Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Paper 40

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 64

Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 1

‘Why wasn’t France First?’ The Industrial Revolution in England and France: New

Data and Further Thoughts on the Question.

England1 in 1500 was lightly urbanised and predominantly agricultural by the standards of the

more developed regions of Eurasia such as the Low Countries and parts of China. Yet, when

Etienne Perlin, a Parisian medical student, visited England in the early 1550s, he witnessed an

opulent society that compared favourably with the France of Henri II and other European

nations he knew of.2 He describes a very prosperous and mercantile nation boasting large

supplies of precious metals and manufactured goods: leather, woollens, draperies, metalware,

tin and lead, as well as many fisheries.3 Perlin also noticed that living standards were high with

meat-rich diets, especially for artisans such as hatmakers and carpenters who enjoyed much

higher real wages than in other parts of Europe.4 White bread, he added, was superior to that

of the French for a similar price,5 and he was very impressed by the fact that houses even in the

smaller towns had several glassed windows, and that all the inns he visited on his tour were

well furnished and decorated, with embroidered cushions and flowers.6 Perlin’s evidence is

1
This paper concerns not Britain but England and Wales. Scotland has been excluded from the analysis because
at the time of writing, no data are available on the occupational structure of Scotland before the middle of the
nineteenth century. With Scots representing only 10-15 per cent of the population of mainland Britain this
omission is not likely to fundamentally distort the picture of the British economy that emerges on the basis of
data from England and Wales alone.
2
It is not entirely clear what part of England he travelled through, but he seems at least to have travelled from
Dover to London and then to Bristol, Cambridge, and Newcastle on his way to Scotland.
3
Estienne Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin
(1558), 17. ‘il y a force argent, & l’or y est gros, & il y a force cuirs, laines, draps, métaux, bon estain, plomb,
force pescheries, qui leur vallent grand deniers.’
4
Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin, 17–19.
‘Les gens d’iceluy lieu sont de grande chère & ayme fort à bancqueter & vous verries force riches tavernes, &
les taverniers qui ont coustumierement grosses bourses, ou il y a trois ou quatre bourserõs plaine d’argent, par
ce moyen pouvons considerer que le pays est fort argēteux & que les gēs de metier gaignent plus en une
semaine que ceux d’allemaigne ou d’espaigne en un mois. Car vous verris des chappeliers & menuisiers
artisans iouer leu escu à la paume ordinairement, ce que ne voyes pas en un autre lieu ordinairement, &
principalement à un iour ouvrier. Et en une taverne faire grãde chere plus souvent que tous les iours avec
connilz, leveraux, & toutes sortes de viande.’
5
Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin, 22. ‘ils
usent du pain bien plus blanc que en la France, tellement qu’il estoit de mon tēps en aussi bon marché qu’en
France.’
6
Perlin, Description Des Royaulmes d’Angleterre et d’Escosse. Composé Par Maistre Estienne Perlin, 20.‘Par
tout les maison quasi de toutes les villes quāt est aux gens de mesiter : & sont toutes icelles maisons comme les
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 2

certainly anecdotal, but his account shows that for a sixteenth-century European traveller,

England was already notable for its commercial and industrial development and for its

relatively higher living standards.

Comparing mid-eighteenth-century France and England – the two main European powers,

well-endowed geopolitical rivals with similar claims to the hall of fame of the Scientific

Revolution7, and profitable colonial empires8 – has been a regular feature in studies looking at

the causes of the Industrial Revolution. If something as dramatic as the Industrial Revolution

‘happened’ in England during the second half of the eighteenth century, it might seem logical

to wonder why a similar revolution did not take hold in France at the same time, or even earlier?

After all, France was the most populous country in Europe, had more than its fair share of all

European scientists, boasted the iconic vehicle of knowledge diffusion (the Encyclopédie), and

was undeniably a great commercial power whose craftsmen and state-supported Manufactures

Royales produced some of the most sought-after goods across wealthy European households.

Yet, comparing the two countries between 1700 and 1750 as a way to elucidate the causes of

the Industrial Revolution supposes: i) that the Industrial Revolution was an event whose causal

chain was very short (the first half of the eighteenth century), and ii) that England and France

were at a similar level of development by 1750, which would make it equally likely for either

to undergo an Industrial Revolution at this point.

The first point had almost no intellectual support until after WWII. The early scholarship

on the Industrial Revolution, from Toynbee to Mantoux, and up to Clapham saw it as the

gradual (and in Clapham’s case incomplete) culmination of a long process of Smithian growth

ouvrerois des barbiers de France tāt par hault, que par bas, & verries a leurs ouvreoirs & fenestres tant de ville
que de villages forces fleurs, & aux tavernes forces foin dessus les planchiers de boys, & forces oreillies de
tapisseries sur lesquelz les voyagers se assisent’.
7
Peter (ed ) Mathias, Science & Society 1600 - 1900 (Cambridge, 1972), 81; Joel Mokyr and Professor of
Economics and History Joel Mokyr, The Economics of the Industrial Revolution (1985), 128.
8
Guillaume Daudin, ‘Commerce et prospérité : la France au XVIIIe siècle. 2e éd.’, (2011).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 3

and institutional and structural transformations.9 On this view, by 1750 most of the divergence

between England and the rest of Europe, including France, had already happened, and as

Mantoux put it: ‘the Industrial Revolution was no accident’. Looking at the causes for

England’s primacy necessarily required these leading early historians to turn their scholarly

attention to the previous centuries.

Yet, in the black and white ideological world of the post war, the wisdom of these earlier

views got lost in the clamour for brash, politically amenable conclusions. In the nascent field

of comparative economic development, explaining the British Industrial Revolution became a

case in point in the (academic) confrontations of the Cold War to prove the superiority and

historical ineluctability of Western capitalism. The origin of this battle for history really got

going with early Modernisation theorists, and especially the publication of W.W. Rostow’s

Stages of Growth in 1960, closely followed by Alexander Gerschenkron’s Economic

Backwardness, and the work of economic historians such as David Landes, and Rostow again,

with a more ambitious comparative restatement of his stage theory in How it all began.10

Regardless of the merit of their explanations and the nature of their analyses – which have been

the subject of countless articles and pugnacious debates – all these authors share the assumption

that England and France were at comparable levels of economic development in say 1750,

1780, 1800, or even 1850 in the case of Kindleberger.11

Coinciding with the rise of Modernisation Theory, a flurry of new publications by

economists, economic historians and statisticians greatly improved the empirical basis for the

9
Arnold Toynbee, Lectures on the Industrial Revolution in England (London, 1884); Paul Mantoux, La
Révolution Industrielle Au XVIIIe Siècle (Paris, 1906), IX; J. H. Clapham, An Economic History of Modern
Britain : Machines and National Rivalries (1887-1914) with an Epilogue 1914-1929 (1938).
10
W. W. Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth. A Non-Communist Manifesto (pp. x. 178. University Press,
1960); Alexander Gerschenkron, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (1962); David S. Landes,
The Unbound Prometheus : Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to
the Present (Cambridge, 1969); Walt Whitman Rostow, How It All Began: Origins of the Modern Economy
(1975).
11
Charles Poor Kindleberger, Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1851-1950 (1964).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 4

quantitative analysis of economic development in the nineteenth century. These works

constructed long series of key economic indicators (including GDP) constructed using the

National Accounting framework developed between the 1920s and the 1940s and adopted by

most governments in the 1950s for macroeconomic surveying and forecasting. In order to apply

(Keynesian) macroeconomic models to the past, one only had to re-construct series from

existing statistical data and piecemeal historical records. Following in the footsteps of Nobel-

laureate Simon Kuznets, statisticians and economic historians across the Atlantic started to

produce similar retrospective series for their countries. Phyllis Dean and W.A. Coal published

their monumental British Economic Growth from 1688 to 1959 in 1962, arguing that the British

economy experienced its first sustained growth episode between 1760-1850, the ‘classical

period’ of the Industrial Revolution.12 During these ‘years of miracles’ (Mokyr), major

technological innovations came in a continuous stream and drove economic growth in a way

unprecedented in human history.13 Inventions radically decreased the cost of manufactured

goods and increased their quality while vastly expanding their supply, from the refining of

coke-smelted iron with coal to the mechanisation of spinning and weaving and the development

of the steam engine. In this approach to development what is taken as the starting point for this

miraculous story is, in fact, the tail end of a much longer technological evolution associated

with using coal for industrial processes in England. This included: lime burning, by 1400,

textile dying, by 1500, salt making, by 1550, brewing, before 1600, glass manufacturing, in

1612, malting, by 1650, firing pottery, in the 1670s, lead smelting, also in the 1670s, copper

smelting, in 1676, iron smelting, in 1709, and finally iron refining, in 1784.14

12
Phyllis Deane and William Alan Cole, British Economic Growth, 1688-1959: Trends and Structure (1962).
13
Joel Mokyr, The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress (1992).
14
J. R. Harris, The British Iron Industry 1700-1850 (Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire, 1988); John Hatcher,
The History of the British Coal Industry: Volume 1: Before 1700: Towards the Age of Coal (Oxford, 1993).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 5

In France, too, efforts to produce long series of economic data got going after the war.

Collaborative efforts by historians (Fernand Braudel and Ernest Labrousse) and economists

(Jan Marczewski and Francois Perroux) led to the publications of some series by Perroux and

Marczewski in 1947, but the interdisciplinary cooperation proved rather short-lived, and

historians adopted their own vision of quantitative history – called histoire sérielle - that did

not fit in the National Accounting framework.15 It was from the mid 1960s and until the 1980s

that new national accounts series were finally produced by Tibor Markovitch, Jean-Claude

Toutain and Maurice Lévy-Leboyer.16 Having retrospective series for both France and Britain

suddenly made possible a new quantitative approach to the past performance of the two

economies, and Marczeswki’s ‘Le produit physique de l'économie française de 1789 à 1913:

comparaison avec la Grande-Bretagne’, was the first to engage in this systematic comparative

exercise.17

The subject of the economic performance of France over the long nineteenth century and

the speed and nature of its industrialisation thus briefly became a hot topic for Anglophone

economic historians in the 1980s. The publication of a series of revisionist accounts, which

presented a much more optimistic outlook of the French economy, led to some striking

conclusions regarding its economic performance both in the eighteenth century (seen to be on

par with Britain by Richard Roehl and Rondo Cameron), and in the nineteenth century (over-

15
François Perroux, Pierre Uri, and Jan Marczewski, Le Revenu National (Paris, 1947).
16
Jean Marczewski and Jean-Claude Toutain, ‘Histoire quantitative de l’économie française.’, Cahiers de
l’Institut de science économique appliquée. Série AF, Histoire quantitative de l’économie française, i (1961);
Tihomir J. Markovitch, Histoire quantitative de l’économie française: L’industrie française de 1789 à 1964.
Analyse des faits, 3 vols (Paris, France, 1966); Jean-Claude Toutain, Histoire Quantitative de l’économie
Française. IX, Transports En France 1830-1965 (Paris, 1967); Maurice Lévy-Leboyer and François
Bourguignon, L’Économie Française Au XIXe Siècle (Paris, 1985), 185 F; Jean-Claude Toutain, La Production
Agricole de La France de 1810 à 1990 Croissance, Productivité, Structures (Grenoble, 1993).
17
Jean Marczewski and Tihomir J. Markovitch, ‘Le produit physique de l’économie française de 1789 à 1913
(comparaison avec la Grande-Bretagne)’, Les Cahiers de l’Institut de science économique appliquée, clxiii
(1965).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 6

performing compared to Britain by Patrick O’Brien and Caglar Keyder).18 These positive

interpretations found that France growth trends rather than absolute levels. It is after all easier

to grow faster further from the frontier (catch-up growth), and France experienced an earlier

demographic transition and relatively slower population growth in the nineteenth century,

which inevitable skews per capita figures in its favour.

Since then, however, most economic historians have walked back on these judgments.

