Chemical 1.7 0.1 17.0 3.2 0.1 31.6 67.6
Textiles 42 10.5 4.0 45.7 18 2.5 5.4
Food & drink 22.3 8 2.8 6.9 1 6.9 14.8
Paper 1.1 1.5 0.7 0.4 1.4 0.3 0.5
Construction 14 15 0.9 13.9 16 0.9 1.9
Nb: the margins of errors for these figures were not specified by all authors, but we can assume they are large
since where they were made clear (by Feinstein), they stand between 15 and 20 per cent for this period.
The common wisdom is that French agriculture performed relatively poorly in the second half
of the seventeenth century and throughout the eighteenth century, but with the caveat that some
regions did better than others.51 Hoffman calculated TFP growth rates for French agriculture
between 1520 and 1789 and found increasing productivity in the Paris Basin and the North and
limited to the arable sector and excluding the Mediterranean regions) between 1600 and 1800,
50
Markovitch, Histoire quantitative de l’économie française; Jean-Claude Toutain, Le produit intérieur brut de
la France de 1789 à 1982 (Grenoble, 1987); Charles H. Feinstein, ‘Economic Growth Since 1870: Britain’s
Performance in International Perspective’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, iv (1988); Crafts and Harley,
‘Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View’; N. F. R.
Crafts, ‘British Economic Growth, 1700-1831: A Review of the Evidence’, The Economic History Review,
xxxvi (1983); Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’.
51
See Emmanuel Le Roy Ladurie and Joseph Goy (eds.), Les fluctuations du produit de la dîme; conjoncture
décimale et domaniale de la fin du Moyen Age au XVIIIe siècle. (Paris, 1972); Fernand Braudel, Ernest
Labrousse, and Pierre Léon, Histoire économique et sociale de la France Tome III, 4 vols (Paris, 1976), iii;
Robert C. Allen, ‘Economic Structure and Agricultural Productivity in Europe, 1300-1800’, European Review of
Economic History, iii (2000); Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée’.
52
Philip T. Hoffman, Growth in a Traditional Society, The French Countryside, 1450-1815 (Princeton, N.J.,
1996).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 18
indicating divergent regional trajectories.53 The problem with metrics such as TFP and grain
yield estimates is that they come with high compound margins of errors, which makes the
comparison of the performance of the primary sector across countries problematic. For this
reason, we think it is preferable to consider the relative size of the primary sector as the key
comparative measure – albeit indirect – of the overall efficiency of an economy in the early
eighteenth century.54 As such, the early shift out of the primary sector in E&W (fig.3a and 3b)
indicates without any doubt a much higher level of aggregate agricultural productivity. By
1710, 44 per cent of the English active male population could support the other 56 per cent not
working the land (imported calories are negligible), while in France at the same date the
proportion was 70 to 30. These numbers indicate a spectacular difference in the carrying
capacity of the primary sector (that is the share of the population able to survive without
producing food themselves in an economy with limited food imports) in the two countries.
And, finally, given that there is compelling evidence that the English (already comically but
also enviously dubbed ‘les rosbifs’ in the eighteenth century) ate much better than the French
in this period, these figures underestimate the difference between the two countries.
We currently have only limited data for the proportion of French women working in
agriculture in the early eighteenth century, but given that the share of the female labour force
employed in agriculture in France was higher than the male share in 1800, and in E&W much
lower than the male share, it is likely that the inclusion of women would not change the result
(fig.3a), and, would only increase the size of the productivity gap. One remarkable feature,
though, is the early sexual division of labour in agriculture in E&W visible in fig.3a.
53
George W. Grantham, ‘Divisions of Labour: Agricultural Productivity and Occupational Specialization in
Pre-Industrial France’, The Economic History Review, xlvi (1993).
54
E. Anthony Wrigley, ‘Urban Growth and Agricultural Change: England and the Continent in the Early
Modern Period’, The Journal of Interdisciplinary History, xv (1985); Karl Gunnar Persson and Paul Sharp, ‘An
Economic History of Europe: Knowledge, Institutions and Growth, 600 to the Present’, Higher Education from
Cambridge University Press, (2015).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 19
Agriculture was far more feminine in France with 35.4 per cent of the total agricultural labour
force being women in 1801, against 26 per cent in Britain in 1817. Observing the large of
number of women working in the fields of France was one of the most common tropes in
contemporary travelogues. In July 1789 Edward Rigby, from Norwich, observed that in
Northern France ‘women … seem to do a great deal of labour, especially in the country. They
carry great burdens, and seem to be employed to go to market with the produce of the fields on
their backs.’ Further, he notes that: ‘the agriculture is chiefly done by women.’55 A couple of
years earlier Arthur Young had made a similar observation about Normandy where he noticed:
‘women … ploughing with a pair of horses to sow barley. The difference [he added] of the
customs of the two nations is in nothing more striking than in the labours of the sex; in England,
it is very little that they will do in the fields except to glean and make hay … in France, they
What explains this difference between the two countries? The question covers at least
three distinct issues: farmers’ wives and daughters, farm servants, and agricultural labourers.
It is safe to assume that farmers’ wives and daughters would have participated in farm work
right through to the nineteenth century. However, as the proportion of farmers’ households in
England and Wales was falling throughout the period 1500-1851, the share of farm labour
supplied by farmers’ wives and daughters decreased substantially.57 Regarding farm servants
there is currently no clear indication in the literature. We still do not know whether the share
of female farm servants declined over the eighteenth century, or before, or not at all. As for
55
Edward Rigby and Elizabeth Eastlake, Dr. Rigby’s Letters from France &c. in 1789. (London, 1880), 16.
56
Arthur Young, Arthur Young’s Travels in France: During the Years 1787, 1788, 1789, ed. Matilda Betham-
Edwards (Cambridge, 2012), entry for May 22nd 1787.
57
A major area of uncertainty, in both England and France, is the relative labour inputs directly into the farm by
farmers' wives and daughters, compared with adult male farmers and farmers' sons. No doubt higher in pastoral
areas, especially dairying, than in arable areas. We are not including in this discussion the extent to which
female farm household members 'household work' should be considered as contributing to or underpinning the
operation of the farm.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 20
day labourers, the evidence is that only a modest share of day labour was ever supplied by
women, and it seems (although not yet proven) that the share declined in the century after 1750.
However, the share of all farm labour supplied by day labour was certainly increasing from
shift labour inputs from farmers’ wives and daughters to farm servants, this must have led to
declining female participation.59 The question then becomes, ‘When did proletarianisation
really take off in E&W: in the fourteenth, fifteenth, or sixteenth century?’ The jury is still out
on this aspect, but preliminary results from a survey of coroners’ inquest data on accidental
deaths indicate that in Southern England it was certainly before 1500 (data shows three
labourers to every farmer, as much as in 1700). This early proletarianisation again suggests
looking back at the early modern or even medieval roots of the precocious economic
development in E&W.
Furthermore, making the reasonable assumption that the withdrawal of women from
agriculture before 1750 was not absorbed by an equivalent decline in the female labour force
participation rate (FLFP) necessarily means that other sources of employment became available
both in the secondary sector (proto-industry and manufacturing) and, crucially, in the tertiary
sector.60 In the early nineteenth century – because of the sharp decline in FLFP caused by the
mechanisation of spinning – the tertiary sector had become the fastest growing sector for
female employment, and already by 1800 half of the labour force in the service industry in
E&W were women (51 per cent) against just over a third in France (36.5 per cent). There, as
58
Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘The Rise of Agrarian Capitalism and the Decline of Family Farming in England’, The
Economic History Review, (2011).
