gpw054
gpw054
gpw054
doi: 10.1093/oep/gpw054
Advance Access Publication Date: 22 December 2016
Abstract
The paper considers the austerity measures introduced in the wake of the financial
and economic crisis in the late 2000s in relation to their distributional impact across
households and potential effects on aggregate demand. We determine the size,
composition and effects of fiscal consolidation using a ‘bottom-up’ measurement
strategy and find notable cross-country variation. We show that while richer house-
holds tend to bear a greater burden in most countries, combined cuts in public
wages and transfers are more likely to affect liquidity-constrained households and
thereby aggregate demand, casting doubts on the presumed effectiveness of such
measures for macro-economic recovery. This suggests that in order to reach robust
policy conclusions it is important to consider the distributional patterns of detailed
policy measures.
1. Introduction
Following the financial and economic crisis which started in the late 2000s, governments
introduced extensive fiscal consolidation measures to address budget deficits. The way in
which fiscal consolidation is achieved and the cost of the crisis is distributed has implica-
tions for the prospects for macro-economic recovery and financial stability, as well as for
the political acceptability of pathways in this direction.
Several studies have suggested that fiscal adjustments based on spending cuts, including
both cuts in government services and public transfers to households, are more effective
in reducing public debt and less harmful to economic growth than fiscal adjustments based
on tax increases (e.g. Alesina and Perotti, 1995, 1997; McDermott and Wescott, 1996;
Alesina and Ardagna 1998, 2010, 2013; von Hagen and Strauch, 2001; IMF, 2010;
Guajardo et al., 2011; Alesina et al., 2012).1 Nevertheless, recent studies based on struc-
tural macro models shed some light on the fact that cuts in (unproductive) government
spending are associated with long-run benefits but they can have short-run adjustment costs
and pronounced distributional effects. In particular, some studies highlight the potentially
detrimental effects of cuts in public transfers that are borne by liquidity-constrained house-
holds (Coenen et al., 2008, 2012; Forni et al., 2010; Clinton et al., 2011).
Such studies, however, tend to take a macro-economic perspective and overlook how
measures affect the whole distribution of household incomes, which could be a critical
1 It should be noted that there are some differences between early studies in terms of whether some
items have been considered as part of spending or tax adjustments. For example, Alesina and
Perotti (1995) include cash transfers in spending, while Blanchard and Perotti (2002) deduct these
from taxes.
634 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
outcomes and offer more explicit choices, while macro-economic and labour market poli-
cies – and even cuts in public services – are blunt instruments in terms of their distributional
effects.
The extent to which a decrease in disposable income due to fiscal consolidation meas-
ures reduces household spending on goods and services provides a link between our micro-
based approach and the macro literature on fiscal consolidation. We exploit the variation
in income among households and link such a change to the potential reduction in their con-
sumption, depending on the liquidity constraints they face (Auerbach and Feenberg, 2000;
Coenen et al., 2012). Our approach shows the importance of the interactions between the
2. Methodology
2.1 Fiscal microsimulation
We focus on policy measures which directly impact household budgets and household ag-
gregate demand, and which were introduced explicitly in order to cut the public deficit or
stem its growth. These policy changes were not only many but also typically applied across
the board, affecting large parts of population to some extent or another, and therefore pro-
vided no natural control groups for estimating causal effects on household incomes and de-
mand. We therefore make use of fiscal microsimulation techniques (Bourguignon and
Spadaro, 2006; Figari et al., 2015) to define and construct a counterfactual scenario: what
would have happened in the absence of the fiscal consolidation measures.