Revised occupational and output data have largely undone the positive assessment of French

economic performance both in terms of trend and levels, and following Nick Crafts, François

Crouzet, Maurice Lévy-Leboyer and François Bourguignon, Paul Bairoch, and Jean-Pierre

Dormois, all settled for a moderately pessimistic diagnosis for France in the nineteenth

century.19 One point worth noting is that to date a wide disagreement remains on the

quantification and the performance of the French economy in the late nineteenth century. With

four competing GDP series (Toutain, Lévy-Leboyer and Bourguignon, Dormois, and Ridolfi)

and 50 years of impassioned discussions from which no consensus has emerged among

economic historians, it is important to take any definitive judgement based on any one of these

series with a light pinch of salt.20 In recent years, especially in answer to R.C. Allen’s

18
Rondo Cameron and Charles E. Freedeman, ‘French Economic Growth: A Radical Revision’, Social Science
History, vii (1983); Richard Roehl, ‘French Industrialization: A Reconsideration’, Explorations in Economic
History, xiii (1976); Patrick Karl O’Brien and Caglar Keyder, Economic Growth in Britain and France, 1780-
1914 : Two Paths to the Twentieth Century (London, 1978).Bairoch’s series (1978) also reflect this positive
assessment of French economic growth relative to Britain. His series rely on Toutain’s data (published in 1987),
which is by far the most optimistic industrial output series for France. Lévy-Leboyer and Bourguignon (1985)
and Dormois (1999) have suggested much lower figures for the value of the French industrial output.
19
N. F. R. Crafts, ‘Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1830–1910: A Review of the Evidence’, The
Journal of Economic History, xliv (1984); François Crouzet, De la supériorité de l’Angleterre sur la France:
l’économique et l’imaginaire, XVIIe-XXe siècles (Paris, 1985); Lévy-Leboyer and Bourguignon, L’Économie
Française Au XIXe Siècle; Paul Bairoch, Victoires et Déboires. Histoire Économique et Sociale Du Monde Du
XVIe Siècle à Nos Jours (Paris, 1997); Jean-Pierre Dormois, ‘Évaluation et Composition Du Produit Industriel
Français Avant 1914’, Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, (1997); Jean-Pierre Dormois, ‘Tracking the
Elusive French Productivity Lag in Industry’, Hitotsubashi Univ. Research Unit for Statistical Analysis in
Social Sciences, Inst. of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi Univ.
20
A discussion is available in A. Litvine (2020), French Occupational Structure, Industrialisation and Economic
Growth, France, 1695 to the Present, pp.8 ff.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 7

comparative causal explanation of the Industrial Revolution,21 new series for France have

appeared, showing that it fared slightly better than Allen thought in the eighteenth century,

with relatively higher real wages22 and sustained commercial and industrial expansion.23 These

new observations do not change, however, the modest performance of the French economy

over the whole period. First, it is not surprising that wages were higher in the more industrially

and technologically advanced regions like Normandy, and when compared to similar regions

across the Channel the relative difference between the two countries remains significant.

Second, real wages in France on the eve of the Revolution were not desperately low only

insofar as food was also relatively cheap or the average diet less abundant. The French

population had already reached its pre-Black Death level (around twenty million) sometime

between 1600 and 1650 and Malthusian pressures must undoubtedly have been building up

(although not consistently across the country) from the mid seventeenth century, unlike in

England, which did not recover its pre-Black Death population until the late eighteenth century.

England had thus a much more favourable land/labour ratio in the early modern period

compared to much of Europe, which also coincides with the timing of the divergence between

England and France (around 1650) suggested by Ridolfi’s and Nuvolari’s recent GDP figures.24

https://www.campop.geog.cam.ac.uk/research/occupations/outputs/preliminary/france_1695_present_al.pdf. See
also Jean-Claude Toutain, ‘Comparaison entre les différentes évaluations du produit intérieur brut de la France
de 1815 à 1938 ou L’histoire économique quantitative a-t-elle un sens ?’, Revue économique, xlvii (1996). And
for the more recent: Leonardo Ridolfi and Alessandro Nuvolari, ‘L’histoire Immobile? A Reappraisal of French
Economic Growth Using the Demand-Side Approach, 1280–1850’, European Review of Economic History, xxv
(2021).
21
Robert C. Allen, The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective (Cambridge, 2009).
22
Cédric Chambru and Paul Maneuvrier-Hervieu, The Evolution of Wages in Early Modern Normandy (1600–
1850) (University of Zurich, 2021); Leonardo Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée: A Study on
Real Wages, Working Days and Economic Performance from Louis IX to the Revolution (1250–1789)’,
European Review of Economic History, xxi (2017); Vincent Geloso, ‘Were Wages That Low? Real Wages in
the Strasbourg Region Before 1775’, The Journal of Interdisciplinary History, xlviii (2018); Leonardo Ridolfi,
‘Six Centuries of Real Wages in France from Louis IX to Napoleon III: 1250–1860’, The Journal of Economic
History, lxxix (2019).
23
Daudin, ‘Commerce et prospérité’.
24
Ridolfi and Nuvolari, ‘L’histoire Immobile?’
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 8

Beyond the data and the conclusion regarding economic performance lies one of the most

important methodological - perhaps we could even say epistemological – issues in economic

history. Using the wealth of new data published in the 1960s and 1970s, Nick Crafts penned

an article comparing Britain and France, which claimed that the Industrial Revolution was

fundamentally a stochastic (i.e., an accidental) process.25 His conclusion was that: ‘Put in the

context of England's primacy in achieving the “decisive innovations,” it does not of itself

necessarily imply that Britain ex ante in, say 1740 had the greater probability of achieving the

first industrial revolution or that one should feel obliged to seek reasons for Britain's inevitable

primacy going far back into her history.’ Since then, Crafts has distanced himself from this

interpretation, and most explanations now agree that technological change is endogenous, path-

dependent, gradual and multi-factored, but his methodology in reaching this conclusion

remains a powerful component of many studies in our field.26 ‘As far as economic theory is

concerned’, Crafts argued in the same article, ‘it is in fact difficult using neo-classical

assumptions to derive predictions about the rate of technological progress in general or even to

support the assertions of writers such as Crouzet, Landes and Habakkuk of the beneficial effect

of the “shortages” experienced by the British economy in the first half of the eighteenth

century.’ What conclusion should we derive from this statement? Is it that Crouzet, Landes,

Habakkuk, Allen and Wrigley are wrong? Or rather that neo-classical assumptions and models

based on their work may be problematic for historical knowledge production – especially in

terms of causal inference. Arthur Lewis, himself a Nobel prize winner in economics, would

agree with this: ‘from the point of view of countries with surplus labour [definitely the case of

25
Crafts (1977), ‘Industrial Revolution in England and France: Some Thoughts on the Question, “Why was
England First?”’, The Economic History Review
26
N. F. R. Crafts, British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution (Oxford, 1985); N. F. R. Crafts
and C. K. Harley, ‘Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley
View’, The Economic History Review, xlv (1992); N. F. R. Crafts, ‘Macroinventions, Economic Growth,
and‘Industrial Revolution’in Britain and France’, Economic History Review, xlviii (1995).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 9

all early-modern economies] neoclassicism is not an analytical framework which can relevantly

fit [our] problems’.27 Before trying to determine causality, should we not first apply ourselves

to describing as precisely as possible the nature of the phenomena studied? This fundamental

empiricism would surely spare us the absurdity of concluding that what was, could not have

been. What good is it to use a probabilistic model to show that Britain's industrialisation was

‘partly due to chance’ and that ‘France could have moved out of agriculture and into

manufacturing faster than Britain, but the probability was less than 30 percent’, if we can

document that it was not the case?28

As the optimistic accounts of French economic performance were being rejected, and

perhaps as part of the diminishing importance of cold-war mentality, key estimates of economic

growth for Britain were also revised downwards, and the British Industrial Revolution came

again to be seen as a more gradual and protracted process with early modern origins.29 More

recent work by Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley using occupational data has confirmed and extended

Crafts’ revisionism, showing that the growth in manufacturing employment in Britain took

place between 1550 and 1750, not between 1750 and 1850 – long before any other European

country.30 Thus, logically, if both Britain and France fared less well than previously thought

during the classical period of the Industrial Revolution (1760-1850), the divergence between

the two countries must have originated not in the late eighteenth century but much earlier, and

was clearly present in the seventeenth or, perhaps even, the sixteenth century, by the time of

Perlin’s visit to England.

27
W. Arthur Lewis, ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’, The Manchester School, xxii
(1954).
28
Nico Voigtländer and Hans-Joachim Voth, ‘Why England? Demographic Factors, Structural Change and
Physical Capital Accumulation during the Industrial Revolution’, Journal of Economic Growth, xi (2006).
29
Crafts, British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution; Crafts and Harley, ‘Output Growth and the
British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View’.
30
Leigh Shaw-Taylor and E. A. Wrigley, ‘Occupational Structure and Population Change’, in Roderick Floud,
Jane Humphries, and Paul Johnson (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain (2014).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 10

Recent work by Broadberry et al. suggests that British GDP per capita stagnated from 1350

to 1650 and then grew at around 0.5% per year from 1650 to 1830.31 Regardless of the merit of

these figures, their findings do not contradict this early divergence hypothesis. Firstly, the

phase of slow economic maturation, 1500-1650, that enabled more rapid ‘modern’ economic

growth thereafter was not accompanied by large increase in GDP per capita, and in the context

of a population at least doubling between 1500 and 1650, the fact that living standards did not

collapse is in itself suggestive of major economic development.32 Secondly, it should be noted

that GDP estimates are controlled conjectures with significant margins of error, even if this is

only too rarely acknowledged by their producers.33 This article suggests that a key feature

traditionally associated with industrialisation – occupational change – happened before 1700

in England and that it is this precocity which explains the different paths taken by the two

countries before 1750. Using new occupational data at the sub-sectoral level, we conclude that

it is time to rehabilitate the older, long-term view of the Industrial Revolution and pay more

attention to suggestions made by Nef for the period 1540-1640, and by both Crouzet and

Wrigley and Schofield on the longer period 1550-1750 regarding the early modern roots of the

British industrial divergence.34

Nef had shown that the shift to energy-intensive forms of production in the sixteenth

century meant that England had a decisive comparative advantage when it came to industrial

products like saltpetre, glass, salt, dyes, alum, and in the ship building industry; but above all

31
Stephen Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’, Cambridge Core, (2015).
32
We do not accept Broadberry et al’s suggestion that economic development is reducible to GDP per capita
growth. Achieving the same GDP per capita at double the population over the same area clearly requires
considerable economic development.
33
Charles Hilliard Feinstein and Mark Thomas, ‘Making History Count: A Primer in Quantitative Methods for
Historians’, (2012).
34
John U. Nef, ‘A Comparison of Industrial Growth in France and England from 1540 to 1640’, Journal of
Political Economy, xliv (1936); François Crouzet, ‘Angleterre et France au XVIIIe siècle : essai d’analyse
comparée de deux croissances économiques’, Annales, xxi (1966); François M. Crouzet, Britain Ascendant :
Comparative Studies in Franco-British Economic History (1990); E. A. Wrigley, The Population History of
England 1541-1871 : A Reconstruction (Cambridge, 1981).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 11

in coal, metal and textiles, which all helped Britain vastly expand her trade across the world

between 1540 and 1640.35 By 1700, Britain was already an exception in Europe, while France,

despite episodic growth in the sixteenth and early seventeenth century, remained a relatively

poor performer. Growth picked up after 1715 accompanied by population growth but limited

structural change at the national level. In the word of Crouzet, ‘on the eve of the Revolution

the French economy was the same it had been under Louis XIV [1643-1715]. It was simply

producing more.’36 The following revolutionary decade left the French economy in tatters but

laid the bases for subsequent (modest but steady) growth in the nineteenth century.37

1. Description of the data

This paper is an outgrowth of a collaborative international research project, The International

Comparative History of Occupational Structure (INCHOS). The INCHOS project provides

harmonised data to compare the development of occupational structure across 19 different

countries during the period in which they industrialised and made the transition to modern

economic growth. The fruits of this research will be published as Saito and Shaw-Taylor,

Occupational structure, industrialization and economic growth in a comparative perspective.

The present authors contributed chapters on England and Wales, and on France; a much fuller

description of sources and methods will be found there.

For England and Wales (henceforward E&W), the published population censuses of 1851,

1861, 1871, 1881, 1891, 1901 and 1911 provided detailed enumerations of occupations by both

age and sex in over 400 categories and are the source of all our occupational data for the period

35
What has been sometime called the ‘Nef thesis’, his argument for dubbing this period a first industrial
revolution, has been rejected, but in part – and unhelpfully we believe – for the mislabelling of early-modern
economic development as a revolution. It is also true that Nef stopped his analysis in 1640 and sometimes
argued that little change happened afterwards. We now know that development carried on right through, which
fits very nicely with the gradualist interpretation that came out of the work of Crafts and Harley.
36
Crouzet, Britain Ascendant : Comparative Studies in Franco-British Economic History, 26.
37
Crafts, ‘Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1830–1910’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 12

1851-1911. The 1841 census also recorded male and female occupations in considerable detail.

However, while the male data are reliable, female occupations are systematically under-

enumerated compared with the later censuses. We also have male data for c.1710 and c.1817,

but of very different provenance. From the 1st of January 1813 it became a legal requirement

to record the occupations of fathers in Anglican baptism registers. Since 90 per cent of all men

married in this period and other denominations widely used Anglican baptisms, counts of the

occupations of the fathers provides a quasi-census of male occupations.38 Data were collected

from virtually all 11,400 Anglican baptism registers, generating 2.5m observations over an

eight-year period centred on 1817. Comparison with other sources shows that this generates a

robust picture of male occupational structure.