59
Ivy Pinchbeck, Women Workers and the Industrial Revolution, 1750-1850 (London, 1930), 44, 110; Shaw-
Taylor, Sudgen, and You, ‘A Preliminary Estimate of the Female Occupational Structure of England and Wales
1700–1911’. Available at:
campop.geog.cam.ac.uk/research/occupations/outputs/preliminary/female_estimates_lst_ks_xy_2019.pdf
60
Women’s LFPR was comparable to men’s, even during marriage. See Amy Louise Erickson, ‘Married
Women’s Occupations in Eighteenth-Century London’, Continuity and Change, xxiii (2008).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 21
fig.3b shows, only 14.4 per cent of the female labour force was employed in the tertiary sector,
while it had already reached 32.4 per cent in E&W. This large gap is consistent with the rising
pace of urbanisation in E&W (table 2) over the eighteenth century. Cities across Europe drew
from a large pool of female migrants to work in domestic services and manufacturing61 so that
– as it was certainly the case in Paris by 1800 – cities contained substantially more women than
men, and even more so in E&W (clearly visible in figs.5a-b). By 1851, 30 per cent (35 in 1881)
of the female labour force in E&W were employed as domestic servants, but only eight per
cent (13 in 1881) in France, and logically, the more urban the population, the higher the ratio
of female to male workers was likely to be in the service industry (fig.2). This fact also suggests
that the urban demand for female labour was a key determinant of the rate of exit of young
females from the primary sector in E&W and contributed to its precocious structural
England in 1801 but much less so in France, where male emigration dominates most of the
northern half of the country (figs.5a-b). More generally, the fact that the sexual distribution of
the French population remained so stable over the first half of the century, especially compared
to the English and Welsh cases, is testament to the very limited structural (i.e., urban)
Figs. 3a-b. Comparison of the evolution of the share of the labour force employed in agriculture
61
Amy Louise Erickson. and A. Schmidt, ‘Migration’, in Christine MacLeod and Maria Ågren, eds, The Whole
Economy, Cambridge University Press, forthcoming
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 22
PRIMARY #M EW PRIMARY #F EW
PRIMARY # M FR PRIMARY #F FR
80.0
70.0
60.0
50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
TERTIARY #M EW TERTIARY #F EW
TERTIARY # M FR TERTIARY #F FR
70.0
60.0
50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 23
The rapid population growth in France over the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries
Goubert and Wrigley and Schofield, most demographic historians seem to agree that the French
population was too large in the seventeenth century.62 The eighteenth century saw a definite
improvement. Dupâquier argued that France was experiencing a virtuous Boserupian cycle
grew much more rapidly in the nineteenth centuries but strikingly did so without precipitating
a Malthusian crisis.64
POP FR POP EW
46,000
41,000
36,000
31,000
26,000
21,000
16,000
11,000
6,000
1,000
1350 1600 1800
62
Alfred Sauvy, Théorie générale de la population. (Paris, 1952); Pierre Goubert, 100 000 provinciaux au
XVIIe siècle: Beauvais et le Beauvaisis de 1600 à 1730 (1968); Wrigley, The Population History of England
1541-1871 : A Reconstruction.
63
Jacques Dupâquier, Introduction a La Demographie Historique (Paris, 1974).
64
E. A. Wrigley, ‘Coping with Rapid Population Growth: How England Fared in the Century Preceding the
Great Exhibition of 1851’, in David Feldman and Jon Lawrence (eds.), Structures and Transformations in
Modern British History (Cambridge, 2011).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 24
Fig. 5a-b Sex ratios in 1801 and 1851 by arrondissement and registration district
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 25
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 26
More quantitative studies have confirmed this view. Weir did not identify any Malthusian
pressure in France after 1740, and finally Grantham calculated that by 1800 only forty per cent
of the population was required to produce all the food necessary to feed the whole population.66
Yet, the situation might not have been as rosy as they suggest.
pressures dominated in most regions while some experienced faster (Boserupian) productivity
growth. The divergence in regional performance in agriculture is now well documented,67 and
we know it was then a dominant factor in the geography of living standards.68 The same was
65
GIS-datasets for Belgium and the Netherlands kindly provided by Isabelle Devos and Rombert Stapel.
66
David R. Weir, ‘Life Under Pressure: France and England, 1670–1870’, The Journal of Economic History,
xliv (1984); Grantham, ‘Divisions of Labour: Agricultural Productivity and Occupational Specialization in Pre-
Industrial France’.
67
Hoffman, Growth in a Traditional Society, The French Countryside, 1450-1815.
68
Laurent Heyberger, ‘Niveaux de vie biologiques, disponibilités alimentaires et consommations populaires en
France au milieu du xixe siècle’, Annales de demographie historique, cxviii (2009).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 27
Secondly, even the more optimistic narrative does not fundamentally diminish the
comparative backwardness of the French economy. The most advanced regions were able to
sustain higher population density than the poorer ones, but even these remained well below
levels observed in the denser regions of E&W (fig.6). As cross-country variations in population
density were highly correlated to land productivity and technological development, just a
glance at the map below should suffice to see that by 1800 Britain had reached a much higher
level of development.69 The eighteenth century looked favourably only when compared to the
cause. If, as contended by Grantham, only a modest share of the population sufficed to produce
the calories required to sustain the whole population, while a much larger contingent was
labour force. Grantham himself showed that retention of a surplus rural labour force was
required to match peak labour demand at harvest time, and that subsequent changes in
integration in the second half of the nineteenth century.70 Was this not simply the situation in
most, or perhaps all, early modern societies across Eurasia at the time – apart from Britain?
Here again, Britain stands as sui generis. The real question is why and how Britain could afford
to reallocate such a large (relatively less productive) share of its population, while others were
not even at similar level of GDP/capita. Older explanations were psychological (attributing the
the Code Civil, for keeping unnecessary unproductive labour in rural areas), but they all work
69
Quamrul Ashraf and Oded Galor, ‘Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch’, American Economic
Review, ci (2011); Oded Galor, ‘The Demographic Transition and the Emergence of Sustained Economic
Growth’, Journal of the European Economic Association, iii (2005).
70
Grantham, ‘Divisions of Labour: Agricultural Productivity and Occupational Specialization in Pre-Industrial
France’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 28
on the premise that it would have been possible to reallocate such a large share of the labour
In France, rural labor – the peasantry – was free to move but chose to remain
on the land, often substantially self-sufficient and at lower material reward than
urban alternatives offered. They were able to make that choice because they
owned the land. By staying on the land the peasant family chose a lifestyle that
the same in alternative uses – the retention of labor on family farms reduced
the marginal product of labor in agriculture below that in the rest of the
maintaining rural peasant status. It is hard not to accept that at least for the
generations making the choice that this was an informed and rational decision.72
Given that France reached in 1844 the level of GDP/capita that Britain achieved in 1700 and
that the share of primary sector employment in France at this date (1841) was 63 per cent of
the total labour force (for both sexes), it would have taken a sectoral reallocation of 9.6 million
people (that is 44 per cent of the total labour force) in order to match E&W’s level of
employment in the primary sector. If we do the same calculation using Britain’s level of
GDP/capita in 1800, which France achieved in 1874, when it had 54 per cent of its labour force
in the primary sector, it would have then taken a re-allocation of over 3 million people (or 17
71
This includes: Paul Hohenberg, ‘Change in Rural France in the Period of Industrialization, 1830–1914’, The
Journal of Economic History, xxxii (1972); Robert Brenner, ‘Agrarian Class Structure and Economic
Development in Pre-Industrial Europe’, Past & Present, (1976); P. K. O’Brien, ‘Agriculture and the Industrial
Revolution’, The Economic History Review, xxx (1977); O’Brien and Keyder, Economic Growth in Britain and
France, 1780-1914 : Two Paths to the Twentieth Century; Maurice Agulhon et al., Histoire de la France rurale,
tome 3 : De 1789 à 1914 (1992); Patrick Karl O’Brien, ‘Path Dependency, or Why Britain Became an
Industrialized and Urbanized Economy Long before France’, The Economic History Review, xlix (1996).
72
C. Knick Harley, ‘British and European Industrialization’, in Jeffrey G. Williamson and Larry Neal (eds.),
The Cambridge History of Capitalism: Volume 1: The Rise of Capitalism: From Ancient Origins to 1848
(Cambridge, 2014), i.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 29
per cent of total labour force). How likely was that to happen in a short period of time? Our
argument, in a nutshell, is that France could not have reallocated such a large share of its labour
force, as: i) the urban demand for this extra labour did not exist, ii) the urban infrastructure
required to maintain such a large population was non-existent, iii) French living standards were
so low that the urban penalty caused by mass urban migration would have led to a major human
and demographic catastrophe, and iv) the institutional mitigation of the costs associated to the
transfer of labour from surplus regions (the Poor Law) did not exist in France.73 Lewis and
O’Brien and Keyder were therefore probably right in describing a French path – potentially
population growth to maintain decent levels of GDP per capita throughout the nineteenth
century, and a slow release of labour from the countryside to mitigate the negative effects of
rapid urbanisation.74 After all, keeping people on the land might have been a necessary social
and welfare policy for societies with very low living standards and deficient infrastructures.
