Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
The International Spectator Italian Journal of International Affairs ISSN: 0393-2729 (Print) 1751-9721 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rspe20 States versus Corporations: Rethinking the Power of Business in International Politics Milan Babic, Jan Fichtner & Eelke M. Heemskerk To cite this article: Milan Babic, Jan Fichtner & Eelke M. Heemskerk (2017) States versus Corporations: Rethinking the Power of Business in International Politics, The International Spectator, 52:4, 20-43, DOI: 10.1080/03932729.2017.1389151 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/03932729.2017.1389151 © 2017 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group Published online: 16 Nov 2017. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 12758 View Crossmark data Citing articles: 1 View citing articles Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rspe20 The InTernaTIonal SpecTaTor, 2017 Vol. 52, no. 4, 20–43 https://doi.org/10.1080/03932729.2017.1389151 OPEN ACCESS States versus Corporations: Rethinking the Power of Business in International Politics Milan Babic , Jan Fichtner and Eelke M. Heemskerk University of amsterdam ABSTRACT KEYWORDS Over 25 years ago, Susan Strange urged IR scholars to include multinational corporations in their analysis. Within IR and IPE discussions, this was either mostly ignored or reflected in an empirically and methodologically unsatisfactory way. We reiterate Strange’s call by sketching a fine-grained theoretical and empirical approach that includes both states and corporations as juxtaposed actors that interact in transnational networks inherent to the contemporary international political economy. This realistic, juxtaposed, actorand relations-centred perspective on state and corporate power in the global system is empirically illustrated by the example of the transnationalisation of state ownership. International relations; international political economy; multinational corporations; states; power [I]t seems to me that so many writers and teachers in conventional international relations are like the orthodox theologians in Galileo’s time. They are like Flat Earthers who refuse utterly to recognise that the earth is round and revolves around the sun. Similarly, they refuse to see that the relations between states is but one aspect of the international political economy, and that in that international political economy, the producers of wealth – the transnational corporations – play a key role.1 In her criticism of the state of International Relations (IR) over 25 years ago, Susan Strange directly addressed the discipline’s core questions: “What is power in the world system / international political economy? And who has it?”.2 She compellingly argued that if IR is serious about developing an answer to these fundamental questions, the discipline necessarily needs to integrate international business and its growing power into the investigation of international politics. Failure to do so not only leads to a partial and incomplete understanding of global power relations, it also gravely diminishes our ability to develop valid explanations of why we see particular outcomes of this global power play: who wins and who loses. Writing in the closing decade of the 20th century, Strange registered that the ongoing rise of big multinational corporations (MNCs) as well as similar developments, CONTACT Milan Babic m.babic@uva.nl 1 Strange, “Big Business and the State”, 246. 2 Ibid. @mbabic_1 © 2017 The author(s). published by Informa UK limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the creative commons attribution-noncommercial-noDerivatives license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited, and is not altered, transformed, or built upon in any way. THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 21 such as the emergence of a global and highly concentrated professional corporate service industry, fundamentally altered the power balance in the international political economy. Yet, Strange’s cri de coeur has left the discipline largely unaffected; the role of business as a transnational actor has remained a side phenomenon in the study of international politics. Every now and then a disturbing study underscores the ongoing importance of Strange’s critique, ranging from Naomi Klein’s No Logo, to the study by Stefania Vitali et al. showing that nearly 40 percent of the control over the economic value of MNCs in the world is held, via a complicated web of ownership relations, by a group of only 147 MNCs.3 But besides these revealing yet piecemeal contributions, the corporation has yet to emerge as a broadly accepted and systematically analysed object of research in international politics. This bias is problematic, given the sizable increase in significance and power of internationally operating corporations vis-à-vis nation states in the course of globalisation,4 as well as the fundamental role of big corporations in shaping neoliberal capitalism since the 1980s.5 The transnationalisation, or de-nationalisation, of production and finance has created new and growing opportunities for firms to shift production, participate in complex global value chains that are difficult to regulate, and circumvent state attempts to regulate and tax