Comprehensive data on female occupations do not exist before 1851. We have instead

calculated sub-sectoral sex ratios from the 1851 population census and applied these ratios to

the male occupational data for earlier periods. Of course, these would not necessarily have been

the same c.1710, c.1817 and in 1851. The approach followed here is to use the 1851 sex ratios

where we have no reason to believe they would have differed from those prevailing in that

year. For certain sectors (textiles, agriculture and the making of clothes) the existing secondary

literature strongly suggests that the ratios would have been different, and we have drawn on

the secondary sector to modify the ratios accordingly.39

The results of this work have already proved transformative for the national history of the

British Industrial Revolution. Deane and Cole believed that as late as 1760 between 60 and 80

per cent of the labour force was employed in agriculture and that this figure had fallen to 25

38
P M Kitson et al., ‘The Creation of a Census of Adult Male Employment for England and Wales for 1817’;
Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley, ‘Occupational Structure and Population Change’.
39
The methodology and results are described in: Leigh Shaw-Taylor, Keith Sudgen, and Xuesheng You, ‘A
Preliminary Estimate of the Female Occupational Structure of England and Wales 1700–1911’, (2021).
Available at: https://www.campop.geog.cam.ac.uk/research/occupations/outputs/preliminary/
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 13

per cent by 1851.40 They thus saw the Industrial Revolution as characterised by a massive

change in the structure of employment. Crafts, drawing on work by Lindert and Williamson,

suggested a more protracted structural transformation when he estimated that agriculture

accounted for 56 per cent of the labour force in 1688.41 Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley confirmed

the size of the primary sector as 50 per cent of the labour force c.1710 but present a very

different picture of secondary and tertiary-sector employment.42

In France, as in England, regular census-taking began in 1801 but occupational data were

only compiled in the published returns after 1851, which means that for the first half of the

nineteenth century little occupational data is readily available.43 Unfortunately, until 1896 (or

perhaps even 1901) the unadjusted occupational data collected during quinquennial censuses

and industrial (1839-47 and 1860-65) and agricultural (1840, 1852, 1862, 1882, 1892) surveys

were, generally, of poor quality, especially for female and child labour, which were both

dramatically under-recorded, if at all. The data presented in this chapter are based on: i) new

capitation tax-based estimates for the period 1695-1790 using an expanded sample from

Ostroot and Snyder,44 ii) new estimates based on burial, marriages and baptism records for the

period 1740-1819 from the Enquête Henry-Biraben, iii) revised sectoral estimates from

Marchand and Thélot for 1811-1896,45 and iv) adjusted census returns from 1851 onwards.46

40
Deane and Cole, British Economic Growth, 1688-1959.
41
Peter H. Lindert and Jeffrey G. Williamson, ‘English Workers’ Living Standards During the Industrial
Revolution : A New Look’, Economic History Review, xxxvi (1983); Crafts, British Economic Growth during
the Industrial Revolution.
42
Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley, ‘Occupational Structure and Population Change’.
43
The authors are currently collecting and compiling these data from the nominative census lists, but it will be
many years until a national coverage is achieved.
44
Nathalie Ostroot and Wayne Snyder, ‘The Quality of Life in Historical Perspective France: 1695?1990’,
Social Indicators Research, xxxviii (1996); Wayne Snyder, ‘Occupational Evolution in XVIIIth and XIXth-
Century France’, The Journal of European Economic History, xxxv (2006).
45
O. Marchand and Claude Thélot, Deux Siècles de Travail En France: Population Active et Structure Sociale,
Durée et Productivité Du Travail (Paris, 1991), 140 FRF.
46
Alexis Litvine, ‘French Occupational Structure, Industrialisation and Economic Growth France, 1695 to the
Present.’, in Leigh Shaw-Taylor and Osamu Saito (eds.), Occupational Structure, Industrialization and
Economic Growth in a Comparative Perspective.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 14

Four striking features emerge from a simple glance at the data presented in tables 1a-b

and fig.1 below: i) the radical difference in the level of employment in the primary sector from

the early eighteenth century between the two countries (around 70 per cent of the total labour

force in France, below 40 per cent in E&W). ii) The industrial divergence between France and

E&W (measured in the relative share of employment in the secondary sector) happened well

before the Industrial Revolution. By 1710, E&W had already 43 per cent of its active male

labour force working in the secondary sector (as opposed to Crafts’ previous estimate of 19 per

cent in 1688), while only 16 per cent of working age males were employed in industry in France

by 1725. As a consequence, the secondary sector was already by this date three times larger in

E&W than in France. iii) The flatness of the share of the secondary sector throughout the

classical period of the Industrial Revolution in E&W, and the steady growth in employment in

the tertiary sector during the eighteenth and early nineteenth century, a development which has

not been a feature of the dominant historical national accounts view of the Industrial Revolution

so far. Inversely, the stagnation of tertiary sector employment in France until the mid-

nineteenth century, which suggests a much more limited commercial integration and slower

urbanisation. These points confirm the observations made by Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley, while

emphasising the uniqueness and precocity of the English economy.

Although there is no reliable comparative estimate of industrial output by 1700, rough

indications of output levels in 1750 can be taken from Broadberry and O’Rourke.47 According

to these figures, British industrial output per capita was twice as large as that of France by

1750. Given that French industrial output for the period 1700-1750 grew by an estimate of 52

47
Figures from: Paul Bairoch, ‘International Insutrialisation Levels from 1750 to 1980’, Journal of European
Economic History, II, ii (1982); Crafts and Harley, ‘Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A
Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View’; Stephen Broadberry and Kevin H. O’Rourke, The Cambridge
Economic History of Modern Europe: Volume 1: 1700–1870 (Cambridge, 2010), i.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 15

per cent,48 and that British output grew by 34 per cent over the same period,49 we can safely

assume that French industrial output per capita was at least 60 per cent smaller than that of the

British by 1700. And not only was British industrial output per capita larger, but its composition

reveals a much deeper and longer structural transformation of the economy. Judging by the

relative weight of sectors in the total output circa 1800 (table 1), the most striking feature is

that the share of the food and drink industry in both the total industrial output and the industrial

labour force was respectively three and eight times lower than in France. A likely explanation

of the difference is that in E&W the share of food production had already shrunk with the

growth of other industries, especially manufacturing, chemicals and heavy industry. Even

accounting for the specialised and export-oriented wine and spirit production in France, this

clearly suggests – not unlike Engel’s Law (which posits that the share of income spent on food

decreases as total income grows) – a much less diverse and mature industrial sector. Using the

same data, we can also have an indication of relative intra-sectoral productivity gaps by looking

at the ratio of the share of the labour force to their respective share in the total industrial value

added by sector. This gives an idea of how much one per cent of the labour force in each sector

contributed to the total industrial output by 1800. Obviously, these ratios (table 1, columns 3

and 6) are only meaningful indications within countries and not between them – it is worth

remembering that by 1800 the industrial output per capita was 2.14 times bigger in E&W.

In the following pages we will use our new sub-sectoral data to examine: 1) the evolution

of agricultural productivity and the impact of urbanisation, 2) the mineralisation of the

economy, 3) productivity growth and the textile industries, 4) the role of consumer demand

and market specialisation and 5) the impact of transport on market integration.

48
Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée’.
49
Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 16

Fig. 1a-b Sectoral distribution of the male and female labour force (in %)

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
c1720 c1810 1851 1881 1911
P_FR S_FR T_FR P_EW S_EW T_EW

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
c1720 c1810 1851 1881 1911
P_FR S_FR T_FR P_EW S_EW T_EW
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 17

Table 1 Share of total industrial value added and share of the industrial labour force per

sector in France and E&W c.180050

FRANCE E&W
VA IndLF VA IndLF
(1) (2) (1)/(2) (4) (5) (4)/(5) (4)/(5)*2.14
Mining & fuel 0.2 0.2 1.0 4.0 4 1.0 2.1
Metals 6 2.5 2.4 7.0 8.5 0.8 1.8
Chemical 1.7 0.1 17.0 3.2 0.1 31.6 67.6
Textiles 42 10.5 4.0 45.7 18 2.5 5.4
Food & drink 22.3 8 2.8 6.9 1 6.9 14.8
Paper 1.1 1.5 0.7 0.4 1.4 0.3 0.5
Construction 14 15 0.9 13.9 16 0.9 1.9

Nb: the margins of errors for these figures were not specified by all authors, but we can assume they are large
since where they were made clear (by Feinstein), they stand between 15 and 20 per cent for this period.

2. Agricultural productivity and economic development

The common wisdom is that French agriculture performed relatively poorly in the second half

of the seventeenth century and throughout the eighteenth century, but with the caveat that some

regions did better than others.51 Hoffman calculated TFP growth rates for French agriculture

between 1520 and 1789 and found increasing productivity in the Paris Basin and the North and

South-East.52 Similarly, Grantham observed an increase in productivity across France (albeit

limited to the arable sector and excluding the Mediterranean regions) between 1600 and 1800,

50
Markovitch, Histoire quantitative de l’économie française; Jean-Claude Toutain, Le produit intérieur brut de
la France de 1789 à 1982 (Grenoble, 1987); Charles H. Feinstein, ‘Economic Growth Since 1870: Britain’s
Performance in International Perspective’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, iv (1988); Crafts and Harley,
‘Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View’; N. F. R.
Crafts, ‘British Economic Growth, 1700-1831: A Review of the Evidence’, The Economic History Review,
xxxvi (1983); Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’.
51
See Emmanuel Le Roy Ladurie and Joseph Goy (eds.), Les fluctuations du produit de la dîme; conjoncture
décimale et domaniale de la fin du Moyen Age au XVIIIe siècle. (Paris, 1972); Fernand Braudel, Ernest
Labrousse, and Pierre Léon, Histoire économique et sociale de la France Tome III, 4 vols (Paris, 1976), iii;
Robert C. Allen, ‘Economic Structure and Agricultural Productivity in Europe, 1300-1800’, European Review of
Economic History, iii (2000); Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée’.
52
Philip T. Hoffman, Growth in a Traditional Society, The French Countryside, 1450-1815 (Princeton, N.J.,
1996).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 18

indicating divergent regional trajectories.53 The problem with metrics such as TFP and grain

yield estimates is that they come with high compound margins of errors, which makes the

comparison of the performance of the primary sector across countries problematic. For this

reason, we think it is preferable to consider the relative size of the primary sector as the key

comparative measure – albeit indirect – of the overall efficiency of an economy in the early

eighteenth century.54 As such, the early shift out of the primary sector in E&W (fig.3a and 3b)

indicates without any doubt a much higher level of aggregate agricultural productivity. By

1710, 44 per cent of the English active male population could support the other 56 per cent not

working the land (imported calories are negligible), while in France at the same date the

proportion was 70 to 30. These numbers indicate a spectacular difference in the carrying

capacity of the primary sector (that is the share of the population able to survive without

producing food themselves in an economy with limited food imports) in the two countries.

And, finally, given that there is compelling evidence that the English (already comically but

also enviously dubbed ‘les rosbifs’ in the eighteenth century) ate much better than the French

in this period, these figures underestimate the difference between the two countries.

We currently have only limited data for the proportion of French women working in

agriculture in the early eighteenth century, but given that the share of the female labour force

employed in agriculture in France was higher than the male share in 1800, and in E&W much

lower than the male share, it is likely that the inclusion of women would not change the result

(fig.3a), and, would only increase the size of the productivity gap. One remarkable feature,

though, is the early sexual division of labour in agriculture in E&W visible in fig.3a.

53
George W. Grantham, ‘Divisions of Labour: Agricultural Productivity and Occupational Specialization in
Pre-Industrial France’, The Economic History Review, xlvi (1993).
54
E. Anthony Wrigley, ‘Urban Growth and Agricultural Change: England and the Continent in the Early
Modern Period’, The Journal of Interdisciplinary History, xv (1985); Karl Gunnar Persson and Paul Sharp, ‘An
Economic History of Europe: Knowledge, Institutions and Growth, 600 to the Present’, Higher Education from
Cambridge University Press, (2015).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 19

Agriculture was far more feminine in France with 35.4 per cent of the total agricultural labour

force being women in 1801, against 26 per cent in Britain in 1817. Observing the large of

number of women working in the fields of France was one of the most common tropes in

contemporary travelogues. In July 1789 Edward Rigby, from Norwich, observed that in

Northern France ‘women … seem to do a great deal of labour, especially in the country. They

carry great burdens, and seem to be employed to go to market with the produce of the fields on

their backs.’ Further, he notes that: ‘the agriculture is chiefly done by women.’55 A couple of

years earlier Arthur Young had made a similar observation about Normandy where he noticed:

‘women … ploughing with a pair of horses to sow barley. The difference [he added] of the

customs of the two nations is in nothing more striking than in the labours of the sex; in England,

it is very little that they will do in the fields except to glean and make hay … in France, they

plough and fill the dung carts.’56

What explains this difference between the two countries? The question covers at least

three distinct issues: farmers’ wives and daughters, farm servants, and agricultural labourers.

It is safe to assume that farmers’ wives and daughters would have participated in farm work

right through to the nineteenth century. However, as the proportion of farmers’ households in

England and Wales was falling throughout the period 1500-1851, the share of farm labour

supplied by farmers’ wives and daughters decreased substantially.57 Regarding farm servants

there is currently no clear indication in the literature. We still do not know whether the share

of female farm servants declined over the eighteenth century, or before, or not at all. As for

55
Edward Rigby and Elizabeth Eastlake, Dr. Rigby’s Letters from France &c. in 1789. (London, 1880), 16.
56
Arthur Young, Arthur Young’s Travels in France: During the Years 1787, 1788, 1789, ed. Matilda Betham-
Edwards (Cambridge, 2012), entry for May 22nd 1787.
57
A major area of uncertainty, in both England and France, is the relative labour inputs directly into the farm by
farmers' wives and daughters, compared with adult male farmers and farmers' sons. No doubt higher in pastoral
areas, especially dairying, than in arable areas. We are not including in this discussion the extent to which
female farm household members 'household work' should be considered as contributing to or underpinning the
operation of the farm.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 20

day labourers, the evidence is that only a modest share of day labour was ever supplied by

women, and it seems (although not yet proven) that the share declined in the century after 1750.

