Asymmetric Wholesale Pricing:
Theory and Evidence*
Sourav Ray**
Department of Marketing
DeGroote School of Business, McMaster University
1280 Main Street, Hamilton, ON L8S-4M4, Canada
Phone: (905) 525-9140 ext. 22370; Fax: (905) 521-8995
Email: sray@mcmaster.ca
Haipeng (Allan) Chen
Department of Marketing
University of Miami
Coral Gables, FL 33124, USA
Mark E. Bergen
Department of Marketing and Logistics Management
Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota
Minneapolis, MN 55455, USA
Daniel Levy
Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University
Ramat-Gan 52900, Israel
JEL Codes: E31, E12, L11, L16, L22, L81, M21, M31
Keywords: Asymmetric Pricing, Channel Pricing, Costs of Price Adjustment, Menu Costs,
Wholesale Prices, Channels of Distribution, Retailing, Economic Model, Scanner Data
January 2005
* We thank two anonymous referees, an area editor, and the editor Steve Shugan for constructive comments, suggestions and
guidance through the revision process. Special thanks to our discussant Justin Johnson, and the participants at the 2002 INFORMSCornell University Conference on Pricing Research in Ithaca, NY, the 2002 Marketing Science conference in Edmonton, AB; the
marketing department seminars at JMSB – Concordia University, HEC, and McGill University, all in Montreal, and at CSOM –
University of Minnesota, Minneapolis; and Bianca Grohmann for their valuable feedback. Research assistance by Manish Aggarwal
is gratefully acknowledged. Parts of this research have been funded by FRDP of Concordia University and by the INE program of
SSHRC, Canada. All authors contributed equally. The usual disclaimer applies.
** Corresponding author
Forthcoming in: Marketing Science
Asymmetric Wholesale Pricing:
Theory and Evidence
Abstract
Asymmetric pricing is the phenomenon where prices rise more readily than they fall. We
articulate, and provide empirical support for, a theory of asymmetric pricing in wholesale
prices. In particular, we show how wholesale prices may be asymmetric in the small but
symmetric in the large, when retailers face costs of price adjustments. Such retailers will not
adjust prices for small changes in their costs. Upstream manufacturers then see a region of
inelastic demand where small wholesale price changes do not translate into commensurate
retail price changes. The implication is asymmetric – small wholesale increases are more
profitable because manufacturers will not lose customers from higher retail prices; yet, small
wholesale decreases are less profitable, because these will not create lower retail prices, hence
no extra revenue from greater sales. For larger changes, this asymmetry at wholesale vanishes
as the costs of changing prices are compensated by increases in retailers’ revenue that result
from correspondingly large retail price changes. We first present a formal economic model of
a channel with forward looking retailers facing costs of price adjustment to derive the testable
propositions. Next, we test these on manufacturer prices in a supermarket scanner dataset to
find support for our theory. We discuss the contributions of the results for the asymmetric
pricing, distribution channels and cost of price adjustment literatures, and implications for
public policy.
2
1. Introduction
Asymmetric pricing is a phenomenon where prices rise readily but fall slowly. Frequent
reports in the popular press lament the fact that prices are asymmetric. It is not uncommon to read
headlines about prices “rising like rockets …(but)… falling like feathers” (Octane, v.13-3, June
1999, pp.6-7); retail pork prices not coming down even if hog prices do (New York Times, Jan. 7,
1999) and government subsidies to dairy farmers not lowering dairy products prices, even if a hike
in the price of industrial milk paid to farmers, raises such prices at the store (Canadian Press
Newswire, Dec. 18, 2000). The resulting public interest in the phenomenon has spawned a large
academic literature devoted to the issue. Asymmetry has been studied across a broad range of
product markets (Peltzman, 2000), including gasoline (Bacon, 1991; Borenstein and Shepard, 1996;
Karrenbrock, 1991); fruit and vegetables (Pick et al., 1991; Ward, 1982); pork (Boyde and Brorsen,
1988); and banking (Hannan and Berger, 1991; Neumark and Sharpe, 1992).
Yet, despite the substantial research in asymmetric pricing, the theoretical literature in the
area is still in its nascent stages. Peltzman (2000) for example, comments that “Economic theory
suggests no pervasive tendency for prices to respond … (asymmetrically) …” Most existing
research is empirically driven, attempting to establish the scale and scope of asymmetry. Only a few
papers develop formal theories. These include explanations based on monopoly power (Benabou
and Gertner, 1993; Borenstein and Shepard, 1996), inflation with costs of price adjustment (Ball
and Mankiw, 1994), elasticity differences in a channel with costs of price adjustment (Madsen and
Yang, 1998) and information processing costs of consumers (Chen et al. 2004). Yet, in the context
of the broad evidence of asymmetric pricing, the theoretical field is still largely unexplored. For
authors like Peltzman (2000) this represents a “serious gap in a fundamental area of economic
theory.” Similar sentiments are echoed by Ball and Mankiw (1994), Borenstein et al. (1997), and
Blinder et al. (1998), all calling for further theory development to close this gap. Surprisingly, given
3
the ubiquity of the phenomenon and the rich marketing literature in pricing (cf. DeSarbo et al.,
1987; Hess and Gerstner, 1987; Ratchford and Srinivasan, 1993; Tellis and Zufryden, 1995;
Kadiyali et al., 2000), marketing’s contribution to research in asymmetric pricing has been marginal
till date. To the best of our knowledge, marketing has not directly studied asymmetric pricing. 1
In this paper we hope to address this gap by offering, and providing empirical support for, a
theory of asymmetric pricing. Our theory combines insights from the literature on channels of
distribution with insights from the literature on costs of price adjustment to suggest why wholesale
prices may be asymmetric. This is a natural direction to explore for two very important reasons.
First, we know little about the role played by the distribution channel and the business-tobusiness linkages implied therein, in determining asymmetric pricing at any level of the channel.
Yet, such linkages have been consistently argued to have important influences on the channel’s
pricing practices. 2 There is no reason to believe asymmetric pricing will be an exception. Quite to
the contrary, Peltzman (2000) suggests, “an explanation for asymmetry may require a fuller
understanding of those vertical market linkages.” By focusing on asymmetry in wholesale prices in
the context of a distribution channel, we help to clarify the role of such vertical linkages.
Second, while there is a large literature on the importance of costs of price adjustment for
price rigidity we are only beginning to develop our understanding of the implications of these costs
on both pricing decisions of other members of the distribution channel, and asymmetric pricing. 3
For example, Levy et al. (1997) attempt to calibrate the source and magnitude of these costs, but do
not explore asymmetry or the implications for channel pricing. On the other hand, Ball and Mankiw
1
The marketing literature on price adjustment costs is limited. See the paper on haggling by Desai and Purohit (2004) as
an example of how these costs might impact marketing strategy. On asymmetry, see Greenleaf, (1995); Kopalle et al.
(1996) etc. for their consideration of asymmetric reference price effects which is the closest related work.
2
See Jeuland and Shugan (1983); Moorthy (1988); Choi (1991); Messinger and Narasimhan (1995); Ingene and Parry
(1995); Bergen et al. (1996) etc.
3
For the literature on these costs, see Mankiw, 1985; Ball and Mankiw, 1994, 1995; Danziger, 1987; Levy et al., 1997;
Basu, 1995; Blinder et al., 1998; Dutta et al., 1999; Slade, 1998; Zbaracki et al., 2004 etc.
4
(1994) combine costs of price adjustment with inflation to offer an explanation of asymmetric
pricing. There are also authors who combine channels of distribution and costs of price adjustment.
For example, Basu (1995) has addressed both price adjustment costs and channels of distribution in
his work on stages of processing, although he focuses on the implications for price rigidity rather
than any asymmetry issues in his paper. And Madsen and Yang (1998) look at differences in price
elasticities in channels of distribution with costs of price adjustment to offer an explanation for
asymmetric pricing. We develop this literature to increase our understanding of the implications of
costly price adjustment on prices throughout the channel of distribution, and asymmetry.
We suggest that retail costs of price adjustment may result in asymmetric pricing by
manufacturers. If retailers face costs of price adjustment, they will not adjust retail prices for small
changes in wholesale prices. This changes the demand curve faced by the manufacturers. In
essence, they then see a region of inelastic demand where small wholesale price changes do not
translate into commensurate retail price changes. The implication is asymmetric for manufacturers –
it will make small wholesale price increases more profitable because they will not lose customers
from higher retail prices. Yet, they will find it less profitable to make small wholesale price
decreases, because these will not translate into lower retail prices, and therefore no extra revenue
will be generated by these wholesale price cuts.
For larger wholesale price changes however, retail prices move readily because the cost of
changing prices is compensated by increases in retailers’ revenue. As a result, wholesale prices
adjust symmetrically to large changes. To formalize this idea we present an economic model with
costly price adjustment in a distribution channel where members have rational expectations because
they are forward looking and therefore behave with foresight. Using the model we derive testable
predictions about patterns of wholesale price adjustment.
5
In order to test this theory we need data on upstream prices in a channel where we believe
price adjustment is costly for the retailer. A natural place to look is in the grocery industry, where
these costs have been shown to exist (Levy et. al. 1997, 1998; Dutta et. al.1999). Specifically, we
use the Dominick's scanner data set because it has a measure of upstream prices that the retailer paid
for its products (wholesale prices), and because the existence of retail costs of price adjustment in
this industry has been documented in the earlier studies. The data consist of up to 400 weekly
observations of this measure of wholesale prices in 29 different product categories, covering the
period of about eight years between 1989 and 1997.
We conduct the analysis for each of the 29 categories and find almost uniform support for our
theoretical propositions – asymmetry in the small, but symmetry in larger wholesale price changes.
In order to check if our results are due to inflation, we redo each category level analysis, first for
non-inflationary, and then for deflationary periods in the dataset. In both cases we find our results to
be robust across the categories considered. Yet, one limitation of the wholesale data in the
Dominick’s dataset is that the reported numbers are not actual wholesale prices but weighted
averages of the inventory. Therefore, we also check if the results could be an artifact of the manner
in which wholesale prices have been calculated, and conclude that this cannot explain our results.
In the rest of the paper, we first present the model, followed by an account of the data,
analysis and the results. We then discuss the theoretical and managerial implications for the
literatures spanning asymmetric pricing, distribution channels and costs of price adjustment. The
implications for public policy are discussed next. We finish the paper by highlighting the principal
conclusions, important limitations and opportunities for future research.
6
2. Theoretical Model
In this section we offer a theory where asymmetric pricing at wholesale level is driven by the
presence of downstream costs of price adjustment. Thus, at a minimum, we need to consider a 2level distribution channel, with pricing decisions for each member, and downstream costs of price
adjustment.
Specifically, we model a channel with one manufacturer selling through one retailer to end
customers. The customer demand is a continuously differentiable function, decreasing in p: D(p), in
each period. For feasibility, we assume the demand function is such that there is at least one price
above cost at which demand is positive. We let the manufacturer set the wholesale price wi and
retailer set the retail price pi in each period i. Both manufacturer and retailer choose prices to
maximize their profits. To explore price adjustment from one period to the other, we need to
consider at least two periods. We denote the initial pricing period as t0, where channel members set
the initial price of the product. The second, or the “adjustment period” is denoted t1. In the
adjustment period firms will decide whether, and how much, to adjust prices given the costs of price
adjustment and any changes in market conditions.
We assume the retailers must bear a fixed cost x whenever they change retail prices. Thus, in
period t1, if the retailer decides to change prices from those they set in the initial period t0, they must
incur a cost of x. If the retailer chooses not to adjust prices in period t1, then they do not have to bear
this cost.
The manufacturers are also assumed to have a fixed cost y whenever they change wholesale
prices. They can avoid this cost in period t1 by not changing their t0 period prices. 4
4
In the analysis we consider a case with y=0 for expositional simplicity. The general case with y›0 is dealt with in the
appendix.
7
The impetus for price changes comes from changing market conditions. We focus on changes
in manufacturers’ costs as a proxy for such an impetus. 5 More specifically, the manufacturer faces a
unit production cost c in the initial period t0, and this cost changes by an amount Δc in the
adjustment period t1. We assume Δc is a single-peaked symmetric distribution with mean zero. 6
In terms of how the channel prices are set in each period we will assume a Stackelberg game
with the manufacturers as price leaders, i.e. they set wholesale prices anticipating the retailers’
reactions to these prices. The retailers then take the wholesale prices as given and set retail prices.
In setting these prices across periods, we let both the retailer and manufacturer act with foresight,
i.e. in period t0 both consider the pricing actions they will take in t1.
In this setup asymmetric pricing occurs when the likelihood of positive price adjustments are
systematically greater than those of negative ones given similar changes in market conditions. For
example, given Δc≠0 of a given magnitude, asymmetric pricing is exhibited if the likelihood of
prices rising following Δc>0 is greater than the likelihood of prices falling following Δc<0.
Asymmetry is also exhibited if the magnitude of the positive price adjustment is greater than the
magnitude of the negative adjustment. For Δc=0, asymmetric pricing would be exhibited if the
likelihood of prices rising is greater than the likelihood of prices falling or remaining the same.
In the following paragraphs we first set up the general problem. We then explore a model of
this channel without any costs of price adjustment to illustrate that asymmetric pricing is not a result
of the vertical separation in a channel setting, per se. Subsequently, we investigate this model with
only retail costs of price adjustment (x). This illustrates that by itself, costly price adjustment leads
5
There are many other ways market conditions can change. These include changing demand, entry or exit of
competitors, change in the macro-economy (inflation or recession), change in government regulation (price or produce
control), as well as acts of God (unseasonal weather patterns) etc. The spirit of these results would remain unchanged,
regardless of the specific situation.
6
Note that if there are inflationary trends, the expected value of Δc would be non-zero. So, our results are essentially
derived for a zero inflation scenario.
8
to price rigidity but not asymmetry. However, this also allows us to illustrate how these downstream
costs of adjustment, lead to upstream asymmetry in wholesale prices during the adjustment period.
In the appendix we explore the general model with the manufacturer costs of adjustment (y) to
investigate its effects on our results.
2.1 General case of channel with costs of price adjustment
The retail profit functions in the initial period t0 and in the adjustment period t1 are
respectively:
Πr0=Max(p0): {(p0 - w0) D(p0)}
Πr1=Max(p1,δ): {(p1 – w1) D(p1)-δx} where δ=1 if p1≠p0, otherwise 0
(1)
Similarly, the manufacturer profit functions are respectively:
Πm0=Max(w0): {(w0- c) D(p0)}
Πm1=Max(w1,δ): {(w1- c - Δc) D(p1)-δy} where δ=1 if w1≠w0, otherwise 0.
(2)
where, wi and pi are the wholesale and retail prices in period i and Πmi, Πri being the corresponding
profits.
Both the manufacturer and retailer maximize total profits over the two periods. We assume
that the feasibility conditions of profit maximization are satisfied, i.e. positive profit maximizing
prices are feasible and that demand is positive at such prices.
The retailer and the manufacturer must take their expected t1 period solutions into account, in
solving for their initial (t0) period prices. These t0 prices are then considered when solving for the
adjustment (t1) period prices. Our solution process therefore, is to proceed backward by first solving
for the t1 period prices w1 and p1, given the t0 prices p0 and w0. We then derive the equilibrium t0
prices using the t1 period solutions. The equilibrium t1 prices can then be obtained by substituting
these t0 solutions.
9
Additionally, in each period, we solve for the prices in a Stackelberg fashion where the
manufacturer takes into account the retail reaction function p(w) in setting its wholesale price. For
example, the t0 period solutions are derived in two stages.
First, the retail reaction function p0(w0) is obtained from: 7
Max(p0; p1e): {(p0 – w0) D(p0)}+{(p1e – w1e) D(p1e)}
(3)
where, p1e=p0+Δpe and w1e=w0+Δwe, the superscript “e” denoting the prices expected by the retailer
in the adjustment period. Next, this is substituted into the manufacturer problem to solve:
Max(w0; w1e): {(w0– c) D(p0(w0)}+{(w1e– c –E(Δc)) D(p1e)}
(4)
where, E(Δc) is the expectation of Δc based on the distributional assumptions made earlier.
Having set up the general problem, we now consider below the implications for asymmetric
pricing.
2.2 Channel pricing without costs of price adjustment
We begin by exploring the pricing decisions of channel members when there are no costs of
price adjustment (x=0, y=0).
Adjustment Period t1
With no costs of price adjustment in t1, from (1), δ is not a factor in the retail problem. Hence
the initial period price has no affect on the adjustment period solutions and we can directly solve for
the equilibrium adjustment period prices. The retailer sets p to maximize (p-w1)D(p), which gives
the retailer’s price reaction function p1(w1) that solves:
p1 ( w1 ) = p ( w1 ) s.t. p =
∂ log D
w1
where ε r1 = ε r1 ( w1 ) = −
∂ log p
1 − 1 ε r1
(5)
7
We do not include a discount factor for the second period profits. Such a factor does not affect our central results but
makes the notations more complex.
10
Similarly, from (2), the manufacturer sets w to maximize {(w-(c+Δc)) D(p1(w))}. This gives
the wholesale price w1* which solves: 8
w=
∂ log D
c + Δc
, where ε m1= ε m1 ( p1 ( w)) = −
∂ log w
1 − 1 ε m1
(6)
The equilibrium retail price p1* is then given by: p1* = p1(w1*).
From (5) and (6), in equilibrium,
w1* =
c + Δc
c + Δc
and p1* =
*
(1 − 1 ε m1 )
(1 − 1 ε r*1 )(1 − 1 ε m* 1 )
(7)
Initial Period t0
In the initial period, since there are no costs of price adjustment, neither the manufacturer nor
retailer needs to take into account the impact of initial pricing decisions on later adjustment period
actions. The maximization problems therefore become identical to that of the adjustment period
except that costs will be c+E(Δc) rather than c+Δc. By our distributional assumption of Δc,
E(Δc)=0. Hence the equilibrium solutions with the appropriate notations are:
w0* =
c
c
and p 0* =
*
*
(1 − 1 ε m 0 )
(1 − 1 ε r 0 )(1 − 1 ε m* 0 )
(8)
Notice from (7) that both w1* and p1* exhibit symmetric pricing pattern – both negative and
positive cost changes of similar magnitudes elicits the same magnitude of wholesale and retail price
changes. Hence, the channel per se does not lead to any asymmetric price adjustment.
2.3 Channel pricing with Downstream Costs of Price Adjustment
Consider now the case, when we allow for downstream costs of price adjustment, x in the
earlier set up. In the context of the vertical separation of a distribution channel, these costs lead to
asymmetric adjustment of prices. For ease of exposition, we keep y=0 in the following discussion.
8
Subsequently, the superscript “*” will be used to denote equilibrium solutions.
11
When x>0, the price adjustment decision of the retailer changes. In the adjustment period t1, the
retailer will not change prices unless market forces change sufficiently to make such price
adjustment worthwhile.
Adjustment Period t1
The retailer’s objective function in t1, given the initial pricing decision p0 is:
Πr1=Max(p,δ): {(p – w1) D(p)-δx } where δ=1 if p1≠p0, otherwise 0
(9)
Here it incurs a cost x when it changes price (δ=1) from the t0 period price p0. When it does
not change price (δ=0), it does not incur this cost.
The solutions are obtained first by solving for δ=1 and then for δ=0. In the first case, x is a
fixed exogenous parameter, and does not affect the first order conditions. So the retailer’s desired
price in the adjustment period is the same as previously solved in (7). The retailer’s solution is a
price reaction function p1(w1) that solves:
p1 ( w 1 ) = p ( w 1 ) s.t. p =
∂ log D
w1
, where ε r1 = ε r1 ( w 1 ) = −
∂ log p
1 − 1 ε r1
(10)
Now, the retailer will implement a new price (δ=1) only if by doing so it is going to be better
off than by staying at p0. Therefore, it will not change price (δ=0) if: (p1(w1)-w1)D(p1(w1))–x≤(p0w1)D(p0). The retailer’s solution therefore is:
⎧ p ( w ) if Γ( p1 ( w1 ), p0 , x)
p1 ( w1 ) = ⎨ 1 1
otherwise
⎩ p0
(11)
where, Γ(p1(w1),p0,x) denotes that the following condition is satisfied:
{ΠR(p1(w1))–x > ΠR(p0)}, with ΠR(p) = (p–w)D(p).
ΓC(•) therefore denotes complementary condition: {ΠR(p1(w1))–x ≤ ΠR(p0)}
(12)
12
To solve the manufacturer problem, recall from (7) that if the retailer reacts to the
manufacturer’s price change, the optimal wholesale price will be w1 =
c + Δc
. But the existence
(1 − 1 ε m1 )
of downstream costs of price adjustment creates a region defined by ΓC(•) above, where the retailer
does not change its own price. Hence demand would be inelastic to any wholesale price change in
that region and the manufacturer will not find it optimal to price as in (7). For wholesale price
changes where Γ(•) is satisfied however, the retailer will change its price and the manufacturer will
find it optimal to price as in (7). Taking this into account the manufacturer’s wholesale pricing
decision in the adjustment period is:
⎧w = Argmax w (( w − (c + Δc)) D( p1 ( w)) if Γ( p1 ( w1 ), p0 , x)
w1 = ⎨ 1
otherwise
⎩w11 = Argmax w (( w − (c + Δc)) D( p0 )
(13)
Since δ≠0, from (9), the t1 period solutions are a function of the t0 period prices. We therefore
first solve for the t1 prices given the t0 prices p0 and w0. Subsequently, the t0 solutions p0* and w0*
are derived by incorporating the t1 results. These are substituted back, to get the final t1 solutions p1*
and w1*. In the following we discuss these price adjustment decisions.
