ISSN 1518-3548
Working Paper Series
Delegated Portfolio Management
Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak
December, 2002
ISSN 1518-3548
CGC 00.038.166/0001-05
Working Paper Series
Brasília
n. 60
Dec
2002
P. 1-22
Working Paper Series
Edited by:
Research Department (Depep)
(E-mail: workingpaper@bcb.gov.br)
Reproduction permitted only if source is stated as follows: Working Paper Series n. 60
Authorized by Ilan Goldfajn (Deputy Governor for Economic Policy).
General Control of Subscription:
Banco Central do Brasil
Demap/Disud/Subip
SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B – Edifício-Sede – 2º subsolo
70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil
Phone: (5561) 414-1392
Fax: (5561) 414-3165
The views expressed in this work are those of the authors and do not reflect those of the Banco Central or its members.
Although these Working Papers often represent preliminary work, citation of source is required when used or reproduced.
As opiniões expressas neste trabalho são exclusivamente do(s) autor(es) e não refletem a visão do Banco Central do Brasil.
Ainda que este artigo represente trabalho preliminar, citação da fonte é requerida mesmo quando reproduzido parcialmente.
Banco Central do Brasil Information Bureau
Address:
Secre/Surel/Diate
SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B
Edifício-Sede – 2º subsolo
70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil
Phones:
(5561) 414 (....) 2401, 2402, 2403, 2404, 2405, 2406
DDG:
0800 992345
Fax:
(5561) 321-9453
Internet:
http://www.bcb.gov.br
E-mails:
cap.secre@bcb.gov.br
dinfo.secre@bcb.gov.br
Delegated Portfolio Management
Paulo Coutinho*
Benjamin Miranda Tabak**
Abstract
In this paper, we examine optimal portfolio decisions within a decentralized
framework. There are many portfolio managers choosing optimal portfolio
weights in a mean-variance framework and taking decisions in a
decentralized way. However, the overall portfolio may not be efficient, as
the portfolio managers do not take into account the overall covariance
matrix. We show that the initial endowment that portfolio managers can use
within the firm in order to manage their portfolios can be used as a control
variable by the top administration and redistributed within the firm in order
to achieve overall efficiency.
Keywords: Optimal Portfolio, Decentralized, Efficient Frontier, Portfolio
Management.
* Economics Department, Universidade de Brasília. E-mail address: coutinho@unb.br
** Research Department, Central Bank of Brazil. E-mail address: benjamin.tabak@bcb.gov.br
3
1.
Introduction
One of the main tasks of portfolio managers is to achieve the best possible trade-off
between risk and return. This task involves the determination of the best risk-return
opportunities available from feasible portfolios and the choice of the best portfolio from
this feasible set. However, in many situations, the portfolio is managed in a
decentralized way, with the top administration of the firm delegating to different
portfolio managers partial control about investment in subclasses of assets.
In general, the top administration of trading firms decides the amount of wealth invested
in certain asset classes. The top administration however delegates to portfolio managers
the control of which specific securities to hold and the proportions of these securities in
the portfolio.
1
The delegation process may imply in an overall inefficient portfolio. Even if all
portfolio managers are in the efficient frontier for their particular asset class it may be
the case that, in the aggregate, the resulting portfolio is an inefficient one as portfolio
managers are not taking into account the overall covariance matrix and all possible
combinations that would result in the best trade-off between risk and return.
These considerations has led us to examine which conditions should be met so that even
in a decentralized decision making set the overall portfolio would be efficient. Our
findings suggest that the initial endowment available for investing by the portfolio
managers and the risk free interest rate they face when taking investment decisions can
be used as control variables to attain overall efficiency.
Although we recognize that asymmetry of information play a crucial role in the
delegation process, in this paper, we put these considerations to concentrate in the pure
compatibility of solutions between the different portfolio managers with the overall
1
Classical articles in asset allocation choice are Tobin (1958) and Markowitz (1952, 1959).
4
solution. Bhattacharya and Pfleiderer (1985) develop a model of decentralized
investment management under asymmetric information, where they are especially
concerned about screening agents with superior information and on the surplus
extraction from the agent. Barry and Starks (1984) show that risk sharing considerations
are sufficient to motivate the use of multiple managers. Stoughton (1993) investigate the
significance of nonlinear contracts on the incentive for portfolio managers to collect
information, justifying employment of portfolio managers with the notion of superior
skills at acquiring and interpreting information related to movement in security prices.