However, the share of all farm labour supplied by day labour was certainly increasing from

1500 or perhaps even before.58 Overall, as soon as proletarianisation in agriculture began to

shift labour inputs from farmers’ wives and daughters to farm servants, this must have led to

declining female participation.59 The question then becomes, ‘When did proletarianisation

really take off in E&W: in the fourteenth, fifteenth, or sixteenth century?’ The jury is still out

on this aspect, but preliminary results from a survey of coroners’ inquest data on accidental

deaths indicate that in Southern England it was certainly before 1500 (data shows three

labourers to every farmer, as much as in 1700). This early proletarianisation again suggests

looking back at the early modern or even medieval roots of the precocious economic

development in E&W.

Furthermore, making the reasonable assumption that the withdrawal of women from

agriculture before 1750 was not absorbed by an equivalent decline in the female labour force

participation rate (FLFP) necessarily means that other sources of employment became available

both in the secondary sector (proto-industry and manufacturing) and, crucially, in the tertiary

sector.60 In the early nineteenth century – because of the sharp decline in FLFP caused by the

mechanisation of spinning – the tertiary sector had become the fastest growing sector for

female employment, and already by 1800 half of the labour force in the service industry in

E&W were women (51 per cent) against just over a third in France (36.5 per cent). There, as

58
Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘The Rise of Agrarian Capitalism and the Decline of Family Farming in England’, The
Economic History Review, (2011).
59
Ivy Pinchbeck, Women Workers and the Industrial Revolution, 1750-1850 (London, 1930), 44, 110; Shaw-
Taylor, Sudgen, and You, ‘A Preliminary Estimate of the Female Occupational Structure of England and Wales
1700–1911’. Available at:
campop.geog.cam.ac.uk/research/occupations/outputs/preliminary/female_estimates_lst_ks_xy_2019.pdf
60
Women’s LFPR was comparable to men’s, even during marriage. See Amy Louise Erickson, ‘Married
Women’s Occupations in Eighteenth-Century London’, Continuity and Change, xxiii (2008).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 21

fig.3b shows, only 14.4 per cent of the female labour force was employed in the tertiary sector,

while it had already reached 32.4 per cent in E&W. This large gap is consistent with the rising

pace of urbanisation in E&W (table 2) over the eighteenth century. Cities across Europe drew

from a large pool of female migrants to work in domestic services and manufacturing61 so that

– as it was certainly the case in Paris by 1800 – cities contained substantially more women than

men, and even more so in E&W (clearly visible in figs.5a-b). By 1851, 30 per cent (35 in 1881)

of the female labour force in E&W were employed as domestic servants, but only eight per

cent (13 in 1881) in France, and logically, the more urban the population, the higher the ratio

of female to male workers was likely to be in the service industry (fig.2). This fact also suggests

that the urban demand for female labour was a key determinant of the rate of exit of young

females from the primary sector in E&W and contributed to its precocious structural

transformations. The pattern of female emigration is already clearly visible in South-East

England in 1801 but much less so in France, where male emigration dominates most of the

northern half of the country (figs.5a-b). More generally, the fact that the sexual distribution of

the French population remained so stable over the first half of the century, especially compared

to the English and Welsh cases, is testament to the very limited structural (i.e., urban)

transformation of the economic geography of France over this period.

Figs. 3a-b. Comparison of the evolution of the share of the labour force employed in agriculture

and in the service industry for both sexes 1700s -1901

61
Amy Louise Erickson. and A. Schmidt, ‘Migration’, in Christine MacLeod and Maria Ågren, eds, The Whole
Economy, Cambridge University Press, forthcoming
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 22

PRIMARY #M EW PRIMARY #F EW
PRIMARY # M FR PRIMARY #F FR
80.0

70.0

60.0

50.0

40.0

30.0

20.0

10.0

-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911

TERTIARY #M EW TERTIARY #F EW
TERTIARY # M FR TERTIARY #F FR

70.0

60.0

50.0

40.0

30.0

20.0

10.0

-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 23

The rapid population growth in France over the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries

(fig.4) may have precipitated an intensification of Malthusian constraints. From Sauvy to

Goubert and Wrigley and Schofield, most demographic historians seem to agree that the French

population was too large in the seventeenth century.62 The eighteenth century saw a definite

improvement. Dupâquier argued that France was experiencing a virtuous Boserupian cycle

(pressure on resources leading to increasing agricultural productivity).63 English population

grew much more rapidly in the nineteenth centuries but strikingly did so without precipitating

a Malthusian crisis.64

Fig. 4. Stylised evolution of population growth 1350-1900 (in million)

POP FR POP EW

46,000
41,000
36,000
31,000
26,000
21,000
16,000
11,000
6,000
1,000
1350 1600 1800

62
Alfred Sauvy, Théorie générale de la population. (Paris, 1952); Pierre Goubert, 100 000 provinciaux au
XVIIe siècle: Beauvais et le Beauvaisis de 1600 à 1730 (1968); Wrigley, The Population History of England
1541-1871 : A Reconstruction.
63
Jacques Dupâquier, Introduction a La Demographie Historique (Paris, 1974).
64
E. A. Wrigley, ‘Coping with Rapid Population Growth: How England Fared in the Century Preceding the
Great Exhibition of 1851’, in David Feldman and Jon Lawrence (eds.), Structures and Transformations in
Modern British History (Cambridge, 2011).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 24

Fig. 5a-b Sex ratios in 1801 and 1851 by arrondissement and registration district
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 25
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 26

Fig. 6 Population density at parish/municipal level in 1794-1801, 1856-1851 and 188165

More quantitative studies have confirmed this view. Weir did not identify any Malthusian

pressure in France after 1740, and finally Grantham calculated that by 1800 only forty per cent

of the population was required to produce all the food necessary to feed the whole population.66

Yet, the situation might not have been as rosy as they suggest.

Firstly, national stagnation and regional improvements can coincide. Malthusian

pressures dominated in most regions while some experienced faster (Boserupian) productivity

growth. The divergence in regional performance in agriculture is now well documented,67 and

we know it was then a dominant factor in the geography of living standards.68 The same was

probably true across the eighteenth century.

65
GIS-datasets for Belgium and the Netherlands kindly provided by Isabelle Devos and Rombert Stapel.
66
David R. Weir, ‘Life Under Pressure: France and England, 1670–1870’, The Journal of Economic History,
xliv (1984); Grantham, ‘Divisions of Labour: Agricultural Productivity and Occupational Specialization in Pre-
Industrial France’.
67
Hoffman, Growth in a Traditional Society, The French Countryside, 1450-1815.
68
Laurent Heyberger, ‘Niveaux de vie biologiques, disponibilités alimentaires et consommations populaires en
France au milieu du xixe siècle’, Annales de demographie historique, cxviii (2009).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 27

Secondly, even the more optimistic narrative does not fundamentally diminish the

comparative backwardness of the French economy. The most advanced regions were able to

sustain higher population density than the poorer ones, but even these remained well below

levels observed in the denser regions of E&W (fig.6). As cross-country variations in population

density were highly correlated to land productivity and technological development, just a

glance at the map below should suffice to see that by 1800 Britain had reached a much higher

level of development.69 The eighteenth century looked favourably only when compared to the

misery of the seventeenth century.

Third, sectoral reallocation is a consequence of economic development and not its

cause. If, as contended by Grantham, only a modest share of the population sufficed to produce

the calories required to sustain the whole population, while a much larger contingent was

employed in agriculture, this is a clear indication of sub-optimal sectoral allocation of the

labour force. Grantham himself showed that retention of a surplus rural labour force was

required to match peak labour demand at harvest time, and that subsequent changes in

occupational structure were fundamentally linked to improvements in transports and market

integration in the second half of the nineteenth century.70 Was this not simply the situation in

most, or perhaps all, early modern societies across Eurasia at the time – apart from Britain?

Here again, Britain stands as sui generis. The real question is why and how Britain could afford

to reallocate such a large (relatively less productive) share of its population, while others were

not even at similar level of GDP/capita. Older explanations were psychological (attributing the

reticence to migrate to a peasant mentality) or institutional (blaming peasant property, and/or

the Code Civil, for keeping unnecessary unproductive labour in rural areas), but they all work

69
Quamrul Ashraf and Oded Galor, ‘Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch’, American Economic
Review, ci (2011); Oded Galor, ‘The Demographic Transition and the Emergence of Sustained Economic
Growth’, Journal of the European Economic Association, iii (2005).
70
Grantham, ‘Divisions of Labour: Agricultural Productivity and Occupational Specialization in Pre-Industrial
France’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 28

on the premise that it would have been possible to reallocate such a large share of the labour

force.71 Even Harley’s recent account adopts this view:

In France, rural labor – the peasantry – was free to move but chose to remain

on the land, often substantially self-sufficient and at lower material reward than

urban alternatives offered. They were able to make that choice because they

owned the land. By staying on the land the peasant family chose a lifestyle that

misallocated labor if we accept the criterion that marginal product should be

the same in alternative uses – the retention of labor on family farms reduced

the marginal product of labor in agriculture below that in the rest of the

economy. In effect, peasant families chose to expend potential land rent on

maintaining rural peasant status. It is hard not to accept that at least for the

generations making the choice that this was an informed and rational decision.72

Given that France reached in 1844 the level of GDP/capita that Britain achieved in 1700 and

that the share of primary sector employment in France at this date (1841) was 63 per cent of

the total labour force (for both sexes), it would have taken a sectoral reallocation of 9.6 million

people (that is 44 per cent of the total labour force) in order to match E&W’s level of

employment in the primary sector. If we do the same calculation using Britain’s level of

GDP/capita in 1800, which France achieved in 1874, when it had 54 per cent of its labour force

in the primary sector, it would have then taken a re-allocation of over 3 million people (or 17

71
This includes: Paul Hohenberg, ‘Change in Rural France in the Period of Industrialization, 1830–1914’, The
Journal of Economic History, xxxii (1972); Robert Brenner, ‘Agrarian Class Structure and Economic
Development in Pre-Industrial Europe’, Past & Present, (1976); P. K. O’Brien, ‘Agriculture and the Industrial
Revolution’, The Economic History Review, xxx (1977); O’Brien and Keyder, Economic Growth in Britain and
France, 1780-1914 : Two Paths to the Twentieth Century; Maurice Agulhon et al., Histoire de la France rurale,
tome 3 : De 1789 à 1914 (1992); Patrick Karl O’Brien, ‘Path Dependency, or Why Britain Became an
Industrialized and Urbanized Economy Long before France’, The Economic History Review, xlix (1996).
72
C. Knick Harley, ‘British and European Industrialization’, in Jeffrey G. Williamson and Larry Neal (eds.),
The Cambridge History of Capitalism: Volume 1: The Rise of Capitalism: From Ancient Origins to 1848
(Cambridge, 2014), i.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 29

per cent of total labour force). How likely was that to happen in a short period of time? Our

argument, in a nutshell, is that France could not have reallocated such a large share of its labour

force, as: i) the urban demand for this extra labour did not exist, ii) the urban infrastructure

required to maintain such a large population was non-existent, iii) French living standards were

so low that the urban penalty caused by mass urban migration would have led to a major human

and demographic catastrophe, and iv) the institutional mitigation of the costs associated to the

transfer of labour from surplus regions (the Poor Law) did not exist in France.73 Lewis and

O’Brien and Keyder were therefore probably right in describing a French path – potentially

even an ‘everyone-else-but-Britain’ path – to economic development based on limited

population growth to maintain decent levels of GDP per capita throughout the nineteenth

century, and a slow release of labour from the countryside to mitigate the negative effects of

rapid urbanisation.74 After all, keeping people on the land might have been a necessary social

and welfare policy for societies with very low living standards and deficient infrastructures.