Retailer price adjustment decision – Rigidity, but not Asymmetry
Equation (11) implies that there exists a region of small wholesale price changes around zero
where retail prices are rigid. To see this, consider the retail solution in (11). Substituting w0* and p0*,
the ΓC(p1(w1),p0,x) condition can be written as {ΠR(p1(w1))–x ≤ ΠR(p0*)} or (p1(w1)-w1)D(p1(w1))x≤(p0*-w1)D(p0*). Substituting w1=w0*+Δw and rearranging: (p1(w1)-w0*)D1-(p0*-w0*)D0+(D0-D1)Δw
-x≤0, where D0=D(p0*) and D1=D(p1(w1)).
13
Now, let K=(p1(w1)-w0*)D1-(p0*-w0*)D0. It must be the case that K<0. This is because p0*
being the profit maximizing price; the profit (p0*-w0*)D0 must be greater than profit determined by
any other retail price. Therefore, rewrite the ΓC(•) condition as: -|K|+(D0-D1)Δw -x≤0
For Δw=0: the condition is identically satisfied.
For Δw>0: by assumptions of a well behaved profit function, p1(w1)>p0*. Consequently,
D0>D1, since the demand function is downward sloping. We can then rewrite the ΓC(•) condition as:
-|K|+|(D0-D1)|Δw -x≤0. Clearly therefore, there exists a Δwr =
| K | +x
> 0 such that the ΓC(•)
| D0 − D1 |
condition is satisfied only if Δw≤Δwr.
For Δw<0: by similar logic as above, p1(w1)<p0* and consequently, D0<D1. The ΓC(•)
condition can then be rewritten as: -|K|-|(D0-D1)|Δw -x≤0. Therefore, there exists a
Δwr = −
| K | +x
< 0 such that the ΓC(•) condition is satisfied only if Δw≥Δwr.
| D0 − D1 |
Taken together, the ΓC(•) condition implies a region of small wholesale price changes where
the retailer does not change its price. This is given by -|Δwr|≤Δw≤|Δwr| where,
Δwr =
| ( p1 ( w1 ) − w0* ) D( p1 ( w1 )) − ( p0* − w0* ) D( p0* ) | + x
| D ( p0* ) − D( p1 ( w1 )) |
Since the retail reaction function is of the form p1 (Δw) =
(14)
w0* + Δw
, this region of price rigidity
1 − 1 ε r1
still does not suggest asymmetry. In fact, when |Δw|>|Δwr|, the retail price adjustment is symmetric
in that both negative and positive Δw will elicit matching positive and negative retail price
adjustments. If we abstract away from the channel and look at the price adjustment decisions of the
retailer as an individual economic agent, we are led to conclude that while it leads to price rigidity,
14
price adjustment cost per se does not lead to asymmetric pricing. This is a standard result in the
costs of adjustment literature (cf. Carlton, 1986; Danziger, 1987; Kashyap, 1995 etc.).
Manufacturer decision – Asymmetry
When the retail solutions are folded back into the manufacturer problem, the region of retail
rigidity can now be obtained as -|Δwr*|≤Δw*≤|Δwr*| where,
Δwr* =
| ( p1* − w0* ) D( p1* ) − ( p0* − w0* ) D( p0* ) | + x
| D( p0* ) − D( p1* ) |
(15)
Substituting this, the manufacturer solution is:
⎧w* if | Δw* |>| Δwr* |, where w1* = w*0 + Δw*
w1 = ⎨ 1*
*
*
*
*
⎩w11 if | Δw |≤| Δwr |, where w11 = Argmax w ( w − c − Δc) D( p0 )
(16)
Notice in solving for w11* that demand D(p0*) is unaffected by changes in wholesale costs.
Consequently, the maximization problem reduces to one of maximizing w, which gives
w11*=w0*+|Δwr*| as the solution.
Consider now the nature of the region defined by |Δw*|≤|Δwr*|. First, note that Δw* is the
wholesale price adjustment that the manufacturer would make in the absence of any retail costs of
price adjustment. Now, if Δc=0, we have Δw*=0 and therefore, w1*=w0*. Therefore,
since w1* =
c + Δc
Δc
, we can write Δw* =
. Since (1-1/εm1*)>0, |Δw*|≤|Δwr*| can now be
*
*
(1 − 1 ε m1 )
(1 − 1 ε m1 )
rewritten in terms of Δc as:
-|Δcr|≤Δc ≤|Δcr| where |Δcr|=|Δwr*|(1-1/εm1*)
(17)
Substituting this, the manufacturer solutions can now be expressed as:
⎧ c + Δc
if | Δc |>| Δcr |
⎪
w1 = ⎨ (1 − 1 ε m* 1 )
⎪⎩w0* + | Δwr* | if − | Δcr |≤ Δc ≤| Δcr |
(18)
15
Consider the implication of the above solution for wholesale prices. For changes in costs that
are large, whether positive or negative – i.e. when |Δc|>|Δcr|, we have symmetric adjustment because
wholesale price changes by commensurate amounts in either directions.
However, for changes in costs that are small, i.e. in the range -|Δcr|≤Δc≤|Δcr|, we have
asymmetric adjustment. The asymmetry can be seen from the following: when the cost change is
non-negative (0≤Δc≤Δcr), the wholesale price goes up by the amount |Δwr*| but when the cost
change is negative (-Δcr≤Δc<0), not only does the wholesale price not come down, but it actually
increases by the same magnitude. To relate it back to our earlier definitions of asymmetry – given
identical magnitudes of small positive and negative cost changes in the range -|Δcr|≤Δc≤|Δcr|, the
likelihood of prices rising following Δc≥0 is greater than the likelihood of prices falling following
Δc<0.
The asymmetry above is driven by the retail costs of price adjustment, x and the concomitant
retail rigidity. If the manufacturer knows that the retailer’s price adjustment is costly, it will have an
incentive to raise wholesale prices, and a disincentive to lower them, in the region of rigidity for the
retailers. The incentives these retail costs of price adjustment create for asymmetric pricing by
manufacturers is the heart of our argument in this paper.
Initial Period t0
In the initial period the retailer’s solution would take into account the expected wholesale
prices in the next period, w1e=w0+Δwe. In equilibrium, w1e=w0*+|Δwr*|. The retailer changes price in
t1 only if |Δw|>|Δwr*|, otherwise its price remains unchanged. Hence, the retailer solves for the price
that will maximize profits over the two periods t0 and t1 as per the following:
Πr= Maxp{(p-w0*) D(p(w)) + (p-w0*-|Δwr*|) D(p(w))}
(19)
The solution gives p0* which gives:
16
*
p0 =
2 w0* + Δwr*
(
2 1−1 ε
*
r0
)
, where ε r*0 = ε 0 ( p 0* ) = −
∂ log D
∂ log p
(20)
The forward looking retailer therefore compensates for its cost of adjustment by charging
(
Δwr*
2 1 − 1 ε r*0
)
more in the initial period than what it would charge if it did not have any such costs.
To derive the manufacturer price w0*, we fold the retail solution into the manufacturer
problem. Now, the manufacturer’s wholesale prices change in both directions in t1 only for large
enough cost changes (|Δc|>|Δcr|). For smaller cost changes however, wholesale prices change only
upwards, by |Δwr*|. In fact, this is true even if there is no change in costs. Since E(Δc)=0, in
equilibrium, the manufacturer solution must incorporate this upwards adjustment in t1.
To set w0* therefore, the manufacturer maximizes over the two periods as:
Πm= Maxw{(w-c) D(p0(w)) + (w+|Δwr*|-c) D(p0(w))}
(21)
The solution gives,
*
w0 =
2c − Δwr*
2(1 − 1 ε
*
m0
)
, where ε m* 0 = ε 0 ( p 0* ( w0* )) = −
∂ log D
∂ log w
Notice that the t0 prices of the manufacturer are
(22)
(
Δwr*
2 1 − 1 ε m* 0
)
less than the price that would be
if there were no costs of price changes in the channel.
To summarize, the equilibrium channel prices are:
⎧⎛
c + Δc
c + Δc ⎞
⎟ if | Δc |>| Δcr |
,
⎪⎜⎜
*
*
( p1 , w1 ) = ⎨⎝ (1 − 1 ε r1 )(1 − 1 ε m1 ) (1 − 1 ε m* 1 ) ⎟⎠
⎪( p * , w* + | Δw* |)
if − | Δcr |≤ Δc ≤| Δc r |
r
⎩ 0 0
17
(
)
⎛ 2c − Δwr* 1 ε m* 0
2c − Δwr*
⎜
(p ,w ) =
,
⎜ 2 1 − 1 ε r*0 1 − 1 ε m* 0 2 1 − 1 ε m* 0
⎝
*
0
*
0
(
)(
) (
)
⎞
⎟
⎟
⎠
(23)
In the adjustment period, for retail prices, the solutions imply symmetric adjustment for large
cost changes (|Δc|>|Δcr|), but rigidity when cost changes are small enough (-|Δcr|≤Δc≤|Δcr|). For
wholesale prices however, the implications are different. While, for large cost changes, the
adjustments are symmetric, for small changes we now have asymmetry. Retailers take this into
account in setting their initial prices and manufacturers take retailers into account in setting the
initial wholesale price as well. Thus we have rational expectations for all channel participants.
The above discussions lead to the following research proposition:
Proposition 1: There is a range of cost changes for which the manufacturer will
adjust its wholesale prices asymmetrically. In particular, the manufacturer
will only adjust its prices upwards regardless of the direction of cost changes,
in a region of cost changes of small magnitudes: -|Δcr|≤Δc≤|Δcr|. For cost
changes of larger magnitudes, the wholesale prices will adjust symmetrically.
We address the consequences of upstream costs of price adjustment, y in the Appendix. These
costs imply regions of wholesale price rigidity, but not asymmetry. Our main results are robust to
reasonable specifications of y. More specifically, when y is small relative to x (y‹‹x) and does not
cause wholesale prices to remain unchanged, the asymmetry results are identical.
3. Empirical Validation
Our general empirical approach is to test the main implications of the model using upstream
price data. Typically however, upstream data are difficult to get. Therefore, we first choose a
context that broadly satisfies some of the key assumptions of the model and then use the available
scanner data that also has upstream prices. Specifically, we use scanner data from a large Midwestern supermarket chain.
18
3a. Implications of the Model
Our theory predicts that for small cost changes (indirectly observed by small wholesale
changes) wholesale prices are more likely to change in the positive direction than in the negative,
but for large cost changes (indirectly observed by large wholesale changes) wholesale prices should
not exhibit any such systematic pattern. It follows, therefore, that positive wholesale price changes
are more likely than negative wholesale price changes when the magnitude of change is small but
they are equally likely when the magnitude of change is large. In other words, wholesale prices will
exhibit asymmetry in the small but not in the large.
Moreover, recall that our results were derived in the absence of inflationary trends. Therefore,
this pattern should be independent of inflation. In other words, we expect that the pattern of
asymmetry in the small will be observed in non-inflationary periods as well. 9 The availability of
data that cover a long time span enables us to examine this implication by separating the data into
inflation-period, low-inflation-period, and deflation-period sub-samples.
3b. Data
To examine the empirical validity of the model’s implications, we use data from Dominick’s
Finer Food (DFF), which is one of the largest retail supermarket chains in the larger Chicago
metropolitan area, operating 94 stores with a market share of about 25 percent. Large multi-store
U.S. Supermarket chains of this type made up about $310,146,666,000 in total annual sales in 1992,
which was 86.3% of total retail grocery sales (Supermarket Business, 1993). In 1999 the retail
grocery sales has reached $435 billion. Thus the chain we study is a representative of a major class
of the retail grocery trade. Moreover, Dominick’s type multi-store supermarket chains’ sales
9
Note that we abstain from defining what might constitute a “small” price change because its precise magnitude will
vary with the size of the price adjustment cost as well as with various demand factors. Instead, we focus on what it
implies in terms of the observable behavior of the wholesale price by letting the data tell us what may constitute a
“small” price change. See the discussion in the results’ section below.
19
constitute about 14 percent of the total retail sales of about $2,250 billion in the US. Since retail
sales account for about 9.3 percent of the GDP, our data set is a representative of as much as 1.28
percent of the GDP, which seems substantial. Thus the market we are studying has a quantitative
economic significance as well.
The data consist of up to 400 weekly observations of wholesale prices covering the period
from September 14, 1989 to May 8, 1997. 10 The length of individual product’s price time series,
however, varies depending on when the data collection for the specific category began and ended.
Note that Dominick’s UPC-level database does not include all products the chain sells. The
database includes 29 different product categories, representing approximately 30 percent of
Dominick’s revenues (see Table 4). 11
Dominick’s sets its prices on a chain-wide basis at the corporate headquarters, but there may
still be some price variation across the chain’s stores depending on the competitive market structure
in and around the location of the individual stores (Levy, et al., 2002, Dutta et al., 2002). According
to Barsky et al. (2003), Dominick’s in general maintains three price zones depending on the local
market conditions. For example, if a particular store of the chain is located in the vicinity of a Cub
Food store, then the store may be designated a “Cub-fighter” and as such, it may pursue a more
aggressive pricing policy in comparison to the stores located in other zones. In the analysis
described below we have used all the data available from all stores.
The wholesale price data we have is not direct. Rather, they are calculated indirectly, from the
retail prices reported in the chain’s scanner database, which are the actual retail transaction prices
(i.e., the price customers paid at the cash register each week), and the profit margin the supermarket
makes on each product. Thus, the wholesale price series we use are calculated according to the
10
The wholesale prices here are the Average Acquisition Costs (AAC) – see a later section for a discussion.
Note that the data for Beer and Cigarette categories may be problematic. Unlike the others, they are subject to various
kinds of tax rules and government regulations such as restrictions on sales and promotional practices. We nevertheless
present the results for all 29 categories for the sake of completeness.
11
20
formula Pw = (1 – m) Pr, where Pw denotes the wholesale price, m denotes the gross margin
measured as a percentage of the retail price, and Pr denotes the retail price. 12
3c. Relevance of the Empirical Context
Before discussing the data analysis results, let us briefly consider the similarity of the data we
are studying – wholesale price data, and their source – a large retail supermarket chain, to the
environment envisioned by the model described in the theoretical section of the paper. In particular
we want to assess the empirical validity of some of the assumptions on which the model is based.
The first assumption of the model is that the retailer faces costs of price adjustment. How
valid is this assumption? In a recent series of papers, a group of scholars from marketing,
economics, and organizational behavior, study price change process and its cost at five large US
supermarket chains each operating between 100 to over 1,000 stores, and demonstrate “…that
changing prices in these establishments is a complex process, requiring dozens of steps, and nontrivial amount of resources” (Levy, et al., 1997, p. 791). They provide direct measures of these
costs, finding that they lead to over $100,000 per store annually (over 35 percent of the net margin)
at major grocery chains like the one examined in this study.13 Slade (1998) also estimates these
costs to be as high as $2.72 per price change in grocery store chains of similar characteristics. Thus,
it has been documented in these studies that retail supermarket chains not only face costs of price
adjustment, but that the costs are quite substantial.
A second assumption concerns the relative magnitudes of the manufacturer and retailer costs
of price adjustment (y<<x). Although manufacturers also face costs of price adjustment, they may
not be as substantial in this industry because of the Robinson-Patman act. This requires that all
12
The dataset reports the variable “profit” which is defined as “the gross margin in percent that DFF makes on the sale
of the UPC.” See Peltzman (2000) page 501 for a discussion.
13
The follow-up studies by Levy, et al. (1998), Dutta, et al. (1999), and Zbaracki, et al. (2002), which explore other
retail and wholesale settings, further confirm and reinforce the original findings. See also Blinder, et al. (1998).
21
retailers have access to the same terms and conditions for goods of like grade and quality. Branded
consumer packaged goods are often of like grade and quality in this industry (for consumer and
logistical reasons). As such, much of the manufacturer pricing is setting the schedule that all
retailers have access to. Although this may require a large amount of resources in aggregate, the
costs for any particular retailer would be minimal. 14
Our third assumption is about the fixed nature of the costs of price adjustment. In this regard
we have followed the existing theoretical studies of costly price adjustment models, which typically
treat the costs as fixed. 15 But more importantly, the studies by Levy, et al. (1997, 1998), Dutta, et al.
(1999) and Slade (1998) find that the price adjustment costs the supermarkets face are indeed
fixed. 16 In fact, Slade (1998) estimates that the magnitude of the fixed component of theses costs
exceed that of any variable component by a magnitude of about fifteen times. According to Levy et
al. (1997), the major steps required to change shelf prices include: tag change preparation, tag
change itself, tag change verification, and resolution of price mistakes at the store, zone or corporate
level (pp. 798-799; also see their Figure 1). Therefore, many of the cost components, such as the
labor time spent during the price tag change process, the cost of printing and delivering new price
tags, and the cost of the in-store supervision time, do not change with the size of price change.
Thus, our assumption that price adjustment costs the supermarkets face are fixed (as opposed to
convex), is consistent with the existing evidence on the nature of such costs in the retail
supermarket setting. 17
14
See Levy et al. (1997) for a discussion of the impact of centralized pricing to reduce the costs of price adjustment.
See, for example, Mankiw (1985) and Danziger (1987).
16
Alternatively, these costs could vary with the size of price change (i.e., the bigger the price change, the larger is its
cost), which is known as “convex price adjustment cost.”
17
However, these costs of price adjustments could be a function of such variables as market share of the products,
whether a brand is a national brand or private label, and whether item pricing law is required in the areas where the
retailer is operating (Levy et. al. 2003). Examining how retailer’s menu cost varies with these variables and its
implications on asymmetric pricing are interesting avenues for future research. We thank an anonymous reviewer for
pointing us in that direction.
15
22
Our fourth assumption is that the manufacturers are aware of the existence of the retail price
adjustment costs. This assumption seems reasonable. The retail price change processes and
procedures are common knowledge amongst the practitioners. For example, dozens of articles have
been published in numerous trade publications covering the supermarket industry on electronic
shelf label systems and how can they reduce the price adjustment costs faced by retail supermarket
chains, especially in states with item pricing laws. Moreover, many manufacturers of direct store
delivery products are themselves engaged in price change management and implementation in these
retail stores. These manufacturers are, therefore, intimately familiar with price adjustment
complexities and their costs.
Finally, we believe the assumption on demand stability is also reasonable. Most of the product
categories included in our data set are mature categories, which have likely reached the limit of their
market growth. Moreover, most of the products in these categories are staple goods, which suggest
that large demand variations, which would be typical to fashion or fad goods, are unlikely. 18
3d. Empirical Findings
Below we analyze the predictions of our theory for the entire data set as well as for each of
the individual categories. In each case, we consider the entire sample period as well as two subsamples. One sub-sample includes only those weeks in which the monthly inflation rate was below
0.1 percent, which we call the low-inflation period sample. The other sub-sample includes only
those weeks in which the monthly inflation rate was zero percent or less, which we call the deflation
period sample. For each sub-sample, we first consider price changes in cents (i.e. in absolute terms
and then in percent (i.e. in relative terms). 19
18
See Cagan (1974), Roll (1984), and Dutta, et al. (2002).
The statistical analysis of these various combinations of sample periods/categories/units of measurement has yielded a
total of 180 tables of 50 rows each (29 categories+1 all categories combined x 3 samples/sub-samples x 2 units of
19
23
Analysis of the Data for the Entire Sample Period
Recall that according to our theory, we expect to see more positive price changes “in the
small.” That is, we expect to see more small price increases than decreases. However, as the
magnitude of the price change gets larger, we expect these differences to disappear.
The question that naturally arises is what we mean by “small?” Because the answer is not
obvious, we have chosen to let the data tell us what may constitute a “small” price change in this
market. To accomplish this, we have calculated the frequency of positive and negative price
changes for each possible size of price change in cents, 1 cent, 2 cents, 3 cents, etc., up to 100 cents,
as well as in percents, 1 percent, 2 percent, 3 percent, etc., up to 100 percent. The results are
displayed in Figures 1–3 and Tables 1–3, corresponding to the entire sample, the low inflation subsample, and the deflation sub-samples, respectively.
In Figure 1 we report the frequency of positive and negative price changes found in the entire
Dominick’s database of wholesale prices, that is, when we use all available wholesale price series
for all products and all 29 categories, during the entire 8-year sample period. Figure 1(a) displays
the frequency of price changes in cents while Figure 1(b) displays the frequency of price changes in
percents.
