Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
skip to main content
10.1145/3210377.3210405acmconferencesArticle/Chapter ViewAbstractPublication PagesspaaConference Proceedingsconference-collections
research-article

Intense Competition can Drive Selfish Explorers to Optimize Coverage

Published: 11 July 2018 Publication History

Abstract

We consider a game-theoretic setting in which selfish individuals compete over resources of varying quality. The motivating example is a group of animals that disperse over patches of food of different abundances. In such scenarios, individuals are biased towards selecting the higher quality patches, while, at the same time, aiming to avoid costly collisions or overlaps. Our goal is to investigate the impact of collision costs on the parallel coverage of resources by the whole group. Consider M sites, where a site x has value f(x). We think of f(x) as the reward associated with site x, and assume that if a single individual visits x exclusively, it receives this exact reward. Typically, we assume that if l>1 individuals visit x then each receives at most f(x)/l. In particular, when competition costs are high, each individual might receive an amount strictly less than f(x)/l, which could even be negative. Conversely, modeling cooperation at a site, we also consider cases where each one gets more than f(x)/l. There are k identical players that compete over the rewards. They independently act in parallel, in a one-shot scenario, each specifying a single site to visit, without knowing which sites are explored by others. The group performance is evaluated by the expected coverage, defined as the sum of f(x) over all sites that are explored by at least one player. Since we assume that players cannot coordinate before choosing their site we focus on symmetric strategies. The main takeaway message of this paper is that the optimal symmetric coverage is expected to emerge when collision costs are relatively high, so that the following "Judgment of Solomon" type of rule holds: If a single player explores a site x then it gains its full reward f(x), but if several players explore it, then neither one receives any reward. Under this policy, it turns out that there exists a unique symmetric Nash Equilibrium strategy, which is, in fact, evolutionary stable. Moreover, this strategy yields the best possible coverage among all symmetric strategies. Viewing the coverage measure as the social welfare, this policy thus enjoys a (Symmetric) Price of Anarchy of precisely 1, whereas, in fact, any other congestion policy has a price strictly greater than 1. Our model falls within the scope of mechanism design, and more precisely in the area of incentivizing exploration. It finds relevance in evolutionary ecology, and further connects to studies on Bayesian parallel search algorithms.

