The Bureau of Economic Analysis released new data today showing that
corporate profits reached an all-time nominal high in the second quarter
of 2013. Profits before tax rose to 12.53 percent of GDP from 12.22
percent in the previous quarter, as the following chart shows. That was
just fractionally short of the all-time high of 12.60 percent reached in
the final quarter of 2011. At the same time, the BEA confirmed that GDP
grew by 2.5 percent, the same as the August estimate.
Meanwhile,
proprietors’ income was flat in Q2. Popular discussions often treat
proprietors’ income as a proxy for the income of small business. It
includes the current income of unincorporated businesses that have the
legal forms of proprietorships, partnerships, and tax-exempt
cooperatives. It does not perfectly match up with small firm size
because some small firms are incorporated and some proprietorships,
partnerships, and cooperatives are large.
Proprietors’
income has lagged behind corporate income in recent decades. In the
1950s and 1960s, the shares of corporate profits and proprietors’ income
were roughly the same. Now, corporate profits are half-again greater.
The gap between the two hit an all-time high in Q4 2011, when corporate
profits reached 168 percent of proprietors’ income. (This earlier post
discussed some of the reasons for the increasing disparity between
large and small-business profits, including changes over the years in
tax and healthcare policy.)
In addition to data on GDP and its components, the latest BEA report included new estimates of inflation based on the national income accounts. The broadest measure of inflation, the GDP deflator, grew at just a 0.6 percent annual rate in Q2. The deflator for personal consumption expenditures, closely watched by the Fed, actually fell at a 0.1 percent annual rate. Previously the PCE deflator had been estimated to have been unchanged in the quarter.
Overall, the latest report on GDP and its components
contained few surprises. Compared with August’s second estimate, today’s
third estimate shows the same overall rate of growth of real GDP, at
2.5 percent. Inventory accumulation and the growth of exports were
slightly less rapid than previously estimated. Those changes were offset
by slightly faster growth of consumer spending and a slightly less
rapid decrease in the government’s contribution to GDP.
Follow this link to view or download a classroom-ready slideshow with charts of the latest GDP, profits, and inflation data.
Friday, September 27, 2013
Monday, September 23, 2013
Whatever Became of the Money Multiplier?
If you are teaching or taking an introductory macroeconomics course this fall, you will, at some point, encounter the money multiplier. The multipier posits that there is a stable ratio between M2, the stock of ordinary money in the economy, which consists of currency and bank deposits, and the monetary base, also known as high-powered money, which consists of paper currency issued by the Fed plus reserve balances that commercial banks hold on deposit at the Fed.
Your textbook will go on to explain that the money multiplier gives the Fed great power over the economy. The Fed is able to use open market operations (purchases and sales of government bonds) to control the monetary base. The monetary base, in turn, serves as the raw material from which banks create ordinary money for the rest of us. If the money multiplier has a value of, say, eight, then banks can and will create eight dollars of deposit money for each dollar of high-powered money. Add in the assumption that the quantity of money in circulation powerfully influences investment and consumption spending, and you can see why we obsess so much about quantitative easing, who will win appointment as the Federal Reserve Chair, and every comma in every press release that issues from the stately Eccles building on Constitution Avenue.
There is just one problem. As the following chart shows, something has gone badly wrong with the money multiplier in recent years. For most of the 1990s and 2000s, it was steady as a rock. From 1994 to 2007, the 12-month moving average of the multiplier stayed in a narrow range, between 8.0 and 8.4. Then it fell off a cliff. By July of this year, it had reached a record low of 3.24.
What happened? To answer that question, we need to look a little more closely at the textbook explanation of how the money multiplier is supposed to work, at some features of the banking system that the multiplier model downplays, and finally, at some recent research. >>>Read more
Your textbook will go on to explain that the money multiplier gives the Fed great power over the economy. The Fed is able to use open market operations (purchases and sales of government bonds) to control the monetary base. The monetary base, in turn, serves as the raw material from which banks create ordinary money for the rest of us. If the money multiplier has a value of, say, eight, then banks can and will create eight dollars of deposit money for each dollar of high-powered money. Add in the assumption that the quantity of money in circulation powerfully influences investment and consumption spending, and you can see why we obsess so much about quantitative easing, who will win appointment as the Federal Reserve Chair, and every comma in every press release that issues from the stately Eccles building on Constitution Avenue.