The situation could not have been more different across the Channel where higher
agricultural productivity fed – literally – the very rapid urbanisation of the country. By 1600,
the population of E&W was only marginally more urban than France, but two centuries later
the difference was staggering (table 2). By 1800, the size of the population living in areas
considered to be urban in E&W was a third higher than in France, and the share of the
population living in large towns and cities was almost three times higher. The relationship
between the growth of urban settlements and the rest of the country is a key element in the
social and economic developments happening between 1550 and 1700. In a seminal article, EA
Wrigley showed that the rise of cities is a signal of economic development (which made
73
Peter M. Solar, ‘Poor Relief and English Economic Development before the Industrial Revolution’, The
Economic History Review, xlviii (1995); Peter M. Solar, ‘Poor Relief and English Economic Development: A
Renewed Plea for Comparative History’, The Economic History Review, l (1997).
74
Lewis, ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’; O’Brien and Keyder, Economic Growth
in Britain and France, 1780-1914 : Two Paths to the Twentieth Century.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 30
urbanisation possible in the first place),75 but also that it drove further economic change: market
integration, increasing agricultural productivity, the rise of a mineral economy, lower transport
Unlike the food and processing industry, the share of the industrial labour force
employed in construction was not sensitive to the increase in size of the secondary sector, i.e.,
that the demand elasticity of the construction industry was close to one during the second half
of the nineteenth century. The expectation, however, would be that a faster rate and level of
urbanisation in E&W would have led to an equivalent increase in the share of employment in
the construction industries, but this is not visible in our data. Why? It might be that British
75
E. A. Wrigley, ‘A Simple Model of London’s Importance in Changing English Society and Economy 1650–
1750’, Past & Present, xxxvii (1967).
76
E.A. Wrigley, Energy and the English Industrial Revolution (2010).
77
Data for France from: Jacques Dupâquier, Mée René Le, and Joseph Goy, Histoire de La Population
Française de 1789 à 1914 (Paris, 1988), iii; Paul Bairoch, Jean Batou, and Pierre Chèvre, La population des
villes européennes, 800-1850: banque de données et analyse sommaire des résultats (1988); Marchand and
Thélot, Deux Siècles de Travail En France: Population Active et Structure Sociale, Durée et Productivité Du
Travail; Wrigley, ‘Urban Growth and Agricultural Change: England and the Continent in the Early Modern
Period’; Jan De Vries, European Urbanization, 1500-1800 (1984); John Langton, ‘Urban Growth and Economic
Change: From the Late Seventeenth to 1841’, in Peter Clarke (ed.), The Cambridge Urban History of England,
1540 – 1840, Book, Section vols (Cambridge, 2000), ii. The series are not homogeneous as definitions of urban
population are not strictly identical. Figures in italics are linearly interpolated from the closest available census
date.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 31
original data - but at least two more factors might explain this evolution: i) Britain had a major
competitive advantage in brick making compared to France, and the share of total construction
using brick is very likely to have been much higher in Britain than in France throughout the
period, which confers a secondary advantage in productivity compared to oak or stone building;
ii) the share of the total labour input in the construction industries used for new builds vs.
renovations or repairs has never been estimated for historical periods, but given that
refurbishments amounted to 42 per cent of the total output of the UK construction industry in
2020, it is not unlikely that two thirds of the labour force in the construction industries would
have been employed in repair work in the early nineteenth century, when building standards
and longevity were significantly lower than today.78 If so, the more prevalent use of brick in
E&W compared to timber probably increased the durability of buildings and reduced the needs
for annual repairs, which in turn freed labour time for new constructions.
Fig.2 Distribution of the male labour force for key subsectors 1700-1911 (in %)
78
Office for National Statistics, ‘Construction Statistics, Great Britain’, (2021).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 32
DOMESTIC SERVICES #F EW
DOMESTIC SERVICES #M EW
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 33
7.0
6.0
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 34
Alongside rising urbanisation, E&W underwent a radical shift in its energy base from charcoal
and firewood to coal. According to Nef (1932), this energy divergence started after 1540, when
the use of coal in England increased very rapidly. By 1650, and uniquely for any contemporary
economy, E&W was well advanced in this process of mineralisation with a third of all the
energy consumed coming from coal (table 3). Nef later argued that coal use in England had
then stagnated until the later eighteenth century79 – which we now know not to be the case.80
He also added that between 1735 and 1785 ‘the output of coal and iron grew faster in France
than in England’.81 The higher growth rate for coal in France is factually correct with coal
output growing from c.100,000 tons a year in 1720 to c.600,000 tons by 1789,82 but it reflects
first and foremost the fact that the French coal industry was so very small by 1735 that its
growing rapidly was of little significance compared to the slower growth rate (but from a much
larger base, around three million tons a year in the 1700s to over fifteen million by 1800)83 in
Britain. Overall, coal output and consumption grew steadily and at a much higher average
annual growth rate in E&W than in France from the sixteenth to the nineteenth centuries. The
comparative lens clarifies this debate: by 1800 the annual coal consumption per capita in E&W
reached 41 gigajoules, and barely 0.7 gigajoules in France! By 1851, almost five per cent of
the male labour force in E&W was employed in mining while it only occupied a meagre 0.7
per cent of the French male labour force. Nef’s claim that ‘no domestic practice marked off
79
John U. Nef, ‘The Industrial Revolution Reconsidered’, The Journal of Economic History, iii (1943).
80
Paul Warde, Energy Consumption in England & Wales, 1560-2000 (2007); Wrigley, Energy and the English
Industrial Revolution; Astrid Kander, Paolo Malanima, and Paul Warde (eds.), Power to the People (Princeton,
N.J., 2014).
81
Nef, ‘The Industrial Revolution Reconsidered’, 18.
82
Marcel Rouff, Les mines de charbon en France au XVIIIe siècle, 1744-1791: étude d’histoire économique et
sociale (1922); Jean-Francois Belhoste, ‘L’essor de l’usage Industriel Du Charbon En France Au XVIIIe
Siècle’, Le Charbon de Terre En Europe Occidentale Avant l’usage Du Coke (1999), 44 (NS 7).
83
Hatcher, The History of the British Coal Industry; Brian R. Mitchell, British Historical Statistics (1988), 247.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 35
English from Continental, and particularly French, life more sharply than the use of this newly
adopted coal fire’ was as true in 1640 as it was in 1800, and perhaps even in 1850.84
The higher energy output was driven by the energy intensive industrialisation and the
growing demand for domestic coal heating spurred by rapid urbanisation, directly related to
the higher share of the male labour force employed in mining in E&W (fig.8). This fact, already
outlined by Nef and Wrigley, is not unexpected. What is more surprising is that the ratio of the
share of the industrial value added to the labour force in the extractive industries should be the
same in the two countries (table 1 column 6), and that the productivity gap between the two
countries (column 7) did not exceed a factor of 2. This signals the enabling rather than
revolutionary role of technological change in the extractive industries before 1800. From the
1760s the key progress achieved with early steam pumps and steam haulage85 (for getting coal
up the pit shaft) made possible (by shifting the decreasing marginal return curve to the right)
the large increase in coal extracted – from deeper, better ventilated shafts – but it did not
fundamentally alter the apparent productivity of labour at the coalface until much later in the
nineteenth century.86 The work of a coal miner was fundamentally the same throughout the
period, but technology simply made it possible to mine much more of it.
And with this enormous increase in the supply of coal in the economy (see table 3
below) came major positive externalities for the more voracious industrial sectors, such as the
salt, brewing, glass (lead-oxide crystal), ceramics (especially stoneware) metal wares and the
smelting of non-ferrous metals – all elements already mentioned by Perlin in the 1550s! The
very large difference in the share of the male population (and therefore most likely of the whole
population) employed in the metal industries illustrates the tail end of this process very clearly.
84
Nef, ‘A Comparison of Industrial Growth in France and England from 1540 to 1640’, 170.
85
G. Clark and D. Jacks, ‘Coal and the Industrial Revolution, 1700-1869’, European Review of Economic
History, xi (2007).