References

[1]
Susanne Albers and Matthias Hellwig. 2013. Online Makespan Minimization with Parallel Schedules. CoRR abs/1304.5625 (2013). http://arxiv.org/abs/1304.5625
[2]
Sayan Bhattacharya, Sungjin Im, Janardhan Kulkarni, and Kamesh Munagala. 2014. Coordination mechanisms from (almost) all scheduling policies. In Innovations in Theoretical Computer Science, ITCS'14, Princeton, NJ, USA, January 12--14, 2014. 121--134.
[3]
C. Cannings Broom, M. and G. Vickers. 1997. Multi-player matrix games. Bulletin of Mathematical Biology 59, 3 (1997), 931--952.
[4]
Mark Broom and Jan Rychtár. 2013. Game-theoretical models in biology. CRC Press.
[5]
Maciej Bukowski and Jacek Miekisz. 2004. Evolutionary and asymptotic stability in symmetric multi-player games. International Journal of Game Theory 33, 1 (2004), 41--54.
[6]
Chris Cosner, Juan Dávila, and Salomé Martínez. 2012. Evolutionary stability of ideal free nonlocal dispersal. Journal of Biological Dynamics 6, 2 (2012), 395--405.
[7]
Ross Cressman and Vlastimil Křivan. 2006. Migration dynamics for the ideal free distribution. The American Naturalist 168, 3 (2006), 384--397.
[8]
Ross Cressman and Vlastimil Křivan. 2010. The ideal free distribution as an evolutionarily stable state in density-dependent population games. Oikos 119, 8 (2010), 1231--1242.
[9]
Artur Czumaj and Berthold Vöcking. 2007. Tight Bounds for Worst-case Equilibria. ACM Trans. Algorithms 3, 1, Article 4 (Feb. 2007), 17 pages.
[10]
Dina K.N. Dechmann, Silke L. Heucke, Luca Giuggioli, Kamran Safi, Christian C. Voigt, and Martin Wikelski. 2009. Experimental evidence for group hunting via eavesdropping in echolocating bats. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 276, 1668 (2009), 2721--2728. 0473 arXiv:http://rspb.royalsocietypublishing.org/content/276/1668/2721.full.pdf
[11]
Avigdor Eldar. 2011. Social conflict drives the evolutionary divergence of quorum sensing. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108, 33 (2011), 13635--13640. arXiv:http://www.pnas.org/content/108/33/13635.full.pdf
[12]
Ofer Feinerman and Amos Korman. 2017. The ANTS problem. Distributed Computing 30, 3 (2017), 149--168.
[13]
Ofer Feinerman and Amos Korman. 2017. Individual versus collective cognition in social insects. Journal of Experimental Biology 220, 1 (2017), 73--82. arXiv:http://jeb.biologists.org/content/220/1/73.full.pdf
[14]
Pierre Fraigniaud, Amos Korman, and Yoav Rodeh. 2016. Parallel exhaustive search without coordination. In Proceedings of the 48th Annual ACM SIGACT Symposium on Theory of Computing, STOC 2016, Cambridge, MA, USA, June 18--21, 2016. 312--323.
[15]
Peter Frazier, David Kempe, Jon Kleinberg, and Robert Kleinberg. 2014. Incentivizing exploration. In Proceedings of the fifteenth ACM conference on Economics and computation. ACM, 5--22.
[16]
Stephen Dewitt Fretwell and Henry L. Lucas Jr. 1969. On territorial behavior and other factors influencing habitat distribution in birds. Acta biotheoretica 19, 1 (1969), 16--32.
[17]
Luc-Alain Giraldeau and Thomas Caraco. {n. d.}. Social Foraging Theory. Princeton University Press ({n. d.}).
[18]
Chaitanya S Gokhale and Arne Traulsen. 2010. Evolutionary games in the multiverse. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 107, 12 (2010), 5500-- 5504.
[19]
Thomas Gregor, Koichi Fujimoto, Noritaka Masaki, and Satoshi Sawai. 2010. The Onset of Collective Behavior in Social Amoebae. Science 328, 5981 (2010), 1021--1025. arXiv:http://science.sciencemag.org/content/328/5981/1021.full.pdf
[20]
William D. Hamilton. 1996. Narrow roads of geneland. Freeman. Freeman (1996).
[21]
Thomas T Hills, Peter M Todd, David Lazer, A David Redish, Iain D Couzin, Cognitive Search Research Group, et al. 2015. Exploration versus exploitation in space, mind, and society. Trends in cognitive sciences 19, 1 (2015), 46--54.
[22]
Martyn Kennedy and Russell D. Gray. 1993. Can Ecological Theory Predict the Distribution of Foraging Animals? A Critical Analysis of Experiments on the Ideal Free Distribution. Oikos 68, 1 (1993), 158--166. http://www.jstor.org/stable/ 3545322
[23]
Jon Kleinberg and Sigal Oren. 2011. Mechanisms for (mis) allocating scientific credit. In Proceedings of the forty-third annual ACM symposium on Theory of computing. ACM, 529--538.
[24]
Amos Korman and Yoav Rodeh. 2017. Parallel search without coordination. In Proceedings of the 24th International Colloquium on Structural Information and Communication Complexity, SIROCCO 2017, Porquerolles, France, June 19--22, 2017.
[25]
Ilan Kremer, Yishay Mansour, and Motty Perry. 2014. Implementing the Wisdom of the Crowd. Journal of Political Economy 122, 5 (2014), 988--1012.
[26]
Yishay Mansour, Aleksandrs Slivkins, and Vasilis Syrgkanis. 2015. Bayesian incentive-compatible bandit exploration. In Proceedings of the Sixteenth ACM Conference on Economics and Computation. ACM, 565--582.
[27]
John M. McNamara and Alasdair I. Houston. 2009. Integrating function and mechanism. Trends in Ecology & Evolution 24, 12 (2009), 670 -- 675.
[28]
Linda Mealey. 1995. The sociobiology of sociopathy: An integrated evolutionary model. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 18(3) (1995), 523--541.
[29]
Rodrigo A Medellin, Marina Rivero, Ana Ibarra, J Antonio de la Torre, Tania P Gonzalez-Terrazas, Leonora Torres-Knoop, and Marco Tschapka. 2018. Follow me: foraging distances of Leptonycteris yerbabuenae (Chiroptera: Phyllostomidae) in Sonora determined by fluorescent powder. Journal of Mammalogy 99, 2 (2018), 306--311. arXiv:/oup/backfile/content_public/journal/jmammal/99/2/- 10.1093_jmammal_gyy016/1/gyy016.pdf
[30]
Dov Monderer and Lloyd S Shapley. 1996. Potential games. Games and economic behavior 14, 1 (1996), 124--143.
[31]
Douglas W Morris. 2003. Shadows of predation: habitat-selecting consumers eclipse competition between coexisting prey. Evolutionary Ecology 17, 4 (2003), 393--422.
[32]
AJ Nicholson. 1954. An outline of the dynamics of animal populations. Australian Journal of Zoology (1954), 9--65.
[33]
Noam Nisan, Tim Roughgarden, Eva Tardos, and Vijay V. Vazirani. 2007. Algorithmic Game Theory. Cambridge University Press.
[34]
Martin J Osborne and Ariel Rubinstein. 1994. A course in game theory. MIT press.
[35]
Yiangos Papanastasiou, Kostas Bimpikis, and Nicos Savva. 2017. Crowdsourcing exploration. Management Science (2017).
[36]
Geoffrey A Parker. 1978. Searching for mates. Behavioural ecology: an evolutionary approach 1 (1978), 214--244.
[37]
Geoffrey A Parker. 1984. Evolutionary stable strategies. Behavioural ecology: an evolutionary approach (1984), 30--61.
[38]
Noa Pinter-Wollman, Tamar Dayan, David Eilam, and Noga Kronfeld-Schor. 2006. Can aggression be the force driving temporal separation between competing common and golden spiny mice? Journal of Mammalogy 87, 1 (2006), 48--53.
[39]
H Ronald Pulliam and Thomas Caraco. 1984. Living in groups: is there an optimal group size. Behavioural ecology: an evolutionary approach 2 (1984), 122--147.
[40]
H Ronald Pulliam and Brent J Danielson. 1991. Sources, sinks, and habitat selection: a landscape perspective on population dynamics. The American Naturalist 137 (1991), S50--S66.
[41]
Nicanor Quijano and Kevin M Passino. 2007. The ideal free distribution: Theory and engineering application. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, Part B (Cybernetics) 37, 1 (2007), 154--165.
[42]
Robert W Rosenthal. 1973. A class of games possessing pure-strategy Nash equilibria. International Journal of Game Theory 2, 1 (1973), 65--67.
[43]
J. Maynard Smith and G. R. Price. 1973. The Logic of Animal Conflict. Nature 246(5427) (1973), 15--18.
[44]
Tom Tregenza. 1995. Building on the ideal free distribution. Adv. Ecol. Res (1995), 253--307.
[45]
Adrian Vetta. 2002. Nash equilibria in competitive societies, with applications to facility location, traffic routing and auctions. In Foundations of Computer Science, 2002. Proceedings. The 43rd Annual IEEE Symposium on. IEEE, 416--425.

