lecture_mean_variance
lecture_mean_variance
Decision makers are assumed to prefer higher expected return (∂u/∂E[rp ] > 0) and to dislike increased
variance (∂u/∂var(rp ) < 0).
Definition 1 (Mean variance utility representation) We say that preferences over portfolios of assets
can be represented with a mean variance utility representation u(p), where p is the portfolio,
in such a manner that u(·, ·) is an increasing function of E[rp ] and a decreasing function of σ(rp ), where rp
is the portfolio return.
Proposition 1 The choices of a risk–averse, nonsatiated individual with quadratic preferences satisfy a
mean variance utility representation.
Proposition 2 Suppose returns are normally distributed. Then preferences can be represented with a mean
variance utility representation.
For general utility functions a mean-variance representation can be motivated by a Taylor expansion
around expected future wealth:
1
u(W̃ ) = u(E[W̃ ] + u′ (E[W̃ ])(W̃ − E[W̃ ]) + u′′ (E[W̃ ])(W̃ − E[W̃ ])2 + h.o.t.
2
Under a number of assumptions about the applicability of this expansion, the expected utility function can
be expressed as
1
E[u(W )] ≈ u(E[W ]) + u′′ (E[W ])σ 2 (W )
2
Since u′ > 0 and u′′ < 0 this means that for the utility functions for which this is a reasonable approx-
imation utility is increasing in expected wealth and decreasing in variance of expected wealth, which also
implies that it has the same signs for returns, since W̃ = W0 (1 + r̃).
1
2 The mathematics of the Mean Variance Frontier.
This part will cover the basic results about the mean variance frontier.
We assume that investors preferences over portfolios p satisfy a mean variance utility representation,
u(p) = u(E[rp ], σ(rp )), with utility increasing in expected return (∂u/∂E[rp ] > 0) and decreasing in variance
(∂u/∂var(rp ) < 0).
In this part we consider the representation of the portfolio opportunity set of such decision makers.
There are a number of useful properties of this opportunity set which follows purely from the mathematical
formulation of the optimization problem. It is these properties we focus on here.
3 Setup.
Assumption 1 (Securities) There exists n ≥ 2 risky securities, with expected returns e
E[r1 ]
E[r2 ]
e=
..
.
E[rn ]
and covariance matrix V
σ(r1 , r1 ) σ(r1 , r2 ) . . .
σ(r2 , r1 ) σ(r2 , r2 ) . . .
V=
..
.
σ(rn , r1 ) ... σ(rn , rn )
Definition 2 (Portfolio) A portfolio p is defined by a set of weights w invested in the risky assets.
ω1
ω2
w= .
..
ωn
The expected return on a portfolio is calculated as
E[rp ] = w′ e
and the variance of the portfolio is
E[rp ] = w′ Vw
2
Definition 4 (Minimum Variance Frontier) The set of all frontier portfolios is called the minimum
variance frontier.
wp = g + hE[rp ]
where
1
g= (B1′ − Ae′ ) V−1
D
1
h= (Ce′ − A1′ ) V−1
D
A = 1′ V−1 e
B = e′ V−1 e
C = 1′ V−1 1
B A
A=
A C
D = BC − A2 = |A|
Remark 1 The portfolio defined by weights g is a portfolio with expected return 0. The portfolio defined by
weights (g + h) is a portfolio with expected return 1. Note also the useful property that g1′ = 1, and h1′ = 0.
Proposition 4 The portfolios g and (g + h) generate the entire minimum variance frontier.
Proposition 5 Any two portfolios on the minimum variance frontier with distinct means are sufficient to
generate the minimum variance frontier.
Proposition 6 The covariance between any two frontier portfolios p and q can be found as
1
C A A
cov(rp , rq ) = E[rp ] − E[rq ] − +
D C C C
By setting q = p, this result also let us to describe the variance of any frontier portfolio.
3
6 The global minimum variance portfolio
Definition 5 (Global Minimum Variance Portfolio) The portfolio that minimizes variance regardless
of expected return is called the global minimum variance portfolio.
Let mvp be the global minimum variance portfolio.