According to Figure 1a, indeed, for small price changes we find systematically more priceincreases than decreases. The difference appears particularly large for price changes of up to about
30 cents. Beyond that, the difference between the frequency of positive and negative price changes
quickly disappears as the size of price changes increases. In fact, the two series become virtually
indistinguishable beyond that point, at least visually. According to Table 1a, the frequency of price
increases exceeds the frequency of price decreases in statistical terms as well: the higher frequency
measurement = 180). While these tables are too many to be included even in the referee’s appendix, they are available
to interested readers on request.
24
of positive price changes is systematically significant for absolute price changes of up to 36 cents.
Beyond that the two series crisscross each other without any systematic pattern.
A similar pattern is observed when we consider the frequency of price changes in relative
terms, i.e., in percents. For price changes of up to about 8–10 percent, we indeed see more priceincreases than decreases. Beyond that point the two series do not exhibit a clear systematic pattern,
as they crisscross each other. Further, the differences between positive and negative price changes
slowly disappear. According to the figures in Table 1b, the higher frequency of positive price
changes is systematically significant for relative price changes of up to 8 percent. Beyond that the
two series crisscross each other without any systematic pattern. Thus, the results we find in terms of
both absolute as well as relative terms are consistent with the model’s prediction: for small price
changes there are more price increases than decreases. The asymmetry disappears, for larger price
changes.
Next we consider the behavior of the wholesale price data for individual categories. We
looked at the frequency of negative and positive price changes first as a function of the size of price
change in cents, and then in percents. 20
We find that, the frequency of positive price changes exceeds the frequency of negative price
changes “in the small” for all 29 categories displayed. For most categories, the difference appears
particularly strong for price changes of up to 10-15 cents. Beyond that the two time series exhibit a
very similar behavior, often merging with each other. We have conducted formal statistical
significance tests for each of the 29 individual categories, and they confirm our interpretation of the
results: the frequency of positive price changes exceeds the frequency of negative price changes for
all 29 categories included in our sample. According to these tests, for most categories the
20
Only the plots for Toothpastes are given in Figure 5. Due to sheer volume, the rest of the category level plots are
included in the technical appendix available at the Marketing Science website.
25
asymmetry holds for absolute price changes of between 5–20 cents. Table 4 reports these cutoff
points for each category.
Now consider the price change behavior in percents. We find that for all categories considered
(the category of Beer being the only exception), the frequency of positive price changes exceeds the
frequency of negative price changes “in the small.” In most cases, “small” visually appears to mean
about 5–8 percent change. The results of a formal statistical testing of the hypothesis of asymmetry
confirm this conclusion: they indicate that the asymmetry in relative terms holds for price changes
in the range of 2–9 percents with the majority of the categories falling in the range of 5–8 percent.
Table 4 reports these cutoff points for each category. Thus, the analysis of asymmetry in relative
terms reveals a greater homogeneity across the 29 product categories. Overall, we conclude that the
wholesale prices of every product category exhibit asymmetric pricing in the small, in both absolute
and relative terms.
Analysis of the Data for Low Inflation and Deflation Periods
A possible criticism of the findings we have reported so far, however, is the fact that during
the sample period covered in this study, US was experiencing inflation. In Figure 4 we plot the
monthly inflation rate in the US as measured by the Producer Price Index. We use the Producer
Price Index because it is likely to be a better indicator of the wholesalers’ costs than the more
commonly used Consumer Price Index. Given that during the period we study there was inflation in
the US, it is possible that the finding we are documenting is merely a reflection of that fact. That is,
during inflation period, even if prices go up and down, we would expect that ceteris paribus, prices
will go up more often than down.
One possible answer to this criticism, however, is that if the reason for the asymmetry we are
documenting is inflation, then we should see more positive than negative price changes not only “in
26
the small” but also “in the large.” As discussed above, however, the data do not indicate such an
asymmetry.
A direct, and perhaps more methodical, response to the above criticism can be given by
conducting the following analysis. Let us try and see whether the asymmetric pricing we document
“in the small” for the entire sample period, also exists in the data when the observations pertaining
to the inflationary periods are excluded from the analysis. Given our large sample of observations,
such an analysis is possible.
We have conducted two versions of such an analysis. In the first, we included only those
observations during which the monthly Producer Price Index inflation rate did not exceed 0.1
percent, a very low inflation rate by any historical standard. We call this a low/zero inflation
sample. In the second version, we took an even more conservative stand by including in the analysis
only these observations in which the monthly inflation rate was zero or negative. We call this a
deflation period sample.
In Figures 2a and 2b we report the frequency of positive and negative price changes found in
the Dominick’s wholesale prices during low/zero inflation periods. In Figures 3a and 3b we report
the frequency of positive and negative price changes during deflation periods. Figures 2a and 3a
display the frequency of price changes in cents, and Figures 2b and 3b in percents. In both low
inflation and deflation periods, our substantive conclusions remain the same – we find significantly
more price increases than decreases for small price changes. For absolute changes, the difference
appears especially big for price changes of up to about 10–15 cents. For percentage changes the
difference appears large for changes up to about 5 percent. Beyond these, the difference in the
frequency of positive and negative price changes quickly disappears as the size of price change
increases.
27
The findings remain unchanged for individual categories as well. The results are very similar
to the findings reported for the entire data set. With the exception of Beer, the frequency of positive
price changes exceeds the frequency of negative price changes “in the small” for all others. Formal
statistical significance tests for each of the 28 categories confirmed that the asymmetry holds for
absolute price changes of between 5- 20 cents, with the difference being particularly strong between
10-15 cents. In terms of percentage changes, the asymmetry holds for price changes of 11 percent or
less, with the majority of the categories falling in the range of 5–8 percent. Beyond these the two
time series exhibit a very similar behavior, often merging with each other, in both (cents and %)
cases. Thus, the analysis of asymmetry in relative terms again reveals a greater homogeneity across
the 29 product categories. Table 4 reports these cutoff points for each category.
Could the Results be an Artifact of How the Wholesale Prices Are Calculated?
Yet another criticism of our results could be that our findings are a direct result of the manner
in which the wholesale prices are calculated. Our wholesale price, as reported in the Dominick’s
database, is based on the average acquisition cost (AAC). The AAC per unit is calculated as
follows:
AAC (t ) =
{Purch(t ) × price(t )} + {EndInventory (t − 1) − sales(t )}× AAC (t − 1)
TotalInventory (t )
where,
Purch(t) = Inventory bought in t;
price(t) = Per unit wholesale price paid in t;
EndInventory(t-1) = Inventory at end of t-1;
Sales(t) = Retail sales at t;
TotalInventory(t) = Total Inventory at t
28
The role of forward buying by retailers
Can it be claimed that our results could be just an artifact of the manner in which AAC is
calculated? Manufacturers often inform the retailer in advance of an impending temporary price
reduction, permitting the retailer to completely deplete its inventory and then “forward-buying” to
overstock at the lower price (Peltzman, 2000). Since new purchases form a large proportion of the
total inventory in this case, the large discount shows up as a commensurately large reduction in
AAC. On the other hand, a retailer buys less when the wholesale price goes up. Consequently, a
wholesale price increase of the same large magnitude as the decrease considered earlier, will
translate into a relatively smaller increase in AAC. Ceteris paribus, it is reasonable to expect that
the observed asymmetry in the small therefore may be driven by such forward buying
phenomenon. 21
In the absence of actual wholesale prices, how do we conduct a direct test to check for the
above effect? Note that the forward buying rationale suggests that if the manner of calculating AAC
was the major driver of the observed asymmetry, it should be more pronounced for products that
are subjected to greater degree of forward buying. For products not subject to major fluctuations in
its purchases driven by promotional prices, we should expect much lesser degree of such systematic
distortion. This leads to the following null proposition which holds true if the manner of computing
AAC was the major driver of our results. 22
Forward Buying Proposition: Products subject to greater degree of forward buying
will exhibit greater asymmetry than products that are subject to lesser degree
of forward buying.
Unfortunately, we do not have direct data on the degree of forward buying. However, several
authors (Hoch and Banerji, 1993; Rao, 1991; Lal, 1990) have suggested that in general, private
21
We thank an anonymous reviewer for alerting us to this potential rival explanation of our results.
This is not to be confused with our theoretical proposition earlier. Here we intend to check if the “null,” (forward
buying is a key driver of the observed asymmetry), can be rejected in favor of the “alternate” (that it is not).
22
29
labels are not promoted as heavily, and hence are likely to be forward-bought less than national
brands. 23 Therefore, a comparison of national brands to private labels provides a natural context to
test the above proposition. In essence, if forward buying is the main driver of our results, the
predicted asymmetry should be stronger for national brands than for private labels. We therefore
undertook two additional analyses to explore whether, and to what extent, can our results be
attributed to the method of computing AAC. In the paragraphs below we discuss the data used for
the test and briefly summarize the findings.
National Brand versus Private Label Data
For the purposes of the test we need data on comparable national brand (NB)-private label
(PL) product pairs. We base our identification of such NB-PL pairs on a recently published study of
Barsky, et al (2003), who use the same Dominick’s data to investigate the size of markups for
nationally branded products sold in the U.S. retail grocery industry. Their measure of markup is
based on a comparison of the prices of matched pairs of NB-PL products. To implement their
strategy, therefore, Barsky, et al. (2003) had to identify the product pairs based on several
comparability criteria, which included, among other attributes, product’s quality, size, packaging,
etc. For quality comparison, they used Hoch and Banerji’s (1993) PL product quality rankings.
After filtering out the product pairs that were not comparable for various reasons (for
example, size differences, quality differences, insufficient number of observations, etc.), Barsky, et
al. (2003) were left with 231 matched NB-PL product pairs of comparable size and quality,
covering 19 product categories. 24 These categories are Analgesics, Bottled Juices, Cereals, Cheeses,
23
Hoch and Banerji (1993) suggest national brands will promote more to reduce private label market share (page 61).
Also see Pauwels and Srinivasan (2004). Rao (1991) presents evidence from three product categories that shows private
labels are promoted less frequently than national brands (Table 1, page 140). Lal (1990) argues based on his theoretical
model that “…(the private label) has a constant retail price – that is, it is never promoted” (page 433) and that “… (the
empirical evidence) do not contradict the second hypothesis that the local/store brand is promoted less often than the
national brands” (page 439).
24
See Barsky, et al. (2003), Tables 7A.1-7A.19 for a detailed list of the NB-PL product pairs.
30
Cookies, Crackers, Canned Soups, Dish Detergent, Frozen Entrees, Frozen Juices, Fabric Softeners,
Grooming Products, Laundry Detergent, Oatmeal, Snack Crackers, Tooth Pastes, Toothbrushes,
Soft Drinks, and Canned Tuna. However, Barsky, et al. (2003) argue that Toothbrushes category is
an outlier for its unusually high markup ratio, in comparison to the remaining 18 categories.
Consequently, they omit the Toothbrushes category from much of their analysis.25 Following their
strategy, therefore, we also exclude the category of Toothbrushes from our analysis, which leaves us
with 18 categories of matched NB-PL pairs for the analyses.
The first analysis compared the aggregate asymmetries between national brands and private
labels. No significant difference was found either in the absolute (cents) or relative (%) asymmetry
thresholds. We also did not find any statistical difference in the degrees of asymmetry, when we
considered the difference between the number of positive and negative changes expressed as a
percentage of the number of positive changes.
The second analysis compared category level asymmetries between national brands and
private labels. Again, we found no evidence to suggest that there is a significant difference between
the two groups either in absolute (cents) or relative (%) terms. 26
Forward-buying is not a key driver of the observed asymmetry in the small
To conclude, it is unlikely that our empirical results are an artifact of the manner in which the
wholesale prices have been calculated. We subject the data to a series of tests to check if there are
patterns consistent with the forward buying hypotheses. None of the analyses, whether descriptive,
or statistical, provide support for these hypotheses.
Such a conclusion must however, be tempered with the knowledge that we are after all
dealing with a derived measure of wholesale prices and a better test of our theory would be with
25
26
See Barsky, et al., 2003, p. 194.
Details of these tests are in a separate technical appendix available at the Marketing Science website.
31
actual wholesale prices. Unfortunately, such data is not available. We are not unique in dealing with
this problem. A number of other authors who have dealt with it bemoan the lack of proper
wholesale price data (cf. Cecchetti, 1986; Peltzman, 2000; Chintagunta, 2002; Levy, et al. 2002;
Chevalier, et al. 2003 etc.). Creative approaches like estimating wholesale prices from regression
which is particularly common in the empirical industrial organization literature (see Carlton and
Perloff, 1994), using aggregate price indexes as a proxy, such as wholesale price index (Cecchetti,
1986), rough accounting estimates (Nevo, 2001), even simulation (Tellis and Zufryden, 1995) are
the norm in such cases. Others may ignore explicit consideration of wholesale prices altogether
(Gerstner et al., 1994; Pesendorfer, 2001).
While the lack of accurate wholesale price data is unfortunate, we believe that should not
hinder theory building in the domain of wholesale prices. Nevertheless, the onus is on the researcher
to ensure that any empirical test of theory using weak wholesale data is actually robust to the
weakness of the data. It is in that spirit that we conducted these additional checks.
To keep things in perspective therefore, it is necessary to understand that while we stand
behind the spirit of our results, we recognize that the verity of the exact magnitudes of the
asymmetry we report is subject to some uncertainty.
Overall, by ruling out inflation and forward buying as potential rival explanations of our
results, we conclude that our theory offers the most consistent explanation of the observed
asymmetry in the small. 27
27
Other authors using this dataset (e.g. Peltzman, 2000) restrict their sample till September 1994 because of a change in
manufacturers’ pricing policies from that point in time. To maintain comparability and to rule out this policy change as
a driver of our results, we conduct an additional analysis by restricting our sample to the pre-September 1994 period.
The details of this test are in the technical appendix available at the Marketing Science website. Our central result
remains unaffected by this change, thereby ruling it out as a central driver of our results. We thank an anonymous
reviewer for suggesting this additional check.
32
4. Discussion
Our primary goal in this paper is to offer and empirically validate a theory of asymmetric
pricing. To this end, we offer a channel based theory of asymmetric pricing – that costs of price
adjustment for downstream channel members can create an incentive for asymmetric pricing by
upstream channel members. We go on to present evidence of asymmetric wholesale pricing “in the
small” with symmetric wholesale pricing “in the large,” which is consistent with this theory. To the
best of our knowledge, no other paper reports such patterns of asymmetries at the wholesale level.
Theoretically, this paper merges two different lines of research – costs of price adjustment in
economics and distribution channels in marketing. By themselves, neither implies asymmetry.
Traditional economic theories based on costs of price adjustment suggest that nominal rigidities are
usually symmetric, with “prices (responding) similarly to positive and negative shocks” (Ball and
Mankiw, 1994; p. 247). Similarly, channels of distribution are often argued to be a source of many
pricing distortions, (e.g. double marginalization – Jeuland and Shugan, 1983; free riding – Bergen
and John, 1997), but not asymmetry. Taken together however, costs of price adjustment and
channels of distribution suggest ranges of asymmetric pricing by the upstream firm.
Since most of the existing research has focused on asymmetric pricing by a single decision
maker (primarily, the retailer), we expand the scope of asymmetry research by explicitly exploring
the implications of the business-to-business linkages in a channel. This builds on a long tradition in
marketing of using the distribution channel to improve our understanding of a variety of marketing
issues beyond the traditional scope of the channels literature. 28 .
By combining a channels perspective with the costs of price adjustment perspective, we
generate predictions and empirical findings that cannot be easily explained by the existing theories
28
Examples include product introduction and design (Rao and McLaughlin, 1989; Villas-Boas, 1998), unbundling
(Wilson et al., 1990), advertising (Bergen and John 1997) etc.
33
of asymmetric pricing. For example, asymmetry that is driven by inflation (Ball and Mankiw, 1994)
cannot account for asymmetry in non-inflationary periods, or deflationary periods that we observe
in our data. Similarly, market power based explanations for wholesale asymmetry suggest that
asymmetric adjustments may be a means to extract monopoly rent from retailers (Benabou and
Gertner, 1993; Borenstein and Shepard, 1996). Yet this does not explain why we observe
asymmetry in small but not in large wholesale price changes. In the same way, the differences in
elasticities and costs across levels of the distribution channel, required to explain asymmetry in
Madsen and Yang (1998), does not explain why asymmetry occurs in the small, but not in the large.
More generally, Peltzman (2000) concludes, “…attributing asymmetries to imperfect competition is
unlikely to be rewarding.”
There are also some promising cross-disciplinary theoretical directions this paper suggests.
We extend the marketing literature on channels of distribution to explicitly considering the costs of
price adjustment and its implications on channels pricing behavior. Traditionally, these costs of
price adjustment have been known as “menu costs” (Ball and Mankiw, 1994) and are associated
primarily with price rigidity. Although we focus on asymmetric pricing issues, there are many other
natural applications for marketers to explore. One direction is how these costs of price adjustment
impact pass-through of manufacturer price changes (cf. Kim and Staelin, 1999; Tyagi, 1999). There
is a literature in economics called "stages of processing" that is related to channels of distribution. It
has considered the extent of pass-through in the context of studying price rigidity/flexibility in
stages of processing, but has not explored price asymmetry. The main focus of these studies has
been on the effect of the number of stages of processing on the degree of price flexibility. For
example, Blanchard (1983) focuses on the role of price adjustment costs on the degree of price
rigidity in markets with a stages of processing structure (which though not identical, quite resembles
the channels structure), and Basu (1995) who studies the role of price adjustment costs in
34
economies with the input-output structure, which is an alternative way of looking at the
organization of production in market economies. See also Gordon (1990).
In expanding the costly price adjustment theory to include channels of distribution, we
explore how the presence of these costs may fundamentally alter the nature of transactions within
the channel, as well. The implications are not just price rigidity, which is a direct effect of these
costs, but asymmetric pricing, which is more strategic in nature. This suggests that this literature
broaden its consideration to look at the impacts of these costs on the incentives and actions of
related parties to transactions.
Empirically, we document systematic evidence of asymmetric pricing that, taken in the
context of previous empirical research, is particularly surprising. Specifically, Peltzman (2000)
studies the same Dominick's dataset and reports finding no systematic evidence of asymmetry. Yet,
our results are actually more complementary than contradictory to Peltzman’s. The key differences
between the papers are the location and size of asymmetry within the distribution channel. While
Peltzman looked downstream, we look for asymmetry in upstream channel prices. This in turn
addresses one of Peltzman’s own conclusions that the “vertical market linkages” of a distribution
channel may be key factors in asymmetric adjustment. Additionally, Peltzman looks for asymmetry
overall, both the large and the small without distinguishing between the two. Our results suggest the
need to consider differences in asymmetry within the magnitude continuum as well.
Finally, our paper has public policy implications. Generally speaking, marketing scholars over
the years have consistently called for greater involvement of marketers in shaping public policy (cf.
Alderson, 1937; Guiltinan and Gundlach, 1996). More specifically, policy implications of pricing
strategies have been a central concern for a number of marketing researchers (Gerstner and Hess,
1990; Wilkie et al., 1998 etc.). Yet, the literature is relatively sparse and in a recent editorial,
Grewal and Compeau (1999) point out that, “…(there is a need for)… marketing researchers to
35
examine the public policy issues raised by the strategic pricing practices firms employ.”
Asymmetric pricing is such a strategy and has not escaped the view of policy makers who worry
about prices that are too quick to rise, but are not clear about the central causes. This is evidenced in
headlines such as: “California politicians ask for price caps on electricity” (CNN.com, May 22,
2001), or in comments such as US Vice President Dick Cheney’s: “We get politicians who want to
go out and blame somebody and allege there is some kind of conspiracy, instead of dealing with the
real issues” (CNN.com, May 22, 2001). Our perspective suggests that there may be asymmetric
pricing upstream in the channel. But this upstream asymmetry may be bounded by the size of the
costs of price adjustment of downstream channel members. Any concern with asymmetric pricing
must therefore factor in the efficiency issues inherent in such costs. For example, asymmetric
pricing is less likely to be a significant concern for channels that invest in reducing such costs.
5. Conclusions
This paper is only another step in our understanding of asymmetric pricing. It does suggest
future theoretical work to explore additional implications of costs of price adjustment on pricing,
contracting and design of channels of distribution. Presently this theory is only applicable in
upstream channel pricing. The logic of asymmetric pricing may be extended to retail pricing
decisions as well. A couple of recent papers (Chen et al. 2004; Müller and Ray, 2003) explore the
implications for retail pricing decisions. We call for more investigations in the same vein. We did
not have access to wholesaler’s cost data. If such data were to become available, future empirical
work could take advantage of it in order to directly assess the implications of this theory. In
addition, future work could explore the cross-category differences (Hoch et al., 1995) in the extent
of asymmetry.
36
On another note recall that we show asymmetric adjustment of wholesale prices is a subgame
perfect equilibrium in a 2-period model. One especially promising area of future theoretical
research would be to explore the implications for the results if we extend the model to longer time
horizons. Such an extension can be done in several ways. If we merely extend the game to n
periods, the results are unlikely to be substantively different from the conclusions we draw from our
simpler model. However, the outcomes are not intuitive in a model with repeated strategic
interactions between manufacturers and retailers. In this context, note that a benefit of having
forward looking retailers in our current model is that – in equilibrium retailers are not disadvantaged
by asymmetric pricing in the small – they adjust their initial pricing decisions to reflect this
economic reality. So it is not clear that a richer space of punishments, relationships or prices would
necessarily be of any improvement to the retailer in this situation. The costs are real, and as such
any solution would have to factor them into the equilibrium. Nevertheless, while we suspect that
asymmetry will still be an equilibrium outcome, more rigorous theoretical efforts are needed before
a definitive answer can be given.