There is just one problem. As the following chart shows, something has gone badly wrong with the money multiplier in recent years. For most of the 1990s and 2000s, it was steady as a rock. From 1994 to 2007, the 12-month moving average of the multiplier stayed in a narrow range, between 8.0 and 8.4. Then it fell off a cliff. By July of this year, it had reached a record low of 3.24.
What happened? To answer that question, we need to look a little more closely at the textbook explanation of how the money multiplier is supposed to work, at some features of the banking system that the multiplier model downplays, and finally, at some recent research. >>>Read more
Sunday, September 22, 2013
US Working Age Poverty Remains Near Record High in 2012
The Bureau of the Census released data for U.S. poverty rates and
family income today. The headline poverty rate for all individuals was
essentially unchanged from 2011, at 15 percent. The poverty rate reached
an all-time low of 11.3 percent in 2000. Median family income declined
from $51,100 to $51,017, a change that is not statistically significant.
One of the most striking trends in recent poverty data has been the rise in poverty among the working-age population. As the following chart shows, when the government first began to publish poverty data, the elderly were the poorest segment of the population, with children in second place. Since that time, poverty rates among the elderly have fallen dramatically, while those of children have changed little. Meanwhile, the poverty rate for working-age individuals (defined as 18 to 65 years) has risen, and has continued to rise during the current economic recovery. It reached 13.7 percent of the population in 2010, and has not showed a statistically significant change from that level since.
One might wonder why working-age poverty would not have decreased as a result of the gradual fall in unemployment rates. Another data series helps explain why it has not.>>>Read more
One of the most striking trends in recent poverty data has been the rise in poverty among the working-age population. As the following chart shows, when the government first began to publish poverty data, the elderly were the poorest segment of the population, with children in second place. Since that time, poverty rates among the elderly have fallen dramatically, while those of children have changed little. Meanwhile, the poverty rate for working-age individuals (defined as 18 to 65 years) has risen, and has continued to rise during the current economic recovery. It reached 13.7 percent of the population in 2010, and has not showed a statistically significant change from that level since.
One might wonder why working-age poverty would not have decreased as a result of the gradual fall in unemployment rates. Another data series helps explain why it has not.>>>Read more
Saturday, September 21, 2013
What Does the U-6 "Broad Unemployment Rate" Really Tell Us?
During the recent deep recession and slow recovery, U-6, an
alternative measure of unemployment issued by the Bureau of Labor
Statistics, has received increased attention. People often refer to U-6,
which includes several groups of workers in addition to the officially
unemployed, as the “broad unemployment rate.” No doubt, part of its
popularity stems from the simple fact that the broad measure of
joblessness makes the employment situation look worse than the standard
one, and bad news attracts readers and viewers. Beyond that, thought,
just what does U-6 really add to our understanding of labor market
conditions?
What U-6 tells us
The main contribution of U-6, as I see it, is to remind us that those whom the BLS defines as unemployed—those who are not working for pay even an hour a week but have looked for work within the last four weeks—are not the only ones who suffer when labor markets are weak. U-6 brings in two groups of people who feel labor market distress even though they do not fit the official definition of unemployed:>>>Read more
What U-6 tells us
The main contribution of U-6, as I see it, is to remind us that those whom the BLS defines as unemployed—those who are not working for pay even an hour a week but have looked for work within the last four weeks—are not the only ones who suffer when labor markets are weak. U-6 brings in two groups of people who feel labor market distress even though they do not fit the official definition of unemployed:>>>Read more
Monday, September 9, 2013
US Unemployment Rate Falls to 7.3 Percent in August, a New Low for the Recovery
The U.S. unemployment rate edged down from 7.39 percent in July to 7.28 percent in August, according to data released today
by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The decrease did not, however,
reflect an across-the-board strengthening of the labor market. According
to the BLS household survey, the civilian labor force, the number of
unemployed, and the number of employed all decreased slightly for the
month, both before and after seasonal adjustment. The labor force
participation rate and the employment-population ratio also decreased on
the month.