In essence, fiscal or ‘tax-benefit’ microsimulation modelling applies detailed tax-benefit
policy rules to a representative sample of households, using survey or register information
on household characteristics and market income as input. It enables the derivation of
disposable income for each household as well as the overall distribution under existing
636 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
tax-benefit systems and, more importantly, the effect of tax-benefit policy changes on the
household income distribution. In doing so, the heterogeneity in household budget con-
straints due to the interactions between the detailed tax-benefit rules and personal and
household characteristics is fully taken into account. The focus on the entire distribution of
changes in the target variable (rather than change for an average person or in the mean
value alone) is one of the key distinctions from regression techniques or macro models. The
first-order impact of tax-benefit policy changes on household incomes, i.e. the mechanical
effect, is estimated without imposing any behavioural relationships and is strictly atheoreti-
cal. Static calculations also represent an important element of behavioural models, where
We have chosen to interpret the ‘absence of the fiscal consolidation measures’, i.e. our
counterfactual scenario, as the continuation of pre-fiscal consolidation policies, indexed ac-
cording to standard practice and official assumption, or law. Such indexation of monetary
values of tax-benefit policies is not the same across countries under consideration. Apart
from public pensions, most of the countries do not regularly index fiscal policies and in-
stead change these occasionally on an ad hoc basis. The only countries not applying any
indexation are Greece and Lithuania.
To estimate the effect of policies we apply both the actual 2012 tax-benefit policies and
the (indexed) pre-fiscal consolidation policies to the same households, keeping their charac-
The version of EUROMOD used in this paper is based on information on personal and
household characteristics (including market incomes) from the 2008 EU Statistics on
Incomes and Living Conditions (EU-SILC) micro-data (or its more detailed national version
where available). EU-SILC is a nationally representative annual household survey collecting
detailed income information, in this wave for 2007 calendar year. Sample sizes range from
about 12,000 to13,000 individuals in Portugal, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania to more than
50,000 people in Italy.
Due to the gap between the data collection year (which was before the financial and eco-
nomic crisis) and the reference time of our analysis, we adjust the input data to account for
Type of measures EE EL ES IT LV LT PT RO
Benefit/pension cuts (or freezing) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Increased income taxes/reduced tax concessions Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No
Increased worker social insurance contributions Yes Yes No Yes Yes No Yes No
Public sector pay-cuts (or freezing) No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Increased property taxes No Yes (Yes) Yes (Yes) (Yes) (Yes) (Yes)
Increased rates of VAT Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Start period of measures 2009 2010 2010 2011 2009 2009 2009 2010
Notes: ‘Yes’ in bold indicates that measures are simulated in our analysis. (Yes) in parenthesis indicates that
measures were introduced but are not possible to simulate given data limitations. The fiscal consolidation
measures included here are those that have a direct effect on household income plus increases in the VAT
rate(s) as of June 2012.
640 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
Country Public Public Means- Non means- Income Workers Total effect Effect of VAT
sector pensions tested tested taxes SIC on disposable changes on
salaries benefits benefits income disposable
income
Notes: The measures included here are those that have a direct effect on household disposable income (changes
to direct taxes, cash benefits and public sector pay) and increases in the VAT rate(s) (see Table A2 in the online
Appendix).
Source: own calculations with EUROMOD. A negative sign indicates a reduction in household income.
A. PAULUS, F. FIGARI, AND H. SUTHERLAND 641
or in pre-tax relative prices; and (2) the VAT increases are proportional to the pre-reform
VAT payments. The effect of VAT increases ranges from less than 1% of disposable income
in Italy to more than 3% in Greece and Romania and is clearly substantial compared to
other components considered here.
To the best of our knowledge, the simulated size of each policy offers a unique quantifi-
cation of the consolidation measures faced by the household sector across countries. As
stressed in Anderson et al. (2015), who use aggregate data from the IMF World Economic
Outlook, ‘information on the composition of the adjustment on a country basis is not read-
ily available’. Indeed, one of the aims of our paper is to provide alternative and more pre-
EE EL ES
-20-15-10 -5 0
0
change as % of average disposable income
-5
-5
-10
-10
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
IT LV LT
0
0
-15 -10 -5
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
PT RO
0
0
-5
-5
-10
-10
1 2 3 4 5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Fig. 1. Percentage change in household disposable income due to simulated household income-based
fiscal consolidation measures by household income decile group
Notes: The measures included here are those that have a direct effect on household disposable in-
come (changes to direct taxes, cash benefits and public sector pay) and increases in the VAT rate(s).
Deciles are based on equivalized household disposable income in 2012 in the absence of fiscal con-
solidation measures and are constructed using the modified OECD equivalence scale. The charts are
drawn to different scales, but the interval between gridlines on each of them is the same.