86
G. N. Von Tunzelmann, Steam Power and British Industrialization to 1860 (1978).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 36
By 1800 just under 4 per cent of the total male labour force was employed in the metal
industries in E&W but under 0.5 per cent of the total male labour force in France, a staggering
eight-fold difference. Pig iron output figures per capital show a similar gap between the two
economies: from 4,705 tons per million inhabitants in EW in 1700 to 11,250 tons per million
inhabitants by 1790, compared with 1,100 tons and 3,392 tons in France at the same dates.87
Our data also confirm the negative correlation between increased pressures on wood
resources (the so-called “timber crisis”) and coal mining in France from the late eighteenth
century. The higher the price of heating and fuel the stronger the incentive to overcome the
natural barriers to large-scale coal mining, i.e., pumping water out and transporting cheaply
large amounts of coal. Urbanisation, intensive arable farming, an increase in the share of
pastoral land required for meat-rich urban diets, and the large forestry cover required to produce
timber and charcoal for construction and both industrial and domestic processes, all contributed
to raising wood prices up to a level that progressively made it economically viable to dig coal
on an industrial scale,88 but whereas this process started in the 1650s in E&W, our data for
France show a clear scissor effect in the evolution of the share of the labour force employed in
the mining and forestry industries happening only after 1850 (fig. 8). By 1800 mining occupied
only a trivial share of the labour force. At the same time, forestry occupied eight times as large
a relative share of the labour force in France than in England at what might have been France’s
peak dependence on wood (the share of the male labour force employed in forestry reaches its
87
Mitchell, British Historical Statistics, 280; Philip Riden, ‘The Output of the British Iron Industry before
1870’, The Economic History Review, xxx (1977), 443; Crouzet, ‘Angleterre et France au XVIIIe siècle’, 268.
88
R. C. Allen, ‘Why the Industrial Revolution Was British: Commerce, Induced Invention, and the Scientific
Revolution’, The Economic History Review, lxiv (2011).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 37
century as the historical minimum of French forestry cover, well below its level at the last Ice
89
Xavier Rochel et al., ‘Quelles sources cartographiques pour la définition des usages anciens du sol en
France ?’, Revue Forestière Française, (2017); J. Dupouey et al., ‘Cartographie Des Forêts Anciennes de
France : Objectifs, Bilan et Perspectives’, Colloque International « Géohistoire de l’environnement et Des
Paysages » (Toulouse, 2016); R. Fuchs et al., ‘A High-Resolution and Harmonized Model Approach for
Reconstructing and Analysing Historic Land Changes in Europe’, Biogeosciences, x (2013); Richard Fuchs et
al., ‘The Potential of Old Maps and Encyclopaedias for Reconstructing Historic European Land Cover/Use
Change’, Applied Geography, lix (2015); Richard Fuchs et al., ‘Gross Changes in Reconstructions of Historic
Land Cover/Use for Europe between 1900 and 2010’, Global Change Biology, xxi (2015).
90
Warde, Energy Consumption in England & Wales, 1560-2000; Kander, Malanima, and Warde, Power to the
People.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 38
MINING EW FORESTRY EW
MINING FR FORESTRY FR
10.0
1.0
0.1
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
By 1851 – the end of the classical period of the Industrial Revolution – the share of the
male labour force employed in the secondary sector in E&W had only increased to 50.8 per
cent of the male labour force: an increase of less than 15 per cent over 140 years! By 1700 the
British population was not much less industrial than a century and a half later. Yet the nature
of industrial labour changed dramatically over this period with the rise of more geographically
concentrated and mechanised production. In France, the situation could not have been more
different. By 1700 around 16 per cent of the male labour force was occupied in the secondary
sector to reach just over 25 per cent by 1851 (an increase of 58 per cent). Given that over the
same period the total industrial output grew by a multiple of 116 in Britain91 but only 6.5 times
91
Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
in France,92 it is clear (regardless of the reliability of these figures) that British industrialisation
was achieved mostly by productivity gains linked to mechanisation and regional specialisation
while French industrialisation up to 1851 was infinitely slower and more labour intensive. As
the French economy started from a much lower initial share of employment in the secondary
sector, the effects of productivity growth in the modernising sectors (which certainly existed)
remained imperceptible at an aggregate level until much later in the nineteenth century, because
Were data available to consider figures for the both sexes together, the comparison
would undoubtedly be even more striking. Between 1700 and 1851 the estimated share of the
female labour force employed in the secondary sector in E&W collapsed from 51 to 39 per cent
(table 1b).93 Symbolic of this slump was the complete annihilation of the hand-spinning
industry in the south-east caused by mechanisation and further concentration in the textile
heartlands.94 There is still sadly no equivalent data for eighteenth-century France, but it is very
likely that the total share of the female labour force employed in industry grew throughout the
eighteenth and nineteenth centuries alongside and in spite of limited mechanisation. Although
in both countries, textiles represented a very large share of the industrial output in the late
eighteenth century – woollens on their own represented almost twenty per cent of the French
industrial output c.1790 – nowhere in Europe was the share of the labour force employed in
textiles as high as in E&W.95 Compared to France, the share of total employment in the textile
industry in E&W remained three times larger (15% to 4.3%) by 1851, and still twice as large
92
Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée’; Jean-Claude Toutain and Yves Breton, La croissance
française, 1789-1990: nouvelles estimations (Paris, 1997).
93
Note these figures are for the total amount of labour input, not individuals in the labour force. It could be 75%
of women with half of them working half time and half full time for instance. In any case, the actual number of
women employed in the secondary sector will be far more than 50% in 1760.
94
Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘Diverse Experiences: The Geography of Adult Female Employment and the 1851
Census’, in Nigel Goose (ed.), Women’s Work in Industrial England: Regional and Local Perspectives
(Hatfield, 2007). See also: www.economiespast.org
95
Tihomir J. Markovitch, ‘La croissance industrielle sous l’Ancien Régime’, Annales, xxxi (1976).
39
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
by 1891 (12.1% to 6.8%). By 1851, it was at least twice as large for men and three times as
large for women (fig.9), and these ratios would have been much greater a century earlier. Only
perhaps in the districts which had a very high share of the female labour force employed in
textiles in the late eighteenth century (especially in Normandy, but even there the amount of
predominant female textile employment that emerges from raw census data) mechanisation
caused a de-industrialisation similar in scale to what occurred across southern England (Terki-
Mignot, in progress).
The evolution of the textile industries throughout the eighteenth and nineteenth
centuries in E&W also underlines another major – and often overlooked – comparative aspect,
that is the very significant divergence between English and French textiles before the era of
mechanised spinning and the path-dependency that resulted from this early specialisation.
Unlike R.C. Allen’s view that France failed to adopt the spinning Jenny because of skewed
relative factor prices (‘wages were too low in France to make it profitable to invest in labour
replacement technology’), it is clear that French textile entrepreneurs did know and experiment
with Jennies from the 1770s, but that the technology failed to catch on, not because of labour
costs in spinning, but because of the major structural differences (counts spun, organisation of
household production, and concentration) between French and English textile industries.96 Nef
had already argued that textiles were not the first but among the last industries to be
the production process throughout the early-modern period.97 Everywhere most of the
production – and certainly all the preparatory work – was organised as a loose and poorly
96
John Styles, ‘The Rise and Fall of the Spinning Jenny: Domestic Mechanisation in Eighteenth-Century Cotton
Spinning’, Textile History, li (2020).
97
John Ulric Nef, Industry and Government in France and England, 1540-1640. (Ithaca, 1957); John Ulrich
Nef, The Conquest of the Material World (Chicago, 1964).
40
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
interconnected network of cottage industries. France might have held a competitive advantage
in the headline-grabbing production of niche upper-market goods such as lace, tapestry, silk,
and fine clothing, often supported by public investment in highly capital-intensive production,
such as in the Manufactures Royales, but this was a superficial illusion detracting attention
from the low-quality, low capital intensity, poorly integrated and regulated production of
coarser yarn and fabric that dominated throughout the country. In E&W, inversely, the rapid
growth in the demand for cloth and household textile goods from the expanding group of
middling-sorts consumers and urbanites led to an early (c.1700) concentration in the woollens
and cotton industries: in East Anglia, in the West Riding and Lancashire, but also in the
finishing process in and around London, especially in the dyeing trades. The agglomeration
effects derived from this concentration were unparalleled in France, and the industrial
geography of nineteenth century France largely mirrors regional patterns established before
1700.