The situation could not have been more different across the Channel where higher

agricultural productivity fed – literally – the very rapid urbanisation of the country. By 1600,

the population of E&W was only marginally more urban than France, but two centuries later

the difference was staggering (table 2). By 1800, the size of the population living in areas

considered to be urban in E&W was a third higher than in France, and the share of the

population living in large towns and cities was almost three times higher. The relationship

between the growth of urban settlements and the rest of the country is a key element in the

social and economic developments happening between 1550 and 1700. In a seminal article, EA

Wrigley showed that the rise of cities is a signal of economic development (which made

73
Peter M. Solar, ‘Poor Relief and English Economic Development before the Industrial Revolution’, The
Economic History Review, xlviii (1995); Peter M. Solar, ‘Poor Relief and English Economic Development: A
Renewed Plea for Comparative History’, The Economic History Review, l (1997).
74
Lewis, ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’; O’Brien and Keyder, Economic Growth
in Britain and France, 1780-1914 : Two Paths to the Twentieth Century.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 30

urbanisation possible in the first place),75 but also that it drove further economic change: market

integration, increasing agricultural productivity, the rise of a mineral economy, lower transport

costs, rising real wages and demand for industrial goods.76

Table 2 Urbanisation rates at different thresholds in France and in E&W77

DATES FRANCE E&W


2,000+ 5,000+ 10,000+ 2,500+ 5,000+ 10,000+
1700/1671 17 12 8 17 13 10
1806/1801 19 12 9 34 28 24
1821 20 15 10 40 34 29
1831 21 17 11 45 40 34
1841 23 18 13 49 44 38
1851 26 19 14 54 49 44
1861 28 23 18
1871 31 28 22
1881 35 30 24

Unlike the food and processing industry, the share of the industrial labour force

employed in construction was not sensitive to the increase in size of the secondary sector, i.e.,

that the demand elasticity of the construction industry was close to one during the second half

of the nineteenth century. The expectation, however, would be that a faster rate and level of

urbanisation in E&W would have led to an equivalent increase in the share of employment in

the construction industries, but this is not visible in our data. Why? It might be that British

75
E. A. Wrigley, ‘A Simple Model of London’s Importance in Changing English Society and Economy 1650–
1750’, Past & Present, xxxvii (1967).
76
E.A. Wrigley, Energy and the English Industrial Revolution (2010).
77
Data for France from: Jacques Dupâquier, Mée René Le, and Joseph Goy, Histoire de La Population
Française de 1789 à 1914 (Paris, 1988), iii; Paul Bairoch, Jean Batou, and Pierre Chèvre, La population des
villes européennes, 800-1850: banque de données et analyse sommaire des résultats (1988); Marchand and
Thélot, Deux Siècles de Travail En France: Population Active et Structure Sociale, Durée et Productivité Du
Travail; Wrigley, ‘Urban Growth and Agricultural Change: England and the Continent in the Early Modern
Period’; Jan De Vries, European Urbanization, 1500-1800 (1984); John Langton, ‘Urban Growth and Economic
Change: From the Late Seventeenth to 1841’, in Peter Clarke (ed.), The Cambridge Urban History of England,
1540 – 1840, Book, Section vols (Cambridge, 2000), ii. The series are not homogeneous as definitions of urban
population are not strictly identical. Figures in italics are linearly interpolated from the closest available census
date.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 31

construction workers enjoyed a higher productivity, or simply a case of misreporting in the

original data - but at least two more factors might explain this evolution: i) Britain had a major

competitive advantage in brick making compared to France, and the share of total construction

using brick is very likely to have been much higher in Britain than in France throughout the

period, which confers a secondary advantage in productivity compared to oak or stone building;

ii) the share of the total labour input in the construction industries used for new builds vs.

renovations or repairs has never been estimated for historical periods, but given that

refurbishments amounted to 42 per cent of the total output of the UK construction industry in

2020, it is not unlikely that two thirds of the labour force in the construction industries would

have been employed in repair work in the early nineteenth century, when building standards

and longevity were significantly lower than today.78 If so, the more prevalent use of brick in

E&W compared to timber probably increased the durability of buildings and reduced the needs

for annual repairs, which in turn freed labour time for new constructions.

Fig.2 Distribution of the male labour force for key subsectors 1700-1911 (in %)

78
Office for National Statistics, ‘Construction Statistics, Great Britain’, (2021).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 32

TEXTILES ENG&W TEXTILES FR


CONSTRUCTION ENG&W CONSTRUCTION FR
METAL ENG&W METAL FR
MINING ENG&W MINING FR
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911

DOMESTIC SERVICES #F EW
DOMESTIC SERVICES #M EW

40.0

35.0

30.0

25.0

20.0

15.0

10.0

5.0

-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 33

ROAD TRANSPORT EW ROAD TRANSPORT FR


INLAND NAVIGATION EW INLAND NAVIGATION FR
SEA TRANSPORT EW SEA TRANSPORT FR
RAIL TRANSPORT EW RAIL TRANSPORT FR
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911

ARMED FORCES EW ARMED FORCES FR

7.0

6.0

5.0

4.0

3.0

2.0

1.0

-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 34

3. The transition to a mineral economy and energy-intensive production

Alongside rising urbanisation, E&W underwent a radical shift in its energy base from charcoal

and firewood to coal. According to Nef (1932), this energy divergence started after 1540, when

the use of coal in England increased very rapidly. By 1650, and uniquely for any contemporary

economy, E&W was well advanced in this process of mineralisation with a third of all the

energy consumed coming from coal (table 3). Nef later argued that coal use in England had

then stagnated until the later eighteenth century79 – which we now know not to be the case.80

He also added that between 1735 and 1785 ‘the output of coal and iron grew faster in France

than in England’.81 The higher growth rate for coal in France is factually correct with coal

output growing from c.100,000 tons a year in 1720 to c.600,000 tons by 1789,82 but it reflects

first and foremost the fact that the French coal industry was so very small by 1735 that its

growing rapidly was of little significance compared to the slower growth rate (but from a much

larger base, around three million tons a year in the 1700s to over fifteen million by 1800)83 in

Britain. Overall, coal output and consumption grew steadily and at a much higher average

annual growth rate in E&W than in France from the sixteenth to the nineteenth centuries. The

comparative lens clarifies this debate: by 1800 the annual coal consumption per capita in E&W

reached 41 gigajoules, and barely 0.7 gigajoules in France! By 1851, almost five per cent of

the male labour force in E&W was employed in mining while it only occupied a meagre 0.7

per cent of the French male labour force. Nef’s claim that ‘no domestic practice marked off

79
John U. Nef, ‘The Industrial Revolution Reconsidered’, The Journal of Economic History, iii (1943).
80
Paul Warde, Energy Consumption in England & Wales, 1560-2000 (2007); Wrigley, Energy and the English
Industrial Revolution; Astrid Kander, Paolo Malanima, and Paul Warde (eds.), Power to the People (Princeton,
N.J., 2014).
81
Nef, ‘The Industrial Revolution Reconsidered’, 18.
82
Marcel Rouff, Les mines de charbon en France au XVIIIe siècle, 1744-1791: étude d’histoire économique et
sociale (1922); Jean-Francois Belhoste, ‘L’essor de l’usage Industriel Du Charbon En France Au XVIIIe
Siècle’, Le Charbon de Terre En Europe Occidentale Avant l’usage Du Coke (1999), 44 (NS 7).
83
Hatcher, The History of the British Coal Industry; Brian R. Mitchell, British Historical Statistics (1988), 247.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 35

English from Continental, and particularly French, life more sharply than the use of this newly

adopted coal fire’ was as true in 1640 as it was in 1800, and perhaps even in 1850.84

The higher energy output was driven by the energy intensive industrialisation and the

growing demand for domestic coal heating spurred by rapid urbanisation, directly related to

the higher share of the male labour force employed in mining in E&W (fig.8). This fact, already

outlined by Nef and Wrigley, is not unexpected. What is more surprising is that the ratio of the

share of the industrial value added to the labour force in the extractive industries should be the

same in the two countries (table 1 column 6), and that the productivity gap between the two

countries (column 7) did not exceed a factor of 2. This signals the enabling rather than

revolutionary role of technological change in the extractive industries before 1800. From the

1760s the key progress achieved with early steam pumps and steam haulage85 (for getting coal

up the pit shaft) made possible (by shifting the decreasing marginal return curve to the right)

the large increase in coal extracted – from deeper, better ventilated shafts – but it did not

fundamentally alter the apparent productivity of labour at the coalface until much later in the

nineteenth century.86 The work of a coal miner was fundamentally the same throughout the

period, but technology simply made it possible to mine much more of it.

And with this enormous increase in the supply of coal in the economy (see table 3

below) came major positive externalities for the more voracious industrial sectors, such as the

salt, brewing, glass (lead-oxide crystal), ceramics (especially stoneware) metal wares and the

smelting of non-ferrous metals – all elements already mentioned by Perlin in the 1550s! The

very large difference in the share of the male population (and therefore most likely of the whole

population) employed in the metal industries illustrates the tail end of this process very clearly.

84
Nef, ‘A Comparison of Industrial Growth in France and England from 1540 to 1640’, 170.
85
G. Clark and D. Jacks, ‘Coal and the Industrial Revolution, 1700-1869’, European Review of Economic
History, xi (2007).
86
G. N. Von Tunzelmann, Steam Power and British Industrialization to 1860 (1978).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 36

By 1800 just under 4 per cent of the total male labour force was employed in the metal

industries in E&W but under 0.5 per cent of the total male labour force in France, a staggering

eight-fold difference. Pig iron output figures per capital show a similar gap between the two

economies: from 4,705 tons per million inhabitants in EW in 1700 to 11,250 tons per million

inhabitants by 1790, compared with 1,100 tons and 3,392 tons in France at the same dates.87

Our data also confirm the negative correlation between increased pressures on wood

resources (the so-called “timber crisis”) and coal mining in France from the late eighteenth

century. The higher the price of heating and fuel the stronger the incentive to overcome the

natural barriers to large-scale coal mining, i.e., pumping water out and transporting cheaply

large amounts of coal. Urbanisation, intensive arable farming, an increase in the share of

pastoral land required for meat-rich urban diets, and the large forestry cover required to produce

timber and charcoal for construction and both industrial and domestic processes, all contributed

to raising wood prices up to a level that progressively made it economically viable to dig coal

on an industrial scale,88 but whereas this process started in the 1650s in E&W, our data for

France show a clear scissor effect in the evolution of the share of the labour force employed in

the mining and forestry industries happening only after 1850 (fig. 8). By 1800 mining occupied

only a trivial share of the labour force. At the same time, forestry occupied eight times as large

a relative share of the labour force in France than in England at what might have been France’s

peak dependence on wood (the share of the male labour force employed in forestry reaches its

maximum in 1881). It is no surprise that current scholarship points at the mid-nineteenth

87
Mitchell, British Historical Statistics, 280; Philip Riden, ‘The Output of the British Iron Industry before
1870’, The Economic History Review, xxx (1977), 443; Crouzet, ‘Angleterre et France au XVIIIe siècle’, 268.
88
R. C. Allen, ‘Why the Industrial Revolution Was British: Commerce, Induced Invention, and the Scientific
Revolution’, The Economic History Review, lxiv (2011).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 37

century as the historical minimum of French forestry cover, well below its level at the last Ice

Age, and current levels.89

Table 3 Mineralisation of energy expenditure, 1650-190090

DATE (EW) (FR) (EW*) (FR*)


% % GJ GJ
1650 32.1 - 6.5 -
1700 48.6 - 14.8 -
1800 77.5 3.8 40.8 0.7
1850 91.7 27 82 5.7
1900 95.5 73.6 144.1 36
Share of coal in total energy expenditure (%) (E&W) and (FR)
Per capita coal consumption (in Giga Joules) (E&W*) (FR*)

89
Xavier Rochel et al., ‘Quelles sources cartographiques pour la définition des usages anciens du sol en
France ?’, Revue Forestière Française, (2017); J. Dupouey et al., ‘Cartographie Des Forêts Anciennes de
France : Objectifs, Bilan et Perspectives’, Colloque International « Géohistoire de l’environnement et Des
Paysages » (Toulouse, 2016); R. Fuchs et al., ‘A High-Resolution and Harmonized Model Approach for
Reconstructing and Analysing Historic Land Changes in Europe’, Biogeosciences, x (2013); Richard Fuchs et
al., ‘The Potential of Old Maps and Encyclopaedias for Reconstructing Historic European Land Cover/Use
Change’, Applied Geography, lix (2015); Richard Fuchs et al., ‘Gross Changes in Reconstructions of Historic
Land Cover/Use for Europe between 1900 and 2010’, Global Change Biology, xxi (2015).
90
Warde, Energy Consumption in England & Wales, 1560-2000; Kander, Malanima, and Warde, Power to the
People.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 38

Fig. 8 Forestry and mining occupational shares, 1710-1911

MINING EW FORESTRY EW
MINING FR FORESTRY FR
10.0

1.0

0.1
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911

4. Productivity growth in the textile industry.

By 1851 – the end of the classical period of the Industrial Revolution – the share of the

male labour force employed in the secondary sector in E&W had only increased to 50.8 per

cent of the male labour force: an increase of less than 15 per cent over 140 years! By 1700 the

British population was not much less industrial than a century and a half later. Yet the nature

of industrial labour changed dramatically over this period with the rise of more geographically

concentrated and mechanised production. In France, the situation could not have been more

different. By 1700 around 16 per cent of the male labour force was occupied in the secondary

sector to reach just over 25 per cent by 1851 (an increase of 58 per cent). Given that over the

same period the total industrial output grew by a multiple of 116 in Britain91 but only 6.5 times

91
Broadberry et al., ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870’.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

in France,92 it is clear (regardless of the reliability of these figures) that British industrialisation

was achieved mostly by productivity gains linked to mechanisation and regional specialisation

while French industrialisation up to 1851 was infinitely slower and more labour intensive. As

the French economy started from a much lower initial share of employment in the secondary

sector, the effects of productivity growth in the modernising sectors (which certainly existed)

remained imperceptible at an aggregate level until much later in the nineteenth century, because

of the overall growth in the size of the secondary sector.