Proposition 8 (Global Minimum Variance Portfolio) The minimum variance portfolio mvp has ex-
pected return E[rmvp ] = C
A
and variance var(rmvp ) = C1 .
Proposition 9 (Global minimum variance portfolio) The global minimum variance portfolio has weights
−1 ′ −1 1
′
wmvp = 1′ V−1 1 1 V = 1′ V−1
C
E[r]
6
A
C
-
p1 σ(r)
C
7 Efficient portfolios.
Definition 6 (Efficient Portfolio) Portfolios on the minimum variance frontier with expected returns
higher than E[rmvp ] are called efficient
E[r]
6
A
C
-
p1 σ(r)
C
Proposition 11 All portfolios on the positively–sloped segment of the efficient set are positively correlated.
Proposition 12 The proportion of an efficient portfolio invested in a given individual asset changes mono-
tonically along the efficient frontier.
4
8 The zero beta portfolio
Proposition 15 For any portfolio p on the frontier, there is a frontier portfolio zc(p) satisfying
cov(rzc(p) , rp ) = 0.
This portfolio is called the zero beta portfolio relative to p. The zero beta portfolio zb(p) has return
D
A
E[rzc(p) ] = − C2
C E[rp ] − A
C
6 s
p
s mvp
E[rzc(p) ] zc(p)
s
-
Proposition 16 In E[r]−σ(r) space, E[rzc(p) ] is found on intercept of the tangency line at p on the efficient
frontier.
E[r] 6
sp
s mvp
szc(p)
-
σ(r)
Proposition 17 In E[r] − σ 2 (r) space the line from p to E[rzc(p) ] goes through the minimum variance
portfolio mvp.
5
E[r] 6
sp
s mvp
szc(p)
-
σ 2 (r)
Proposition 19 The covariance vector of individual assets with any portfolio can be expressed as an exact
linear function of the individual mean returns vector if and only if the portfolio is efficient.
Remark 2 This is the basis for Roll’s claim that the only possible test of the CAPM is that the market
portfolio is mean variance efficient.
Proposition 20 Consider any portfolio p not on the portfolio frontier. The intercept on the expected rate
of return axis of a line from p though mvp is equal to the expected return on a portfolio q, which has zero
covariance with p and has the minimum variance among all the zero covariance portfolios with p.
E[r] 6
s
p
s
mvp
s
E[rq ] q
-
σ 2 (r)
6
10 Allowing for a riskless asset.
Suppose have N risky assets with weights w and one riskless assets with return rf .
Intuitively, the return on a portfolio with a mix of risky and risky assets can be written as
Proposition 21 An efficient portfolio in the presence of a riskless asset has the weights
E[rp ] − rf
wp = V−1 (e − 1rf )
H
where
H = (e − 1rf )′ V−1 (e − 1rf )
(E[rp ] − rf )2
σ 2 (rp ) =
H
Remark 4 Note that standard deviationn is a linear function of E[rp ]. The efficient set is a line in mean-
standard deviation space.
E[r] 6
se
A s mvp
C
rf
@
@
@
@
p@ -
1
C @ σ(r)
7
E[r] 6
rf
A @ s mvp
C
@
@
@
@ s
@e
p1 -
C
σ(r)
Proposition 25 If rf = C A
, the weight in the risk free asset is one. The risky portfolio is an zero investment
portfolio. The efficient set consists of two asymptotes toward the efficient set of risky assets.
E[r] 6
A s
C
@ mvp
@
@
@
@
@
p1 -
C
σ(r)
E[rp ] − rf
Sp =
σ(rp )
Proposition 27 The Sharpe ratio Sp of a portfolio p is the slope of the line in mean-standard deviations
space from the risk free rate through p.
Proposition 28 The tangency portfolio has the maximal Sharpe Ratio on the efficient frontier.
Example
8
E[r̃p ]
6 The Sharpe Index
r
E[r̃m ] m
r
p
The Sharpe Ratio
rf
-
σm σp
14 Short-sale constraints.
So far the analysis has put no restrictions on the set of weights wp that defines the minimum variance frontier.
For practical applications, existence of negative weights is problematic, since this involves selling securities
short.