In both countries, the value added per worker was higher in the chemical industries
(encompassing soap, wax and candles and gunpowder, but also critical intermediary products
such as dye, potash, alkali, soda and starch). Growth in the chemical industry was proportional
to the textile industries. Kerridge estimated that around a fifth of the cost of woollen cloth came
from dyeing (soap and dyes), but also wax and starch for weaving linen,98 and Barker showed
that textiles (mainly cottons) and the hard soap and glass industries were the three main
consumers of alkali. Given that the output of the textile industries in E&W was more than twice
the value of the French output and increasing very rapidly in the late eighteenth century,
demand for chemical intermediary products was also logically twice as large. The rising costs
of these chemicals because of trade disruption (warfare) and rising competition for resources
98
Brian W. Peckham, ‘Technological Change in the British and French Starch Industries, 1750-1850’,
Technology and Culture, xxvii (1986).
41
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
from all European textile industries were serious additional production expenses for
manufacturers, in both England and France, and led to the industrial production of synthetic
substitutes.99 Higher consumer demand and a faster rate of urbanisation in E&W might also
have played a role in creating a larger market for domestic products such as candles and soap.
Fig.9 Share of the labour force employed in the textile industries, 1700-1900
TEXTILES #M EW TEXTILES #F EW
TEXTILES # M FR TEXTILES #F FR
45.0
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Although demand-led explanations of the Industrial Revolution have not convinced economic
occupational data clearly indicate the impact of living standards on the development of
99
T. C. Barker, R. Dickinson, and D. W. F. Hardie, ‘The Origins of the Synthetic Alkali Industry in Britain’,
Economica, xxiii (1956).
100
Jan de Vries, ‘The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution’, The Journal of Economic History,
liv (1994); Jan de Vries, The Industrious Revolution : Consumer Behavior and the Household Economy, 1650 to
the Present (Cambridge, 2008).
42
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
consumer-oriented industries in the early modern period, such as clothing, shoe making and
more generally textiles.101 Together, these sectors accounted for over half of the entire industrial
output of both countries before 1800 (table 1). Our data show that the precocious specialisation
of English industry in consumer goods is already notable in 1700 (fig. 10a-c) and contrasts
dramatically with the situation in France where a strikingly high proportion of the labour force
concentrated in the processing of food and drink. This difference must necessarily be the result
of very different levels of demand for these goods, and therefore we would argue of living
standards. By 1740, the Welsh political economist Josiah Tucker was in no doubt as to the
The Manufactures of the Kingdom … are more adapted for the Demands of Peasants
Tradesmen, and Manufacturers in middling Life; and for wholesale Dealers, Merchants,
and all Persons of Landed Estates, to appear in genteel Life; than for the Magnificence
of Palaces, or the Cabinets of Princes. Thus it is, according to the very Spirit of our
Constitution, that the English of these several Denominations have better Conveniencies
in their Houses, and affect to have more in: Quantity of clean, neat Furniture, and a
greater Variety (such as Carpets, Screens, Window Curtains, Chamber Bells, polished
Brass Locks, Fenders, &c. &c. (Things hardly known Abroad among Persons of such a
Rank) than are to be found in any other Country in Europe, Holland excepted. … Were
101
This does not reassert demand as a cause for the Industrial Revolution but shows that higher demand was the
consequence of the economic development of England before 1700.
43
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
in France, and of a Peasant, or Mechanic in England, the latter would be found, upon an
to Allen’s high-wage economy thesis and its relation to mechanisation in the textile industry.103
Despite all the nuances and criticisms waged at Allen’s work, and the new data produced since
its publication, so far none has however repudiated the fundamental fact that aggregate living
standards were significantly higher in Britain than in France in the eighteenth century, and that
for this simple reason aggregate demand must have been significantly higher. The size of the
The relative size of the footwear industry provides indirect evidence of this. By 1700
the share of the male labour force employed in the footwear industry was twice as large in
E&W than in France, and it was still at least 50 per cent larger in 1850. Shoes were – and
perhaps still are for a large part of lower income countries, especially for children – among the
most visible tell-tale sign of economic development. Our comparative data are supported by
denoting the strict footwear hierarchy of poverty. Beyond social standing, the relationship
between footwear quality and living standards was commonly accepted as a reliable indicator
102
Josiah Tucker, Instruction for Travellers, 1758, p.40. Quoted in Neil McKendrick, The Birth of a Consumer
Society : The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England (London, 1982), 25–6; Margaret Spufford,
Great Reclothing of Rural England: Petty Chapman and Their Wares in the Seventeenth Century (1984), 4.
103
Apart from the literature on real wages mentioned above, see Ugo Gragnolati, Daniele Moschella, and
Emanuele Pugliese, ‘The Spinning Jenny and the Industrial Revolution: A Reappraisal’, The Journal of
Economic History, lxxi (2011); Craig Muldrew, ‘“Th’ancient Distaff” and “Whirling Spindle”: Measuring the
Contribution of Spinning to Household Earnings and the National Economy in England, 1550–17701’, The
Economic History Review, lxv (2012); Jane Humphries and Benjamin Schneider, ‘Spinning the Industrial
Revolution’, The Economic History Review, lxxii (2019) and the ensuing debate with Allen, including:; Jane
Humphries and Benjamin Schneider, ‘Losing the Thread: A Response to Robert Allen’, Economic History
Review, lxxiii (2020); Judy Z. Stephenson, ‘Mistaken Wages: The Cost of Labour in the Early Modern English
Economy, a Reply to Robert C. Allen’, The Economic History Review, lxxii (2019), and the ensuing debate with
Allen in EHR; John Styles, ‘Robert Allen’s Spinning Jenny Is Still Broken.’, The Spinning Project, (2019);
Humphries and Schneider, ‘Losing the Thread’.
44
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
century peasants as suffering ‘from hunger and nudity,’ with ‘three quarters of them only
wearing – in both summer and winter – half rotten and torn fabric and clogs, which they wear
bare foot throughout the year. If they do happen to own shoes, they are only worn on Sundays
and holidays.’105 The iconography of footwear is equally revealing. Take two paintings by
Louis Le Nain (illustrations 1a-b below) both dating from 1642 with a remarkably similar
composition: in the first one, Les Petits joueurs de cartes, a group of youngsters are playing
cards under the vigilant care of a maid and either an older brother or a young servant. The two
boys in the foreground, clearly from a less affluent household than the children on the other
side of the table, are barefoot. We cannot see the feet of the other children, but in another
version of this painting held in the Royal collection, the elegantly dressed boy coming through
the door on the right-hand side very visibly dons a pair of leather shoes. As is often the case in
Le Nain brothers’ paintings of peasants’ interiors, shoes reveal the social dynamic of the group.
The second painting is even more revealing in this regard. In Repas de paysans Le Nain puts
together an allegoric triptych of the social condition of French peasantry: in the middle a rich
farmer dressed in a shiny coat with a white-collar shirt and a carefully trimmed beard
accompanied by his son, dressed in the same manner and holding a violin; on the left a
relatively wealthy peasant household represented by a man with simple unsullied woollen shirt
and trousers slightly damaged at the knees, indicating his working condition, and his wife and
son both dressed in a similar manner. The man wears shoes. Finally, on the right-hand side, a
104
Giorgio Riello, A Foot in the Past: Consumers, Producers and Footwear in the Long Eighteenth Century
(2006).
105
Sébastien Le Prestre Vauban, Description géographique de l’élection de Vézelay: contenant ses revenus, sa
qualité, les moeurs de ses habitants, leur pauvreté et leur richesse, la fertilité du pays et ce que l’on pourrait y
faire pour en corriger la stérilité et procurer l’augmentation des peuples et l’accroissement des bestiaux, ed.
Jean-François Pernot (Saint-Léger-Vauban, France, 1986). ‘Il ne faut donc pas s'étonner si des peuples si mal
nourris ont si peu de force. A quoi il faut ajouter que ce qu'ils souffrent de la nudité y contribue beaucoup, les
trois quarts n'étant vêtus, hiver et été, que de toile à demi pourrie et déchirée, et chaussés de sabots, dans
lesquels ils ont le pied nu toute l'année. Que si quelqu'un d'eux a des souliers, il ne les met que les jours de fêtes
et dimanches.