Source: own calculations with EUROMOD.
column) shifts the overall balance between cuts in public transfers and tax increases further
towards the latter. Public wage and benefit cuts remain clearly a dominant source of
consolidation in Portugal and Romania (70% or more), while tax increases account for
67–74% of consolidation in Estonia, Greece, Spain, and Italy. Unlike other countries,
A. PAULUS, F. FIGARI, AND H. SUTHERLAND 643
Lithuania and Latvia have roughly an equal mix. Nevertheless, there is no clear association
between the design of the austerity measures and the change in inequality of disposable
income.
To have a better understanding of the extent to which the design of the austerity
measures is related to their distributional pattern, Fig. 2 shows the variation in disposable
income due to tax increases and cuts in public transfers by income decile groups. It is im-
portant to note that the tax increases are net of any automatic tax reductions due to public
sector pay cuts or other taxable benefits. The overall effect from cuts of public transfers
tends to be progressive in all countries but Estonia. The main drivers of such a distribu-
EE EL ES
0 0
0
change in average disposable income, %
-5
-10
-5 -15 -5
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
IT LV LT
0 0 0
-5
-5 -10 -5
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
PT RO
0 0
-5 -5
-10 -10
1 2 3 4 5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Fig. 2. Percentage change in household disposable income due to cuts in public transfers and tax
increases by household income decile group
Notes: See Fig. 1.
644 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
pension benefits are notable only in a few countries though their incidence across the in-
come distribution is very diverse (progressive in Latvia, regressive in Portugal, flat in
Lithuania). There are important interactions in all countries, in the form of means-tested
benefits absorbing part of income losses due to other instruments. However, this is only evi-
dent for countries like Estonia (where social assistance was also made more generous),
Spain and Romania; while in other countries the negative effect from cuts in non means-
tested benefits (Greece, Lithuania) or even in means-tested benefits themselves (Portugal)
dominates.
On the revenue side, the pattern of the distribution of tax increases is regressive in
Notes: Liquidity-constrained individuals based on the out-of-sample prediction of the probability of being
liquidity constrained taking into account the simulated effects of austerity measures and labour market adjust-
ments. Per cent of austerity measures in terms of the aggregate revenue.
Source: Own calculations with EUROMOD.
Following Auerbach and Feenberg (2000) one can assume that if the income shock is
perceived as transitory and households can borrow, their demand does not change.
However, according to Auerbach and Feenberg (2000) and Galı et al. (2007) it is also usual
to assume that households who face liquidity constraints fully adjust consumption expend-
iture after changes in disposable income or, in other words, consume their entire after-tax
income each year (Clinton et al., 2011). Our identification of the liquidity (and credit) con-
strained households follows the usual practice in the micro-based literature (Jappelli et al.,
1998) and uses survey questions to define who is liquidity constrained. In our analysis, we
consider liquidity-constrained households to be those who declare themselves as not having
‘the capacity to face unexpected financial expenses’ (see Dolls et al., 2012, for a robustness
check with respect to the alternative questions included in the Survey of Consumer
Finances). Given the estimates found in the literature (Jappelli et al., 1998), the identifica-
tion of liquidity-constrained households through direct survey evidence represents an upper
bound.5 We rely on the information included in the EU-SILC 2011 to predict the probabil-
ity of being liquidity constrained in 2012 given income and other socio-economic character-
istics of the household and taking into account the simulated effects of austerity measures
and labour market adjustments. The percentage of liquidity-constrained individuals ranges
from around 35% in Greece, Spain, Italy, and Portugal to 76% in Latvia (see Table 4)
showing an increasing trend since the beginning of the economic crisis.6
In aggregate terms, liquidity-constrained individuals face a relatively small share of total
austerity measures (taking into account VAT increases as well), ranging from less than
5 In addition to the effects on household spending capacity, liquidity constraints might cause the re-
cession to be deeper and more prolonged through their effects on firm productivity. As supported
by recent empirical evidence, credit to enterprises is positively and significantly associated with
economic growth (Beck et al., 2012), while the effect of household credit on economic growth
seems ambiguous.