Were data available to consider figures for the both sexes together, the comparison

would undoubtedly be even more striking. Between 1700 and 1851 the estimated share of the

female labour force employed in the secondary sector in E&W collapsed from 51 to 39 per cent

(table 1b).93 Symbolic of this slump was the complete annihilation of the hand-spinning

industry in the south-east caused by mechanisation and further concentration in the textile

heartlands.94 There is still sadly no equivalent data for eighteenth-century France, but it is very

likely that the total share of the female labour force employed in industry grew throughout the

eighteenth and nineteenth centuries alongside and in spite of limited mechanisation. Although

in both countries, textiles represented a very large share of the industrial output in the late

eighteenth century – woollens on their own represented almost twenty per cent of the French

industrial output c.1790 – nowhere in Europe was the share of the labour force employed in

textiles as high as in E&W.95 Compared to France, the share of total employment in the textile

industry in E&W remained three times larger (15% to 4.3%) by 1851, and still twice as large

92
Ridolfi, ‘The French Economy in the Longue Durée’; Jean-Claude Toutain and Yves Breton, La croissance
française, 1789-1990: nouvelles estimations (Paris, 1997).
93
Note these figures are for the total amount of labour input, not individuals in the labour force. It could be 75%
of women with half of them working half time and half full time for instance. In any case, the actual number of
women employed in the secondary sector will be far more than 50% in 1760.
94
Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘Diverse Experiences: The Geography of Adult Female Employment and the 1851
Census’, in Nigel Goose (ed.), Women’s Work in Industrial England: Regional and Local Perspectives
(Hatfield, 2007). See also: www.economiespast.org
95
Tihomir J. Markovitch, ‘La croissance industrielle sous l’Ancien Régime’, Annales, xxxi (1976).

39
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

by 1891 (12.1% to 6.8%). By 1851, it was at least twice as large for men and three times as

large for women (fig.9), and these ratios would have been much greater a century earlier. Only

perhaps in the districts which had a very high share of the female labour force employed in

textiles in the late eighteenth century (especially in Normandy, but even there the amount of

rural by-employment undertaken by these women considerably blurs the picture of

predominant female textile employment that emerges from raw census data) mechanisation

caused a de-industrialisation similar in scale to what occurred across southern England (Terki-

Mignot, in progress).

The evolution of the textile industries throughout the eighteenth and nineteenth

centuries in E&W also underlines another major – and often overlooked – comparative aspect,

that is the very significant divergence between English and French textiles before the era of

mechanised spinning and the path-dependency that resulted from this early specialisation.

Unlike R.C. Allen’s view that France failed to adopt the spinning Jenny because of skewed

relative factor prices (‘wages were too low in France to make it profitable to invest in labour

replacement technology’), it is clear that French textile entrepreneurs did know and experiment

with Jennies from the 1770s, but that the technology failed to catch on, not because of labour

costs in spinning, but because of the major structural differences (counts spun, organisation of

household production, and concentration) between French and English textile industries.96 Nef

had already argued that textiles were not the first but among the last industries to be

revolutionised by mechanisation, and were rather marked by a relative absence of change in

the production process throughout the early-modern period.97 Everywhere most of the

production – and certainly all the preparatory work – was organised as a loose and poorly

96
John Styles, ‘The Rise and Fall of the Spinning Jenny: Domestic Mechanisation in Eighteenth-Century Cotton
Spinning’, Textile History, li (2020).
97
John Ulric Nef, Industry and Government in France and England, 1540-1640. (Ithaca, 1957); John Ulrich
Nef, The Conquest of the Material World (Chicago, 1964).

40
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

interconnected network of cottage industries. France might have held a competitive advantage

in the headline-grabbing production of niche upper-market goods such as lace, tapestry, silk,

and fine clothing, often supported by public investment in highly capital-intensive production,

such as in the Manufactures Royales, but this was a superficial illusion detracting attention

from the low-quality, low capital intensity, poorly integrated and regulated production of

coarser yarn and fabric that dominated throughout the country. In E&W, inversely, the rapid

growth in the demand for cloth and household textile goods from the expanding group of

middling-sorts consumers and urbanites led to an early (c.1700) concentration in the woollens

and cotton industries: in East Anglia, in the West Riding and Lancashire, but also in the

finishing process in and around London, especially in the dyeing trades. The agglomeration

effects derived from this concentration were unparalleled in France, and the industrial

geography of nineteenth century France largely mirrors regional patterns established before

1700.

In both countries, the value added per worker was higher in the chemical industries

(encompassing soap, wax and candles and gunpowder, but also critical intermediary products

such as dye, potash, alkali, soda and starch). Growth in the chemical industry was proportional

to the textile industries. Kerridge estimated that around a fifth of the cost of woollen cloth came

from dyeing (soap and dyes), but also wax and starch for weaving linen,98 and Barker showed

that textiles (mainly cottons) and the hard soap and glass industries were the three main

consumers of alkali. Given that the output of the textile industries in E&W was more than twice

the value of the French output and increasing very rapidly in the late eighteenth century,

demand for chemical intermediary products was also logically twice as large. The rising costs

of these chemicals because of trade disruption (warfare) and rising competition for resources

98
Brian W. Peckham, ‘Technological Change in the British and French Starch Industries, 1750-1850’,
Technology and Culture, xxvii (1986).

41
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

from all European textile industries were serious additional production expenses for

manufacturers, in both England and France, and led to the industrial production of synthetic

substitutes.99 Higher consumer demand and a faster rate of urbanisation in E&W might also

have played a role in creating a larger market for domestic products such as candles and soap.

Fig.9 Share of the labour force employed in the textile industries, 1700-1900

TEXTILES #M EW TEXTILES #F EW
TEXTILES # M FR TEXTILES #F FR
45.0

40.0

35.0

30.0

25.0

20.0

15.0

10.0

5.0

-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911

5. Demand-led occupational change: food, drink and consumer goods

Although demand-led explanations of the Industrial Revolution have not convinced economic

historians (including in its last incarnation, the “industrious revolution”),100 sub-sectoral

occupational data clearly indicate the impact of living standards on the development of

99
T. C. Barker, R. Dickinson, and D. W. F. Hardie, ‘The Origins of the Synthetic Alkali Industry in Britain’,
Economica, xxiii (1956).
100
Jan de Vries, ‘The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution’, The Journal of Economic History,
liv (1994); Jan de Vries, The Industrious Revolution : Consumer Behavior and the Household Economy, 1650 to
the Present (Cambridge, 2008).

42
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

consumer-oriented industries in the early modern period, such as clothing, shoe making and

more generally textiles.101 Together, these sectors accounted for over half of the entire industrial

output of both countries before 1800 (table 1). Our data show that the precocious specialisation

of English industry in consumer goods is already notable in 1700 (fig. 10a-c) and contrasts

dramatically with the situation in France where a strikingly high proportion of the labour force

concentrated in the processing of food and drink. This difference must necessarily be the result

of very different levels of demand for these goods, and therefore we would argue of living

standards. By 1740, the Welsh political economist Josiah Tucker was in no doubt as to the

social diffusion of these new goods across society:

The Manufactures of the Kingdom … are more adapted for the Demands of Peasants

and Mechanics, in order to appear in warm Circumstances; - for Farmers, Freeholders,

Tradesmen, and Manufacturers in middling Life; and for wholesale Dealers, Merchants,

and all Persons of Landed Estates, to appear in genteel Life; than for the Magnificence

of Palaces, or the Cabinets of Princes. Thus it is, according to the very Spirit of our

Constitution, that the English of these several Denominations have better Conveniencies

in their Houses, and affect to have more in: Quantity of clean, neat Furniture, and a

greater Variety (such as Carpets, Screens, Window Curtains, Chamber Bells, polished

Brass Locks, Fenders, &c. &c. (Things hardly known Abroad among Persons of such a

Rank) than are to be found in any other Country in Europe, Holland excepted. … Were

an Inventory to be taken of the Houshold Goods and Furniture of a Peasant, or Mechanic

101
This does not reassert demand as a cause for the Industrial Revolution but shows that higher demand was the
consequence of the economic development of England before 1700.

43
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

in France, and of a Peasant, or Mechanic in England, the latter would be found, upon an

Average, to exceed the former in Value at least as three to one.102

There is now a growing literature on comparative living standards, mostly in reaction

to Allen’s high-wage economy thesis and its relation to mechanisation in the textile industry.103

Despite all the nuances and criticisms waged at Allen’s work, and the new data produced since

its publication, so far none has however repudiated the fundamental fact that aggregate living

standards were significantly higher in Britain than in France in the eighteenth century, and that

for this simple reason aggregate demand must have been significantly higher. The size of the

gap remains an open question, but not the gap itself.

The relative size of the footwear industry provides indirect evidence of this. By 1700

the share of the male labour force employed in the footwear industry was twice as large in

E&W than in France, and it was still at least 50 per cent larger in 1850. Shoes were – and

perhaps still are for a large part of lower income countries, especially for children – among the

most visible tell-tale sign of economic development. Our comparative data are supported by

other evidence. In eighteenth-century France, indigents were commonly called ‘va-nus-pieds’,

denoting the strict footwear hierarchy of poverty. Beyond social standing, the relationship

between footwear quality and living standards was commonly accepted as a reliable indicator

102
Josiah Tucker, Instruction for Travellers, 1758, p.40. Quoted in Neil McKendrick, The Birth of a Consumer
Society : The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England (London, 1982), 25–6; Margaret Spufford,
Great Reclothing of Rural England: Petty Chapman and Their Wares in the Seventeenth Century (1984), 4.
103
Apart from the literature on real wages mentioned above, see Ugo Gragnolati, Daniele Moschella, and
Emanuele Pugliese, ‘The Spinning Jenny and the Industrial Revolution: A Reappraisal’, The Journal of
Economic History, lxxi (2011); Craig Muldrew, ‘“Th’ancient Distaff” and “Whirling Spindle”: Measuring the
Contribution of Spinning to Household Earnings and the National Economy in England, 1550–17701’, The
Economic History Review, lxv (2012); Jane Humphries and Benjamin Schneider, ‘Spinning the Industrial
Revolution’, The Economic History Review, lxxii (2019) and the ensuing debate with Allen, including:; Jane
Humphries and Benjamin Schneider, ‘Losing the Thread: A Response to Robert Allen’, Economic History
Review, lxxiii (2020); Judy Z. Stephenson, ‘Mistaken Wages: The Cost of Labour in the Early Modern English
Economy, a Reply to Robert C. Allen’, The Economic History Review, lxxii (2019), and the ensuing debate with
Allen in EHR; John Styles, ‘Robert Allen’s Spinning Jenny Is Still Broken.’, The Spinning Project, (2019);
Humphries and Schneider, ‘Losing the Thread’.

44
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

of impoverishment.104 The intendant Vauban described the immiseration of late seventeenth-

century peasants as suffering ‘from hunger and nudity,’ with ‘three quarters of them only

wearing – in both summer and winter – half rotten and torn fabric and clogs, which they wear

bare foot throughout the year. If they do happen to own shoes, they are only worn on Sundays

and holidays.’105 The iconography of footwear is equally revealing. Take two paintings by

Louis Le Nain (illustrations 1a-b below) both dating from 1642 with a remarkably similar

composition: in the first one, Les Petits joueurs de cartes, a group of youngsters are playing

cards under the vigilant care of a maid and either an older brother or a young servant. The two

boys in the foreground, clearly from a less affluent household than the children on the other

side of the table, are barefoot. We cannot see the feet of the other children, but in another

version of this painting held in the Royal collection, the elegantly dressed boy coming through

the door on the right-hand side very visibly dons a pair of leather shoes. As is often the case in

Le Nain brothers’ paintings of peasants’ interiors, shoes reveal the social dynamic of the group.

The second painting is even more revealing in this regard. In Repas de paysans Le Nain puts

together an allegoric triptych of the social condition of French peasantry: in the middle a rich

farmer dressed in a shiny coat with a white-collar shirt and a carefully trimmed beard

accompanied by his son, dressed in the same manner and holding a violin; on the left a

relatively wealthy peasant household represented by a man with simple unsullied woollen shirt

and trousers slightly damaged at the knees, indicating his working condition, and his wife and

son both dressed in a similar manner. The man wears shoes. Finally, on the right-hand side, a

104
Giorgio Riello, A Foot in the Past: Consumers, Producers and Footwear in the Long Eighteenth Century
(2006).
105
Sébastien Le Prestre Vauban, Description géographique de l’élection de Vézelay: contenant ses revenus, sa
qualité, les moeurs de ses habitants, leur pauvreté et leur richesse, la fertilité du pays et ce que l’on pourrait y
faire pour en corriger la stérilité et procurer l’augmentation des peuples et l’accroissement des bestiaux, ed.
Jean-François Pernot (Saint-Léger-Vauban, France, 1986). ‘Il ne faut donc pas s'étonner si des peuples si mal
nourris ont si peu de force. A quoi il faut ajouter que ce qu'ils souffrent de la nudité y contribue beaucoup, les
trois quarts n'étant vêtus, hiver et été, que de toile à demi pourrie et déchirée, et chaussés de sabots, dans
lesquels ils ont le pied nu toute l'année. Que si quelqu'un d'eux a des souliers, il ne les met que les jours de fêtes
et dimanches.