45
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
miserable, landless day labourer and his son, both dishevelled and barefoot. The father sits on
A few years later, Defoe also used clogs as a symbol of the comparative misery of the
French, ‘our Neighbours … reduced to Black Bread, Garlick, and Wooden Shoes’,106 and
Boulainvilliers, the French dilettante historian, seconded him. In his Etat de la France
published five years after his death, in 1727, he noted that in hard times the number of people
wearing clogs and clog making increased significantly: ‘On fabrique … das toutes les Forêts
beaucoup de Sabots, que la pauvreté à rendu beaucoup plus communs qu’ils n’étoient du tems
de nos Peres.’107 The Swiss traveller Cesar de Saussure, who was in England between 1725
and 1729, was surprised to see that, unlike on the Continent, ‘the lower classes are usually well
dressed, wearing good cloth and linen. You never see wooden shoes in England, and the poorest
individuals never go with naked feet’.108 The situation – and the analysis – were not very
All the country, girls and women, are without shoes or stockings [he remarked]
and the ploughmen at their work have neither sabots nor feet to their stockings. This
among the poor being of more consequence than among the rich: the wealth of a
nation lies in its circulation and consumption; and the case of poor people abstaining
106
Daniel Defoe and Henry Sacheverell, A Speech without Doors (1710), 13.
107
Henri de (1658-1722) Auteur du texte Boulainvilliers, État de La France, Dans Lequel on Voit Tout Ce Qui
Regarde Le Gouvernement Ecclésiastique, Le Militaire, La Justice, Les Finances, Le Commerce, Les
Manufactures, Le Nombre Des Habitans, & En Général Tout Ce Qui Peut Faire Connoître à Fond Cette
Monarchie. Tome 1 / . Extrait Des Mémoires Dressez Par Les Intendans Du Royaume, Par Ordre Du Roi, Louis
XIV... Avec Des Mémoires Historiques Sur l’ancien Gouvernement de Cette Monarchie Jusqu’à Hugues Capet.
Par Monsieur Le Comte de Boulainvilliers. On y a Joint Une Nouvelle Carte de La France... Tome Premier [-
Second] (1727), 260.
108
César de Saussure, A Foreign View of England in the Reigns of George I and George II.: The Letters of
Monsieur Cesar de Saussure to His Family; Translated and Edited by Madame Van Muyden (1902), 113.
46
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
from the use of manufactures of leather and wool ought to be considered as an evil
Edward Rigby, who travelled through France a year after Young, also noted of French women
– perhaps not without some excitement on his part – that ‘their legs are quite naked, with neither
shoe nor stocking.’110 Malthus, too, when travelling on the Continent in 1829 made a series of
similar observations: in Western Flanders he remarked on ‘women without shoes, and later on,
going towards Coblenz, he wrote down: ‘people looking poor - women and children without
stockings and shoes.’111 From the seventeenth century onwards footwear clearly denoted living
standards, and British travellers consistently remarked on the general bareness of Continental
feet.
At the bottom of this footwear hierarchy were those too poor to own shoes, followed
by a very large group of impoverished rural households who either had to make their own
footwear or could only afford a couple of pair of clogs per year, which meant that several
members of the household (and clearly women in most cases as seen above) still went barefoot
or with makeshift substitutes. Using clog output estimates for the late nineteenth century (table
4) it is possible to calculate that each adult used between two and three pairs of clogs per year
– which corresponds to contemporary descriptions of the wear and tear of wooden shoes. By
1700, only better off farmers might have used three pairs of clogs per year and perhaps owned
a pair of thick leather shoes worn on Sundays, and their urban counterparts, qualified artisans,
a couple of pairs of thick (often goat) leather or fabric shoes sometimes protected with gaiters,
but most of the rural population had no option but managing with much more limited makeshift
footwear. As it is unlikely (given the already optimistic output per worker figure for 1870
109
Young, Arthur Young’s Travels in France, 27.
110
Rigby and Eastlake, Dr. Rigby’s Letters from France &c. in 1789., 6.
111
Patricia James, The Travel Diaries of Thomas Robert Malthus (2009), 231, 237, and 240.
47
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
shown in table 4 below) that clog makers unassisted by machines could produce over 5 pairs
per day, day in, day out, 300 days per year, even if in the better cases an improved division of
labour only involved the carving out from an existing wooden block, it seems clear that a very
large number of agricultural labourers before the mid nineteenth century would have been
producing/mending their own footwear when they owned some. Standing apart from the great
majority and topping the footwear hierarchy, the gentry and aristocracy donned elaborate
made-to-measure shoes adorned with ribbons, lace, velvet and fine leather, and produced at
great expense by a small number of exclusive shoemakers all located in larger cities. But like
Young himself noted, this top end consumption gives a very distorted picture of the very
Before mechanisation (which began in earnest in the second half of the nineteenth
century) we can safely assume that the share of the labour force employed in shoemaking is a
the population employed in the shoe making industry therefore signals a larger demand for
market-produced footwear and a substitution effect from clogs (or no shoes at all) to more
labour-intensive leather shoes. Using this metric, we can observe that by 1700 the share of the
male labour force employed in the footwear industry was twice as large in E&W than in France,
and that it was still at least 50 per cent larger in 1850 (fig. 10b).
The gap had disappeared by 1901, but by then the effects of mechanisation make this
ratio a much less telling measure of living standards. In England, productivity gains caused by
the introduction of the sewing machine and agglomeration effects through lower transport costs
led to lower share of the population employed in this industry. In France, productivity gains
combined with English imports forced small-scale urban shoemakers to specialise on upmarket
48
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor
luxury goods and almost completely wiped out the scattered rural shoe industry.112 It is perhaps
more revealing to look at the fate of the rural clog making industry after 1850 to have an idea
of relative living standards. First, if we assume that clogs were typical Giffen goods (with
negative elasticity of demand - i.e., the richer people were, the fewer clogs they bought), the
persistence of the clog making industry would signal stagnating living standards. This is not
based on empirical research, but it was certainly how Young, Defoe, Boulainvilliers and almost
every traveller saw it, apart, perhaps, from a handful of folklorists of the later nineteenth
century who romanticised clogs as an image of an idyllic peasant civilisation. After a very
painful personal experiment by one of the authors trying to wear clogs for a couple of days, we
would dare anyone to defend any form of cultural relativism in this respect. Secondly, the
absence of productivity gains in the clog industry allows us to track the evolution of demand
over the second half of the century. Clog making remained the work of individual ‘sabotiers’
providing footwear to fellow villagers or selling them at local markets. Data from the Gazette
du Sabotier, regardless of their accuracy, show that mechanisation in France only took hold in
the early twentieth century, and that millions of pairs were still being produced each year, even
as late as the 1930s.113 By this date, exactly half of the French population (that is around 20
million people) still lived in rural areas, and if we were to believe these numbers, 34 million
pairs of wooden shoes were produced per year! What would Defoe or Young have thought of
children stuffing clogs with barley straw to go to school in the 1930s? Yet, this was a reality.
112
Alain Cottereau, ‘Problemes de Conceptualisation Comparative de l’industrialisation: L’exemple Des
Ouvriers de La Chaussure En France et En Grande-Bretagne’, in Susanna Magri and Christian Topalov (eds.),
Villes Ouvrières, 1900-1950, Book, Section vols (Paris, 1989).
113
J. Daydé, ‘L’industrie des sabots et galoches en France et particulièrement dans le Sud-Ouest’, Revue
géographique des Pyrénées et du Sud-Ouest. Sud-Ouest Européen, vi (1935).