This has led to the investigation of restricted mean variance frontiers, where the weights are constrained
to be non-negative.
14.1 Conditions under which all portfolio weights are optimally positive
To avoid having to deal with shortsale constraints an obvious question to ask is whether there are conditions
on e and V which guarantees that optimal weights will be positive. Unfortunately no simple answer here.
See some comments in Roll (1977) and Green (1986).
15 Further issues.
Backing out expected returns from weights and V.
9
16 The mean variance consequences of the tracking error criterion
While we are on the topic of mean variance mathematics one applied topic may serve to show the usefulness
of knowledge of this particular mathematical representation. Consider the case of tracking error
10
16.2 Analyzing the tracking error criterion in a mean variance framework
Definition 9 (Tracking error) A tracking error is defined relative to a benchmark portfolio. The tracking
error of any portfolio relative to the benchmark is the difference in return between the portfolio and the
benchmark.
Definition 10 (TEV criterion) The Tracking Error Variance criterion for portfolios is to minimize the
variance of the tracking error subject to achieving a given desired expected tracking error.
To formulate the problem, define
• e as the vector of expected returns,
The exact formulation of the optimization problem, given a desired tracking error G, is:
1 ′
xp = arg min x Vx
x 2
subject to
x′ e = G
x′ 1 = 0
Proposition 30 The optimal weights for the tracking error portfolio xp with the desired tracking error G
has the form
G
xp = (wy − wmvp )
E[ry ] − E[rmvp ]
where mvp is the minimum variance portfolio and y is another frontier portfolio with expected return E[ry ] =
B
A.
Remark 5 The portfolio y lies on a line from the origin through mvp in mean-variance space.
11
E[r]
6 r
y
A
C
r mvp
-
1 σ 2 (r)
C
Corrolary 2 The optimal xp relative to a benchmark b is independent of the benchmark, it only depends on
the desired tracking error G.
I.e. No matter what benchmark, for a given tracking error, everybody will make the same set of trades.
where K = G
E[ry ]−E[rmvp ] .
E[rb ]
σ(rp ) = σ (rb ) + σ (rxp ) + 2Kσ (rmvp )
2 2 2
−1
E[rmvp ]
Proposition 33 The distance between the TEV frontier for a given benchmark and the global mv frontier
is constant.
E[r]
6
r
b
-
σ 2 (r)
Corrolary 3 If a given benchmark portfolio is M-V inefficient, all its associated TEV optimal portfolios
will be M-V inefficient.
16.4 Concluding
Tracking error and its variations seems sensible, and may still be sensible:
Important purpose: Simplifies the monitoring problem of principals, which is an important feature.
12
16.5 References
Mahoney (2004), good on the conflicts on mutual fund managers.
Roll (1992) for the mean variance stuff
Assumption 3 (Perfect markets) The markets for all assets are perfect with no taxes or transactions
costs. Unlimited borrowing and short selling are permitted with full use of the proceeds. Each asset is
infinitely divisible.
Assumption 6 (State-independent utility) Investors are risk averse and maximize the expectation of a
von Neuman–Morgenstern utility function which depends solely on wealth.
Assumption 7 (Complete Markets) Each competitive investor can obtain any pattern of returns through
the purchase of marketed assets (subject only to his own budget constraint). If the number of outcome states
is finite, markets are complete if the number of marketed assets with linearly independent returns is equal to
the number of states.
Proposition 34 Given the above assumption, supposing mean-variance pricing holds for all assets, and
markets are complete. Then this can not be an equilibrium, since arbitrage opportunities will exist.
References
Philip H Dybvig and Jonathan E Ingersoll. Mean-variance theory in complete markets. Journal of Business, 55(2):233–251,
1982.
Richard C Green. Positively weighted portfolios on the minimum-variance frontier. Journal of Finance, 41:1051–1068, 1986.
Paul G Mahoney. Manger-investor conflicts in mutual funds. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(2):161–182, Spring 2004.
Richard Roll. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests– Part I: On past and potential testability of the theory. Journal of
Financial Economics, 4:129–176, 1977.
Richard Roll. A mean/variance analysis of tracking error. Journal of Portfolio Management, (13–22), summer 1992.
13