Finally, we hope this paper reinforces the value of bringing scholars in marketing and
economics together to study issues of common interest. This paper brings a marketing perspective
to this dialog by conducting this investigation in the context of a distribution channel and by
considering store-level marketing data. We believe this is the first paper in marketing to incorporate
costs of price adjustment explicitly into their analysis. There are a variety of issues in marketing that
may benefit from a consideration of these costs of price adjustment in the area of pass-through,
promotional pricing, EDLP, etc. It also brings an economic perspective to this dialogue in the work
on asymmetric pricing and costs of price adjustment, areas where marketing researchers are relative
newcomers but may have important insights and evidence to bring to these areas of inquiry. We feel
both disciplines can benefit greatly from these kinds of cross-disciplinary explorations.
37
APPENDIX
A.0 General case of channel with costs of price adjustment
The general set up of the model is given in the main body of the paper. The solution proceeds
by first solving for the t1 prices w1 and p1, given any t0 prices p0 and w0. Subsequently, the t0 results
are obtained by incorporating the t1 solutions. Substituting these back into the t1 period solutions
gives the final results.
Adjustment Period t1
The solutions are obtained first by solving for δ=1 and then for δ=0. In the first case, x is a
fixed exogenous parameter, and does not affect the first order conditions: Hence, Argmaxp {(pw)D(p) –x} = Argmaxp (p-w) D(p). The retailer’s price reaction function p1(w) solves:
p ( w) = p1 ( w) s.t. p =
∂ log D
w
where ε r1 = ε r1 ( w) = −
∂ log p
1 − 1 ε r1
(A-1)
Now, the retailer will implement a new price (δ=1) only if by doing so it is going to be better
off than by staying at p0. It will not change price (δ=0) if: (p1(w)-w)D(p1(w))–x≤(p0-w)D(p0). The
retailer’s solution therefore is:
⎧ p ( w) , if Γ(p1 (w), p 0 , x)
p ( w) = ⎨ 1
otherwise
⎩ p0 ,
(A-2)
where,
Γ(p1(w),p0,x) ≡ [ΠR(p1(w))–x > ΠR(p0)] and ΠR(p) = (p–w)D(p).
The t1 period wholesale prices for the manufacturer is obtained by solving:
Πm1=Max(w1,δ): {(w1- c - Δc) D(p1)-δy}.
(A-3)
The manufacturer incurs a cost y when it changes price (δ=1) from w0. When it does not
38
change price, δ=0.
The manufacturer solutions must also internalize the effects of x. There are three possible
outcomes. The first is, both the manufacturer and the retailer readjust their prices. The second is, the
manufacturer does but the retailer does not readjust. The third is, neither readjusts.29
The wholesale solutions then are expressed as:
⎧w1
⎪
w1 = ⎨w11
⎪w
⎩ 0
if Γ( p1 ( w1 ), p0 , x) and Φ( w1 , w0 , p( w1 ), y )
if Γ C ( p1 ( w11 ), p0 , x) and Φ( w11 , w0 , p ( w11 ), y )
if Φ C ( w11 , w0 , p( w0 ), y )
(A-4)
where, p(w) is the retail reaction function to wholesale prices;
Γ(p1(w),p0,x) ≡ [ΠR(p1(w))–x > ΠR(p0)]; ΓC(•) ≡ [ΠR(p1(w))–x ≤ ΠR(p0)];
Φ(w1,w0,p(w),y) ≡ [ΠM(w1)–y > ΠM(w0)]; ΦC(•) ≡ [ΠM(w1)–y ≤ ΠM(w0)];
ΠR(p) = (p–w)D(p); ΠM(w)=(w–c–Δc)D(p(w));
(A-5)
w1= Argmaxw{(w-(c+Δc))D(p1(w))} s.t. Γ(p1(w1),p0,x) and Φ(w1,w0,p(w1),y);
w11= Argmaxw{(w-(c+Δc))D(p0)} s.t. ΓC(p1(w11),p0,x) and Φ(w11,w0,p(w11),y).
The corresponding retail prices are given by:
⎧p
p1 = ⎨ 1
⎩ p0
if Γ( p1 ( w1 ), p0 , x) and Φ ( w1 , w0 , p( w1 ), y )
otherwise
(A-6)
The Γ and Φ conditions in the first rows of both the manufacturer and retailer solutions can
now be redefined in terms of the cost changes. In particular, using procedures similar to that used
earlier in the main paper, we can show the existence of Δcr and Δcm with properties ∂|Δcr|/∂x>0 and
∂|Δcm|/∂y>0 respectively, such that:
29
The alternative where the retailer readjusts but the manufacturer does not is not feasible in our setup because if the
wholesale prices do not change, retail prices remain unchanged as well.
39
Γ(•) ⇒ |Δc|>|Δcr| and, Φ(•) ⇒ |Δc|>|Δcm|
(A-7)
Initial Period t0
The t1 solutions are then incorporated into the t0 problem to solve for p0* and w0*. First, the
retail reaction function p0(w0) is obtained from:
Max(p0; p1e): {(p0 – w0) D(p0)}+{(p1e – w1e) D(p1e)}
(A-8)
where, p1e=p0+Δpe and w1e=w0+Δwe, the superscript “e” denoting the prices expected by the retailer
in the adjustment period. Next, this is substituted into the manufacturer problem to solve:
Max(w0; w1e): {(w0– c) D(p0(w0)}+{(w1e– c –E(Δc)) D(p1e)}
(A-9)
where, E(Δc) is the expectation of Δc based on the distributional assumptions made earlier.
The solutions p0* and w0* are then substituted back into the t1 solutions to get p1* and w1*.
With this general problem as the background, we will now consider the role of the upstream
costs of price adjustment, y for our results. 30
A.1 Pricing with only upstream costs of price adjustment (y>0, x≈0): Rigidity
We start by exploring the role of y in isolation of any channel effects. For this we set x≈0 and
let y>0. The results show that y by itself only leads to price rigidity but not asymmetry. Adjustment
Period t1
The manufacturer will not implement a new price if it is better off by staying at w0*. Since p0*
remains the profit maximizing retail price if wholesale prices remain at w0*, the condition when the
wholesale does not change can be written as:
{w1* − (c + Δc )}D ( p1 ( w1* )) − y ≤ {w0* − (c + Δc )}D ( p 0* ) .
(A-10)
The equilibrium channel prices can then be expressed as,
30
For ease of exposition and notational economy, we will henceforth derive the t1 period solutions as functions of w0*
and p0* and solve for the functional forms of w0* and p0* later when solving the t0 period problem.
40
⎧( w* , p * ) if Φ ( w1* , w0* , p( w), y )
( w1 , p1 ) = ⎨ 1* 1*
⎩( w0 , p0 ) otherwise
where, w1* solves w =
(A-11)
c + Δc
; p1*=p1(w1*); Φ as defined earlier in (A-5), is given by
1 − 1 ε m1
Φ(w1,w0,p(w),y) ≡ [ΠM(w1)–y > ΠM(w0)] with ΠM(w)=(w–c–Δc)D(p(w)).
Using procedures similar to earlier, it follows from (A-10) and (A-11) that there exists a Δcx0
with the property ∂|Δcx0|/∂y>0 such that prices are unchanged for |Δc|≤|Δcx0|
(A-12)
Hence the primary contribution of price adjustment costs at the manufacturer end in this setup
is price rigidity at both wholesale and retail when cost changes are small enough. For |Δc|>|Δcx0|,
wholesale prices adjust to w1* and retail prices to p1*. Notice that this adjustment pattern is
symmetric in that both negative and positive Δc will elicit matching positive and negative price
adjustments. In fact, if we abstract away from the channel and look at the price adjustment decisions
of an individual economic agent (i.e. when p(w)=w), 31 we are led to conclude that while it leads to
price rigidity, price adjustment cost per se does not lead to asymmetric pricing. This is a standard
result in the costs of adjustment literature (cf. Carlton, 1986; Danziger, 1987; Kashyap, 1995 etc.).
Initial Period t0
Now, note that the rigidity imposed by y creates a potential marginal distortion for the
manufacturer of magnitude |Δcx0|. In this region of small costs changes, there would be no change in
demand as there would be no change in manufacturer prices. In other words, even if costs were to
go up by |Δcx0| (with the commensurate negative effect on profits), the manufacturer will not adjust
its prices in t1. A profit-maximizing manufacturer would incorporate this in its t0 solution. The t0
solution for manufacturer prices therefore, is obtained by setting E(Δc)= |Δcx0|:
31
Essentially, completely ignoring the existence of the retailer in the above case.
41
Max(w): {(w-c) D(p0*) + (w-c-|Δcx0|) D(p0*)}
(A-13)
The solution gives w0* which solves:
w=
2c + Δ c x 0
2(1 − 1 ε m 0 )
, where ε m 0= ε 0 ( p 0 ( w)) = −
∂ log D
∂ log w
(A-14)
This price would remain in effect in t1 unless |Δc|>|Δcx0|, when as per the t1 period solutions,
prices will adjust symmetrically. The manufacturer acting in a forward looking manner, therefore,
compensates for its cost of adjustment by charging
Δc x 0
2(1 − 1 ε m 0 )
more in the initial period than what
it would charge if it did not have any such costs.
A.2 Pricing with both up- and down-stream costs of price adjustment (y>0, x>0)
We now consider the more general case discussed earlier (x>0,y>0). This explores how y may
affect the asymmetry results obtained earlier. The main conclusion is that y implies regions of
wholesale price rigidity, but not asymmetry. We start by considering the different cases dependent
on the relative magnitude of y.
First, for convenience, we present the general solution for period t1 in terms of the ranges of
cost changes:
⎧( w1* , p1* ) if | Δc |>| Δcr | and | Δc |>| Δcm |
⎪
( w1 , p1 ) = ⎨( w11* , p0* ) if | Δc |≤| Δcr | and | Δc |>| Δcm |
⎪( w* , p * ) if | Δc |≤| Δc |
m
⎩ 0 0
(A-15)
1. Large y: Rigidity
Suppose now, y is large (y>>x). In particular, let y be large enough such that |Δcm|≥|Δcr|. 32
Adjustment Period t1
32
Recall that ∂|Δcm|/∂y>0.
42
When |Δcm|≥|Δcr| the condition in the second row of the manufacturer solution is not feasible.
We can then rewrite the equilibrium channel prices in t1 as,
⎧( w* , p * ) if | Δc |>| Δcm |
( w1 , p1 ) = ⎨ 1* 1*
⎩( w0 , p0 ) otherwise
(A-16)
Hence, for large y, the main implication of price adjustment costs is still one of rigidity in
channel prices for small enough cost changes.
Initial Period, t0
w0*
In t0, the retailer solution is simply: p =
.
1 − 1 ε r*0
*
0
The manufacturer solution on the other hand is obtained in a manner similar to the earlier
subsection, by considering Δcm instead of Δcx0:
w0* =
2 c + Δc m
(
2 1−1 ε
*
m0
)
, where ε m* 0 = ε 0 ( p 0* ( w0* )) = −
∂ log D
∂ log w
(A-17)
2. Small y: Asymmetry
Let y be small: y<<x. In particular, let y small enough such that |Δcm|<|Δcr|. In this subsection,
we will first solve the t1 prices and derive the t0 prices for the special cases of different magnitudes
of y discussed subsequently.
The t1 equilibrium prices can be derived from (A-4) and (A-15) which are equivalent. From
(A-15), if |Δcm|<|Δcr|, then |Δc|>|Δcm| is identically satisfied whenever |Δc|>|Δcr| and (w1*,p1*) are the
equilibrium prices. Then, w1* =
c + Δc
is the solution to Maxw{(w-(c+Δc)) D(p1(w))} s.t.
1 − 1 ε m* 1
|Δc|>|Δcr|.
43
From the functional form it is clear that, given small y, for large enough cost changes
(|Δc|>|Δcr|), the wholesale price here is still symmetric with respect to positive and negative
directions of cost changes.
p1* can be obtained from the retail reaction function: p1* =
w1*
.
1 − 1 ε r*1
Now, what happens when the costs changes are small – specifically, |Δc|≤|Δcr|? From (A-15)
w11* is the solution to Maxw{(w-(c+Δc)) D(p0*)}. Using the equivalency between (A-4) and (A-15),
since demand is independent of w, this maximization boils down simply to maximizing w subject to
the conditions ΓC(•) and Φ(•) in (A-4). The ΓC(•) implies: (p1*-w11)D(p1*)–x≤(p0*-w11)D(p0*). Using
procedures similar to that employed earlier, we can express this as
-|Δwr*|≤Δw*≤|Δwr*| where, Δwr* =
| ( p1* − w0* ) D( p1* ) − ( p0* − w0* ) D( p0* ) | + x
| D( p0* ) − D( p1* ) |
(A-18)
Since the maximization exercise involves maximizing the wholesale price, w11*=w0*+|Δwr*| is
the profit maximizing solution. 33 The corresponding Φ condition can therefore be written as
(w0+|Δwr*|-c-Δc)D(p0*)–y>(w0*-c-Δc)D(p0*) or:
|Δwr*| D(p0*)>y
(A-19)
So, as expected, for small cost changes (|Δc|≤|Δcr|), the results predict asymmetry. However,
this asymmetry appears contingent on certain magnitudes of y. So, now let us consider the
implication the magnitude of y has on the final solutions.
Let y*=|Δwr*| D(p0*)
(A-20)
Case A: y>y*
33
w11>w11* is not profit maximizing here. In that case, Δw>Δwr* and the ΓC condition is violated – in other words, the
retail price will change and our maximization exercise will be different, with w1* as the profit maximizing outcome.
44
Adjustment period t1
If y>y* the corresponding Φ condition (A-19) is always violated (|Δc|≤|Δcm|) and manufacturer
prices remain unchanged at w0*. Without any change in wholesale prices, the retail prices also
remain unchanged at p0*.
Hence, when y is large enough, the results predict rigidity for both upstream and downstream
prices.
Initial Period t0
Since |Δcm| represents the marginal distortion due to its costs of price changes, the
manufacturer sets the w0* that maximizes:
Πm= Maxw{(w-c) D(p(w)) + (w-c-|Δcm|) D(p(w))}.
The solution gives: w0* which solves:
w0*=
2 c + Δc m
(
2 1−1 ε
*
m0
)
, where ε m* 0 = ε 0 ( p 0 ( w0* )) = −
∂ log D
∂ log w
(A-21)
As before, the manufacturer, acting in a forward looking manner, therefore, compensates for
its cost of adjustment by charging
(
Δc m
2 1 − 1 ε m* 0
)
more in the initial period than what it would charge
if it did not have any such costs.
p0* is obtained by substituting w0* into the retail reaction function: p 0* =
w0*
.
1 − 1 ε r*1
Case B: 0≤y≤y*
Adjustment Period t1
If y is quite small, in particular, if y≤y*, the Φ condition (A-19) is identically satisfied for all
Δc. When (A-19) is thus satisfied, w11*=w0*+|Δwr*| is the solution.
45
The equilibrium channel prices when 0<y≤y* then are:
⎧( w* , p * )
if | Δc |>| Δcr |
( w1 , p1 ) = ⎨ 1* 1 *
*
⎩( w0 + | Δwr |, p0 ) otherwise
p1* can be derived by substituting w1* in the reaction function: p1* ( w1* ) =
(A-22)
w1*
, which would be
1 − 1 ε r*1
symmetric to any changes in wholesale prices.
Hence, when y is small enough, the results predict asymmetry for upstream prices. This is
very similar to the effect illustrated in the main paper.
Initial Period t0
The initial period solutions are obtained as solved in the main paper. Essentially, the retailer’s
solution would take into account the expected wholesale prices in the next period. This price would
remain in effect unless |Δw|>|Δwr*|. The equilibrium retail price at t0 therefore is obtained from:
Πr= Maxp{(p-w0*) D(p(w)) + (p-w0*-|Δwr*|) D(p(w))}
(A-23)
The solution gives p0*:
*
p0 =
2 w0* + Δwr*
(
2 1−1 ε
*
r0
)
, where ε r*0 = ε 0 ( p 0* ) = −
∂ log D
∂ log p
(A-24)
To derive the manufacturer prices, we fold the retail solution back into the manufacturer
problem. In doing so, we consider the magnitude of the expected cost change and the upward
adjustment of the wholesale prices as discussed earlier in the main body of the paper. To set w0*
therefore, the manufacturer maximizes over the two periods as:
Πm= Maxw{(w-c) D(p0(w)) + (w+|Δwr*|-c) D(p0(w))}
(A-25)
The solution gives,
46
*
w0 =
2c − Δwr*
(
2 1−1 ε
*
m0
)
, where ε m* 0 = ε 0 ( p 0* ( w0* )) = −
∂ log D
∂ log w
(A-26)
These t0 prices remain in effect unless the magnitude of the cost change is large enough
(|Δc|>|Δcr|) to effect a change in channel prices.
Consider now the implications of the solutions for channel prices. For retail prices, we still
predict symmetric adjustment for large cost changes (|Δc|>|Δcr|) but (symmetric) rigidity when cost
changes are small enough (|Δc|≤|Δcr|).
For wholesale prices the results are a function of the magnitude of y. When y is large (y>y*),
we get (symmetric) rigidity for small costs changes (|Δc|≤|Δcr|). When the cost change is large
enough (|Δc|>|Δcr|), we get symmetric adjustment. When y is small (y≤y*) however, we get
asymmetry for small costs changes (|Δc|≤|Δcr|) and symmetric adjustment for large ones (|Δc|>|Δcr|).
The intuition behind the asymmetry results is derived from the impact of the retailer’s costs of
price adjustment, x and the resulting retail price rigidity. This creates a region of wholesale price
changes (both positive and negative) where the demand is inelastic, leading to the asymmetric
adjustment of wholesale prices. The manufacturer costs, y however, does not play any direct role in
this asymmetry. Its primary role in this setup is to determine when the manufacturer will not find it
profitable to change its wholesale prices. Since retail prices only change following wholesale price
changes, this implies that y’s primary contribution is in determining regions of wholesale, and by
corollary, retail price rigidity.
Interestingly, wholesale asymmetry (when wholesale price changes in the adjustment period)
persists even for very small cost changes in spite of the fact that manufacturer costs of price
adjustment y>0. This happens because, in the region of retail rigidity, the manufacturer can
compensate y by the increase in profits that follows asymmetric positive adjustment. However, this
47
is only true for small enough y. For large enough y, this asymmetry will not happen because the
manufacturer cannot compensate y by the increase in profits due to the asymmetric adjustment. If y
is so large that the manufacturer will implement only a large wholesale price change, we may not
see any rigidity at retail because the magnitude of wholesale price change may be larger than the
region of retail rigidity.
It is worthwhile to note that even if wholesale asymmetry is a direct result of retail rigidity, it
does not imply that retailers will be taken advantage of. The fact that forward-looking retailers will
take these costs into account when setting initial and future prices is a standard result in the
economics literature. In our case, the nature of the expected distortions in the adjustment period,
introduced by these costs, is incorporated in the initial period prices.
In conclusion, when y is large (y››x), the main prediction is rigidity in channel prices for small
enough cost changes. However, generally speaking, y‹‹x. 34 In this case, wholesale price changes are
symmetric with respect to large positive and negative cost changes. However, for small cost
changes the results predict asymmetry depending on the magnitude of y. Specifically, when y>y*
where y*=|Δwr*| D(p0*), the results predict rigidity for both upstream and downstream prices.
However, when y≤y* the results predict asymmetry for upstream prices. This is stated in the
following research proposition:
Proposition 1A: When y is small (0<y≤y*), there is a range of cost changes for which
the manufacturer will adjust its wholesale prices asymmetrically. In
particular, the manufacturer will only adjust its prices upwards regardless of
the direction of cost changes, in a region of cost changes of small
magnitudes: -|Δcr|≤Δc≤|Δcr|. For cost changes of larger magnitudes, the
wholesale prices will adjust symmetrically.
34
See the empirical section of the main paper for a discussion.
48
References
Alderson, Wroe (1937); “A Marketing View of Competition;” Journal of Marketing, v.1(3), 189190.
Bacon, Robert W. (1991); “Rockets and Feathers: The Asymmetric Speed of Adjustment of UK
Retail Gasoline Prices to Cost Changes;” Energy Economics, v.13(3), 211-218.
Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw (1994), “A Sticky-Price Manifesto,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, 127–152.
Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw (1995), “Relative Price Changes as Aggregate Supply
Shocks,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Volume 110, No. 1 (February), 161–193.
Barsky, Robert, Mark Bergen, Shantanu Dutta, and Daniel Levy (2003), “What Can the Price Gap
between Branded and Generic Products Tell Us About Markups?” in Scanner Data and
Price Indexes, edited by R. Feenstra and M. Shapiro, National Bureau of Economic
Research, the University of Chicago Press, 165-225.