The BLS also publishes data on a broader measure of unemployment and undermployment known as U-6. That measure takes into account people who are working part-time but would prefer full-time work, and so-called marginally attached workers. The latter incude people who have not looked for work because they think none is available and people who would like a job and are available for work, but who did not look for work in the previous four weeks because of study, family responsibilities, or other reasons. Both involuntary part-time workers and marginally attached workers decreased for the month, bringing U-6 to 13.7 percent. As the chart shows, that also was a new low for the recovery.
According to the separate survey of business establishments, the number of payroll jobs grew by 169,000 during August. The establishment survey excludes farm workers and the self-employed, does not correct for workers holding two jobs, and differs in other details of methodology. It is not unusual for the household employment data and the payroll jobs data to point in opposite directions. >>>Read More
Follow this link to view or download a classroom-ready slideshow with charts of the latest jobs data
The BLS also publishes data on a broader measure of unemployment and undermployment known as U-6. That measure takes into account people who are working part-time but would prefer full-time work, and so-called marginally attached workers. The latter incude people who have not looked for work because they think none is available and people who would like a job and are available for work, but who did not look for work in the previous four weeks because of study, family responsibilities, or other reasons. Both involuntary part-time workers and marginally attached workers decreased for the month, bringing U-6 to 13.7 percent. As the chart shows, that also was a new low for the recovery.
According to the separate survey of business establishments, the number of payroll jobs grew by 169,000 during August. The establishment survey excludes farm workers and the self-employed, does not correct for workers holding two jobs, and differs in other details of methodology. It is not unusual for the household employment data and the payroll jobs data to point in opposite directions. >>>Read More
Follow this link to view or download a classroom-ready slideshow with charts of the latest jobs data
Wednesday, September 4, 2013
Brazil's Volatile Real: Why Currency Fluctuations are Painful
Brazil’s volatile currency, the real, is back in the news. Two years
ago, the real hit all-time highs against the dollar. The rise prompted
Brazil’s finance minister, Guido Mantega, to accuse the central banks of
advanced countries, the Fed in particular, of conducting a “currency war”
at his country’s expense. Now the real is heading back toward the lows
it reached in 2008, at the depth of the global financial crisis. One
might think that if a strong real is bad, then a weak real must be good,
but that has not been the reaction. Instead, the recent depreciation
has caused Brazil’s central bank president to complain about the “adverse winds” from a strong dollar.
Why are currency fluctuations, regardless of direction, so painful, and not just for Brazil? The traditional notion is that exchange rate movements, whether appreciation or depreciation, produce roughly equal gains and losses. Some of them come from the effects on trade in goods and services. When a country’s currency appreciates, its exporters find it harder to sell their products abroad and domestic producers have a harder time competing with imports. They are losers. Meanwhile, firms that use imported inputs and consumers of imported goods are winners. There are also financial effects. People whose foreign currency assets exceed their foreign currency liabilities gain from appreciation of the domestic currency, and those with foreign currency liabilities greater than foreign currency assets lose.>>>Read more
Why are currency fluctuations, regardless of direction, so painful, and not just for Brazil? The traditional notion is that exchange rate movements, whether appreciation or depreciation, produce roughly equal gains and losses. Some of them come from the effects on trade in goods and services. When a country’s currency appreciates, its exporters find it harder to sell their products abroad and domestic producers have a harder time competing with imports. They are losers. Meanwhile, firms that use imported inputs and consumers of imported goods are winners. There are also financial effects. People whose foreign currency assets exceed their foreign currency liabilities gain from appreciation of the domestic currency, and those with foreign currency liabilities greater than foreign currency assets lose.>>>Read more
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)