Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Jump to content

Round-robin item allocation

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Round robin is a procedure for fair item allocation. It can be used to allocate several indivisible items among several people, such that the allocation is "almost" envy-free: each agent believes that the bundle they received is at least as good as the bundle of any other agent, when at most one item is removed from the other bundle. In sports, the round-robin procedure is called a draft.

Setting

[edit]

There are m objects to allocate, and n people ("agents") with equal rights to these objects. Each person has different preferences over the objects. The preferences of an agent are given by a vector of values - a value for each object. It is assumed that the value of a bundle for an agent is the sum of the values of the objects in the bundle (in other words, the agents' valuations are an additive set function on the set of objects).

Description

[edit]

The protocol proceeds as follows:

  1. Number the people arbitrarily from 1 to ;
  2. While there are unassigned objects:
    • Let each person from 1 to pick an unassigned object.

It is assumed that each person in their turn picks an unassigned object with a highest value among the remaining objects.

Additivity requirement

[edit]

The round-robin protocol requires additivity, since it requires each agent to pick their "best item" without knowing what other items they are going to get; additivity of valuations guarantees that there is always a "best item" (an item with a highest value). In other words, it assumes that the items are independent goods. The additivity requirement can be relaxed to weak additivity.

Properties

[edit]

The round-robin protocol is very simple to execute: it requires only m steps. Each agent can order the objects in advance by descending value (this takes time per agent) and then pick an object in time .

The final allocation is EF1 - envy-free up to one object. This means that, for every pair of agents and , if at most one object is removed from the bundle of , then does not envy .

Proof:[1] For every agent , divide the selections made by the agents to sub-sequences: the first subsequence starts at agent 1 and ends at agent ; the latter subsequences start at and end at . In the latter subsequences, agent chooses first, so they can choose their best item, so they do not envy any other agent. Agent can envy only one of the agents , and the envy comes only from an item they selected in the first subsequence. If this item is removed, agent does not envy.

Additionally, round-robin guarantees that each agent receives the same number of items (m/n, if m is divisible by n), or almost the same number of items (if m is not divisible by n). Thus, it is useful in situations with simple cardinality constraints, such as: assigning course-seats to students where each student must receive the same number of courses.

Efficiency considerations

[edit]

Round-robin guarantees approximate fairness, but the outcome might be inefficient. As a simple example, suppose the valuations are:

z y x w v u
Alice's value: 12 10 8 7 4 1
George's value: 19 16 8 6 5 1

Round-robin, when Alice chooses first, yields the allocation with utilities (24,23) and social welfare 47. It is not Pareto efficient, since it is dominated e.g. y the allocation , with utilities (25,25).

An alternative algorithm, which may attain a higher social welfare, is the Iterated maximum-weight matching algorithm.[2] In each iteration, it finds a maximum-weight matching in the bipartite graph in which the nodes are the agents and the items, and the edge weights are the agents' values to the items. In the above example, the first matching is , the second is , and the third is . The total allocation is with utilities (18,32); the social welfare (- the sum of utilities) is 50, which is higher than in the round-robin allocation.

Note that even iterated maximum-weight matching does not guarantee Pareto efficiency, as the above allocation is dominated by (xwv, zyu) with utilities (19,36).

Round-robin for groups

[edit]

The round-robin algorithm can be used to fairly allocate items among groups. In this setting, all members in each group consume the same bundle, but different members in each group may have different preferences over the items. This raises the question of how each group should decide which item to choose in its turn. Suppose that the goal of each group is to maximize the fraction of its members that are "happy", that is, feel that the allocation is fair (according to their personal preferences). Suppose also that the agents have binary additive valuations, that is, each agent values each item at either 1 ("approve") or 0 ("disapprove"). Then, each group can decide what item to pick using weighted approval voting:[3]

  • Each group member is assigned a weight. The weight of member j is a certain function w(rj,sj), where:
    • rj is the number of remaining goods that j approves;
    • sj is the number of goods that j's group should still get such that the chosen fairness criterion is satisfied for j.
  • Each remaining item is assigned a weight. The weight of item g is the sum of weights of the agents who approve g: sum of w(rj,sj) for all j such that j values g at 1.
  • The group picks an item with the largest weight.

The resulting algorithm is called RWAV (round-robin with weighted approval voting). The weight function w(r,s) is determined based on an auxiliary function B(r,s), defined by the following recurrence relation:

  • .