Basu, Susanto (1995), “Intermediate Goods and Business Cycles: Implications for Productivity and
Welfare,” American Economic Review, 85, No. 3, 512–531.
Benabou, Roland and Robert Gertner (1993), “Search with Learning from Prices – Does Increased
Inflationary Uncertainty lead to Higher Markups?” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. LX,
69–93.
Bergen, Mark, and George John (1997): “Understanding Cooperative Advertising Participation
Rates in Conventional Channels;” Journal of Marketing Research, v.XXXIV (Aug), 357369.
Bergen, Mark, Shantanu Dutta and Steven M. Shugan (1996): “Branded Variants: A Retail
Perspective;” Journal of Marketing Research, v.XXXIII, 9-19.
Blanchard, Olivier J. (1983), “Price Asynchronization and Price-Level Inertia,” in R. Dornbusch
and M. Simonsen, Inflation, Debt, and Indexation (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), 3–24.
Blinder, Alan S., Elie R.D. Canetti, David E. Lebow, and Jeremy B. Rudd (1998), Asking about
Prices: A New Approach to Price Stickiness (New York: Russel Sage Foundation).
Borenstein, Severin and Andrea Shepard (1996), “Dynamic Pricing in Retail Gasoline Markets,”
Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. XXVII, 429–51.
49
Borenstein, Severin, Colin A. Cameron and Richard Gilbert (1997), “Do Gasoline Prices Respond
Asymmetrically to Crude Oil Price Changes?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
112(1), 305–339.
Boyde, Milton S. and Wade B. Brorsen (1988); "Price Asymmetry in the U.S. Pork Marketing
Channel;" North Central Journal of Agricultural Economics, v.10(1), 103-109.
Cagan, Philip (1974), “The Hydra-Headed Monster: The Problem of Inflation in the United States,”
Domestic Affairs Case Study No. 26, American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC.
Carlton, Dennis W. (1986), “The Rigidity of Prices,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76(4), 637–
58.
Carlton, Dennis, and Jeffrey Perloff (1994), Modern Industrial Organisation (NY, NY: Harper
Collins).
Cecchetti, Steve (1986), “The Frequency of Price Adjustment: A study of the Newsstand Prices of
Magazines,” Journal of Econometrics 31, 255–274.
Chen, Haipeng, Sourav Ray, Mark Bergen and Daniel Levy (2004); “Asymmetric Price Adjustment
"in the Small:" An Implication of Rational Inattention;” manuscript, Winter 2002 North
American Meeting of the Econometric Society, Atlanta, USA, January 3-6, 2002.
Chevalier, Judith, Anil Kashyap, and Peter Rossi (2003), “Why Don’t Prices Rise During Periods of
Peak Demand? Evidence from Scanner Data,” American Economic Review 93(1), 15–37.
Chintagunta, Pradeep (2002); “Investigating Category Pricing Behavior in a Retail Chain,” Journal
of Marketing Research, v.39(2), 141-154.
Choi, S.Chan (1991), “Price Competition in a Channel with a Common Retailer;” Marketing
Science, v.10(4), 271-296.
Danziger, Leif (1987), “Inflation, fixed cost of price adjustments, and measurement of relative price
variability,” American Economic Review, v.77(4), 704–713.
Desai, Preyas S., and Devavrat Purohit (2004), ““Let Me Talk to My Manager:” Haggling in a
Competitive Environment,” Marketing Science, v.23(2), 219-233.
DeSarbo, Wayne S., Vithala R. Rao, Joel H. Steckel, Jerry Wind and Richard Colombo (1987); “A
Friction Model for Describing and Forecasting Price Changes;” Marketing Science, v.6(4),
299-319.
Dutta, Shantanu, Mark Bergen, and Daniel Levy (2002), “Price Flexibility in Channels of
Distribution: Evidence From Scanner Data,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,
Vol. 26, No. 11, 1845–1900.
50
Dutta, Shantanu, Mark Bergen, Daniel Levy, and Robert Venable (1999); “Menu Costs, Posted
Prices, and Multiproduct Retailers,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 31(4),
683–703.
Gerstner, Eitan and James D. Hess (1990); “Can Bait and Switch Benefit Consumers?” Marketing
Science, v.9(2), 114-124.
Gerstner, Eitan; James D. Hess and Duncan M. Holthausen (1994); “Price Discrimination Through
a Distribution Channel: Theory and Evidence,” American Economic Review, v.84(5), 14371445.
Gordon, Robert J. (1990); “What is New-Keynesian Economics?” Journal of Economic Literature,
Vol. 28, No. 3, 1115–1171.
Greenleaf, Eric A. (1995); “The impact of reference price effects on the profitability of price
promotions;” Marketing Science, v.14(1), 82-104.
Grewal, Dhruv and Larry D. Compeau (1999); “Pricing and Public Policy: A Research Agenda and
an Overview of the Special Issue;” Journal of Public Policy and Marketing, v.18(1), 3-10.
Guiltinan, Joseph P. and Greogory T. Gundlach (1996); “Aggressive and Predatory Pricing: A
Framework for Analysis;” Journal of Marketing, v.60(3), 87-102.
Hannan, Timothy H. and Allen N. Berger (1991); “The Rigidity of Prices: Evidence from the
Banking Industry;” American Economic Review, v.81(4), 938-945.
Hess, James D. and Eitan Gerstner (1987); “Loss Leader Pricing and Rain Check Policy;”
Marketing Science, v.6(4), 358-374.
Hoch, Stephen J., Byung Do Kim, Alan L. Montgomery and Peter E. Rossi (1995), “Determinants
of Store-Level Price Elasticity,” Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 32, 17–29.
Hoch, Steve and Shumeet Banerji (1993), “When Do Private Labels Succeed?” Sloan Management
Review 34(4), Summer, 57–67.
Ingene, Charles A. and Mark E. Parry (1995); “Channel Coordination When Retailers Compete;”
Marketing Science, v.14(4), 360-377.
Iyer, Ganesh (1998); “Coordinating Channels Under Price and Nonprice Competition;” Marketing
Science, v.17(4), 338-355.
Jeuland, Abel P. and Steven M. Shugan (1983): “Managing Channel Profits;” Marketing Science,
v.2(3), Summer, 239-272.
51
Kadiyali, Vrinda, Pradeep Chintagunta and Naufel Vilcassim (2000); “Manufacturer-Retailer
Channel Interactions and Implications for Channel Power: An Empirical Investigation of
Pricing in a Local Market;” Marketing Science, v.19(2), 127-148.
Karrenbrock, Jeffrey D. (1991); “The Behavior of Retail Gasoline Prices: Symmetric or Not?”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, v.73(4), 19-29.
Kashyap, Anil K. (1995), “Sticky Prices: New Evidence from Retail Catalogues,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Volume 110, No. 1, February, 245–274.
Kim, San Yong and Richard Staelin (1999); “Manufacturer Allowances and Retailer Pass-Through
Rates in a Competitive Environment;” Marketing Science, v.18(1), 59-76.
Kopalle, Praveen K., Ambar G. Rao, and Joao L. Assuncao (1996); “Asymmetric Reference Price
Effects and Dynamic Pricing Policies;” Marketing Science, v.15(1), 60-85.
Lal, Rajiv (1990), "Manufacturer Trade Deals and Retail Price Promotions," Journal of Marketing
Research 27, 428-444.
Levy, Daniel, Benjamin Zeliger, Paul Rubin, Sourav Ray, and Mark Bergen (2003), “On the
Inefficiency of Item Pricing Laws”, manuscript, Law and Economics Workshop, Summer
2003 NBER, Cambridge, MA, Aug. 1 and 2, 2003.
Levy, Daniel, Mark Bergen, Shantanu Dutta, and Robert Venable (1997), “The Magnitude of Menu
Costs: Direct Evidence from Large U.S. Supermarket Chains,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 112, 791–825.
Levy, Daniel, Shantanu Dutta, and Mark Bergen (2002), “Heterogeneity in Price Rigidity: Evidence
from a Case Study Using Micro-Level Data,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 34 (1),
197–220.
Madsen, Jakob B. and Bill Z. Yang (1998), “Asymmetric Price Adjustment in a Menu-cost Model,”
Journal of Economics, Vol. 68(3), 295–309.
Mankiw, N. Gregory (1985), “Small menu costs and large business cycles: a macroeconomic model
of monopoly,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Volume 100, May, 529–539.
Messinger, Paul R. and Chakravarti Narasimhan (1995); “Has Power Shifted in the Grocery
Channel?” Marketing Science, v.14(2), 189-223.
Moorthy, K. Sridhar (1988): “Strategic Decentralization in Channels;” Marketing Science, v.7(4),
Fall, 335-355.
Müller, Georg and Sourav Ray (2003); “Asymmetric Price Adjustments: A Retail Perspective;”
Working Paper, 2001 Midwest Marketing Camp, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor.
52
Neumark, David and Steven A. Sharpe (1992), “Market Structure and the Nature of Price Rigidity:
Evidence from the Market for Consumer Deposits,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
107(2), 657–680.
Nevo, Aviv (2001), “Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry,” Econometrica,
v.69(2), 307-342.
Pauwels, Koen, and Shuba Srinivasan (2004), “Who Benefits from Store Brand Entry?” Marketing
Science, v.23(3), 364-390.
Peltzman, Sam (2000), “Prices Rise Faster Than They Fall,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol.
108(3), 466–502.
Pesendorfer, Martin (2002); “Retail Sales: A Study of Pricing Behavior in Supermarkets,” Journal
of Business, v.75(1), 33-66.
Pick, Daniel H., Jeffrey Karrenbrock and Hoy F. Carmen, (1991); "Price Asymmetry and Marketing
Margin Behavior: An Example for California-Arizona Citrus;" Agribusiness, v.6(1), 75-84
Rao, Ram C. (1991), "Pricing and Promotions in Asymmetric Duopolies," Marketing Science, 10
(2), 131-144.
Rao, Vithala R. and Edward W. McLaughlin (1989); “Modeling the Decision to Add New Products
by Channel Intermediaries;” Journal of Marketing, v.53(Jan), 80-88.
Ratchford, Brian T. and Narasimhan Srinivasan (1993); “An Empirical Investigation of Returns to
Search;” Marketing Science, v.12(1), 73-87.
Roll, Richard (1984), “Orange Juice and Weather,” American Economic Review, 74, 861–880.
Slade, Margaret E. (1998): “Optimal Pricing with Costly Adjustment: Evidence from RetailGrocery prices;” Review of Economic Studies, v.65, 87-107.
Tellis, Gerard J. and Fred S. Zufryden (1995), “Tackling the Retailer Decision Maze: Which Brands
to Discount, How Much, When and Why?” Marketing Science, v.14(3), 271-299.
Tyagi, Rajeev K. (1999): “A characterization of retailer response to manufacturer trade deals;”
Journal of Marketing Research, v.36(4), 510-516.
Villas-Boas, J. Miguel (1998); “Product Line Design for a Distribution Channel;” Marketing
Science, v.17(2), 156-169.
Ward, Ronald W. (1982); "Asymmetry in Retail, Wholesale and Shipping Point Pricing for Fresh
Vegetables;" American Agricultural Economics Association, v.14 (May), 205-215.
Wilkie, William L., Carl F. Mela and Gregory T. Gundlach (1998); “Does “Bait and Switch” Really
Benefit Consumers?” Marketing Science, v.17(3), 273-282.
53
Wilson, Lynn O., Allen M. Weiss, and George John (1990); “Unbundling of Industrial Systems;”
Journal of Marketing Research, v.XXVII, 123-38.
Zbaracki, Mark, Mark Ritson, Daniel Levy, Shantanu Dutta, and Mark Bergen (2004), “The
Managerial and Customer Costs of Price Adjustment: Direct Evidence from Industrial
Markets,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 86, No. 2, 514-533.
54
Table 1a. All Categories Combined, Entire Sample, Price Changes in Cents
Price Change in Cents
Positive
Negative
Z-Value
1
2895106
2098539
356.46
2
1676572
1300313
218.07
3
1247860
1001943
163.95
4
986016
810011
131.33
5
836345
662900
141.65
6
702145
564634
122.18
7
619595
514363
98.82
8
520394
448388
73.16
9
409297
345331
73.63
10
357570
305687
63.71
11
317809
282220
45.94
12
297657
274928
30.04
13
283681
255998
37.68
14
256040
233362
32.42
15
234609
207550
40.69
16
204458
194157
16.32
17
198795
177999
33.88
18
179168
167727
19.43
19
182573
172934
16.17
20
163876
154406
16.79
21
147867
138684
17.15
22
140236
136270
7.54
23
132603
127776
9.46
24
127366
118553
17.77
25
132680
127664
9.83
26
120090
112526
15.68
27
114587
106147
17.96
28
98560
94870
8.39
29
98055
94940
7.09
30
97295
96314
2.23
31
89961
89116
2.00
32
101094
92851
18.72
33
86914
83416
8.48
34
85815
81700
10.05
35
89367
85005
10.45
36
80315
75532
12.12
37
85957
88666
-6.48
38
85041
80912
10.14
39
78067
72677
13.88
40
70122
65406
12.81
41
64565
60255
12.20
42
63398
61014
6.76
43
70939
69516
3.80
44
62361
61711
1.85
45
60022
59303
2.08
46
58291
63867
-15.95
47
51194
51552
-1.12
48
51733
54594
-8.77
49
46529
47104
-1.88
50
45186
46693
-4.97
55
Table 1b. All Categories Combined, Entire Sample, Price Change in Percents
Price Change in %
Positive
Negative
Z-Value
1
3040097
2369790
288.19
2
1833178
1467749
201.13
3
1340358
1117787
141.96
4
1072180
899292
123.13
5
765355
668618
80.78
6
631352
592735
34.90
7
524601
506774
17.55
8
480713
452409
29.30
9
393397
393734
-0.38
10
351780
362894
-13.15
11
322287
331016
-10.80
12
288412
326835
-48.99
13
280326
291078
-14.22
14
250000
300384
-67.91
15
225027
271375
-65.78
16
242802
249251
-9.19
17
221687
252551
-44.82
18
201737
234925
-50.22
19
180080
214481
-54.77
20
201395
196250
8.16
21
160135
192749
-54.90
22
163640
163501
0.24
23
144710
152282
-13.89
24
142030
138348
6.95
25
123762
126999
-6.46
26
126984
113861
26.74
27
116047
111207
10.15
28
102891
113362
-22.52
29
97362
118163
-44.81
30
86047
90755
-11.20
31
76570
88536
-29.45
32
77578
79606
-5.12
33
65036
72268
-19.52
34
69211
63321
16.18
35
63195
58258
14.17
36
60660
54383
18.51
37
58841
44385
44.99
38
55280
43987
35.84
39
53907
38740
49.83
40
46866
41935
16.55
41
67823
40201
84.04
42
43074
35005
28.88
43
45052
34840
36.13
44
40879
35856
18.13
45
41584
39883
5.96
46
41443
31647
36.23
47
30251
28806
5.95
48
29130
31172
-8.32
49
33433
24716
36.15
50
28534
27389
4.84
56
Table 2a. All Categories Combined, Low Inflation, Price Changes in Cents
Price Change in Cents
Positive
Negative
Z-Value
1
1563081
1145605
253.66
2
901586
703395
156.44
3
670891
538954
119.95
4
521048
430541
92.78
5
449189
356776
102.94
6
374921
306464
82.93
7
324646
273707
65.85
8
276121
244961
43.17
9
214997
186572
44.86
10
186824
171666
25.32
11
166624
152614
24.80
12
155122
148049
12.85
13
151697
140288
21.11
14
132013
121424
21.03
15
123295
114419
18.20
16
108076
106859
2.63
17
102463
95490
15.67
18
95988
89244
15.67
19
93151
92083
2.48
20
83270
82713
1.37
21
79235
74453
12.20
22
72416
74441
-5.28
23
68190
72591
-11.73
24
66608
62577
11.22
25
67569
64884
7.38
26
64555
58527
17.18
27
60430
57106
9.70
28
50378
49997
1.20
29
50175
51220
-3.28
30
48271
49089
-2.62
31
42759
42361
1.36
32
53628
50100
10.95
33
42734
42949
-0.73
34
46418
44567
6.14
35
51159
47374
12.06
36
41091
37720
12.01
37
45209
46517
-4.32
38
43291
41026
7.80
39
39149
40027
-3.12
40
36733
33959
10.43
41
33701
31924
6.94
42
33457
33174
1.10
43
35269
35536
-1.00
44
32423
32049
1.47
45
29096
30832
-7.09
46
29609
33998
-17.40
47
26487
27952
-6.28
48
25263
27273
-8.77
49
22910
23985
-4.96
50
20586
23218
-12.58
57
Table 2b. All Categories Combined, Low Inflation, Price Changes in Percents
Price Change in %
Positive
Negative
Z-Value
1
1654535
1292877
210.66
2
987127
792036
146.26
3
714404
610636
90.15
4
572131
494293
75.37
5
404874
363633
47.04
6
330664
314028
20.72
7
278831
273952
6.56
8
256257
242442
19.56
9
206590
214455
-12.12
10
186363
196416
-16.25
11
168146
176572
-14.35
12
151629
179133
-47.82
13
147464
154627
-13.03
14
129467
152450
-43.29
15
115764
141946
-51.57
16
122650
130178
-14.97
17
116947
133105
-32.31
18
103816
123467
-41.22
19
90744
108787
-40.39
20
98804
104223
-12.03
21
81917
101902
-46.61
22
88062
77087
27.01
23
72590
79946
-18.83
24
68782
73531
-12.59
25
64974
60265
13.31
26
66998
58793
23.13
27
58916
56068
8.40
28
50181
61586
-34.11
29
49239
55522
-19.41
30
42851
44625
-6.00
31
38489
42770
-15.02
32
37532
34864
9.92
33
29729
33741
-15.92
34
33954
31617
9.13
35
31013
26232
19.98
36
28902
27289
6.80
37
29610
19209
47.07
38
27315
22345
22.30
39
26582
18427
38.44
40
21786
21579
0.99
41
30072
20970
40.29
42
21894
17748
20.82
43
22440
16368
30.82
44
19791
17235
13.28
45
21168
19614
7.70
46
16818
16723
0.52
47
13292
15199
-11.30
48
13875
16580
-15.50
49
14877
14002
5.15
50
13145
14266
-6.77
58
Table 3a. All Categories Combined, Deflation, Price Changes in Cents
Price Change in Cents
Positive
Negative
Z-Value
1
1072926
797687
201.24
2
614350
482632
125.76
3
463687
368254
104.63
4
359824
292415
83.47
5
307434
244947
84.08
6
256657
215861
59.35
7
221610
188616
51.51
8
187334
167618
33.09
9
149559
127189
42.52
10
129117
115699
27.12
11
112853
103478
20.16
12
106162
100130
13.28
13
103670
95437
18.45
14
89093
84736
10.45
15
84646
78955
14.07
16
72653
72355
0.78
17
73377
64770
23.16
18
65118
61508
10.14
19
66383
65638
2.05
20
57643
57811
-0.49
21
56121
52181
11.97
22
49908
50648
-2.33
23
45871
49709
-12.41
24
43987
42410
5.37
25
46329
43533
9.33
26
44724
41961
9.38
27
39843
41019
-4.14
28
35051
34816
0.89
29
34420
33976
1.70
30
34884
33819
4.06
31
28460
29459
-4.15
32
36880
35455
5.30
33
29696
30226
-2.17
34
32330
29349
12.00
35
35189
32447
10.54
36
27945
24826
13.58
37
31099
31584
-1.94
38
28197
25999
9.44
39
26146
26556
-1.79
40
25296
23063
10.15
41
22027
22258
-1.10
42
21223
21430
-1.00
43
24978
25848
-3.86
44
20919
20625
1.44
45
19661
19357
1.54
46
21522
23253
-8.18
47
17895
18064
-0.89
48
18622
18908
-1.48
49
16249
17575
-7.21
50
14401
15968
-8.99
59
Table 3b. All Categories Combined, Deflation, Price Changes in Percents
Price Change in %
Positive
Negative
Z-Value
1
1141220
898901
169.65
2
681315
540571
127.33
3
496515
418860
81.17
4
382480
340023
49.95
5
283179
250915
44.15
6
225844
213743
18.25
7
190062
188157
3.10
8
172890
166784
10.48
9
138369
147775
-17.58
10
125667
133492
-15.37
11
117385
122344
-10.13
12
104715
128934
-50.10
13
103438
109879
-13.95
14
91527
106677
-34.03
15
77789
95260
-42.00
16
85445
92440
-16.59
17
78764
94632
-38.11
18
68349
84438
-41.16
19
61441
74405
-35.17
20
71493
73817
-6.10
21
53955
71276
-48.95
22
58647
54368
12.73
23
48101
54147
-18.91
24
46712
50332
-11.62
25
46113
41600
15.24
26
48012
41220
22.74
27
39136
38728
1.46
28
35798
43910
-28.73
29
33218
37130
-14.75
30
29206
30894
-6.89
31
25421
29572
-17.70
32
26895
25625
5.54
33
21690
23114
-6.73
34
25150
21731
15.79
35
21084
18316
13.94
36
20576
20044
2.64
37
21365
12417
48.68
38
19234
15076
22.45
39
18150
12685
31.12
40
15093
14572
3.02
41
20177
13296
37.61
42
16177
10801
32.73
43
14710
11249
21.48
44
13787
11451
14.70
45
14500
11752
16.96
46
12246
10721
10.06
47
9181
9836
-4.75
48
9559
9216
2.50
49
10395
9177
8.71
50
8778
9945
-8.53
60
Table 4. What Might Constitute a “Small” Price Change
Statistical Analysis of the Data by Product Category in Absolute (Cents) and Relative (%) Terms
Entire Sample Period
Low/Zero Inflation Period
Deflation Period
Absolut
e
(Cents)
Relativ
e (%)
Absolute
(Cents)
Relative
(%)
Absolut
e
(Cents)
Relative
(%)
Analgesics
30
8
21
10
3
7
Bath Soap
10
2
2
1
2
1
Bathroom Tissues
11
4
9
1
10
1
Beer
3
0
0
2
0
2
Bottled Juices
13
5
21
11
9
5
Canned Soup
13
8
9
7
6
8
Canned Tuna
3
2
3
1
4
2
Cereals
33
9
19
9
19
9
Cheeses
18
6
9
3
5
3
Cigarettes
14
8
1
8
1
3
Cookies
11
6
11
6
11
8
Crackers
15
6
15
5
15
8
Dish Detergent
4
2
4
1
4
1
Fabric Softeners
5
2
8
3
2
3
Front-end-candies
7
9
6
8
6
5
Frozen Dinners
6
1
3
1
3
1
Frozen Entrees
30
5
17
8
8
6
Frozen Juices
9
5
7
6
9
7
Grooming Products
12
8
15
8
13
8
Laundry Detergents
8
2
8
2
6
2
Oatmeal
7
7
2
1
2
1
Paper Towels
1
2
3
4
10
4
Refrigerated Juices
10
6
8
4
4
2
Shampoos
13
7
10
6
13
7
Snack Crackers
7
5
7
5
7
3
Soaps
7
4
9
4
5
3
Soft Drinks
23
9
14
11
14
8
Tooth Brushes
9
8
9
7
11
7
Tooth Pastes
16
5
10
4
10
4
Total (All 29 Categories
Combined)
36
8
19
8
15
8
Notes:
1. The figures reported in the table are the cutoff points of what might constitute a “small” price change for
each category. For each category, the cutoff point is the first point at which the asymmetry is not supported
statistically. Thus, for example, in the Analgesics category, when the entire sample is used and we consider
the price changes in cents, we see that for price changes of up to 30 cents, there is asymmetry as our theory
predicts. Beyond that point the asymmetry disappears.