45
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

miserable, landless day labourer and his son, both dishevelled and barefoot. The father sits on

a rugged three-legged stool, looking away absent-mindedly.

A few years later, Defoe also used clogs as a symbol of the comparative misery of the

French, ‘our Neighbours … reduced to Black Bread, Garlick, and Wooden Shoes’,106 and

Boulainvilliers, the French dilettante historian, seconded him. In his Etat de la France

published five years after his death, in 1727, he noted that in hard times the number of people

wearing clogs and clog making increased significantly: ‘On fabrique … das toutes les Forêts

beaucoup de Sabots, que la pauvreté à rendu beaucoup plus communs qu’ils n’étoient du tems

de nos Peres.’107 The Swiss traveller Cesar de Saussure, who was in England between 1725

and 1729, was surprised to see that, unlike on the Continent, ‘the lower classes are usually well

dressed, wearing good cloth and linen. You never see wooden shoes in England, and the poorest

individuals never go with naked feet’.108 The situation – and the analysis – were not very

different by the time Arthur Young visited France in 1787:

All the country, girls and women, are without shoes or stockings [he remarked]

and the ploughmen at their work have neither sabots nor feet to their stockings. This

is a poverty that strikes at the root of national prosperity; a large consumption

among the poor being of more consequence than among the rich: the wealth of a

nation lies in its circulation and consumption; and the case of poor people abstaining

106
Daniel Defoe and Henry Sacheverell, A Speech without Doors (1710), 13.
107
Henri de (1658-1722) Auteur du texte Boulainvilliers, État de La France, Dans Lequel on Voit Tout Ce Qui
Regarde Le Gouvernement Ecclésiastique, Le Militaire, La Justice, Les Finances, Le Commerce, Les
Manufactures, Le Nombre Des Habitans, & En Général Tout Ce Qui Peut Faire Connoître à Fond Cette
Monarchie. Tome 1 / . Extrait Des Mémoires Dressez Par Les Intendans Du Royaume, Par Ordre Du Roi, Louis
XIV... Avec Des Mémoires Historiques Sur l’ancien Gouvernement de Cette Monarchie Jusqu’à Hugues Capet.
Par Monsieur Le Comte de Boulainvilliers. On y a Joint Une Nouvelle Carte de La France... Tome Premier [-
Second] (1727), 260.
108
César de Saussure, A Foreign View of England in the Reigns of George I and George II.: The Letters of
Monsieur Cesar de Saussure to His Family; Translated and Edited by Madame Van Muyden (1902), 113.

46
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

from the use of manufactures of leather and wool ought to be considered as an evil

of the first magnitude. It reminded me of the misery of Ireland.109

Edward Rigby, who travelled through France a year after Young, also noted of French women

– perhaps not without some excitement on his part – that ‘their legs are quite naked, with neither

shoe nor stocking.’110 Malthus, too, when travelling on the Continent in 1829 made a series of

similar observations: in Western Flanders he remarked on ‘women without shoes, and later on,

going towards Coblenz, he wrote down: ‘people looking poor - women and children without

stockings and shoes.’111 From the seventeenth century onwards footwear clearly denoted living

standards, and British travellers consistently remarked on the general bareness of Continental

feet.

At the bottom of this footwear hierarchy were those too poor to own shoes, followed

by a very large group of impoverished rural households who either had to make their own

footwear or could only afford a couple of pair of clogs per year, which meant that several

members of the household (and clearly women in most cases as seen above) still went barefoot

or with makeshift substitutes. Using clog output estimates for the late nineteenth century (table

4) it is possible to calculate that each adult used between two and three pairs of clogs per year

– which corresponds to contemporary descriptions of the wear and tear of wooden shoes. By

1700, only better off farmers might have used three pairs of clogs per year and perhaps owned

a pair of thick leather shoes worn on Sundays, and their urban counterparts, qualified artisans,

a couple of pairs of thick (often goat) leather or fabric shoes sometimes protected with gaiters,

but most of the rural population had no option but managing with much more limited makeshift

footwear. As it is unlikely (given the already optimistic output per worker figure for 1870

109
Young, Arthur Young’s Travels in France, 27.
110
Rigby and Eastlake, Dr. Rigby’s Letters from France &c. in 1789., 6.
111
Patricia James, The Travel Diaries of Thomas Robert Malthus (2009), 231, 237, and 240.

47
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

shown in table 4 below) that clog makers unassisted by machines could produce over 5 pairs

per day, day in, day out, 300 days per year, even if in the better cases an improved division of

labour only involved the carving out from an existing wooden block, it seems clear that a very

large number of agricultural labourers before the mid nineteenth century would have been

producing/mending their own footwear when they owned some. Standing apart from the great

majority and topping the footwear hierarchy, the gentry and aristocracy donned elaborate

made-to-measure shoes adorned with ribbons, lace, velvet and fine leather, and produced at

great expense by a small number of exclusive shoemakers all located in larger cities. But like

Young himself noted, this top end consumption gives a very distorted picture of the very

limited aggregate demand for consumer goods.

Before mechanisation (which began in earnest in the second half of the nineteenth

century) we can safely assume that the share of the labour force employed in shoemaking is a

reliable comparative indicator of footwear consumption in both countries. A higher share of

the population employed in the shoe making industry therefore signals a larger demand for

market-produced footwear and a substitution effect from clogs (or no shoes at all) to more

labour-intensive leather shoes. Using this metric, we can observe that by 1700 the share of the

male labour force employed in the footwear industry was twice as large in E&W than in France,

and that it was still at least 50 per cent larger in 1850 (fig. 10b).

The gap had disappeared by 1901, but by then the effects of mechanisation make this

ratio a much less telling measure of living standards. In England, productivity gains caused by

the introduction of the sewing machine and agglomeration effects through lower transport costs

led to lower share of the population employed in this industry. In France, productivity gains

combined with English imports forced small-scale urban shoemakers to specialise on upmarket

48
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor

luxury goods and almost completely wiped out the scattered rural shoe industry.112 It is perhaps

more revealing to look at the fate of the rural clog making industry after 1850 to have an idea

of relative living standards. First, if we assume that clogs were typical Giffen goods (with

negative elasticity of demand - i.e., the richer people were, the fewer clogs they bought), the

persistence of the clog making industry would signal stagnating living standards. This is not

based on empirical research, but it was certainly how Young, Defoe, Boulainvilliers and almost

every traveller saw it, apart, perhaps, from a handful of folklorists of the later nineteenth

century who romanticised clogs as an image of an idyllic peasant civilisation. After a very

painful personal experiment by one of the authors trying to wear clogs for a couple of days, we

would dare anyone to defend any form of cultural relativism in this respect. Secondly, the

absence of productivity gains in the clog industry allows us to track the evolution of demand

over the second half of the century. Clog making remained the work of individual ‘sabotiers’

providing footwear to fellow villagers or selling them at local markets. Data from the Gazette

du Sabotier, regardless of their accuracy, show that mechanisation in France only took hold in

the early twentieth century, and that millions of pairs were still being produced each year, even

as late as the 1930s.113 By this date, exactly half of the French population (that is around 20

million people) still lived in rural areas, and if we were to believe these numbers, 34 million

pairs of wooden shoes were produced per year! What would Defoe or Young have thought of

children stuffing clogs with barley straw to go to school in the 1930s? Yet, this was a reality.

Table 4 Clog output and productivity, 1870-1930

DATE (1) (2) (3) (4)

112
Alain Cottereau, ‘Problemes de Conceptualisation Comparative de l’industrialisation: L’exemple Des
Ouvriers de La Chaussure En France et En Grande-Bretagne’, in Susanna Magri and Christian Topalov (eds.),
Villes Ouvrières, 1900-1950, Book, Section vols (Paris, 1989).
113
J. Daydé, ‘L’industrie des sabots et galoches en France et particulièrement dans le Sud-Ouest’, Revue
géographique des Pyrénées et du Sud-Ouest. Sud-Ouest Européen, vi (1935).

49
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 50

1870 25,000 0 37.5 0

1880 25,000 3 37.5 0.036

1890 23,000 10 34.5 0.12

1900 22,000 10 33 0.12

1910 20,000 45 30 0.54

1920 18,000 500 27 6

1930 15,000 1000 22 12

(1) Number of clog-makers; (2) Number of machines; (3) Hand output (millions); (4)

Mechanical output (millions)

Fig.10a-b Consumer industries

TEXTILES #F EW CLOTHING #F EW
FOOTWEAR #F EW TEXTILES #F FR
45.0

40.0

35.0

30.0

25.0

20.0

15.0

10.0

5.0

-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 51

TEXTILES #M EW CLOTHING #M EW FOOTWEAR #M EW


TEXTILES #M FR CLOTHING #M FR FOOTWEAR #M FR
9.0

8.0

7.0

6.0

5.0

4.0

3.0

2.0

1.0

-
1710 1817 1851 1871 1891 1911
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 52

Illustrations 1a-b Louis Le Nain (1642), Repas de paysans114 and Les Petits joueurs de

cartes (1642)115

114
2015 RMN-Grand Palais (musée du Louvre) / Mathieu Rabeau,
https://collections.louvre.fr/ark:/53355/cl010059565
115
2006 RMN-Grand Palais (musée du Louvre) / René-Gabriel Ojéda,
https://collections.louvre.fr/ark:/53355/cl010065568
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 53

On the other end of the productive scope stood the luxury industries. The inventories

of most wealthy Europeans in the eighteenth century included French luxury clothing and fine

decorative household goods, which constituted a major export market for French artisans

renowned across Europe for their fashion-setting wares: embroidered silks dresses, printed

cottons (Oberkampf), furs (Révillon), biscuit porcelain (Sèvres), crystal glass (Baccarat), very

elaborate and decorative clocks (Bréguet) were staples of European courts in the late eighteenth

century. As a Frenchman exiled in Berlin wrote in 1786, the European gentry and nobility

‘dress in the French fashion, accommodate their interiors with French furniture, and cook in

the French way.’116 The apocryphal quote attributed to Colbert (‘fashion is to France what the

gold mines of Peru are to Spain’) was already a trope in the 1780s, and was used to portray and

116
Jean-Pierre Erman, Mémoires pour servir à l’histoire des réfugiés françois dans les États du roi (1786), 245.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 54

advertise French refinement and fashion as a trade and diplomatic policy. The nineteenth

century did not depart from this trajectory of luxury craftmanship, and most of the names would

not sound unfamiliar to a modern reader: Guerlain, Hermès, Cartier, Vuitton, etc. But what

does all this glitter tell us about French economic performance? While France enjoyed a niche

comparative advantage in labour-intensive high-end production, this has often distracted

observers from the hiatus in the nature of French industrial outputs. Whether in textiles,

potteries or clockmaking, the finest pieces cohabited with a much larger production of coarser,

low quality products, crowded out from the mid-market segments by more productive and

better-quality British competitors. In Britain the earthenware and pottery manufacture and the

making of precision instrument occupied a much larger share of the labour force (at least four

times bigger, Table 5). Only the precious metals and jewellery industries – more specifically

oriented towards luxury products – did reveal a substantial comparative advantage for France.

Table 5. Comparison of share of the labour force in the decorative and precision industries

E&W FR

1851 1861 1851 1861

Earthenware, pottery manufacture 0.4 0.4 < 0.1 0.1

Precious metals and jewellery 0.2 0.3 0.6 0.4

Instrument making 0.4 0.5 0.1 0.1

The market specialisation in high-end craftsmanship and the crowding out from mass

production extended in the nineteenth century to the sectors that underwent some element of

mechanisation in the production process. France, for example, enjoyed a comparative

advantage in paper making before the steam age. The paper industry was composed of a string

of typically small workshops located along rivers on the outskirts of towns and which were
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 55

reliant on waterpower and large rags supply (from urban centres) for their production. In the

seventeenth century, France was the major European exporter of paper products, with two

major centres of production in Auvergne and around Charenton providing paper across France

and Europe. In the eighteenth century, however, the geography of paper making slowly evolved

with many small paper mills, spreading along rivers in Northern France, German lands, the

Low Countries and Britain to meet the growing demand for paper. After 1800 the industrial

geography of paper making was almost completely reversed. Between 1800 and 1860, the

British paper output was multiplied by six thanks to the combined benefits of technological

change (the Robert and Fourdrinier machines after 1806), agglomeration benefits, cheap

energy, reduced transport costs, and the enormous increase in the demand from the indigenous

printing industry caused by the emergence of the world’s largest mass media.117

6. Market integration

Our data also point towards key differences in the integration of both labour and

commodities markets in the two countries. Market integration in the eighteenth and early

nineteenth centuries was almost entirely determined by the economic connectivity made

possible by transport infrastructures. More integrated markets unlock the positive externalities

of regional comparative advantage and specialisation. Recent works have revealed the role of

early developments in E&W in lowering freight costs.118 Market integration through transport

infrastructure is also reflected in our data. While 2.2 per cent of the male labour force was

employed in transport by 1700 in France, at the same date it occupied twice as large a share of

117
Juha-Antti Lamberg et al., The Evolution of Global Paper Industry 1800¬–2050: A Comparative Analysis
(2012).
118
On the coaching network: Alan Rosevear, Dan Bogart, and Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘The Spatial Patterns of
Coaching in England and Wales from 1681 to 1836: A Geographic Information Systems Approach’, The
Journal of Transport History, xl (2019); on turnpike trusts and canals: Dan Bogart, ‘Turnpike Trusts and the
Transportation Revolution in 18th Century England’, Explorations in Economic History, xlii (2005); Dan
Bogart, Michael Lefors, and A. E. M. Satchell, ‘Canal Carriers and Creative Destruction in English Transport’,
Explorations in Economic History, lxxi (2019); and on coastal navigation: Dan Bogart et al., ‘Speedier Delivery:
Coastal Shipping Times and Speeds during the Age of Sail’, The Economic History Review, lxxiv (2021).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 56

the male labour force (4.5 per cent) in E&W (see fig.2 above). This ratio peaked to 3.8 times

in 1861, only to go back progressively to 2.4 by 1911. Between 1700 and 1911, the transport

sector in E&W was consistently two to four times larger than in France. If we now weight these

figures by the potential area covered (c.151,000 sq.km for E&W, c.535,000 sq.km in 1700 and

between 1871 and 1914 for France) the balance tilts even more in favour of E&W, which had

2.98 per cent of the male labour force employed in transport per hundred thousand square

kilometres, and France only 0.41 per cent per hundred thousand square kilometres, with the

caveat that in E&W a larger fraction of transport workers were employed in the overseas branch

than in France.