We solve the problem of finding equivalence between decentralized and centralized
portfolio management analytically within a mean-variance framework, which provides
some insights on how to enhance the delegation process.2 Our findings suggest that it is
possible to decentralize investment decisions and construct portfolios that are still
optimal in an aggregate sense. All that is needed are some instruments to control
decisions taken by portfolio managers such as their available initial endowment and the
risk free interest rate that they face, which may be determined endogenously in our
model.
We solve a general case with many portfolio managers that are specialized in some
particular asset class (which may intersect or not in some cases), and show that the
initial endowment that portfolio managers have to invest in their portfolios can be used
by the top administration to achieve overall efficiency.
The organization of the paper is as follows. In section II, we develop the model. Section
III gives some interpretations of the results. Section IV concludes and gives directions
for further research.
2 There may be other difficulties in implementing mean-variance analysis such as the extreme weights
that may arise when sample efficient portfolios are constructed. As Genotte (1986) and Britten-Jones
(1999) noticed, there are huge estimation errors in expected returns estimation, which cannot be ignored.
However, we will not address these points in this paper.
5
2.
The model
We start with n risky assets. Let w be the n x 1 vector of portfolio weights for risky
assets, V the n x n covariance matrix, r the n x 1 expected return vector for all risky
assets, rf the risk free interest rate and rp the portfolio’s expected rate of return.
We characterize an investor’s preferences by utility curves of the following general
form:
1
1
U ( rp , σ p ) = rp − λ σ p2 = w Tr + (1 − w T 1) rf − λ w T Vw .
2
2
(1)
The first part of this utility function is the expected return of one dollar invested in the
portfolio and the second part is half of the variance of one dollar invested in the
portfolio multiplied by a scalar λ . The convenience of this utility function is that
maximizing it is equivalent to find a frontier portfolio, as we will show below. The
coefficient λ may be interpreted as a coefficient of risk aversion.3 Higher levels for
U ( ⋅, ⋅) imply in higher utility for managers and (1) shows that utility increases if the
expected return increases, and it decreases when the variance increases. The relative
magnitude of these changes is governed by λ .
An efficient portfolio is one that maximizes expected return for a given level of variance
(when there is a solution to this problem). We can represent this problem as:
max w ȉr + (1 − w T 1) rf
{w}
s.t.
(2)
1 T
w Ȉw = σ p2 .
2
The Lagrangean for this problem is:
1
l = w ȉr + (1 − w T 1) rf − λ w T Vw − σ 2p
2
.
3 However, this is not the absolute risk aversion as defined in Arrow (1970) which is given by
− U '' ( ⋅) U ' ( ⋅) .
6
(3)
where λ is a positive constant. The first order conditions are:
∂l
= r − 1rf − λ V w p = 0 ,
∂w
(4)
∂l
= rp - w Tp r − (1 − w T 1) rf = 0 .
∂λ
(5)
Observe that (3) is essentially equivalent to (1). The first order condition of (1) is
exactly (4). As V is a positive definite matrix, it follows that the first order conditions
are necessary and sufficient for a global optimum. In this case, we can solve for the
portfolio weights:
wp =
V −1 ( r − 1rf ) .
1
λ
(6)
In what follows, we will show equation (6) in a more convenient way. If we have n
risky assets, the covariance matrix is:
σ 12 σ 12
2
σ 21 σ 2
V= ⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅
σ
⋅
n1
⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅
σ 1n
σ 2n
.
σ ( n−1) n
σ n2
⋅
⋅ σ n ( n −1)
Using Stevens’ (1998) direct characterization of the inverse of the covariance matrix,
we have that the inverse of the covariance matrix is given by:
1
σ 2 1 − R2
1 )
1(
β
− 2 21 2
σ 2 (1 − R2 )
V -1 =
⋅
⋅
β n1
−
2
σ (1 − R 2 )
n
n
−
β12
σ (1 − R
2
1
2
1
)
1
σ (1 − R22 )
⋅ ⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅ ⋅
⋅ ⋅
2
2
−
β n2
σ (1 − Rn2 )
2
n
7
σ (1 − R )
β
− 2 2N 2
σ 2 (1 − R2 )
.