2. In all tables, the critical values for 1%, 5% and 10% significance are 2.575, 1.96, and 1.645, respectively.
61
Positive
Negative
2500000
2000000
1500000
1000000
500000
0
0
10
20
30
40
Frequency of Price Change
Frequency of Price Change
3000000
3500000
Positive
3000000
Negative
2500000
2000000
1500000
1000000
500000
0
0
50
10
20
30
40
50
Price Change in %
Price Change in Cents
(a)
(b)
1750000
Positive
Negative
1500000
1250000
1000000
750000
500000
250000
0
0
10
20
30
Price Change in Cents
(a)
40
50
Frequency of Price Change
Frequency of Price Change
Figure 1: Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes: All 29 Categories, Entire Period
1800000
Positive
Negative
1500000
1200000
900000
600000
300000
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
Price Change in %
(b)
Figure 2: Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes: All 29 Categories, Low Inflation Period
62
Positive
Negative
1000000
800000
600000
400000
200000
0
0
10
20
30
Price Change in Cents
(a)
40
50
Frequency of Price Change
Frequency of Price Change
1200000
1200000
Positive
Negative
1000000
800000
600000
400000
200000
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
Price Change in %
(b)
Figure 3: Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes: All 29 Categories, Deflation Period
Figure 4. Monthly Inflation Rate Based on Producer Price Index, September 1989-May 1997
63
(a) Cents – Entire Period
(b) Percents – Entire Period
(c) Cents – Low/Zero Inflation Period
(d) Percents – Low/Zero Inflation Period
(e) Cents – Deflation Period
(f) Percents – Deflation Period
Figure 5: Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes: Toothpaste
64
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
TECHNICAL APPENDIX
Asymmetric Wholesale Pricing: Theory and Evidence
Sourav Ray*
Department of Marketing
DeGroote School of Business, McMaster University
Email: sray@mcmaster.ca
Haipeng (Allan) Chen
Department of Marketing, University of Miami
Email: hchen@exchange.sba.miami.edu
Mark E. Bergen
Department of Marketing and Logistics Management
Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota
Email: mbergen@csom.umn.edu
Daniel Levy
Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University
And
Department of Economics, Emory University
Email: levyda@mail.biu.ac.il
* Contact author
1 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
TECHNICAL APPENDIX – Data
This appendix addresses the concern regarding our wholesale data: Could the Results be an
Artifact of How the Wholesale Prices Are Calculated?
Our wholesale price, as reported in the Dominick’s database, is based on the average
acquisition cost (AAC). The AAC per unit is calculated as follows:
AAC (t ) =
{Purch(t ) × price(t )} + {EndInventory (t − 1) − sales(t )}× AAC (t − 1)
TotalInventory (t )
where,
Purch(t) = Inventory bought in t;
price(t) = Per unit wholesale price paid in t;
EndInventory(t-1) = Inventory at end of t-1;
Sales(t) = Retail sales at t;
TotalInventory(t) = Total Inventory at t
Lagged adjustment of AAC
Can it be claimed that our results could be just an artifact of the manner in which AAC is
calculated? Manufacturers often inform the retailer in advance of an impending temporary price
reduction, permitting the retailer to completely deplete its inventory and then “forward-buying”
to overstock at the lower price (Peltzman, 2000). Since new purchases form a large proportion of
the total inventory in this case, the large discount shows up as a commensurately large reduction
in AAC. On the other hand, a retailer buys less when the wholesale price goes up. Consequently,
a wholesale price increase of the same large magnitude as the decrease considered earlier, will
translate into a relatively smaller increase in AAC (the so called, lagged adjustment). It is
reasonable to expect that the observed asymmetry in wholesale prices therefore may be driven by
such forward buying phenomenon.
In the absence of actual wholesale prices, how do we conduct a direct test to check for the
above effect? One way of proceeding is to check the data for patterns implied by the above
rationale. We discuss the following analyses in the same spirit.
2 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
National Brands versus Private Labels
Note that the forward buying rationale suggests that if the manner of calculating AAC was
the major driver of our results (asymmetry in the small), it should be more pronounced for
products that are subjected to greater degree of forward buying. For products not subject to
major fluctuations in its purchases driven by promotional prices, we should expect much lesser
degree of such systematic distortion. This leads to the following null proposition which holds
true if the manner of computing AAC was the major driver of our results.1
Forward Buying Proposition: Products subject to greater degree of forward
buying will exhibit greater asymmetry than products that are subject to
lesser degree of forward buying.
Unfortunately, we do not have direct data on the degree of forward buying. However,
according to Hoch et al. (1995), private labels are not promoted as heavily, and hence are
forward-bought less than national brands. Therefore, a comparison of national brands to private
labels provides a natural context to test the above proposition. In essence, if forward buying is
the main driver of our results, the predicted asymmetry should be stronger for national brands
than for private labels. We therefore undertook two additional analyses to explore whether, and
to what extent, can our results be attributed to the method of computing AAC. In the paragraphs
below we first discuss the data and then the individual tests.
National Brand versus Private Label Data
For the purposes of the test we need data on comparable national brand (NB)-private label
(PL) product pairs. We base our identification of such NB-PL pairs on a recently published study
of Barsky, et al (2003), who use the same Dominick’s data to investigate the size of markups for
nationally branded products sold in the U.S. retail grocery industry. Their measure of markup is
based on a comparison of the prices of matched pairs of NB-PL products. To implement their
strategy, therefore, Barsky, et al. (2003) had to identify the product pairs based on several
comparability criteria, which included, among other attributes, product’s quality, size, packaging,
etc. For quality comparison, they used Hoch and Banerji’s (1993) PL product quality rankings.
1
This is not to be confused with our theoretical proposition earlier. Here we intend to check if the “null,” (forward
buying is a key driver of the observed asymmetry), can be rejected in favor of the “alternate” (that it is not).
3 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
After filtering out the product pairs that were not comparable for various reasons (for
example, size differences, quality differences, insufficient number of observations, etc.), Barsky,
et al. (2003) were left with 231 matched NB-PL product pairs of comparable size and quality,
covering 19 product categories.2 These categories are Analgesics, Bottled Juices, Cereals,
Cheeses, Cookies, Crackers, Canned Soups, Dish Detergent, Frozen Entrees, Frozen Juices,
Fabric Softeners, Grooming Products, Laundry Detergent, Oatmeal, Snack Crackers, Tooth
Pastes, Toothbrushes, Soft Drinks, and Canned Tuna. However, Barsky, et al. (2003) argue that
Toothbrushes category is an outlier for its unusually high markup ratio, in comparison to the
remaining 18 categories. Consequently, they omit the Toothbrushes category from much of their
analysis.3 Following their strategy, therefore, we also exclude the category of Toothbrushes from
our analysis and were left with 18 categories with matched NB-PL pairs for our analyses.
Analysis 1: Comparison of aggregate asymmetries between NB and PL
We start by conducting an analysis identical to that used in the main paper and compare
the aggregate asymmetry thresholds between NB and PL pairs for all the 18 categories. The
hypothesis below is derived directly from the null proposition.4
Hypothesis 1: Aggregate asymmetry threshold for National Brands is greater than
that for Private Labels.
Tables R2.1 and R2.2 below report the results of the analysis in terms of absolute changes
(Cents) and relative changes (%), respectively. The thresholds we obtain are marked in bold. In
the absolute case we obtain an asymmetry threshold of 6 cents for the national brands (NB) and 5
cents for private labels (PL). In the relative case, we obtain identical thresholds of 4%.
Two important observations are in order here. First, note the similarity of the magnitudes
of the thresholds in both the tests. So, while we cannot subject Hypothesis 1 to a statistical test of
significance and are limited to comparing two numbers, the prima facie evidence argues against
the hypothesis.
2
See Barsky, et al. (2003), Tables 7A.1-7A.19 for a detailed list of the NB-PL product pairs.
See Barsky, et al., 2003, p. 194.
4
This and all subsequent hypotheses derived from the null proposition are in the nature of null hypotheses which we
aim to reject in favor of the alternate proposition that forward buying is not a key driver.
3
4 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Second, note the presence of significant asymmetry for the PL sample. This last point is
important because if forward buying indeed were a primary driver of our observed asymmetry
and if PLs are not subjected to significant forward buying, we should expect only insignificant
asymmetry for the PL sample. But that is not the case and the asymmetry for PLs is not only
significant but comparable to that of NBs.
Table R2.1: Frequencies of price changes for the 18 categories with NB-PL pairs (Cents)
Price Change
in Cents
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
Positive
4496
2117
1398
1048
823
661
542
489
415
382
270
NB
Negative
3550
1683
1097
860
727
517
493
429
330
306
295
Z-Value
10.546
7.040
6.026
4.304
2.438
4.196
1.523
1.980
3.114
2.897
1.052
Positive
4788
2473
1482
1121
895
682
551
361
365
324
364
PL
Negative
3348
1833
1369
912
736
644
472
397
332
272
255
Z-Value
15.965
9.753
2.116
4.635
3.937
1.044
2.470
1.308
1.250
2.130
4.381
Table R2.2: Frequencies of price changes for the 18 categories with NB-PL pairs (%)
Price Change
in %
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
Positive
4072
1893
1300
905
648
566
428
416
311
321
257
NB
Negative
3304
1512
1056
795
592
526
432
394
369
292
226
Z-Value
8.942
6.529
5.027
2.668
1.590
1.210
0.136
0.773
2.224
1.171
1.411
Positive
4480
2156
1431
1061
758
634
497
415
392
459
340
PL
Negative
3220
1613
1138
887
746
612
536
467
415
362
336
Z-Value
14.359
8.845
5.781
3.942
0.309
0.623
1.213
1.751
0.810
3.385
0.154
Taken together, these observations provide strong evidence that our results are not entirely
driven by the manner of computing AAC. In the subsequent analyses, we conduct further tests to
explore the robustness of this statement.
5 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Let the degree of asymmetry in a given price change be the difference between the number
of positive and negative changes expressed as a percentage of the number of positive changes.
For example, the degree of asymmetry for 1 Cent difference is calculated as: (#POS 1 Cent
changes - #NEG 1Cent changes)/#POS 1 Cent changes. Like earlier, if forward buying is indeed
the primary driver of the asymmetry in AAC, we should expect that it would reflect in a greater
mean degree of asymmetry for NB compared to PL. This leads to the following hypothesis.
Hypothesis 2: Aggregate degree of asymmetry for National Brands is greater than
that for Private Labels.
The difference between hypothesis 1 and hypothesis 2 is that while the first considered
asymmetry thresholds, the second considers the extent of asymmetry between positive and
negative changes.
To conduct this test, we first calculated the degree of asymmetry for each price change and
then compared the mean asymmetry between NB and PL with a paired t-test. We conducted the
test for both absolute (Cents) and relative (%) changes. Given the thresholds of 6 cents for NB
and 5 cents for PL in absolute terms, and 4% for both in relative terms, we restricted the
comparison to small magnitudes (1-11 Cents and 1-11%) in order to focus on the region of
interest.5 Table R2.3a below reports the mean degrees of asymmetry we observe and the results
of the paired t-tests. In the absolute case, we observe an average degree of asymmetry of 15.2%
for NB and 15.0% for PL. For the relative case, the averages are 8.4% and 8.3% for NB and PL
respectively. Notice that none of the comparisons are significant (p = 0.485 and 0.493
respectively), i.e. we find no support for hypothesis 2.
In order to make sure that we did not ignore any possible regions where such asymmetry
might exist, we repeated the analysis successively for 1-5 Cents, 1-6 Cents, 1-7 Cents, 1-8 Cents,
1-9 Cents and 1-10 Cents as well as for 1-5%, 1-6%, 1-7%, 1-8%, 1-9% and 1-10% bands. In
none of these 12 additional comparisons was there any significant difference in the average
degree of asymmetry between NB and PL (all p’s > 0.30).
5
This also has the added advantage of being a strong test because any difference between NB and PL due to forward
buying is more likely to manifest in the small. We also checked even smaller ranges.
6 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Table R2.3a: Comparison of average degree of asymmetry between NB and PL
Absolute (Cents)
NB
PL
Mean Degree
of Asymmetry
t-stat
p value
15.2%
0.039
0.485
Relative (%)
NB
PL
15.0%
8.4%
0.019
0.493
8.3%
In addition to the tests above, we checked the degree of asymmetry of the PL sample. As
argued earlier, if forward buying indeed were a primary driver of our observed asymmetry and if
PLs are not subjected to significant forward buying, we should not expect any significant
asymmetry for the PL sample. To test this we checked if the mean degrees of asymmetry of the
PL sample were significantly greater than zero. The results are in Table R2.3b below. For both
(absolute and elative) cases, the means are significantly greater than zero (p<0.05).
Table R2.3b: Mean degree of asymmetry of PL sample
Mean
t-stat
Sig.
(H0: m=0)
(Absolute - Cents)
0.149965
4.213
p<0.05
(Relative - %)
0.083003
1.913
p<0.05
Therefore, in keeping with the conclusions following Hypothesis 1, the results of the above
analyses provide strong evidence that our results cannot be entirely driven by the manner of
computing AAC. We now drill down further into the data and look at even more disaggregate
comparisons.6
Analysis 2: Comparison of category level asymmetries between NB and PL
For this investigation, we conducted an analysis identical to that used in the main paper,
and compared the asymmetry thresholds between NB and PL for individual categories. The
hypothesis below is derived directly from the proposition.
Hypothesis 3: The average category level asymmetry threshold for National
Brands is greater than that for Private Labels.
6
Note however, that our sample size becomes very small as we drill down to more disaggregate levels.
7 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
To test this hypothesis, we first obtained the asymmetry thresholds for both NB and PL in
individual categories and then compared the average threshold with a paired t-test. The analysis
is conducted for both absolute (Cents) as well as relative (%) changes. Table R2.4a below reports
the mean asymmetry thresholds we observe and the results of the paired t-tests. In the absolute
case, we observe an average degree of asymmetry of 1.111 for NB and 1.389 for PL. For the
relative case, the averages are 0.944% and 1.556% for NB and PL respectively. Notice that none
of the comparisons are significant (p = 0.280 and 0.091 respectively), i.e. we find no support for
hypothesis 3.
Table R2.4a: Comparison of average category level asymmetry thresholds between NB and PL
Absolute (Cents)
NB
PL
Mean Threshold
of Asymmetry
t-stat
p value
1.111
-0.589
0.280
1.389
Relative (%)
NB
PL
0.944%
-1.364
0.091
1.556%
In addition, we also checked the average category level asymmetry thresholds for the PL
sample. In keeping with the arguments made earlier, we should not expect significant asymmetry
in this sample if forward buying was the primary driver of our observed asymmetry. We test if
the average category level asymmetry thresholds for the PL sample are significantly greater than
zero. The results are in table R2.4b. In both (absolute and relative) cases, the average thresholds
are significantly greater than zero (p<0.05)
Table R2.4b: Average category level asymmetry threshold for PL sample
Mean
T
Sig.
(H0: m=0)
(Absolute - Cents)
1.389
4.034
p<0.05
(Relative - %)
1.556
4.932
p<0.05
Again, in keeping with the conclusions following Hypotheses 1 and 2, the results of the
above analyses provide additional evidence that our results cannot be entirely driven by the
manner of computing AAC.
8 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Nevertheless, in search of further robustness, we continue the investigation in greater detail
by comparing individual category level thresholds in the following analysis. In conducting this
analysis however, we feel compelled to point out the drastic loss of sample size that occurs. For
example, the average number of observations per category in the data set, is 3,431,118, while the
average number of observations for each NB-PL pair for a category is only 3,710, a reduction in
excess of 99%. Therefore, the comparisons should be kept in perspective – they are likely to be
more illustrative in nature and perhaps more accurate in a relative sense than in an absolute
sense.
Table R2.5 below reports the asymmetry thresholds we obtain for each NB-PL pair. The
analysis is repeated for both absolute (cents) and relative (%) changes. We also report the sample
size for each pair in the last column.
The results reported in this table provide additional support to our claims following
Hypotheses 1, 2 and 3, that our results cannot be entirely driven by the manner of computing
AAC. This is based on the following three observations.
Observation 1: Out of the 18 product categories for which we have data, 3 didn’t show
asymmetry for either absolute or relative changes; 12 showed the asymmetry for either absolute
or relative changes and showed an asymmetry threshold for private labels that is as large as or
larger than national brands; 3 showed the asymmetry for either absolute or relative change and
showed a larger asymmetry threshold for national brands than for private labels. Therefore, the
proportion of product categories for which the prediction of forward buying is supported is less
than chance level (i.e., 3/15 < 50%; z = 2.32; p < 0.03).
Observation 2: Out of 36 (= 18 x 2) possible comparisons, there are five that are consistent
with the prediction of forward buying (marked in bold in the table). However, 15 are in the
opposite direction and in the remaining 16 cases the threshold is the same for private labels and
national brands.7 Altogether, the majority of comparisons (i.e., 31, or more than 86%) are
inconsistent with the prediction of forward buying.
7
8 of which have an asymmetry threshold of 0 for both NB and PL – an observation that we feel is driven by the
severely limited sample size.
9 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Observation 3: For comparisons where there is a non-zero threshold for either NB or PL,
there are 15 for which the threshold is larger for PL than for NB, compared to 5 for which the
opposite is true. The difference is statistically significant (z = 2.27, p < .03).
Table R2.5: Asymmetry thresholds for the 18 categories with NB-PL pairs
Categories
Absolute (Cents)
Relative (%)
NB
PL
NB
PL
Analgesics
1
1
3
3
Sample Size
5149
Bottled Juices
3
3
1
2
6735
Canned Soup
3
3
4
2
6136
Canned Tuna
0
0
0
0
919
Cereals
3
3
3
4
6111
Cheeses
1
1
0
1
3021
Cookies
2
2
0
1
3513
Crackers
1
0
1
0
2410
Dish Detergent
0
2
0
1
2756
Fabric Softeners
0
0
0
0
2060
Frozen Entrees
0
5
0
3
636
Frozen Juices
2
2
1
3
6587
Grooming Products
0
0
0
0
667
Laundry Detergents
0
2
0
1
3930
Oatmeal
0
0
1
3
920
Snack Crackers
0
0
0
1
1017
Soft Drinks
0
1
0
3
10623
Tooth Pastes
4
0
3
0
3593
Total (all 18 categories
combined)
6
5
4
4
66783
Bold: NB > PL
To conclude, we do not find any strong reason to believe that the forward buying
hypothesis related to AAC is a primary driver of our results. We subject the data to a series of
tests to check if there are patterns consistent with the forward buying hypotheses. None of the
analyses, whether descriptive or statistical, provide support for these hypotheses. In the absence
of such evidence, we conclude that it is highly unlikely that our empirical results are an artifact
of the manner in which the wholesale prices have been calculated.