49
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 50
(1) Number of clog-makers; (2) Number of machines; (3) Hand output (millions); (4)
TEXTILES #F EW CLOTHING #F EW
FOOTWEAR #F EW TEXTILES #F FR
45.0
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 51
8.0
7.0
6.0
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 52
Illustrations 1a-b Louis Le Nain (1642), Repas de paysans114 and Les Petits joueurs de
cartes (1642)115
114
2015 RMN-Grand Palais (musée du Louvre) / Mathieu Rabeau,
https://collections.louvre.fr/ark:/53355/cl010059565
115
2006 RMN-Grand Palais (musée du Louvre) / René-Gabriel Ojéda,
https://collections.louvre.fr/ark:/53355/cl010065568
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 53
On the other end of the productive scope stood the luxury industries. The inventories
of most wealthy Europeans in the eighteenth century included French luxury clothing and fine
decorative household goods, which constituted a major export market for French artisans
renowned across Europe for their fashion-setting wares: embroidered silks dresses, printed
cottons (Oberkampf), furs (Révillon), biscuit porcelain (Sèvres), crystal glass (Baccarat), very
elaborate and decorative clocks (Bréguet) were staples of European courts in the late eighteenth
century. As a Frenchman exiled in Berlin wrote in 1786, the European gentry and nobility
‘dress in the French fashion, accommodate their interiors with French furniture, and cook in
the French way.’116 The apocryphal quote attributed to Colbert (‘fashion is to France what the
gold mines of Peru are to Spain’) was already a trope in the 1780s, and was used to portray and
116
Jean-Pierre Erman, Mémoires pour servir à l’histoire des réfugiés françois dans les États du roi (1786), 245.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 54
advertise French refinement and fashion as a trade and diplomatic policy. The nineteenth
century did not depart from this trajectory of luxury craftmanship, and most of the names would
not sound unfamiliar to a modern reader: Guerlain, Hermès, Cartier, Vuitton, etc. But what
does all this glitter tell us about French economic performance? While France enjoyed a niche
observers from the hiatus in the nature of French industrial outputs. Whether in textiles,
potteries or clockmaking, the finest pieces cohabited with a much larger production of coarser,
low quality products, crowded out from the mid-market segments by more productive and
better-quality British competitors. In Britain the earthenware and pottery manufacture and the
making of precision instrument occupied a much larger share of the labour force (at least four
times bigger, Table 5). Only the precious metals and jewellery industries – more specifically
oriented towards luxury products – did reveal a substantial comparative advantage for France.
Table 5. Comparison of share of the labour force in the decorative and precision industries
E&W FR
The market specialisation in high-end craftsmanship and the crowding out from mass
production extended in the nineteenth century to the sectors that underwent some element of
advantage in paper making before the steam age. The paper industry was composed of a string
of typically small workshops located along rivers on the outskirts of towns and which were
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 55
reliant on waterpower and large rags supply (from urban centres) for their production. In the
seventeenth century, France was the major European exporter of paper products, with two
major centres of production in Auvergne and around Charenton providing paper across France
and Europe. In the eighteenth century, however, the geography of paper making slowly evolved
with many small paper mills, spreading along rivers in Northern France, German lands, the
Low Countries and Britain to meet the growing demand for paper. After 1800 the industrial
geography of paper making was almost completely reversed. Between 1800 and 1860, the
British paper output was multiplied by six thanks to the combined benefits of technological
change (the Robert and Fourdrinier machines after 1806), agglomeration benefits, cheap
energy, reduced transport costs, and the enormous increase in the demand from the indigenous
printing industry caused by the emergence of the world’s largest mass media.117
6. Market integration
Our data also point towards key differences in the integration of both labour and
commodities markets in the two countries. Market integration in the eighteenth and early
nineteenth centuries was almost entirely determined by the economic connectivity made
possible by transport infrastructures. More integrated markets unlock the positive externalities
of regional comparative advantage and specialisation. Recent works have revealed the role of
early developments in E&W in lowering freight costs.118 Market integration through transport
infrastructure is also reflected in our data. While 2.2 per cent of the male labour force was
employed in transport by 1700 in France, at the same date it occupied twice as large a share of
117
Juha-Antti Lamberg et al., The Evolution of Global Paper Industry 1800¬–2050: A Comparative Analysis
(2012).
118
On the coaching network: Alan Rosevear, Dan Bogart, and Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘The Spatial Patterns of
Coaching in England and Wales from 1681 to 1836: A Geographic Information Systems Approach’, The
Journal of Transport History, xl (2019); on turnpike trusts and canals: Dan Bogart, ‘Turnpike Trusts and the
Transportation Revolution in 18th Century England’, Explorations in Economic History, xlii (2005); Dan
Bogart, Michael Lefors, and A. E. M. Satchell, ‘Canal Carriers and Creative Destruction in English Transport’,
Explorations in Economic History, lxxi (2019); and on coastal navigation: Dan Bogart et al., ‘Speedier Delivery:
Coastal Shipping Times and Speeds during the Age of Sail’, The Economic History Review, lxxiv (2021).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 56
the male labour force (4.5 per cent) in E&W (see fig.2 above). This ratio peaked to 3.8 times
in 1861, only to go back progressively to 2.4 by 1911. Between 1700 and 1911, the transport
sector in E&W was consistently two to four times larger than in France. If we now weight these
figures by the potential area covered (c.151,000 sq.km for E&W, c.535,000 sq.km in 1700 and
between 1871 and 1914 for France) the balance tilts even more in favour of E&W, which had
2.98 per cent of the male labour force employed in transport per hundred thousand square
kilometres, and France only 0.41 per cent per hundred thousand square kilometres, with the
caveat that in E&W a larger fraction of transport workers were employed in the overseas branch
than in France.
Sub-sectoral data for the transport sector reveals further differences in the degree of
connectivity and integration of the two economies. First, by 1700 Britain was already
comfortably leagues ahead in both maritime and inland navigation with a combined 3.4 per
cent of the male labour force employed in those sectors compared with only 0.8 per cent in
France. Even if we discount oceanic trading to focus solely on coastal (i.e., domestic) trade, we
can assume that the difference between the two nations was no less significant. Based on Nef’s
claim that perhaps up to half of all merchant fleet was used for coastal shipping,119 and applying
the same ratio to France (although this is undoubtedly an exaggeration given the much more
limited amount of coastal trade by 1700), and while ignoring the fact that oceanic crews would
be larger, we can make an educated guess that the share of the labour force employed in costal
shipping would have occupied over one per cent of the male labour force in E&W and less than
a quarter of a per cent in France. The steady increase in the naval dominance of E&W across
the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries and the crushing of the French naval power after 1800
significantly strengthened the disparity between the two countries. By the late nineteenth
119
Nef, The Conquest of the Material World, 165.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 57
century, E&W’s lead in maritime transport had more than doubled, and the share of the labour
force it employed was eight times larger in E&W than France. It is true that the distribution of
the naval labour force was necessarily concentrated on the coast, and since the coastline of
E&W is more extended than the French one (c.8.9 thousand kilometres for E&W vs. c.5.8
thousand kilometres for France) one would logically expect a larger commercial fleet in E&W.
Yet: i) even this does not compensate for the gap between the two countries. The longer
coastline also means ii) that a larger portion of the territory (coastal areas) was connected to
regional and national markets through maritime links in Britain than in France, and iii) that
France was split in two between more integrated Atlantic regions and landlocked territories.120
It is a famous saying that the sea unites and the land divides, and if so, it clearly worked in
favour of Britain.
There is more to it than natural endowment and the insular position of Britain, though.
Data for inland navigation show that despite a very abundant network of navigable rivers,
France also lagged in this respect. Bogart et al. have shown that improvements to rivers and
the construction of canals and roads were the largest infrastructure investments in England
during the industrial revolution and that inland waterway network increased significantly the
development of regions connected to it.121 The transport of heavy and bulky goods on barges
unlocked the access to raw material and lowered the cost of imports – especially coal – for
urban markets, while faster, more regular and cheaper road transport delivered the lighter and
more valuable commodities. Across the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries many more goods
were being produced in often specialised areas and needed to be distributed to more distant
120
Edward Whiting Fox, History in Geographic Perspective: The Other France (1972).
121
Dan Bogart et al., ‘Turnpikes, Canals, and Economic Growth in England and Wales, 1800-1850’, Working
Paper, (2017).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 58
markets and the very rapid rise in road transport employment throughout the nineteenth century
Data recently produced by Litvine and Mimeur for the ANR-Communes project
confirm this bleak view of French spatial integration before the railways.122 Using their new
multi-modal model of transport for France and comparing it with similar data produced by the
Cambridge Group for the History of Population and Social Structure for E&W, it is possible to
visualise and quantify the difference in terms of level of connectivity for each individual
parish/municipality across the two economies for different dates. These maps (fig. 11)
demonstrate the striking connectivity gap between the two countries in the nineteenth century.