6 According to the SILC in 2008 the share of liquidity constrained individuals ranged from around
20% in Estonia to 57% in Latvia.
646 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
20% in Greece and Portugal to 35% in Estonia and 45% in Romania, while in Lithuania
and above all in Latvia, most of the austerity measures fall on their shoulders.
Assuming that households who face liquidity constraints fully adjust consumption ex-
penditure after changes in disposable income, we can derive a lower bound for the effect on
aggregate household demand as the effect of fiscal consolidation measures faced by the li-
quidity constrained (Table 5).7 The potential impact on aggregate demand, considering the
effects of increases in indirect taxes as well, is highly diverse and ranges from less than 1%
(of total household disposable income) in Italy to more than 7% in Latvia.
In order to explore the potential channels through which fiscal consolidation can affect
aggregate demand, and assuming that variation in income translates into a reduction in
household consumption due to liquidity constraints, we look at the associations between
the size and the design effects and the probability of being liquidity constrained. Table 6
shows the results of ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions where the probability of being
liquidity constrained is regressed over a measure of the size and the design of austerity
measures. From the results it emerges that the size of the austerity measures (expressed as a
percentage of household disposable income) is negatively correlated with the probability of
being liquidity constrained in all countries except Estonia and Romania. This is expected
given the distributive pattern of the austerity measures, being progressive in all countries
but Estonia and Romania (showing a somewhat U-shaped pattern). The design effect,
in turn, shows that a greater reliance on taxes is also associated with a lower probability
of being liquidity constrained, in other words households more likely to be liquidity
constrained tend to be more affected by cuts in public transfers rather than tax increases.
It is important to bear in mind that cuts in public transfers include both reductions in pub-
lic sector pay and in benefits, the latter often being an important source of income for
liquidity-constrained households. Assuming that liquidity-constrained households are more
7 The implications for the overall aggregate demand can be different in a general equilibrium setting
taking into account, among other factors, changes in government debt, future expectations, factor
costs, sovereign risk, cross-country linkages, and monetary policy as shown, e.g. in Coenen et al.
(2008), Clinton et al. (2011), and Anderson et al. (2015).
Table 6. Size and design effects of austerity measures on the probability of being liquidity constrained
Notes: OLS regressions at household level. Dependent variable: Probability of being liquidity constraint. Size: Austerity measures as % of household disposable income. Design: % of
Austerity measures as taxes. Standard errors in brackets; ***significant at 1%; ** at 5%; * at 10%.
Source: Own calculations with EUROMOD.
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/oep/article/69/3/632/2569054 by guest on 18 July 2024
648 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
responsive in terms of consumption to income shocks, then cuts in public transfers can be
seen as having more detrimental effects on aggregate demand than tax increases. The same
pattern is observed even controlling for income decile groups, with the exception of Estonia
and Romania, which is consistent with the distributive pattern observed in those countries.
Once changes in VAT are included, as expected given the regressivity of VAT, in some
countries we observe that higher reliance on taxes is associated with higher probability of
being liquidity constrained but the association is still negative and significant in four
countries.
Overall, our finding that cuts in public transfers are more likely than tax increases to
5. Conclusion
The design and distributional effects of fiscal consolidation measures are of great rele-
vance, not only because inequality, and any driver of growth in it, matters in its own right,
but also because they have implications for the effectiveness of policy for macro-economic
recovery.
We contribute to the literature on fiscal consolidation by estimating the distributional
effects of recent policy reforms in eight EU countries which were intended to reduce budget
deficits. Using the microsimulation approach, we identify and quantify fiscal consolidation
measures introduced through cuts in cash benefits, increases in direct and indirect taxes and
workers’ social contributions and cuts in public sector pay. Our ‘bottom-up’ measure
shows that there is wide cross-country variation in the scale of the resulting aggregate re-
duction in household monetary resources (from 2% to 15%), and in the combinations of
policy instruments that were adopted, resulting in variation in the distributional profiles of
income losses. Most are progressive on the whole, although it should be emphasized that
even if the poor contribute a lower proportion of their income than the rich, in some coun-
tries the scale of the reductions in their income is still large (e.g. in Greece). Including the ef-
fect of increases in VAT, which have been introduced in all the countries, reduces any
progressive effect. The latter are also substantial in absolute terms, in several countries
being of similar magnitude to the changes resulting from the measures affecting household
incomes directly.