Such a conclusion must however, be tempered with the knowledge that we are after all
dealing with a derived measure of wholesale prices and a better test of our theory would be with
actual wholesale prices. Unfortunately, such data is not available. We are not unique in dealing
with this problem. A number of other authors who have dealt with it bemoan the lack of proper
wholesale price data (cf. Cecchetti, 1986; Peltzman, 2000; Chintagunta, 2002; Levy, et al. 2002;
10 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Chevalier, et al. 2003 etc.). Creative approaches like estimating wholesale prices from regression
which is particularly common in the empirical industrial organization literature (see Carlton and
Perloff, 1994), using aggregate price indexes, such as wholesale price index, as a proxy
(Cecchetti, 1985), rough accounting estimates (Nevo, 2001), even simulation (Tellis and
Zufryden, 1995) are the norm in such cases. Others may ignore explicit consideration of
wholesale prices altogether (Gerstner et al., 1994; Pesendorfer, 2001).
While the lack of accurate wholesale price data is unfortunate, we believe that should not
hinder theory building in the domain of wholesale prices. Nevertheless, the onus is on the
researcher to ensure that any empirical test of theory using weak wholesale data is actually
robust to the weakness of the data. It is in that spirit that we conducted these additional checks.
To keep things in perspective therefore, it is necessary to understand that while we stand
behind the spirit of our results, we recognize that the verity of the exact magnitudes of the
asymmetry we report is subject to some uncertainty.
Reverse Asymmetry in the large
It may be worthwhile here, to consider the role of reverse asymmetry in the large vis-à-vis
the forward buying proposition. When a manufacturer offers a temporary off-invoice discount to
a retailer, the retailer tends to buy more of the product than it needs during the period of the sale.
AAC typically falls by a large amount then. Theoretically, if this drop in AAC is not matched by
a similar increase when prices do go up, one should see reverse asymmetry in the large. Since
retailers are normally expected to purchase lesser amounts at higher prices, this leads us to
believe that reverse asymmetry in the large – i.e. more large price decreases than increases, is a
reasonable prediction if the rival forward buying hypothesis was a primary driver of our results.
The method we employed to test this is to compare, for each of the 29 product categories,
the frequencies in which positive price changes exceeded negative price changes (“positive”
asymmetry), with the frequencies in which the opposite holds true (“negative” asymmetry). If the
alternative, lagged adjustment is the main driver, then we should observe relatively more
frequent occurrences of negative than positive asymmetry in the large. If there is no such
negative asymmetry in the large, as our theory predicts, then occurrences of the number of
positive and negative asymmetries should be statistically equal. We report the number of
11 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
occurrences of positive (p) and negative asymmetries (n) as a ratio (p:n) in Table R2.68 We
carried out the analyses for the entire sample, as well as for a sample of low/zero inflation period
and a sample of deflation period. We also did the analyses both in terms of absolute changes in
cents and in terms of percentage changes.
Table R2.6: Number of Positive vs. Negative Asymmetry Beyond Threshold
Entire Sample Period
Low/Zero Inflation Period
Deflation Period
Absolute
(Cents)
Relative
(%)
Absolute
(Cents)
Relative
(%)
Absolute
(Cents)
Relative
(%)
Analgesics
16:1
17:20
21:3
13:18
28:8
14:18
Bath Soap
11:11
26:15
13:15
24:18
12:13
21:14
Bathroom Tissues
10:15
26:12
11:18
32:10
13:15
33:10
Beer
2:43**
29:14
3:34**
29:13
15:21
27:12
Bottled Juices
15:11
26:16
9:10
24:12
20:16
25:14
Canned Soup
19:11
21:13
17:13
17:13
21:16
19:16
Canned Tuna
22:10
24:13
14:17
19:19
16:14
17:15
Cereals
10:1
5:27
22:2
17:19
16:8
16:21
Cheeses
14:11
25:14
13:16
22:21
20:11
21:17
Cigarettes
23:8
20:15
22:22
14:20
9:33**
18:19
Cookies
15:19
23:17
16:16
21:19
15:19
17:19
Crackers
12:13
22:18
17:15
20:19
18:15
19:18
Dish Detergent
16:16
23:16
8:24**
23:17
9:28**
26:16
Fabric Softeners
13:21
23:19
13:20
22:13
10:19**
21:15
Front-end-candies
21:15
11:25**
14:24
8:31**
18:18
6:34**
19:22
Frozen Dinners
21:17
22:20
29:11
22:21
24:13
Frozen Entrees
7:8
18:24
10:15
13:26**
19:17
17:24
Frozen Juices
8:21**
23:15
13:21
24:11
17:17
19:8
Grooming Products
18:11
26:13
12:12
26:14
19:12
26:11
Laundry Detergents
13:12
21:23
8:21**
19:23
14:11
17:20
Oatmeal
36:2
17:20
41:3
21:21
26:8
19:21
Paper Towels
19:12
26:8
16:15
22:16
9:16
23:12
Refrigerated Juices
20:7
26:16
18:15
25:17
19:14
22:17
22:18
Shampoos
11:13
27:16
24:11
23:18
20:13
Snack Crackers
25:11
29:12
15:21
22:20
17:20
25:19
Soaps
7:10
29:10
19:4
32:7
22:4
33:8
Soft Drinks
19:7
13:25**
20:11
14:24
15:17
16:24
Tooth Brushes
17:15
23:15
13:16
21:18
16:17
20:20
Tooth Pastes
12:11
23:17
12:21
26:15
13:20
27:12
Total (All 29 Categories
Combined)
7:4
20:20
12:12
17:23
15:11
19:22
** There are more frequent occurrences of negative asymmetry than positive asymmetry (p < .05).
The results in Table R2.6 do not support the alternative explanation that lagged adjustment
is driving our result. Specifically, with any of the six tests we did, there were three or fewer
8
For example, the ratio 13:12 for Laundry Detergents suggests that there were 13 occurrences of positive to 12
occurrences of negative asymmetries.
12 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
product categories in which there were more negative than positive asymmetry in the large, in a
statistically significant sense (z>1.65, p<0.05). Similarly, when all the 29 product categories
were combined, there was statistically equal number of positive and negative asymmetry in the
large.
However, we acknowledge that it is not clear whether this by itself is a strong test. Reverse
asymmetry in the large appears to be highly contextual and dependent on several factors. After
procuring a large amount of the product at a low cost, the retailer normally quits buying for
several periods while going through its inventory. How AAC adjusts subsequently, is a function
of a number of things including the remaining inventory, quantity purchased, and wholesale
prices when the retailer starts buying again. The hypothesized reverse asymmetry will hold if the
retailer starts buying small quantities before the forward bought inventory is largely depleted.
However, if the retailer waits till the entire inventory is depleted before restocking its entire
inventory at a higher price, then we may not see the reverse asymmetry in the large.9
In our analysis it is difficult to control for these different inventory practices. Nevertheless,
for situations where the reverse asymmetry is not predicted, i.e. where the retailer restocks at a
higher price only after depleting its forward bought inventory, it is not clear that asymmetry in
the small will be driven by forward buying. It is possible that for such products forward buying is
no longer a rival explanation for our finding of asymmetric pricing in the small. For the other
inventory practices (re-ordering in small quantities before depletion of the forward bought
inventory) on the other hand, it appears theoretically reasonable to predict reverse asymmetry in
the large simultaneously with asymmetry in the small.
We understand either can be true, and maybe it’s a combination of both practices.
Nevertheless, even if it is a combination of both practices, reverse asymmetry in the large may be
a reasonable check. Either the inventory pattern occurs often enough to be a rival explanation for
our asymmetric pricing patterns (in which case one should expect reverse asymmetry to be
prevalent) or it does not happen often enough to generate reverse asymmetry (in which case
asymmetric pricing should not be prevalent, so the rival explanation of forward buying is not a
9
We assume that the entire inventory is replenished in this case and that the prices go back up at the point of
repurchase. For certain cases, prices may not go back up to previous levels. For such smaller increases, the
prediction of reverse asymmetry holds along with that of asymmetry in the small.
13 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
problem for our theory). So, we believe, albeit not perfect, the lack of reverse asymmetric pricing
in the large is not a wholly unreasonable metric of the validity of our results.
We do not find any evidence of such reverse asymmetry in our data. In combination with
the results comparing national brands and private labels, we would like to believe this is further
corroborating evidence that our empirical results (asymmetry in the small) are not driven by
forward buying.
Changes in Manufacturer’s Pricing Policies from September 1994
The last check on the measure of wholesale price data concerns a change in the
manufacturers’ pricing policies during the sample period. Starting September 1994,
manufacturers in the Dominick’s dataset adopted retrospective discounts, whereby they offered
rebates based on sales in a specified period rather than offering a direct discount. It is not clear
how this change might affect the AAC. Earlier studies using the same dataset therefore often
restrict their sample up to September 1994 (e.g. Peltzman, 2000; page 472). To rule out that our
results may be driven by this change, we conduct an additional analysis by restricting the sample
to the period September 1989 to August 1994. We find that our central result – that of
asymmetry in the small and symmetry in the large consistently holds in this restricted sample.
Table R2.7 reports the absolute (cents) and relative (%) thresholds obtained for the preSeptember 1004 sample, while Table R2.8 reports the number of instances of positive and
negative asymmetries observed beyond the thresholds for the same sample. There are statistically
equal numbers of positive and negative asymmetries when the entire sample is considered
(p>0.05). In a category level analysis, in 40 out of 58 (i.e., 69%) instances, there are statistically
equal numbers of positive and negative asymmetries. More positive than negative asymmetry is
observed only in 8 instances out of 58 possible comparisons (13.8%). It happened for 3 product
categories in terms of absolute changes, and 5 product categories in terms of relative changes.
More negative than positive asymmetry happened in only 10 instances out of 58 possible
comparisons (17.2%). It happened for 6 product categories in terms of absolute changes, and 4
product categories in terms of relative changes. Overall therefore, our central results (asymmetry
in the small but symmetry in the large remains unchanged for the pre-September 1994 sample,
thereby ruling out the pricing policy change as a driver of our results.
14 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Table R2.7. What Might Constitute a “Small” Price Change?
Statistical Analysis of the Data by Product Category in Absolute (¢) and Relative (%) Terms
Subsample: Sept. 1989 - - August 1994
Categories
Absolute (Cents)
Relative (%)
Analgesics
26
25
Bath Soap
5
5
Bathroom Tissues
5
2
Beer
12
6
Bottled Juices
14
9
Canned Soup
14
13
Canned Tuna
3
3
Cereals
23
10
Cheeses
12
14
Cigarettes
1
1
Cookies
4
9
Crackers
3
2
Dish Detergent
7
3
Fabric Softeners
8
4
Front-end-candies
6
7
Frozen Dinners
7
3
Frozen Entrees
1
1
Frozen Juices
0
0
Grooming Products
14
9
Laundry Detergents
14
4
Oatmeal
10
7
Paper Towels
1
1
Refrigerated Juices
10
3
Shampoos
10
3
Snack Crackers
3
2
Soaps
9
11
Soft Drinks
2
3
Tooth Brushes
15
1
Tooth Pastes
10
6
Total (all 29 product
categories combined)
20
10
Below the thresholds of number of positive changes are significantly more than number of negative
changes (p<0.05).
15 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Table R2.7. Number of Positive vs. Negative Asymmetry Beyond Threshold
Subsample: Sept. 1989 - - August 1994
Absolute (Cents)
Analgesics
Relative (%)
Positive
asymmetry
Negative
asymmetry
Positive
asymmetry
Negative
asymmetry
16
13
9
11
Bath Soap
12
16
20
13
Bathroom Tissues
16
19
12*
27*
Beer
17
15
19
19
Bottled Juices
8*
21*
15
14
Canned Soup
17
9
27**
6**
Canned Tuna
17
20
19
12
Cereals
13**
3**
15
17
Cheeses
17
9
17**
5**
Cigarettes
0*
12*
1*
13*
Cookies
21
14
27**
13**
Crackers
16
20
26
15
Dish Detergent
12
17
17
19
Fabric Softeners
9*
22*
14
22
Front-end-candies
5*
21*
27**
3**
Frozen Dinners
15
22
15
16
Frozen Entrees
27
19
18
24
Frozen Juices
16
19
26
16
Grooming Products
7*
20*
8*
24*
Laundry Detergents
12
15
17
19
Oatmeal
15
8
11
13
Paper Towels
17
16
21
15
Refrigerated Juices
9*
24*
19
12
Shampoos
13
13
24
14
Snack Crackers
18
11
25
15
Soaps
22**
10**
20**
8**
Soft Drinks
27**
13**
14*
31*
Tooth Brushes
16
12
22
13
Tooth Pastes
14
17
20
16
Total (all 29 product
categories combined)
14
11
23
14
**: More positive than negative asymmetry.
*: More negative than positive asymmetry. .
(p < .05).
16 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
TECHNICAL APPENDIX – Future Extension of Model
Speculative comments regarding extending the model to n-periods
In the paper, we have shown why asymmetric adjustment of wholesale prices is a subgame
perfect equilibrium in a 2-period model. It is interesting to posit what the nature of the
equilibrium will be when we extend the game to longer time horizons. Such extension can be
done in several ways.
One way of extending the game would be to consider additional time periods. For
simplicity, we can begin with assuming no additional change in upstream costs beyond those
existing in the current model. If for example, the manufacturer was to set price for n-1 future
periods instead of just one. Since now the retailer would face a cost x in each future period, it
may allow the manufacturer to incorporate the cumulative degree of retailer’s rigidity in the price
it sets following the initial period. Knowing this, the retailer would of course set a
commensurately different initial price. The magnitude of the wholesale asymmetry |∆w*| derived
for the 2-period solution will then be modified by at least two factors – (a) the number of time
periods being considered, n, and (b) the magnitude of discount factor, δ. Taking the liberty to
speculate, it stands to reason that the magnitude of the modification will likely be some
transformation G(|∆w*|; n,δ), where ∑G/∑n›0 and ∑G/∑δ‹0. Substantively therefore, this is
unlikely to be different from the results and conclusions we draw from our simpler model. It
could be further complicated with additional changes in costs (and related uncertainty), which
will likely lead to similar results, although it is not clear how these complexities would be likely
to change the central results of the two period model.
We can also consider another model emphasizing repeated price setting games, with the
manufacturer actions being asymmetric or symmetric pricing in each period. Manufacturer
payoffs in any given period in such a game could be contingent on its historical pricing behavior.
This could be achieved in several ways, e.g. by explicitly giving the retailer the choice of
imposing penalties or even by invoking some sort of reputation mechanisms. The equilibrium
outcome is less certain here. For an infinitely repeated 2-player game, the Folk Theorem would
predict that “any combination of actions observed in any finite number of repetitions is the
unique outcome of some subgame perfect equilibrium” as long as the rate of time preference (the
discount factor) is sufficiently small and the probability that the game ends in any repetition is
17 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
sufficiently small (Rasmusen, 2002; page 112). This would suggest that asymmetric pricing
cannot be completely ruled out, yet may be only one of many possible outcomes, even when
manufacturers expect to be in a continued relationship with the retailer. Nevertheless, these
extensions are beyond the scope of our model and we can merely speculate as to the likely
outcomes of such a setup.
In this context, an observation relevant for our purposes is that there is significant
uncertainty in the duration of relationships between manufacturers and retailers. While
manufacturers and retailers often engage over long time horizons, supermarkets frequently drop
not only individual SKUs but sometimes also entire categories from their product portfolio. As
Peltzman (2000, p. 500) notes, “Occasionally (the) leading items in a category is either
introduced or replaced (within a given observation period).” Turnover in brands is also not
uncommon. Manufacturers may also change the pricing format (see Peltzman’s paper, page
500). These suggest that it may be more accurate to model the pricing game as being of a finite
duration. In that case, it is reasonable to speculate that our results will hold and asymmetry will
be an equilibrium outcome.10 Again, these conjectures are beyond the scope of the model we
currently have in the paper. However, these are certainly interesting and worthy of future
research in the area.
Conjectures aside, in the final analysis, a benefit of making the retailers forward looking in
the model is that – in equilibrium retailers are not disadvantaged by asymmetric pricing in the
small – they adjust their initial pricing decisions to reflect this economic reality. That was
another reason why this was such a valuable extension of the model.11 So it is not clear that a
richer space of punishments, relationships or prices would necessarily be of any improvement to
the retailer in this situation. The costs of price adjustment are real, and as such any solution
would have to factor them into the equilibrium.
References
Barsky, Robert, Mark Bergen, Shantanu Dutta, and Daniel Levy (2003), “What Can the Price
Gap between Branded and Generic Products Tell Us About Markups?” in Scanner Data
10
11
See the discussion in Rasmusen (2002) of the Chainstore Paradox originally explained by Selten (1978).
We thank the reviewers and editors for guiding us to explore this direction – it greatly improved the paper.
18 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
and Price Indexes, edited by R. Feenstra and M. Shapiro, National Bureau of Economic
Research, the University of Chicago Press, 165–225.
Carlton, Dennis, and Jeffrey Perloff (1994), Modern Industrial Organisation (NY, NY: Harper
Collins).
Cecchetti, Steve (1986), “The Frequency of Price Adjustment: A study of the Newsstand Prices
of Magazines,” Journal of Econometrics 31, 255–274.
Chevalier, Judith, Anil Kashyap, and Peter Rossi (2003), “Why Don’t Prices Rise During
Periods of Peak Demand? Evidence from Scanner Data,” American Economic Review
93(1), 15–37.
Chintagunta, Pradeep (2002); “Investigating Category Pricing Behavior in a Retail Chain,”
Journal of Marketing Research, v.39(2), 141-154.
Gerstner, Eitan; James D. Hess and Duncan M. Holthausen (1994); “Price Discrimination
Through a Distribution Channel: Theory and Evidence,” The American Economic
Review, v.84(5), 1437-1445.
Hoch, Stephen J., Byung Do Kim, Alan L. Montgomery and Peter E. Rossi (1995),
“Determinants of Store-Level Price Elasticity,” Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 32,
17–29.
Hoch, Steve and Shumeet Banerji (1993), “When Do Private Labels Succeed?” Sloan
Management Review 34(4), Summer, 57–67.
Levy, Daniel, Shantanu Dutta, and Mark Bergen (2002), “Heterogeneity in Price Rigidity:
Evidence from a Case Study Using Micro-Level Data,” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking 34 (1), 197–220.
Nevo, Aviv (2001), “Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry,”
Econometrica, v.69(2), 307-342.
Peltzman, Sam (2000), “Prices Rise Faster Than They Fall,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol.
108(3), 466–502.
Pesendorfer, Martin (2002); “Retail Sales: A Study of Pricing Behavior in Supermarkets,”
Journal of Business, v.75(1), 33-66.
Rasmusen, Eric (2002); Games and Information: An Introduction to Game Theory, 3rd edition;
Blackwell Publishers, Malden, MA, USA.
Selten, Reinhard (1978), “The Chain-Store Paradox,” Theory and Decision, Volume 9, 127-59.
19 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
Tellis, Gerard J. and Fred S. Zufryden (1995), “Tackling the Retailer Decision Maze: Which
Brands to Discount, How Much, When and Why?” Marketing Science, v.14(3), 271-299.