The relative share of the territory within a six-hour range of a 5000+ settlement differs
significantly both in 1800 and 1830, but the left behind areas in France are remote and less
populated, but when it comes to larger settlements, carrying much larger market potential, the
difference between the two countries is stark. Only a small section of North-Western France,
the Mediterranean coast, Burgundy and the Northern Rhône valley display continuous areas
with significant accessibility to settlements over 10,000 inhabitants, and only one contiguous
area along the Seine for large urban centres over 80,000 inhabitants. If we plot the cumulative
share of the population by the time taken to reach the closer settlement (fig.11), we can see that
the accessibility to 5000+ settlements in France fits exactly that of 80,000+ settlements in
E&W. By this simple visual metric the market potential (that is to say the pool of potential
consumers for the goods produced in a given place for a given journey time) was sixteen times
higher in E&W than in France. All this confirms that the French economy was fundamentally
regional and not national in the first half of the nineteenth century, which is consistent with
observations in the literature that regional specialisation happened at the intra-regional level
122
All data will be available at French Historical GIS, 1700-2020. Administrative units, Populations,
Transports, Economy. (forthcoming 2022), doi.10.5281/zenodo.3727274
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 59
and that cases of national concentration,123 like in the wool industry in the Nord,124 did not
result from the effect of existing comparative advantage but from path-dependency
the nineteenth century when market integration improved, well into the railway age.126
However, our new data invalidates assertions that France enjoyed a market access equivalent
or superior to Britain.127
123
Daudin, ‘Commerce et prospérité’.
124
Markovitch, ‘La croissance industrielle sous l’Ancien Régime’.
125
Paul R. Krugman, ‘Intraindustry Specialization and the Gains from Trade’, Journal of Political Economy,
lxxxix (1981).
126
Pierre-Philippe Combes et al., ‘The Rise and Fall of Spatial Inequalities in France: A Long-Run Perspective’,
Explorations in Economic History, xlviii (2011).
127
Guillaume Daudin, ‘Domestic Trade and Market Size in Late-Eighteenth-Century France’, The Journal of
Economic History, lxx (2010).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 60
Fig.11 Comparative connectivity indices for France and E&W, 1800/1830 (Mimeur/Litvine)
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 61
Another way to look at the low integration of the French economy using our
occupational data is to observe the level of structural by-employment in the economy. By-
employment here means any gainful employment in another sector in addition to a person’s
main occupation. In France, slow urbanisation combined with population growth between 1500
and 1715 and then faster demographic growth and urban stagnation between 1715 and 1800
suggests that almost all excess population was absorbed by rural areas. The low level of
urbanisation in 1851 and the lack of regional specialisation combined with limited productivity
growth in industry before the 1830s also indicate that the bulk of the increase in industrial
output between 1740 and 1850 must have relied largely on rural industries and chronic
intersectoral by-employment, either seasonal or throughout the working day. This was already
the case in the seventeenth century,128 and it remained so well into the nineteenth century:
peasants could be occasional miners, masons, ditch diggers, road builders, flax spinners, knife
grinder, etc., but industrial workers also left their workshops to help out in the fields, especially
during the harvests when wages were higher in agriculture than in the workshops.129 We can
now quantify these intersectoral flows across the nineteenth century.130 Although the share of
total labour input concerned was relatively moderate (the data presented in table 6 below shows
that by 1891 three per cent of the total labour input by both men and women employed in the
primary sector went to secondary-sector activities), around ten per cent of both the male and
female labour force was regularly by-employed throughout the century, which means that out
of a theoretical working year of 300 days one in ten worker would have taken c.90 days off
(ten per cent of the labour force for three per cent of the total labour input) per year to work in
128
Pierre Goubert, Cent mille provinciaux au 17e siècle : Beauvais et le Beauvaisis de 1600 à 1730 (1977);
Pierre Goubert, La Vie Quotidienne Des Paysans Francais Au XVIIe Siecle (Paris, 1982).
129
Pierre Sicsic, ‘City-Farm Wage Gaps in Late Nineteenth-Century France’, The Journal of Economic History,
lii (1992).
130
For a fuller description, see: Litvine, ‘French Occupational Structure, Industrialisation and Economic Growth
France, 1695 to the Present.’
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 62
another sector. This might have little macroeconomic significance as sectoral flows more or
less compensated each other, but it is revealing of both the inability of the agricultural sector
to support a large enough labour force for the peak season in spite of an oversupply of labour,
and the inability of the industrial sector to retain its labour force throughout the year. Why was
it necessary to hire factory hands during the harvest? And why did agricultural labourers, often
holders of small plots also work in industry? This suggests that the French economy functioned
as a juxtaposition of smaller regional economies, which, in most cases, did not reach the scale
required to support independent industrial and agricultural sectors as the regional labour pool
responded to seasonal wage incentives. This long-lasting symbiotic relationship between the
two sectors also acted as a life insurance policy for households able to rely on the food supply
and income – however limited they might be – to face the vagaries of industrial cycles.
Inversely, our new data for in England, and especially evidence from probate inventories have
shown that already by the early eighteenth century, and unlike previous assumptions in the
literature, by-employment in manufacturing (except for domestic spinning) had become very
Table 6 Intersectoral by-employment labour flows in the second half of the nineteenth century
1851 1891
7. Conclusion
131
Sebastian A. J. Keibek and Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘Early Modern Rural By-Employments: A Re-Examination
of the Probate Inventory Evidence’, The Agricultural History Review, lxi (2013).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 63
In 1968, Eric Hobsbawm asked: ‘if we placed ourselves in the Britain of 1750 without the
wisdom of hindsight, would we have predicted the imminent Industrial Revolution? Almost
certainly not.’ Yet, he added, ‘looking back, we can see that no other country was as well-
prepared for the Industrial Revolution.’132 Every word of this still stands today, and comparing
England and France confirms the validity of his pronouncement. England by 1700 was already
in a unique position in Europe, if not the world. Since Hobsbawm’s assessment, lengthy debates
about past economic performance have hinged on comparisons of national accounting series,
and especially GDP. Occupational data complement these metrics by offering a set of robust
and comparable data reflecting the nature and structure of past economies. Our data gives an
unflinching account of the divergence between England and the rest of the world (and in the
case of this article, France) well before the classical period of the Industrial Revolution, and it
puts to rest any argument that by 1700 or 1750 France might have been a serious contender to
industrial primacy. As such our argument stands as the sectoral counterpart of the “little
divergence” between the two countries shown in recent studies of GDP and real wages from
the sixteenth to the eighteenth century. Because it works at the sectoral and industrial level it
economy, with small islands of commercial and industrial prosperity dotted in an ocean of
relative immiseration. The major achievements of French scientists, the riches accumulated in
some trading towns, the global repute of French luxury goods and artistic production, the
industrial prowess and technical achievements often supported by state investments, and the
economic leadership of some enlightened administrators, were but fig leaves hiding the
132
Hobsbawm (1968), Industry and Empire, ch.1, pp.10-11
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 64
bareness of the ancien regime economy. French roads in the late eighteenth century were
symbolic of this French economic mirage: they were beautiful, built at amazing expense by the
State with large and ingenious works of civil engineering, and Arthur Young – who otherwise
pulled no punches in his observations on France – thought they were among the best roads in
Europe, but, he also noted, they enjoyed very little traffic, at least nothing like the commercial
hustle and bustle he was used to witnessing on a typical busy English road.
Yet, France’s backwardness was obviously not absolute but only relative to England. French
development in sixteenth century and seventeenth centuries, however modest and episodic,
was undoubtedly accompanied by some growth of the secondary sector. Seventy per cent of
the labour force employed in agriculture as witnessed in 1700 is high compared with
As Hobsbwam pointed out, being in the best position to industrialise is in no way the
same as explaining why and when it did. In this article, we have not explored in any meaningful
way the causal mechanisms that led England to experience such a rapid and sustained wave of
innovations in the eighteenth century (i.e., “why was England first?”) but our data make a
strong case for the return to a much longer periodisation of the technological and social
enabling factors of the Industrial Revolution, in line with the older literature from Mantoux to
Nef.