The distributional pattern of austerity measures is not only relevant in its own right but
can also have important implications for macro-economic prospects. Based on previous epi-
sodes of fiscal consolidation over the period 1971–2009, Kaplanoglou et al. (2013, p. 7)
A. PAULUS, F. FIGARI, AND H. SUTHERLAND 649
conclude that ‘ameliorating the effects of adjustment on the weaker parts of society is cru-
cial and . . . “fair fiscal adjustments” [may] provide the double dividend of promoting social
cohesion, and enhancing the probability of success of the adjustment’.
The distributional impact of fiscal adjustments can matter for macro-economic dy-
namics, for example, through the effect on aggregate demand as consumption patterns usu-
ally differ between income groups. More disaggregated data and micro level modelling are
needed in order to provide indications for the macro-economic performance of the fiscal
adjustments. Our finding that combined cuts in public wages and transfers are more likely
to affect liquidity-constrained households shows that these measures are not necessarily less
Supplementary material
Supplementary material – the Appendix – is available online at the OUP website.
Funding
This work was supported by the European Commission through the Social Situation Monitor;
and the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC) through the Research Centre on Micro-
Social Change (MiSoC) at the University of Essex [grant number ES/L009153/1].
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to the Editor, two anonymous referees, S. Avram, C. Leventi, H. Levy, J.
Navicke, M. Matsaganis, E. Militaru and O. Rastrigina for their help. We would also like to
thank A. Brandolini, F. Bourguignon, H. Immervoll as well as the participants of the 8th Winter
School on Social Cohesion and Public Policy (Canazei, 2013), the IZA Workshop on the Future
of Labor (Bonn, 2013), the 2013 LIS Summer Lecture (Luxembourg), the 5th Meeting of
ECINEQ (Bari, 2013), the 2013 ImPRovE Conference (Brussels), the 2016 York Fiscal Policy
Symposium for their useful comments. We use EUROMOD F6.0 and acknowledge the contribu-
tion of all past and current members of the EUROMOD consortium. We use microdata from the
2008 EU Statistics on Incomes and Living Conditions (EU-SILC) made available by Eurostat
under contract EU-SILC/2011/55 (for Latvia, Lithuania, Portugal and Romania) and the national
2008 SILC data made available by respective national statistical offices (for Estonia, Greece,
Spain, and Italy).
References
Agnello, L. and Sousa, R.M. (2014) How does fiscal consolidation impact on income inequality?,
Review of Income and Wealth, 60, 702–26.
650 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
Alesina, A. and Ardagna, S. (1998) Tales of fiscal adjustment, Economic Policy, 13, 487–545.
Alesina, A. and Ardagna, S. (2010) Large changes in fiscal policy: taxes versus spending,
Tax Policy and the Economy, 24, 35–68.
Alesina, A. and Ardagna, S. (2013) The design of fiscal adjustments, Tax Policy and the Economy,
27, 19–67.
Alesina, A., Favero, C., and Giavazzi, F. (2012) The output effects of fiscal adjustments, NBER
Working Paper 18336, Cambridge, MA.
Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1995) Fiscal expansions and adjustments in OECD countries,
Economic Policy, 10, 207–48.
Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1997) Fiscal adjustments in OECD countries: composition and macro-
European Commission (2013) Taxation Trends in the European Union: Data for the EU Member
States, Iceland and Norway, Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg.
Favero, C., Giavazzi, F., and Perego, J. (2011) Country heterogeneity and the international evi-
dence on the effects of fiscal policy, IMF Economic Review, 59, 652–82.
Figari, F., Paulus, A., and Sutherland, H. (2015) Microsimulation and policy analysis, in A.B.
Atkinson and F. Bourguignon (eds) Handbook of Income Distribution, Vol. 2B, Elsevier,
Amsterdam, ch. 24.