20 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
TECHNICAL APPENDIX – FIGURES
Category Level Plots of Asymmetric Wholesale Pricing
21 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
60000
Analgesics
4500
4000
3500
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
Negative
50000
Positive
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
50000
Positive
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
5
10
5000
4500
4000
3500
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
Negative
250000
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
Beer
40
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
50
Negative
Positive
0
60000
Bathroom Tissue
Bath Soap
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
250000
Bottled Juice
200000
Negative
Canned Soup
200000
Positive
150000
150000
100000
100000
50000
50000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
80000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
250000
Canned Tuna
70000
Negative
Cereals
200000
Positive
60000
50000
Negative
Positive
150000
40000
100000
30000
20000
50000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
400000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
3500
Cheeses
350000
Negative
300000
Cigarettes
3000
Positive
Negative
Positive
2500
250000
2000
200000
1500
150000
100000
1000
50000
500
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 1.1a. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by Category
22 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
120000
35000
Cookies
100000
Negative
Crackers
30000
Positive
Negative
Positive
25000
80000
20000
60000
15000
40000
10000
20000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
70000
60000
Dish Detergent
50000
Negative
Fabric Softeners
60000
Positive
Negative
Positive
50000
40000
40000
30000
30000
20000
20000
10000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
180000
160000
140000
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
70000
Front-End-Candies
Negative
Frozen Dinners
60000
Positive
Negative
Positive
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
300000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
120000
Frozen Entrees
250000
Negative
Frozen Juices
100000
Positive
200000
80000
150000
60000
100000
40000
50000
20000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
70000
Grooming Products
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
10
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
Negative
Positive
0
5
50
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
Laundry Detergents
40
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 1.1b. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by Category
23 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
50000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
35000
Oatmeal
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
Paper Towels
Positive
0
50
Negative
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
70000
120000
Refrigerated Juices
100000
Negative
Shampoos
60000
Positive
Negative
Positive
50000
80000
40000
60000
30000
40000
20000
20000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
60000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
60000
Snack Crackers
50000
Negative
Soaps
50000
Positive
40000
40000
30000
30000
20000
20000
10000
10000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
250000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
30000
Soft Drinks
200000
Negative
Toothbrushes
25000
Positive
Negative
Positive
20000
150000
15000
100000
10000
50000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
80000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
3000000
70000
Toothpastes
Negative
Total
2500000
Positive
60000
Negative
Positive
2000000
50000
40000
1500000
30000
1000000
20000
500000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 1.1c. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by Category
24 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
50000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
6000
Analgesics
Negative
Bath Soap
5000
Positive
Negative
Positive
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
25000
60000
Bathroom Tissues
50000
Beer
Negative
20000
Positive
40000
Negative
Positive
15000
30000
10000
20000
5000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
250000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
250000
Bottled Juices
200000
Negative
Canned Soup
200000
Positive
150000
150000
100000
100000
50000
50000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
200000
180000
160000
140000
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
80000
Canned Tuna
70000
Negative
Positive
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
5
400000
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Cereals
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
50
10
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
8000
Cheeses
350000
Negative
Cigarettes
7000
Positive
300000
Positive
6000
250000
5000
200000
4000
150000
3000
100000
2000
50000
1000
0
Negative
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 1.2a. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by Category
25 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
160000
Cookies
140000
50000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
Negative
Positive
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Crackers
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
80000
70000
Dish Detergents
60000
Negative
Fabric Softeners
70000
Positive
Positive
60000
50000
Negative
50000
40000
40000
30000
30000
20000
20000
10000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
80000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
80000
Front-End-Candies
70000
Negative
60000
Frozen Dinners
70000
Positive
Positive
60000
50000
50000
40000
40000
30000
30000
20000
20000
10000
10000
0
Negative
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
100000
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
300000
Frozen Entrees
250000
Negative
Positive
200000
150000
100000
50000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
Grooming Products
Positive
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
5
10
45
50
Negative
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Laundry Detergents
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
50
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Positive
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
Negative
10
Frozen Juices
0
50
70000
60000
5
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 1.2b. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by Category
26 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
50000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
35000
Oatmeal
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
Paper Towels
Positive
0
50
140000
Negative
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
70000
Refrigerated Juices
120000
Negative
Shampoos
60000
Positive
100000
50000
80000
40000
60000
30000
40000
20000
20000
10000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
100000
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
70000
Snack Crackers
Negative
Soaps
60000
Positive
Negative
Positive
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
250000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
30000
Soft Drinks
200000
Negative
Toothbrushes
25000
Positive
Negative
Positive
20000
150000
15000
100000
10000
50000
5000
0
0
0
5
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
3500000
Toothpastes
Negative
Total
3000000
Positive
Negative
Positive
2500000
2000000
1500000
1000000
500000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 1.2c. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by Category
27 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
2500
35000
Analgesics
30000
Negative
Bath Soap
2000
Positive
Negative
Positive
25000
20000
1500
15000
1000
10000
500
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
3500
30000
Bathroom Tissue
25000
Negative
Positive
Beer
3000
Negative
Positive
2500
20000
2000
15000
1500
10000
1000
5000
500
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
120000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
120000
Bottled Juice
100000
Negative
Canned Soup
100000
Positive
80000
80000
60000
60000
40000
40000
20000
20000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
120000
Canned Tuna
Negative
Cereals
100000
Positive
Negative
Positive
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
0
5
10
200000
180000
160000
140000
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
3000
Cheeses
Negative
Cigarettes
2500
Positive
Negative
Positive
2000
1500
1000
500
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 2.1a. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by Category,
Low/Zero Inflation Period
28 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
60000
Cookies
50000
Negative
Positive
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
20000
18000
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
Crackers
Positive
0
50
Negative
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
40000
35000
Dish Detergent
30000
Negative
Positive
Fabric Softeners
35000
Positive
30000
25000
Negative
25000
20000
20000
15000
15000
10000
10000
5000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
40000
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
Front-End-Candies
Negative
Positive
35000
Frozen Dinners
Negative
Positive
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
160000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
60000
Frozen Entrees
140000
Negative
120000
Frozen Juices
50000
Positive
Negative
Positive
40000
100000
80000
30000
60000
20000
40000
10000
20000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
40000
35000
30000
Grooming
Negative
Products
Positive
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
50000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
Laundry Detergents
40
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 2.1b. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by Category,
Low/Zero Inflation Period
29 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
16000
30000
Oatmeal
14000
Negative
12000
Paper Towels
25000
Positive
Negative
Positive
20000
10000
8000
15000
6000
10000
4000
5000
2000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
35000
60000
Refrigerated Juices
50000
Negative
Positive
Shampoos
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
40000
20000
30000
15000
20000
10000
10000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
35000
30000
Snack Crackers
25000
Negative
Positive
Soaps
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
20000
20000
15000
15000
10000
10000
5000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
14000
120000
Soft Drinks
100000
Negative
Positive
Toothbrushes
12000
Negative
Positive
10000
80000
8000
60000
6000
40000
4000
20000
2000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
40000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
1600000
35000
Toothpastes
Negative
Positive
30000
Total
1400000
Positive
1200000
25000
1000000
20000
800000
15000
600000
10000
400000
5000
200000
0
Negative
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 2.1c. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by Category,
Low/Zero Inflation Period
30 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
30000
3000
Analgesics
25000
Negative
Bath Soap
2500
Positive
20000
2000
15000
1500
10000
1000
5000
500
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
14000
30000
Bathroom Tissues
25000
Negative
Positive
Beer
12000
Negative
Positive
10000
20000
8000
15000
6000
10000
4000
5000
2000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
140000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
120000
Bottled Juices
120000
Negative
Canned Soup
100000
Positive
100000
Negative
Positive
80000
80000
60000
60000
40000
40000
20000
20000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
120000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
Canned Tuna
Cereals
Negative
100000
Positive
Negative
Positive
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
250000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
6000
Cheeses
200000
Negative
Cigarettes
5000
Positive
Negative
Positive
4000
150000
3000
100000
2000
50000
1000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 2.2a. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by Category,
Low/Zero Inflation Period
31 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
30000
Cookies
Negative
Crackers
25000
Positive
Negative
Positive
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
35000
Dish Detergents
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Front-End-Candies
45
Negative
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
5
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
50
Positive
0
0
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Fabric Softeners
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
50
10
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Frozen Dinners
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
60000
180000
160000
140000
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
Frozen Entrees
Frozen Juices
Negative
50000
Positive
Negative
Positive
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
60000
35000
Grooming Products
30000
Laundry Detergents
Negative
50000
Positive
25000
Negative
Positive
40000
20000
30000
15000
20000
10000
10000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 2.2b. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by Category,
Low/Zero Inflation Period
32 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
20000
18000
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
30000
Negative
Oatmeal
Paper Towels
25000
Positive
Negative
Positive
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
80000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
35000
Refrigerated Juices
70000
Negative
Positive
60000
Shampoos
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
50000
20000
40000
15000
30000
20000
10000
10000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
40000
60000
Snack Crackers
50000
Negative
Positive
Soaps
35000
Positive
30000
40000
Negative
25000
20000
30000
15000
20000
10000
10000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
16000
120000
Negative
Soft Drinks
100000
Positive
Toothbrushes
14000
Positive
12000
80000
Negative
10000
8000
60000
6000
40000
4000
20000
2000
0
0
0
5
10
50000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Toothpastes
45
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
50
5
1800000
1600000
1400000
1200000
1000000
800000
600000
400000
200000
0
10
Total
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 2.2c. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by Category,
Low/Zero Inflation Period
33 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
1600
25000
Analgesics
20000
Negative
Positive
Bath Soap
1400
Negative
Positive
1200
1000
15000
800
10000
600
400
5000
200
0
0
0
5
10
20000
18000
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
2500
Bathroom Tissue
Negative
Beer
2000
Positive
Negative
Positive
1500
1000
500
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
80000
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
Bottled Juice
Negative
Positive
Canned Soup
70000
Negative
Positive
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
80000
30000
Canned Tuna
25000
Negative
Positive
Cereals
70000
Positive
60000
20000
Negative
50000
40000
15000
30000
10000
20000
5000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
50
140000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
1400
Cheeses
120000
Negative
Positive
100000
1000
80000
800
60000
600
40000
400
20000
200
0
Cigarettes
1200
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 3.1a. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by
Category, Deflation Period 34 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
40000
16000
Cookies
35000
Negative
Positive
30000
Crackers
14000
Positive
12000
25000
10000
20000
8000
15000
6000
10000
4000
5000
2000
0
Negative
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
25000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
25000
Dish Detergent
20000
Negative
Fabric Softeners
20000
Positive
15000
15000
10000
10000
5000
5000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
70000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
35000
Front-End-Candies
60000
Negative
Positive
50000
25000
40000
20000
30000
15000
20000
10000
10000
5000
0
Frozen Dinners
30000
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
120000
Frozen Entrees
100000
Negative
Positive
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
10
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
Frozen Juices
40
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
50
25000
5
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
35000
20000
Grooming
Negative
Products
Positive
Laundry Detergents
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
15000
20000
10000
15000
10000
5000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 3.1b. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by
Category, Deflation Period 35 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
10000
9000
8000
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
Oatmeal
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
18000
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
50
40000
Paper Towels
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
25000
Refrigerated Juices
35000
Negative
30000
Shampoos
20000
Positive
25000
Negative
Positive
15000
20000
10000
15000
10000
5000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
25000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
25000
Snack Crackers
20000
Negative
Soaps
20000
Positive
15000
15000
10000
10000
5000
5000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
80000
Soft Drinks
70000
Negative
Positive
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
0
10
9000
8000
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
50
30000
5
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
Toothbrushes
40
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
1200000
Toothpastes
25000
Negative
Total
1000000
Positive
20000
800000
15000
600000
10000
400000
5000
200000
0
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35
Price Change in Cents
40
45
50
Figure 3.1c. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Cents by
Category, Deflation Period 36 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
18000
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
Analgesics
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
20000
Negative
Positive
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
Bath Soap
5
9000
8000
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
50
Negative
Positive
0
50
25000
Bathroom Tissues
2000
1800
1600
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Beer
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
80000
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
Bottled Juices
Negative
Positive
Canned Soup
70000
Negative
Positive
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
80000
30000
Canned Tuna
25000
Negative
Positive
Negative
Cereals
70000
Positive
60000
20000
50000
15000
40000
30000
10000
20000
5000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
160000
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
2500
Cheeses
140000
Positive
120000
Cigarettes
Negative
2000
100000
Negative
Positive
1500
80000
1000
60000
40000
500
20000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 3.2a. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by
Category, Deflation Period 37 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
70000
25000
Cookies
60000
Negative
Positive
Crackers
20000
Negative
Positive
50000
40000
15000
30000
10000
20000
5000
10000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
25000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
30000
Dish Detergents
20000
Negative
Fabric Softeners
25000
Positive
Negative
Positive
20000
15000
15000
10000
10000
5000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
35000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
35000
Front-End-Candies
30000
Negative
Positive
25000
25000
20000
20000
15000
15000
10000
10000
5000
5000
0
Frozen Dinners
30000
Negative
Positive
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
40000
120000
Frozen Entrees
100000
Negative
Positive
Frozen Juices
35000
Positive
30000
80000
25000
60000
20000
Negative
15000
40000
10000
20000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
50
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
40000
25000
Grooming Products
20000
Negative
Positive
Laundry Detergents
35000
Negative
Positive
30000
25000
15000
20000
10000
15000
10000
5000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 3.2b. Frequency of Positive and Negative Retail Wholesale Changes in Percents by
Category, Deflation Period 38 of 39
Technical Appendix
Wholesale Price Asymmetry (Ray, Chen, Bergen, Levy)
12000
Negative
Oatmeal
10000
Positive
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
0
5
50000
45000
40000
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
20000
18000
16000
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
Paper Towels
Positive
0
50
Negative
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
25000
Refrigerated Juices
Negative
Shampoos
20000
Positive
Negative
Positive
15000
10000
5000
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
40000
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
25000
Snack Crackers
35000
Negative
30000
Soaps
20000
Positive
25000
Negative
Positive
15000
20000
10000
15000
10000
5000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
90000
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Soft Drinks
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
0
10000
9000
8000
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
Toothbrushes
45
50
Negative
Positive
0
50
35000
5
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
1200000
Toothpastes
30000
Negative
Total
1000000
Positive
25000
Negative
Positive
800000
20000
600000
15000
400000
10000
200000
5000
0
0
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
0
5
10
15 20 25 30 35 40
Price Change in Percents
45
50
Figure 3.2c. Frequency of Positive and Negative Wholesale Price Changes in Percents by
Category, Deflation Period 39 of 39
Technical Appendix
Bar-Ilan University
Department of Economics
WORKING PAPERS
1-01
The Optimal Size for a Minority
Hillel Rapoport and Avi Weiss, January 2001.
2-01
An Application of a Switching Regimes Regression to the Study
of Urban Structure
Gershon Alperovich and Joseph Deutsch, January 2001.
3-01
The Kuznets Curve and the Impact of Various Income Sources on the
Link Between Inequality and Development
Joseph Deutsch and Jacques Silber, February 2001.
4-01
International Asset Allocation: A New Perspective
Abraham Lioui and Patrice Poncet, February 2001.
5-01
מודל המועדון והקהילה החרדית
.2001 פברואר,יעקב רוזנברג
6-01
Multi-Generation Model of Immigrant Earnings: Theory and Application
Gil S. Epstein and Tikva Lecker, February 2001.
7-01
Shattered Rails, Ruined Credit: Financial Fragility and Railroad
Operations in the Great Depression
Daniel A.Schiffman, February 2001.
8-01
Cooperation and Competition in a Duopoly R&D Market
Damiano Bruno Silipo and Avi Weiss, March 2001.
9-01
A Theory of Immigration Amnesties
Gil S. Epstein and Avi Weiss, April 2001.
10-01 Dynamic Asset Pricing With Non-Redundant Forwards
Abraham Lioui and Patrice Poncet, May 2001.
Electronic versions of the papers are available at
http://www.biu.ac.il/soc/ec/wp/working_papers.html
11-01 Macroeconomic and Labor Market Impact of Russian Immigration in
Israel
Sarit Cohen and Chang-Tai Hsieh, May 2001.
12-01 Network Topology and the Efficiency of Equilibrium
Igal Milchtaich, June 2001.
13-01 General Equilibrium Pricing of Trading Strategy Risk
Abraham Lioui and Patrice Poncet, July 2001.
14-01 Social Conformity and Child Labor
Shirit Katav-Herz, July 2001.
15-01 Determinants of Railroad Capital Structure, 1830–1885
Daniel A. Schiffman, July 2001.
16-01 Political-Legal Institutions and the Railroad Financing Mix, 1885–1929
Daniel A. Schiffman, September 2001.
17-01 Macroeconomic Instability, Migration, and the Option Value
of Education
Eliakim Katz and Hillel Rapoport, October 2001.
18-01 Property Rights, Theft, and Efficiency: The Biblical Waiver of Fines in
the Case of Confessed Theft
Eliakim Katz and Jacob Rosenberg, November 2001.
19-01 Ethnic Discrimination and the Migration of Skilled Labor
Frédéric Docquier and Hillel Rapoport, December 2001.
1-02
Can Vocational Education Improve the Wages of Minorities and
Disadvantaged Groups? The Case of Israel
Shoshana Neuman and Adrian Ziderman, February 2002.
2-02
What Can the Price Gap between Branded and Private Label Products
Tell Us about Markups?
Robert Barsky, Mark Bergen, Shantanu Dutta, and Daniel Levy, March 2002.
3-02
Holiday Price Rigidity and Cost of Price Adjustment
Daniel Levy, Georg Müller, Shantanu Dutta, and Mark Bergen, March 2002.
4-02
Computation of Completely Mixed Equilibrium Payoffs
Igal Milchtaich, March 2002.
5-02
Coordination and Critical Mass in a Network Market –
An Experimental Evaluation
Amir Etziony and Avi Weiss, March 2002.
6-02
Inviting Competition to Achieve Critical Mass
Amir Etziony and Avi Weiss, April 2002.
7-02
Credibility, Pre-Production and Inviting Competition in
a Network Market
Amir Etziony and Avi Weiss, April 2002.
8-02
Brain Drain and LDCs’ Growth: Winners and Losers
Michel Beine, Fréderic Docquier, and Hillel Rapoport, April 2002.
9-02
Heterogeneity in Price Rigidity: Evidence from a Case Study Using
Micro-Level Data
Daniel Levy, Shantanu Dutta, and Mark Bergen, April 2002.
10-02 Price Flexibility in Channels of Distribution: Evidence from Scanner Data
Shantanu Dutta, Mark Bergen, and Daniel Levy, April 2002.
11-02 Acquired Cooperation in Finite-Horizon Dynamic Games
Igal Milchtaich and Avi Weiss, April 2002.
12-02 Cointegration in Frequency Domain
Daniel Levy, May 2002.
13-02 Which Voting Rules Elicit Informative Voting?
Ruth Ben-Yashar and Igal Milchtaich, May 2002.
14-02 Fertility, Non-Altruism and Economic Growth:
Industrialization in the Nineteenth Century
Elise S. Brezis, October 2002.
15-02 Changes in the Recruitment and Education of the Power Elites
in Twentieth Century Western Democracies
Elise S. Brezis and François Crouzet, November 2002.
16-02 On the Typical Spectral Shape of an Economic Variable
Daniel Levy and Hashem Dezhbakhsh, December 2002.
17-02 International Evidence on Output Fluctuation and Shock Persistence
Daniel Levy and Hashem Dezhbakhsh, December 2002.
1-03
Topological Conditions for Uniqueness of Equilibrium in Networks
Igal Milchtaich, March 2003.
2-03
Is the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle Really a Puzzle?
Daniel Levy, June 2003.
3-03
Growth and Convergence across the US: Evidence from County-Level
Data
Matthew Higgins, Daniel Levy, and Andrew Young, June 2003.
4-03
Economic Growth and Endogenous Intergenerational Altruism
Hillel Rapoport and Jean-Pierre Vidal, June 2003.
5-03
Remittances and Inequality: A Dynamic Migration Model
Frédéric Docquier and Hillel Rapoport, June 2003.
6-03
Sigma Convergence Versus Beta Convergence: Evidence from U.S.
County-Level Data
Andrew T. Young, Matthew J. Higgins, and Daniel Levy, September 2003.
7-03
Managerial and Customer Costs of Price Adjustment: Direct Evidence
from Industrial Markets
Mark J. Zbaracki, Mark Ritson, Daniel Levy, Shantanu Dutta, and
Mark Bergen, September 2003.
8-03
First and Second Best Voting Rules in Committees
Ruth Ben-Yashar and Igal Milchtaich, October 2003.
9-03
Shattering the Myth of Costless Price Changes: Emerging Perspectives
on Dynamic Pricing
Mark Bergen, Shantanu Dutta, Daniel Levy, Mark Ritson, and
Mark J. Zbaracki, November 2003.
1-04
Heterogeneity in Convergence Rates and Income Determination across
U.S. States: Evidence from County-Level Data
Andrew T. Young, Matthew J. Higgins, and Daniel Levy, January 2004.
2-04
"The Real Thing:" Nominal Price Rigidity of the Nickel Coke, 1886-1959
Daniel Levy and Andrew T. Young, February 2004.
3-04
Network Effects and the Dynamics of Migration and Inequality: Theory
and Evidence from Mexico
David Mckenzie and Hillel Rapoport, March 2004.
4-04
Migration Selectivity and the Evolution of Spatial Inequality
Ravi Kanbur and Hillel Rapoport, March 2004.
5-04
Many Types of Human Capital and Many Roles in U.S. Growth: Evidence
from County-Level Educational Attainment Data
Andrew T. Young, Daniel Levy and Matthew J. Higgins, March 2004.
6-04
When Little Things Mean a Lot: On the Inefficiency of Item Pricing Laws
Mark Bergen, Daniel Levy, Sourav Ray, Paul H. Rubin and Benjamin Zeliger,
May 2004.
7-04
Comparative Statics of Altruism and Spite
Igal Milchtaich, June 2004.
8-04
Asymmetric Price Adjustment in the Small: An Implication of Rational
Inattention
Daniel Levy, Haipeng (Allan) Chen, Sourav Ray and Mark Bergen, July 2004.
1-05
Private Label Price Rigidity during Holiday Periods
Georg Müller, Mark Bergen, Shantanu Dutta and Daniel Levy, March 2005.
2-05
Asymmetric Wholesale Pricing: Theory and Evidence
Sourav Ray, Haipeng (Allan) Chen, Mark Bergen and Daniel Levy,
March 2005.