⋅
⋅
1
σ n2 (1 − Rn2 )
⋅ ⋅ −
⋅ ⋅
β1n
2
1
2
1
(7)
where R i2 and β ij are the R-squared and the coefficient for the multiple regression of
the excess return for the k-th asset on the excess returns of all the other assets. The
factor σ 12 (1 − R12 ) is the part of the variance of the excess return for the k-th asset that
cannot be explained by the regression on the other risky excess return returns, which is
equivalent to the estimate of the variance of the residual of that regression.
Using this result, we can rewrite (6) as:
1
σ 2 1 − R2
1 )
1(
w
1
β 21
w
−
2
2 1 σ 2 (1 − R22 )
⋅ =
λ
⋅
⋅
⋅
w
n
β n1
−
σ 2 (1 − R 2 )
n
n
−
β12
σ (1 − R
2
1
2
1
)
1
2
σ 2 (1 − R22 )
⋅ ⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅ ⋅
⋅ ⋅
−
βn2
σ (1 − Rn2 )
2
n
σ (1 − R )
r1 − rf
β2N
− 2
r2 − rf
2
σ 2 (1 − R2 )
⋅
⋅
⋅
⋅
rn − rf
1
2
σ n (1 − Rn2 )
⋅ ⋅ −
⋅ ⋅
β1n
2
1
2
1
.
(8)
Letting ei = ri − rf be the excess expected return, the optimal weight for the first risky
asset is:
w1 =
n
1
β1i ei ,
−
e
∑
2
2 1
λσ 1 (1 − R1 )
i =2
(9)
and for the second risky asset is:
n
1
w2 =
e − ∑ β 2i ei .
2
2 2
λσ 2 (1 − R2 )
i =1
i≠2
(10)
In general, for a k-th risky asset we have:
n
1
wk =
ek − ∑ β ki ei .
λσ k2 (1 − Rk2 )
i =1
i≠k
8
(11)
This is the optimal solution for the top administration that takes decisions on an n risky
asset framework. It is interesting to notice that the numerator ek − ∑ β ki ei can be seen
n
i =1
i≠k
as the constant of the regression of excess return of asset k on the excess returns of the
other risky assets and the denominator σ k2 (1 − Rk2 ) is the residual variance of that
regression.
To generate the equivalence between the solution of the top administration and of the
decentralized decision made by portfolio managers, it is necessary to guarantee that
wealth allocated by the top administration is the same as the wealth allocated by
portfolio managers in each risky asset. We will now see some examples of how the
equivalence problem may be solved.
2.1
Example 1. One portfolio manager for each risky asset
Suppose that we have a k-th portfolio manager that takes decisions regarding one risky
asset, denominated asset k. Then the optimal weight for this portfolio manager would
be:
wk ,k =
rk − rf , k
λkσ k2
where λk is the coefficient of risk aversion of the k-th portfolio manager and rf ,k is the
risk free rate that he faces. The solution above shows that optimal weight in the risky
asset is inversely proportional to the risk aversion and the level of risk and directly
proportional to the risk premium offered by the risky asset.
As this portfolio manager does not take into account the overall covariance matrix there
is a small probability that this portfolio will be efficient in an overall sense. A sufficient
condition for efficiency would be that the optimal weight of the top administration
multiplied by this wealth would be equal to the portfolio manager’s optimal weight
multiplied by the portfolio manager’s initial endowment. This equivalence result may be
expressed as:
9
(12)
rk − rf ,k
λkσ k2
W0, k
n
1
=
e − ∑ β ki ei W0
2
2 k
λσ k (1 − Rk )
i≠k
i =1
(13)
We can explicitly find a risk free interest rate that would make this condition true:
rf , k
n
λ
W
1
= rk − k
−
β ki ei 0 .
e
∑
2 k
W0,k
λ (1 − Rk )
i =1
i≠k
(14)
We could solve the problem using the portfolio manager’s initial endowment instead:
W0,k
n
λ
e
1
= k
−
β ki i W0 ,
1
∑
2
λ (1 − Rk ) i =1
ek
i≠k
(15)
where we used rf , k = rf (in this case we can allow the risk free interest rate to be the
same for both the top administration and the portfolio manager). Equation (14) and (15)
must hold for all n portfolio managers for each risky asset. This implies that the risk free
interest rate or initial endowment may be different for portfolio managers.