Cited By

View all

Index Terms

  1. Intense Competition can Drive Selfish Explorers to Optimize Coverage

      Recommendations

      Comments

      Information & Contributors

      Information

      Published In

      cover image ACM Conferences
      SPAA '18: Proceedings of the 30th on Symposium on Parallelism in Algorithms and Architectures
      July 2018
      437 pages
      ISBN:9781450357999
      DOI:10.1145/3210377
      Permission to make digital or hard copies of all or part of this work for personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are not made or distributed for profit or commercial advantage and that copies bear this notice and the full citation on the first page. Copyrights for components of this work owned by others than ACM must be honored. Abstracting with credit is permitted. To copy otherwise, or republish, to post on servers or to redistribute to lists, requires prior specific permission and/or a fee. Request permissions from [email protected]

      Sponsors

      Publisher

      Association for Computing Machinery

      New York, NY, United States

      Publication History

      Published: 11 July 2018

      Permissions

      Request permissions for this article.

      Check for updates

      Author Tags

      1. algorithmic game theory
      2. congestion games
      3. distributed computing
      4. evolutionary game theory
      5. ideal free distribution
      6. incentivizing exploration
      7. mechanism design
      8. symmetric strategies

      Qualifiers

      • Research-article

      Funding Sources

      Conference

      SPAA '18
      Sponsor:

      Acceptance Rates

      SPAA '18 Paper Acceptance Rate 36 of 120 submissions, 30%;
      Overall Acceptance Rate 447 of 1,461 submissions, 31%

      Upcoming Conference

      SPAA '25
      37th ACM Symposium on Parallelism in Algorithms and Architectures
      July 28 - August 1, 2025
      Portland , OR , USA

      Contributors

      Other Metrics

      Bibliometrics & Citations

      Bibliometrics

      Article Metrics

      • Downloads (Last 12 months)2
      • Downloads (Last 6 weeks)1
      Reflects downloads up to 14 Jan 2025

      Other Metrics

      Citations

      Cited By

      View all

      View Options

      Login options

      View options

      PDF

      View or Download as a PDF file.

      PDF

      eReader

      View online with eReader.

      eReader

      Media

      Figures

      Other

      Tables

      Share

      Share

      Share this Publication link

      Share on social media