Sub-sectoral data for the transport sector reveals further differences in the degree of

connectivity and integration of the two economies. First, by 1700 Britain was already

comfortably leagues ahead in both maritime and inland navigation with a combined 3.4 per

cent of the male labour force employed in those sectors compared with only 0.8 per cent in

France. Even if we discount oceanic trading to focus solely on coastal (i.e., domestic) trade, we

can assume that the difference between the two nations was no less significant. Based on Nef’s

claim that perhaps up to half of all merchant fleet was used for coastal shipping,119 and applying

the same ratio to France (although this is undoubtedly an exaggeration given the much more

limited amount of coastal trade by 1700), and while ignoring the fact that oceanic crews would

be larger, we can make an educated guess that the share of the labour force employed in costal

shipping would have occupied over one per cent of the male labour force in E&W and less than

a quarter of a per cent in France. The steady increase in the naval dominance of E&W across

the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries and the crushing of the French naval power after 1800

significantly strengthened the disparity between the two countries. By the late nineteenth

119
Nef, The Conquest of the Material World, 165.
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 57

century, E&W’s lead in maritime transport had more than doubled, and the share of the labour

force it employed was eight times larger in E&W than France. It is true that the distribution of

the naval labour force was necessarily concentrated on the coast, and since the coastline of

E&W is more extended than the French one (c.8.9 thousand kilometres for E&W vs. c.5.8

thousand kilometres for France) one would logically expect a larger commercial fleet in E&W.

Yet: i) even this does not compensate for the gap between the two countries. The longer

coastline also means ii) that a larger portion of the territory (coastal areas) was connected to

regional and national markets through maritime links in Britain than in France, and iii) that

France was split in two between more integrated Atlantic regions and landlocked territories.120

It is a famous saying that the sea unites and the land divides, and if so, it clearly worked in

favour of Britain.

There is more to it than natural endowment and the insular position of Britain, though.

Data for inland navigation show that despite a very abundant network of navigable rivers,

France also lagged in this respect. Bogart et al. have shown that improvements to rivers and

the construction of canals and roads were the largest infrastructure investments in England

during the industrial revolution and that inland waterway network increased significantly the

development of regions connected to it.121 The transport of heavy and bulky goods on barges

unlocked the access to raw material and lowered the cost of imports – especially coal – for

urban markets, while faster, more regular and cheaper road transport delivered the lighter and

more valuable commodities. Across the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries many more goods

were being produced in often specialised areas and needed to be distributed to more distant

120
Edward Whiting Fox, History in Geographic Perspective: The Other France (1972).
121
Dan Bogart et al., ‘Turnpikes, Canals, and Economic Growth in England and Wales, 1800-1850’, Working
Paper, (2017).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 58

markets and the very rapid rise in road transport employment throughout the nineteenth century

illustrates this effect.

Data recently produced by Litvine and Mimeur for the ANR-Communes project

confirm this bleak view of French spatial integration before the railways.122 Using their new

multi-modal model of transport for France and comparing it with similar data produced by the

Cambridge Group for the History of Population and Social Structure for E&W, it is possible to

visualise and quantify the difference in terms of level of connectivity for each individual

parish/municipality across the two economies for different dates. These maps (fig. 11)

demonstrate the striking connectivity gap between the two countries in the nineteenth century.

The relative share of the territory within a six-hour range of a 5000+ settlement differs

significantly both in 1800 and 1830, but the left behind areas in France are remote and less

populated, but when it comes to larger settlements, carrying much larger market potential, the

difference between the two countries is stark. Only a small section of North-Western France,

the Mediterranean coast, Burgundy and the Northern Rhône valley display continuous areas

with significant accessibility to settlements over 10,000 inhabitants, and only one contiguous

area along the Seine for large urban centres over 80,000 inhabitants. If we plot the cumulative

share of the population by the time taken to reach the closer settlement (fig.11), we can see that

the accessibility to 5000+ settlements in France fits exactly that of 80,000+ settlements in

E&W. By this simple visual metric the market potential (that is to say the pool of potential

consumers for the goods produced in a given place for a given journey time) was sixteen times

higher in E&W than in France. All this confirms that the French economy was fundamentally

regional and not national in the first half of the nineteenth century, which is consistent with

observations in the literature that regional specialisation happened at the intra-regional level

122
All data will be available at French Historical GIS, 1700-2020. Administrative units, Populations,
Transports, Economy. (forthcoming 2022), doi.10.5281/zenodo.3727274
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 59

and that cases of national concentration,123 like in the wool industry in the Nord,124 did not

result from the effect of existing comparative advantage but from path-dependency

externalities caused by agglomeration effect a la Krugman.125 Specialisation only picked up in

the nineteenth century when market integration improved, well into the railway age.126

However, our new data invalidates assertions that France enjoyed a market access equivalent

or superior to Britain.127

123
Daudin, ‘Commerce et prospérité’.
124
Markovitch, ‘La croissance industrielle sous l’Ancien Régime’.
125
Paul R. Krugman, ‘Intraindustry Specialization and the Gains from Trade’, Journal of Political Economy,
lxxxix (1981).
126
Pierre-Philippe Combes et al., ‘The Rise and Fall of Spatial Inequalities in France: A Long-Run Perspective’,
Explorations in Economic History, xlviii (2011).
127
Guillaume Daudin, ‘Domestic Trade and Market Size in Late-Eighteenth-Century France’, The Journal of
Economic History, lxx (2010).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 60

Fig.11 Comparative connectivity indices for France and E&W, 1800/1830 (Mimeur/Litvine)
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 61

Another way to look at the low integration of the French economy using our

occupational data is to observe the level of structural by-employment in the economy. By-

employment here means any gainful employment in another sector in addition to a person’s

main occupation. In France, slow urbanisation combined with population growth between 1500

and 1715 and then faster demographic growth and urban stagnation between 1715 and 1800

suggests that almost all excess population was absorbed by rural areas. The low level of

urbanisation in 1851 and the lack of regional specialisation combined with limited productivity

growth in industry before the 1830s also indicate that the bulk of the increase in industrial

output between 1740 and 1850 must have relied largely on rural industries and chronic

intersectoral by-employment, either seasonal or throughout the working day. This was already

the case in the seventeenth century,128 and it remained so well into the nineteenth century:

peasants could be occasional miners, masons, ditch diggers, road builders, flax spinners, knife

grinder, etc., but industrial workers also left their workshops to help out in the fields, especially

during the harvests when wages were higher in agriculture than in the workshops.129 We can

now quantify these intersectoral flows across the nineteenth century.130 Although the share of

total labour input concerned was relatively moderate (the data presented in table 6 below shows

that by 1891 three per cent of the total labour input by both men and women employed in the

primary sector went to secondary-sector activities), around ten per cent of both the male and

female labour force was regularly by-employed throughout the century, which means that out

of a theoretical working year of 300 days one in ten worker would have taken c.90 days off

(ten per cent of the labour force for three per cent of the total labour input) per year to work in

128
Pierre Goubert, Cent mille provinciaux au 17e siècle : Beauvais et le Beauvaisis de 1600 à 1730 (1977);
Pierre Goubert, La Vie Quotidienne Des Paysans Francais Au XVIIe Siecle (Paris, 1982).
129
Pierre Sicsic, ‘City-Farm Wage Gaps in Late Nineteenth-Century France’, The Journal of Economic History,
lii (1992).
130
For a fuller description, see: Litvine, ‘French Occupational Structure, Industrialisation and Economic Growth
France, 1695 to the Present.’
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 62

another sector. This might have little macroeconomic significance as sectoral flows more or

less compensated each other, but it is revealing of both the inability of the agricultural sector

to support a large enough labour force for the peak season in spite of an oversupply of labour,

and the inability of the industrial sector to retain its labour force throughout the year. Why was

it necessary to hire factory hands during the harvest? And why did agricultural labourers, often

holders of small plots also work in industry? This suggests that the French economy functioned

as a juxtaposition of smaller regional economies, which, in most cases, did not reach the scale

required to support independent industrial and agricultural sectors as the regional labour pool

responded to seasonal wage incentives. This long-lasting symbiotic relationship between the

two sectors also acted as a life insurance policy for households able to rely on the food supply

and income – however limited they might be – to face the vagaries of industrial cycles.

Inversely, our new data for in England, and especially evidence from probate inventories have

shown that already by the early eighteenth century, and unlike previous assumptions in the

literature, by-employment in manufacturing (except for domestic spinning) had become very

infrequent, and that it played virtually no role in the nineteenth century.131

Table 6 Intersectoral by-employment labour flows in the second half of the nineteenth century

1851 1891

Labour inputs (in % of total) M F M F


Primary ▻ Secondary 2.3 2.8 3.0 3.0
Secondary ▻ Primary 2.4 3.2 1.9 2.4
Total labour inputs for both sexes 5.1 5.1

7. Conclusion

131
Sebastian A. J. Keibek and Leigh Shaw-Taylor, ‘Early Modern Rural By-Employments: A Re-Examination
of the Probate Inventory Evidence’, The Agricultural History Review, lxi (2013).
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 63

In 1968, Eric Hobsbawm asked: ‘if we placed ourselves in the Britain of 1750 without the

wisdom of hindsight, would we have predicted the imminent Industrial Revolution? Almost

certainly not.’ Yet, he added, ‘looking back, we can see that no other country was as well-

prepared for the Industrial Revolution.’132 Every word of this still stands today, and comparing

England and France confirms the validity of his pronouncement. England by 1700 was already

in a unique position in Europe, if not the world. Since Hobsbawm’s assessment, lengthy debates

about past economic performance have hinged on comparisons of national accounting series,

and especially GDP. Occupational data complement these metrics by offering a set of robust

and comparable data reflecting the nature and structure of past economies. Our data gives an

unflinching account of the divergence between England and the rest of the world (and in the

case of this article, France) well before the classical period of the Industrial Revolution, and it

puts to rest any argument that by 1700 or 1750 France might have been a serious contender to

industrial primacy. As such our argument stands as the sectoral counterpart of the “little

divergence” between the two countries shown in recent studies of GDP and real wages from

the sixteenth to the eighteenth century. Because it works at the sectoral and industrial level it

tells a richer story about changes in the two countries.

Compared to England, France was fundamentally a poorly integrated agrarian

economy, with small islands of commercial and industrial prosperity dotted in an ocean of

relative immiseration. The major achievements of French scientists, the riches accumulated in

some trading towns, the global repute of French luxury goods and artistic production, the

industrial prowess and technical achievements often supported by state investments, and the

economic leadership of some enlightened administrators, were but fig leaves hiding the

132
Hobsbawm (1968), Industry and Empire, ch.1, pp.10-11
Alexis Litvine and Leigh Shaw-Taylor 64

bareness of the ancien regime economy. French roads in the late eighteenth century were

symbolic of this French economic mirage: they were beautiful, built at amazing expense by the

State with large and ingenious works of civil engineering, and Arthur Young – who otherwise

pulled no punches in his observations on France – thought they were among the best roads in

Europe, but, he also noted, they enjoyed very little traffic, at least nothing like the commercial

hustle and bustle he was used to witnessing on a typical busy English road.

Yet, France’s backwardness was obviously not absolute but only relative to England. French

development in sixteenth century and seventeenth centuries, however modest and episodic,

was undoubtedly accompanied by some growth of the secondary sector. Seventy per cent of

the labour force employed in agriculture as witnessed in 1700 is high compared with

England, but much lower than really underdeveloped economies.

As Hobsbwam pointed out, being in the best position to industrialise is in no way the

same as explaining why and when it did. In this article, we have not explored in any meaningful

way the causal mechanisms that led England to experience such a rapid and sustained wave of

innovations in the eighteenth century (i.e., “why was England first?”) but our data make a

strong case for the return to a much longer periodisation of the technological and social

enabling factors of the Industrial Revolution, in line with the older literature from Mantoux to

Nef.

You might also like