However, in general portfolio managers do not trade on one asset but in an asset class
where there may be many assets. This motivates generalizations of the results obtained
above.
2.2
Example 2. One portfolio manager trading on two risky assets
We can assume a k-th portfolio manager that takes decisions regarding two risky, assets
1 and 2. Thus the optimal weights for this portfolio manager would be:
w1, k =
1
( e1 − β12e2 ) ,
λkσ (1 − R1,2k )
(16)
w2,k =
1
( e2 − β 21e1 ) ,
λkσ (1 − R2,2 k )
(17)
2
1
2
2
10
where w1,k and w2,k are the optimal weights for assets 1 and 2, respectively and Ri2,k is
the r-squared of the regression of excess return of the i-th risky asset on excess return of
the other risky assets managed by the portfolio manager k.
Equivalence of results can be derived using the condition that the amount invested in
each risky asset is the same. This condition for the first and second risky assets can be
written, respectively, as:
n
1
1
1
e
e
W
e
β
β1i ei W0
−
=
−
(
)
∑
1
12 2
0, k
2
2
2
2 1
λkσ 1 (1 − R1,k )
λσ 1 (1 − R1 )
i =2
n
1
1
2
e2 − ∑ β 2 i ei W0
( e2 − β 21e1 )W0,k = 2
λkσ 22 (1 − R2,2 k )
λσ 2 (1 − R22 )
i =1
≠
2
i
(18)
(19)
1
2
where W0,k
and W0,k
are the available initial endowments that portfolio manager k has
to invest in assets 1 and 2, respectively. We can find endogenously the amount of initial
endowments that the top administration must dispose to portfolio manager k by solving
(18) and (19):
W0,1 k
W0,2k
n
1
β1i ei
e
−
∑
2 1
i =2
λ (1 − R1 )
= k
W0
1
λ
(e − β e )
(1 − R1,2k ) 1 12 2
n
1
−
β 2i ei
e
∑
2 2
i =2
λ (1 − R2 )
= k
W0
1
λ
(e − β e )
(1 − R2,2 k ) 2 21 1
It is important to notice that this initial endowment depends of the risk aversion of
individual portfolio managers and the top administration.
It is interesting to notice that initial endowment available to the portfolio manager rises
as the portfolio managers are more risk averse relatively to the top administration. As
the ratio λk λ increases, more initial endowment can be disposed to portfolio manager
11
(20)
(21)
k. In general, the initial endowment disposed for portfolio manager k for a risky asset m
should be given by:
W0,mk
2.3
n
1
e − ∑ β mi ei
2 m
1 − Rm )
i =1
λk (
i≠m
W
=
0
1
λ
e
e
β
−
(
)
2
2
m
m
(1 − Rk2,m )
(22)
Example 3. Two portfolio managers trading in the same risky asset m
An interesting example to analyze would be the case where there are two portfolio
managers (k and j) trading on the same asset, say asset m. In this particular case,
equivalence could be obtained by:
wm,kW0,mk + wm , jW0,mj = wmW0 .
(23)
As there is no particular reason for the top administration to use different initial
endowments for portfolio managers, we have that W0,mk = W0,mj and (23) can be rewritten
as:
W0,mk = W0,mj
n
1
e − β e
mi i
λ (1 − R 2 ) m ∑
i =1
m
i
m
≠
W0 .
=
em em
+
λk λ j
(24)
Expression (24) could be easily generalized for any number of portfolio managers
trading on any specific risky asset. The top administration may choose to give different
initial endowments for different portfolio managers to invest in the same asset, in this
case (23) can be rewritten as:
W0,mk =
wm
wm, k
W0
12
−
wm, j
wm , k
W0,mj .
(25)
In this case the initial endowment available for portfolio manager k would depend on
the initial endowment available for portfolio manager j. We will analyze the general
case in the next subsection section.