Intuitively, B(r,s) of an agent represents the probability that the agent is happy with the final allocation. If s ≤ 0, then by definition this probability is 1: the agent needs no more goods to be happy. If 0<s and r<s, then this probability is 0: the agent cannot be happy, since they need more goods than are available. Otherwise, B(r,s) is the average between B(r-1,s) - when the other group takes a good wanted by the agent, and B(r-1,s-1) - when the agent's group takes a good wanted by the agent. The term B(r-2,s-1) represents the situation when both groups take a good wanted by the agent. Once B(r,s) is computed, the weight function w is defined as follows:

When using this weight function and running RWAV with two groups, the fraction of happy members in group 1 is at least B(r, s(r)), and the fraction of happy members in group 2 is at least B(r-1, s(r)).[3]: Lemma 3.6  The function s(r) is determined by the fairness criterion. For example, for 1-out-of-3 maximin-share fairness, s(r) = floor(r/3). The following table shows some values of the function B, with the values of B(r-1, floor(r/3)) boldfaced:

r-s ↓ s → 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
-1 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
0 1 0.500 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
1 1 0.750 0.375 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
2 1 0.875 0.625 0.313 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
3 1 0.938 0.781 0.547 0.273 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
4 1 0.969 0.875 0.711 0.492 0.246 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
5 1 0.984 0.930 0.820 0.656 0.451 0.226 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
6 1 0.992 0.961 0.891 0.773 0.612 0.419 0.209 0.000 0.000 0.000
7 1 0.996 0.979 0.935 0.854 0.733 0.576 0.393 0.196 0.000 0.000
8 1 0.998 0.988 0.961 0.908 0.820 0.698 0.546 0.371 0.185 0.000
9 1 0.999 0.994 0.978 0.943 0.882 0.790 0.668 0.519 0.352 0.176
10 1 1.000 0.997 0.987 0.965 0.923 0.857 0.762 0.641 0.497 0.336

From this one can conclude that the RWAV algorithm guarantees that, in both groups, at least 75% of the members feel that the allocation is 1-out-of-3 MMS fair.

Extensions

[edit]

1. The round-robin protocol guarantees EF1 when the items are goods (- valued positively by all agents) and when they are chores (- valued negatively by all agents). However, when there are both goods and chores, it does not guarantee EF1. An adaptation of round-robin called double round-robin guarantees EF1 even with a mixture of goods and chores.[4]

2. When agents have more complex cardinality constraints (i.e., the items are divided into categories, and for each category of items, there is an upper bound on the number of items each agent can get from this category), round-robin might fail. However, combining round-robin with the envy-graph procedure gives an algorithm that finds allocations that are both EF1 and satisfy the cardinality constraints.[5]

3. When agents have different weights (i.e., agents have different entitlement for the total items), a generalized round-robin protocol called weighted round-robin guarantees EF1 when the items are goods (- valued positively by all agents)[6] and the reversed weighted round-robin guarantees EF1 when the items are chores (-valued negatively by all agents).[7]

See also

[edit]

Round-robin is a special case of a picking sequence.

Round-robin protocols are used in other areas besides fair item allocation. For example, see round-robin scheduling and round-robin tournament.

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Caragiannis, Ioannis; Kurokawa, David; Moulin, Hervé; Procaccia, Ariel D.; Shah, Nisarg; Wang, Junxing (2016). The Unreasonable Fairness of Maximum Nash Welfare (PDF). Proceedings of the 2016 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation - EC '16. p. 305. doi:10.1145/2940716.2940726. ISBN 9781450339360.
  2. ^ Brustle, Johannes; Dippel, Jack; Narayan, Vishnu V.; Suzuki, Mashbat; Vetta, Adrian (2020-07-13). "One Dollar Each Eliminates Envy". Proceedings of the 21st ACM Conference on Economics and Computation. EC '20. Virtual Event, Hungary: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 23–39. arXiv:1912.02797. doi:10.1145/3391403.3399447. ISBN 978-1-4503-7975-5. S2CID 208637311.
  3. ^ a b Segal-Halevi, Erel; Suksompong, Warut (2019-12-01). "Democratic fair allocation of indivisible goods". Artificial Intelligence. 277: 103167. arXiv:1709.02564. doi:10.1016/j.artint.2019.103167. ISSN 0004-3702. S2CID 203034477.
  4. ^ Haris Aziz, Ioannis Caragiannis, Ayumi Igarashi, Toby Walsh (2019). "Fair Allocation of Indivisible Goods and Chores" (PDF). IJCAI 2019 conference.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  5. ^ Biswas, Arpita; Barman, Siddharth (2018-07-13). "Fair division under cardinality constraints". Proceedings of the 27th International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence. IJCAI'18. Stockholm, Sweden: AAAI Press: 91–97. arXiv:1804.09521. ISBN 978-0-9992411-2-7.
  6. ^ Chakraborty, Mithun; Igarashi, Ayumi; Suksompong, Warut; Zick, Yair (2021-08-16). "Weighted Envy-freeness in Indivisible Item Allocation". ACM Transactions on Economics and Computation. ACm: 1–39.
  7. ^ Xiaowei Wu, Cong Zhang, Shengwei Zhou (2023). "Weighted EF1 Allocations for Indivisible Chores". EC 2023conference.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)