The document discusses environmental valuation and the concept of value. It explains that value is determined by peoples' willingness to make tradeoffs rather than natural laws or governments. For market goods, willingness to pay is represented by demand curves, while opportunity costs are represented by cost curves. Net value is calculated as consumer and producer surplus. Valuing non-market goods like the environment is more complex as there are no market prices, but methods examine tradeoffs in time, money, and other opportunities to estimate value. Direct use values come from tangible uses while indirect uses include existence, bequest, option, and altruistic values.
The document discusses environmental valuation and the concept of value. It explains that value is determined by peoples' willingness to make tradeoffs rather than natural laws or governments. For market goods, willingness to pay is represented by demand curves, while opportunity costs are represented by cost curves. Net value is calculated as consumer and producer surplus. Valuing non-market goods like the environment is more complex as there are no market prices, but methods examine tradeoffs in time, money, and other opportunities to estimate value. Direct use values come from tangible uses while indirect uses include existence, bequest, option, and altruistic values.
The document discusses environmental valuation and the concept of value. It explains that value is determined by peoples' willingness to make tradeoffs rather than natural laws or governments. For market goods, willingness to pay is represented by demand curves, while opportunity costs are represented by cost curves. Net value is calculated as consumer and producer surplus. Valuing non-market goods like the environment is more complex as there are no market prices, but methods examine tradeoffs in time, money, and other opportunities to estimate value. Direct use values come from tangible uses while indirect uses include existence, bequest, option, and altruistic values.
The document discusses environmental valuation and the concept of value. It explains that value is determined by peoples' willingness to make tradeoffs rather than natural laws or governments. For market goods, willingness to pay is represented by demand curves, while opportunity costs are represented by cost curves. Net value is calculated as consumer and producer surplus. Valuing non-market goods like the environment is more complex as there are no market prices, but methods examine tradeoffs in time, money, and other opportunities to estimate value. Direct use values come from tangible uses while indirect uses include existence, bequest, option, and altruistic values.
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 19
Environmental Valuation
What is value? • First, the economic view of “value” is anthropocentric. • This means value is determined by people and not by either natural law or government.
• Second, value is determined by peoples’ willingness to make trade-
offs. • When an individual spends money on one good, there is less available for other goods. What is value? • For market goods, the inverse demand curve represents a marginal willingness to pay function. • Each price on the curve represents a marginal willingness to pay for a specific quantity of the good. • The area under the curve at each price/quantity combination represents the total willingness to pay. Marginal WTP Function Marginal Cost Function • Marginal willingness to pay does not measure the total benefit associated with producing a good. • Resources used to produce the good could be used to produce other goods that would benefit society, these benefits must be subtracted from total value to yield net value. • Total resource costs can be examined with the aid of the marginal cost function. Marginal Cost Function • The relevant resource cost associated with a specific output level is given by the area under the marginal cost function at that output level.
• This area represents the opportunity cost of these resources (the
productivity of these resources in their next most productive use). Marginal Cost Function Net value • Net value for a market good is equal to the sum of CS + PS. • Consider the following example where the impact of air pollution on the productivity of agriculture causes less economic output per acre. • This impact is represented by a leftward shift in the MC function and a resulting change in net value equal to area ABCD. Net value for a market good Net value for a market good • The measurement process for determining the change in net value is much more complicated. • In the previous example, farmers may elect to plant a different crop or change quantity of planted acreage in response to the changing productivity. • Economic models consider the connectivity of markets when determining changes in net value. Value and Non-market Goods • This process not as easy for non-market goods (nutrient cycling, clean air, clean water, biodiversity, etc.) • We do not observe prices for non-market goods, so hard to estimate supply/demand functions • Instead, look at WTP or willingness to make tradeoffs to obtain non- market good Value and Non-market Goods • While money is one thing that people give-up or trade-off to obtain goods, it is not the only thing. • Time and other opportunities are sacrificed in order to obtain both market and non-market goods. • Examining these trade-offs can serve as a basis for valuing non-market goods. Direct use values • Non-market goods may have both direct use and indirect use values.
• Direct use values are associated with tangible uses of environmental
resources, such as use in manufacturing processes, recreational activities, or when environmental quality affects human health. Indirect use values • Indirect use values are those associated with more intangible uses of the environment, such as aesthetic benefits or satisfaction derived from the existence of environmental resources. • Indirect use values are also called passive use and nonuse values. • Indirect use values include existence value, bequest value, altruistic value, option value and the value of ecological services. Indirect Use Value – Bequest Value • Bequest value refers to the fact that an individual values having an environmental resource or general environmental quality available for his/her children or grandchildren to experience.
• It is based on the desire to make current sacrifices to raise the well-
being of one’s descendents. Indirect Use Value – Existence Value • Existence value refers to the fact that an individual’s utility may be increased by the knowledge of the existence of an environmental resource even though the individual has no current or potential direct use of the resource. • An individual may never have opportunity to see a whale but places value on preserving the species. Option value • Option value is commonly interpreted as the value of preserving threatened natural resources so that they might be available for use in the future. • Option value is the value given a resource when there is a risk associated with future supply and demand (Dziegielewska, 2009). Indirect Use Value – Altruistic Value • Altruistic value occurs out of one individual’s concern for another.
• A person values the environment not just because that person
benefits from the environmental quality but because the person values the opportunity for other people to enjoy high environmental quality. Not mutually exclusive • A person who has a direct use value for preserving old-growth forests (e.g., backpacker) may also have option, bequest, altruistic, and existence values for old- growth forests.