2.4
A more general case: there are l portfolio managers and n risky assets
Suppose that we have l portfolio managers and n risky assets. Portfolio managers are
specialized in subsets m1 , m2 ,K , ml where mk corresponds to the subset that the k-th
portfolio manager trades. It is assumed that mk I m j ≠ ∅ for some k , j; k ≠ j . The
restrictions that should apply are given by:
∑w
l
1, k
W0,1 k = wW
1 0
2, k
W0,2k = w2W0
∑w
k =1
l
k =1
∑w
M
l
k =1
n,k
W0,nk = wnW0
In this case the top administration decides which assets each portfolio manager should
trade. The examples above help to understand how the top administration would solve
his problem. If there are more than one portfolio manager in a single asset then the top
administration could solve the problem as shown in example 3. If there is only one
portfolio manager in a single asset then he could solve the equivalence result as shown
in example 1. Finally, if portfolio managers trade in more than one asset, all that the top
administration has to do is to use different initial endowment for each risky asset.
3.
Interpreting the results
In this section, we do some comparative static and interpret the expressions previously
found. It would be interesting to understand what happens to portfolio managers’ initial
endowment (or the risk free interest rate) when the exogenous parameters change.
13
If we use expression (15) then the initial endowment would depend on changes in the
expected return for asset k as given below:
∂W0,k
∂rk
=
n
λk
ei
1
W
0 ∑ β ki 2 .
2
λ (1 − Rk ) i =1
ek
(26)
i≠k
The sign of this derivative is positive, reflecting the growth of interest in investing in
risky asset k by the top administration (which can be seen from (11)). We could also
answer how the wealth would change for a given portfolio manager that trades on asset
k when the expected return on asset j changes:
∂W0,k
∂rj
=−
e
λk
1
W0 β kj j
2
ek
λ (1 − Rk )
The sign of this derivative depends on the beta coefficient, i.e., in the correlation
between assets. If the correlation is negative then the top administration would increase
the initial endowment to induce an increase in investment in asset k. The increase
investment in an asset negatively correlated with the asset that improved its expected
return is due to a hedge effect. On the other hand, if correlation were positive then the
initial endowment would be reduced to reduce the risk exposure of the overall portfolio.
We can interpret expression (22), which gives the optimal initial endowment that should
be available for a portfolio manager in order to obtain the equivalence result. The initial
endowment available depends on the ratio of the risk aversion coefficients. The greater
λk the more risk averse is portfolio manager k. If this portfolio manager is more risk
averse than the top administration then he would be propense to underinvest in asset m.
In that case the top administration would increase the portfolio manager’s initial
endowment in order to induce an increase in the portfolio manager’s risk exposure.
W0,mk also depends on the ratio of the Residual Sharpe Ratios. The greater the Residual
Sharpe Ratio of the top administration relative to the Residual Sharpe Ratio of the
portfolio manager for asset m the more willing the top administration is to increase the
portfolio manager’s initial endowment in asset m. Increasing the initial endowment
would make the portfolio manager invest more in that particular asset.
14
(27)
From expression (29) we can derive an interesting relation between the initial
endowments of portfolio managers. The partial derivative of portfolio manager’s k
initial endowment for asset m with respect to the initial endowment of portfolio
manager j for asset m is:
∂W0,mk
∂W
m
0, j
=−
wm , j
wm ,k
mk
1
e − β e
∑
m
mi i
1 − Rm2 ,k )
i =1
λj (
i
m
≠
=−
λk
mj
1
e − β e
mi i
i =1
(1 − Rm2 , j ) m ∑
i≠m
This expression gives us the rate at which the top administration would decrease
(increase) portfolio manager k initial endowment after increasing (decreasing) portfolio
manager j initial endowment. This trading rate is dependent on the risk aversion
coefficients ratio and the Residual Sharpe Ratio Coefficients.
4.
Conclusions
In general, decentralization of portfolio allocation would not generate an efficient global
portfolio as decentralized decisions do no take into account the overall covariance
matrix.
It is possible to use the risk free interest rate and the available initial endowment for
portfolio managers in order to generate an equivalence of portfolio allocation results and
find an efficient global portfolio. If portfolio managers trade in more than one risky
asset then the top administration could use the initial endowment available for investing
in each risky asset as a control variable to obtain the equivalence result. This means that
the top administration could redistribute the initial endowment among portfolio
managers as exogenous parameters change at the beginning of the portfolio building
process. We used here a type of second welfare theorem.
Our findings suggest that the risk free interest rate and the initial endowment used as
control variables depend on a number of parameters and on risk aversion coefficients.