Figari, F., Salvatori, A., and Sutherland, H. (2011) Economic downturn and stress testing
European welfare systems, in H. Immervoll, A. Peichl, and K. Tatsiramos (eds) Who Loses in
the Downturn? Economic Crisis, Employment and Income Distribution, Research in Labor
The term fk ðc; x; mk Þ is a composite arithmetic function what the tax-benefit model can
provide under a range of scenarios, once corresponding tax-benefit rules as they are in place
in each country have been coded. The term can be expanded to indicate that it is a sum of
various cash benefits/transfers and direct taxes (with negative values), a total of N compo-
nents, indexed by i and denoted fk;i :
X
N Xi
fk ðc; x; mk Þ ¼ fk;i c; x; mk ; j¼1
f k;j (2)
i¼1
A. PAULUS, F. FIGARI, AND H. SUTHERLAND 653
Each component – such as personal income tax, property tax, child benefit and social
assistance to name a few – is calculated in steps that closely follow actual policy rules.
The rules are often complex and highly non-linear and modelled in as much detail as pos-
sible given the information on relevant individual and household characteristics available in
the input datasets. The list of individual instruments and the order of their calculation are
specific to the country and the period in question.8 Furthermore, the nested summation-
term in eq. (2) captures potential interactions between instruments (e.g. a benefit might be
means-tested on the basis of income net of taxes, some non means-tested benefits are tax-
able), indexed by j, which in turn determine the order of calculations in a given country.
Here a refers to the year prior to the start of fiscal consolidation (e.g. 2010 in Greece) and
b to the end point of our analysis (i.e. 2012). A expresses statutory indexation rules for the
period from a to b, which can differ across tax-benefit instruments. A is therefore a vector,
which is different from the initial Bargain and Callan (2010) approach where a single scalar
a was used to adjust the monetary values of all instruments. In cases where there are no
statutory rules defined for a particular instrument i, the corresponding adjustment factor is
simply one (i.e. Ai ¼ 1). cb refers to household labour market (and socio-demographic)
characteristics in 2012, derived using the observed characteristics available in EU-SILC
2008 as the basis and modelling labour market transitions in line with labour force changes
observed in LFS between 2007 and 2011 (by selecting individuals randomly according to
their age, gender and education characteristics). Similarly, xb refers to household original
income in 2012, which is obtained by uprating observed income components in 2007 by
growth in the average amount (conditional on employment status in 2012).
The first term on the right hand side of eq. (3), yb ðcb ; xb ; mb Þ, represents disposable in-
come in 2012 simulated according to actual policy rules and (projected) household charac-
teristics and original incomes (including cuts and freezes in public wages). The second term
on the right hand side, ya cb ; xa;w xb;w ; Ama , is our counterfactual disposable income in
2012 with pre-consolidation tax-benefit policy rules (after adjusting monetary values of
policy parameters, ma , according to statutory indexation rules A) applied to the same
household characteristics and original incomes apart from public wages xa;w , which have
been adjusted to reflect their counterfactual levels without enacted cuts and freezes. The dif-
ference between the two terms is our estimate of the effect of fiscal consolidation measures
on disposable income at the household level. In Bargain and Callan’s (2010) terminology,
we estimate the policy effect conditional on end-period household characteristics. This is
not to be confused with the redistributive properties of a given tax-benefit system, which
focuses on how the distribution of x and y differ from each other.
8 The full list of tax-benefit instruments simulated in EUROMOD for each country, the order of calcu-
lation and underlying rules in a given year are documented in EUROMOD Country Reports (avail-
able at https://www.euromod.ac.uk/using-euromod/country-reports/ – last accessed on 4 August,
2016). All components of household disposable income are also indicated in EUROMOD Statistics
on the Distribution and Decomposition of Disposable Income (see https://www.euromod.ac.uk/
using-euromod/statistics – last accessed on 4 August, 2016).
654 DESIGN AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF AUSTERITY MEASURES
where IðÞ takes the whole disposable (or post-indirect tax) income distribution as the
argument.
In section 4, we estimate the probability for a household to be liquidity constrained:
on the basis of realized disposable incomes in 2012. Our estimate of the likely impact on
P
aggregate household demand (in the short run) in turn is derived as DD ¼ pDy.