This motivates further research on estimation of risk aversion coefficients. As it is
widely known these coefficients are not directly observable and to our knowledge there
15
(28)
are not many published work that estimates individual risk aversion coefficients4. This
is left for further research.
Another interesting question would be to answer what is the optimal number of
portfolio managers that a firm should have. This is a very important problem that
trading firms deal with all the time and is still an open question.
Agency considerations and the use of multi-period portfolio selection models would be
another important route to explore within decentralized investment management5.
However, our approach could be use in a dynamic framework. The top administration
must define the investment horizon for the firm and other portfolio managers and at the
end of each period he would coordinate and redistribute initial endowment among
portfolio managers. Nonetheless, this extension raises the question of how well portfolio
managers would have performed within the investment horizon period and this would
lead to asymmetric information considerations among portfolio managers as well.
There are many open questions yet. As the literature on this theme is almost
nonexistent, we answered very simple questions. This is a first step, yet important,
towards an understanding of how delegation of portfolios can be made without loosing
overall efficiency. However, there are many questions to be made and answered. They
are left for further research.
4 Sharpe et alli (1999) derive the risk tolerance for an investor using the equation for an indifference
curve of an investor having constant risk tolerance. Their solution depends of the optimal weights given
by managers for risky assets, on the variance and expected excess return of the portfolio.
5 Sharpe (1981) analyzes decentralized investment management in a different framework. Konno and
Yamazaki (1992), Porter (1973), Pyle and Turnovsky (1970), Roy (1952) and Pye (1972) analyze
different approaches to the mean-variance portfolio criteria such as the safety-first and stochastic
dominance criteria.
16
References
Alexander, G. 1977. The derivation of efficient sets. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 11: 817-830.
Arrow, K. 1970. Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Barry, C.B., Starks, L.T. 1984. Investment Managers and risk sharing with multiple
managers. Journal of Finance, 39: 477-491.
Bhattacharya, S., Pfleiderer, P. 1985. Delegated portfolio management, Journal of
Economic Theory, 36: 1-25.
Britten-Jones, M. 1999. The sampling error in estimates of mean-variance efficient
portfolio weights. Journal of Finance, 54: 655-671.
Elton, E.J., Gruber, M.J. 1995. Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. New
York: John Wiley & Sons.
Elton, E.J., Gruber, M. J., Padberg, M.W. 1976. Simple criteria for optimal portfolio
selection. Journal of Finance, 11: 1341-1357.
Elton, E.J., Gruber, M. J., Padberg, M.W. 1978. Simple criteria for optimal portfolio
selection: tracing out the efficient frontier. Journal of Finance, 14: 296-302.
Genotte, G. 1986. Optimal portfolio choice under incomplete information. Journal of
Finance, 41: 733-749.
Huang, C., Litzenberger, R.H. 1988. Foundations for Financial Economics. New York:
Elsevier Science Publishing Co.
Konno, H., Yamazaki, H. 1992. Mean absolute deviation portfolio optimization and it’s
applications to Tokyo stock market. Management Science, 39: 519-531.
Markowitz, H. 1952. Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance, 7: 77-91.
Markowitz, H. 1959. Portfolio selection: efficient diversification of investments. New
York: John Wiley & Sons.
Porter, B. 1973. An empirical comparison of stochastic dominance and mean-variance
portfolio choice criteria. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8: 567608.
Pye, G. 1972. Minimax Portfolio choices. Financial Analyst Journal, 28: 56-60.
Pyle, D., Turnovsky, S. 1970. Safety-first and expected utility maximization in meanstandard deviation portfolio analysis. Review of Economic and Statistics, 52: 7581.
Roy, A.D. 1952. Safety-first and the holding of assets. Econometrics, 20: 431-449.
17
Stevens, G.V.G. 1998. On the Inverse of the covariance matrix in portfolio analysis.
Journal of Finance, 53: 1821-1827.
Sharpe, W. F. 1981. Decentralized investment management. Journal of Finance, 36:
217-234.
Sharpe, W.F.,Alexander, G. J., Bailey, J. V. 1999. Investments. New Jersey: Prentice
Hall.
Stoughton, N.M. 1993. Moral hazard and the portfolio management problem. Journal of
Finance, 48: 2009-2028.
Tobin, J. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. Review of Economic
Studies, 25: 65-86.
18
Banco Central do Brasil
Trabalhos para Discussão
Os Trabalhos para Discussão podem ser acessados na internet, no formato PDF,
no endereço: http://www.bc.gov.br
Working Paper Series
Working Papers in PDF format can be downloaded from: http://www.bc.gov.br
July/2000
1
Implementing Inflation Targeting in Brazil
Joel Bogdanski, Alexandre Antonio Tombini and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa
Werlang
2
Política Monetária e Supervisão do Sistema Financeiro Nacional no
Banco Central do Brasil
Eduardo Lundberg
Jul/2000
Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision Functions on the Central
Bank
Eduardo Lundberg
July/2000
3
Private Sector Participation: a Theoretical Justification of the Brazilian
Position
Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang
July/2000
4
An Information Theory Approach to the Aggregation of Log-Linear
Models
Pedro H. Albuquerque
July/2000
5
The Pass-Through from Depreciation to Inflation: a Panel Study
Ilan Goldfajn and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang
July/2000
6
Optimal Interest Rate Rules in Inflation Targeting Frameworks
José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto, Fabio Araújo and Marta Baltar J. Moreira
July/2000
7
Leading Indicators of Inflation for Brazil
Marcelle Chauvet
Set/2000
8
The Correlation Matrix of the Brazilian Central Bank’s Standard
Model for Interest Rate Market Risk
José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto
Set/2000
9
Estimating Exchange Market Pressure and Intervention Activity
Emanuel-Werner Kohlscheen
Nov/2000
10
Análise do Financiamento Externo a uma Pequena Economia
Aplicação da Teoria do Prêmio Monetário ao Caso Brasileiro: 1991–1998
Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior
Mar/2001
11
A Note on the Efficient Estimation of Inflation in Brazil
Michael F. Bryan and Stephen G. Cecchetti
Mar/2001
12
A Test of Competition in Brazilian Banking
Márcio I. Nakane
Mar/2001
19
13
Modelos de Previsão de Insolvência Bancária no Brasil
Marcio Magalhães Janot
Mar/2001
14
Evaluating Core Inflation Measures for Brazil
Francisco Marcos Rodrigues Figueiredo
Mar/2001
15
Is It Worth Tracking Dollar/Real Implied Volatility?
Sandro Canesso de Andrade and Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Mar/2001
16
Avaliação das Projeções do Modelo Estrutural do Banco Central do
Brasil Para a Taxa de Variação do IPCA
Sergio Afonso Lago Alves
Mar/2001
Evaluation of the Central Bank of Brazil Structural Model’s Inflation
Forecasts in an Inflation Targeting Framework
Sergio Afonso Lago Alves
July/2001
Estimando o Produto Potencial Brasileiro: uma Abordagem de Função
de Produção
Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho
Abr/2001
Estimating Brazilian Potential Output: a Production Function
Approach
Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho
Aug/2002
18
A Simple Model for Inflation Targeting in Brazil
Paulo Springer de Freitas and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Apr/2001
19
Uncovered Interest Parity with Fundamentals: a Brazilian Exchange
Rate Forecast Model
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Paulo Springer de Freitas and Fabio Araújo
May/2001
20
Credit Channel without the LM Curve
Victorio Y. T. Chu and Márcio I. Nakane
May/2001
21
Os Impactos Econômicos da CPMF: Teoria e Evidência
Pedro H. Albuquerque
22
Decentralized Portfolio Management
Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak
23
Os Efeitos da CPMF sobre a Intermediação Financeira
Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio I. Nakane
24
Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Shocks, Backward-Looking Prices, and
IMF Conditionality
Joel Bogdanski, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and
Alexandre Antonio Tombini
Aug/2001
25
Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Reviewing Two Years of Monetary Policy
1999/00
Pedro Fachada
Aug/2001
26
Inflation Targeting in an Open Financially Integrated Emerging
Economy: the Case of Brazil
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Aug/2001
27
Complementaridade e Fungibilidade dos Fluxos de Capitais
Internacionais
Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior
Set/2001
17
20
Jun/2001
June/2001
Jul/2001
28
Regras Monetárias e Dinâmica Macroeconômica no Brasil: uma
Abordagem de Expectativas Racionais
Marco Antonio Bonomo e Ricardo D. Brito
Nov/2001
29
Using a Money Demand Model to Evaluate Monetary Policies in Brazil
Pedro H. Albuquerque and Solange Gouvêa
Nov/2001
30
Testing the Expectations Hypothesis in the Brazilian Term Structure of
Interest Rates
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Sandro Canesso de Andrade
Nov/2001
31
Algumas Considerações sobre a Sazonalidade no IPCA
Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Roberta Blass Staub
Nov/2001
32
Crises Cambiais e Ataques Especulativos no Brasil
Mauro Costa Miranda
Nov/2001
33
Monetary Policy and Inflation in Brazil (1975-2000): a VAR Estimation
André Minella
Nov/2001
34
Constrained Discretion and Collective Action Problems: Reflections on
the Resolution of International Financial Crises
Arminio Fraga and Daniel Luiz Gleizer
Nov/2001
35
Uma Definição Operacional de Estabilidade de Preços
Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho
Dez/2001
36
Can Emerging Markets Float? Should They Inflation Target?
Barry Eichengreen
Feb/2002
37
Monetary Policy in Brazil: Remarks on the Inflation Targeting Regime,
Public Debt Management and Open Market Operations
Luiz Fernando Figueiredo, Pedro Fachada and Sérgio Goldenstein
Mar/2002
38
Volatilidade Implícita e Antecipação de Eventos de Stress: um Teste
para o Mercado Brasileiro
Frederico Pechir Gomes
Mar/2002
39
Opções sobre Dólar Comercial e Expectativas a Respeito do
Comportamento da Taxa de Câmbio
Paulo Castor de Castro
Mar/2002
40
Speculative Attacks on Debts, Dollarization and Optimum Currency
Areas
Aloisio Araujo and Márcia Leon
Abr/2002
41
Mudanças de Regime no Câmbio Brasileiro
Carlos Hamilton V. Araújo e Getúlio B. da Silveira Filho
Jun/2002
42
Modelo Estrutural com Setor Externo: Endogenização do Prêmio de
Risco e do Câmbio
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Sérgio Afonso Lago Alves e Gil Riella
Jun/2002
43
The Effects of the Brazilian ADRs Program on Domestic Market
Efficiency
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima
44
Estrutura Competitiva, Produtividade Industrial e Liberação
Comercial no Brasil
Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén
21
June/2002
Jun/2002
45
Optimal Monetary Policy, Gains from Commitment, and Inflation
Persistence
André Minella
Aug/2002
46
The Determinants of Bank Interest Spread in Brazil
Tarsila Segalla Afanasieff, Priscilla Maria Villa Lhacer and Márcio I. Nakane
Aug/2002
47
Indicadores Derivados de Agregados Monetários
Fernando de Aquino Fonseca Neto e José Albuquerque Júnior
Sep/2002
48
Should Government Smooth Exchange Rate Risk?
Ilan Goldfajn and Marcos Antonio Silveira
Sep/2002
49
Desenvolvimento do Sistema Financeiro e Crescimento Econômico no
Brasil: Evidências de Causalidade
Orlando Carneiro de Matos
Set/2002
50
Macroeconomic Coordination and Inflation Targeting in a TwoCountry Model
Eui Jung Chang, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Joanílio Rodolpho Teixeira
Sep/2002
51
Credit Channel with Sovereign Credit Risk: an Empirical Test
Victorio Yi Tson Chu
Sep/2002
52
Generalized Hyperbolic Distributions and Brazilian Data
José Fajardo and Aquiles Farias
Sep/2002
53
Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Lessons and Challenges
André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and
Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos
Nov/2002
54
Stock Returns and Volatility
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Solange Maria Guerra
Nov/2002
55
Componentes de Curto e Longo Prazo das Taxas de Juros no Brasil
Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho de
Guillén
Nov/2002
56
Causality and Cointegration in Stock Markets:
the Case of Latin America
Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima
Dec/2002
57
As Leis de Falência: uma Abordagem Econômica
Aloisio Araujo
Dez/2002
58
The Random Walk Hypothesis and the Behavior of Foreign Capital
Portfolio Flows: the Brazilian Stock Market Case
Benjamin Miranda Tabak
Dec/2002
59
Os Preços Administrados e a Inflação no Brasil
Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Thaís Porto Ferreira
Dez/2002
22