corporate activities. As a result, big business has developed a profound structural power position on the global scale.6 This implies a permanent transformation of the relations between state and capital,7 especially in international politics. State and corporate power are no longer exclusively exercised in the iron cage of the nation state, but in the overarching sphere of global capitalism. These recent developments in global politics are at odds with the persistent shadowy existence of the study of corporations in the disciplines of IR and International Political Economy (IPE). We therefore seek to contribute to the systematic study of corporations and corporate power in international politics by providing researchers with an updated view on global power relations research, in which corporations are taken seriously. To be clear, we do not argue that corporations are not taken seriously at all in the extant literature. In it, we see two major opposing perspectives in IR and IPE regarding the role of multinational corporations in the global system. Neither account, however, conforms to Strange’s call in a satisfactory way as both study corporate and state power as one predominating over the other. On the one hand, there is substantive work on the role of MNCs in the international state system pioneered by scholars such as Raymond Vernon or Robert Gilpin.8 This ‘classical’ IR perspective understands multinationals as subordinated to state power: at most, they influence the relations between states, but are not perceived as juxtaposed actors in the system. We see this as a dominantly state-centric view. On the other hand, scholars of transnational capitalism9 or global governance10 theorise corporate power beyond the nation state. Especially the transnational capitalism perspective considers corporate power and, with it, transnationally organized power as the primary factor in the era of globalisation.11 3 Klein, No Logo; Vitali et al., “The network of corporate control”. Brinkmann and Brinkmann, “corporate power and globalization process”. 5 crouch, The Strange Non-death of Neoliberalism, 49; carroll, Making a Transnational Capitalist Class; Van apeldoorn, Transnational Capitalism and European Integration. 6 Van apeldoorn and De Graaff, “The corporation in political Science”; Winecoff, “Structural power and the crisis”; Fuchs, Business power in global governance; Marsh and lewis, “The political power of Business”. 7 Van apeldoorn et al., “reconfiguration of the State-capital nexus”. 8 Vernon, Sovereignty at Bay; Gilpin, “pe of the Multinational corporation” and, Political Economy of International Relations. 9 For instance robinson, A Theory of Transnational Capitalism. 10 For instance May, “corporations as global governance institutions”. 11 Sklair, The Transnational Capitalist Class. 4 22 M. BABIC ET AL. State power here is limited and constrained vis-à-vis the mobility and agility of transnational capital that is detached from the old world of nation states. While state-centrism runs the risk of understating corporate power in contemporary international politics, transnational capitalism’s convincing observation that the “nation state phase of capitalism”12 is over implies that the role of states in global capitalism has ceased to be relevant to understanding global power relations. We believe that in order to advance our understanding of the role of business in international politics, we must establish a dialogue between these two perspectives. We aim to contribute to this dialogue with a set of theoretical and methodological interventions and suggestions. The three theoretical interventions we make are, first, that the study of international politics needs to be made more realistic by integrating corporate power into its analyses; second, that corporations should not be studied as subordinate, but rather as juxtaposed to states in the global system; and third, that these analyses need to be actorand relation-focused, that is, they have to incorporate agency and structural features of the global system. Our main methodological intervention is to depict these three characteristics with a network-analytical approach that can be applied to the study of large sets of different relations between state and corporate power in the global system. Our approach thus consists of three theoretical extensions and their respective empirical implementations, which can be summarized as realistic, juxtaposed, actor- and relations-centred perspectives on state and corporate power in the global system. It helps us to understand power in international politics in a specific and at the same time systematic way. We proceed as follows. The next section positions our approach as advancing and bridging the literature on corporate power in international politics. The subsequent section provides an empirical illustration of our suggested approach, highlighting a typically overlooked phenomenon in international politics: how states can potentially use state-owned enterprises not only in their domestic policies, but also (and perhaps increasingly so) as a tool of international politics. This illustrates the specific power relations arising out of the networks in which states and corporations are tied together in global capitalism, relations that are not one-dimensional but multi-faceted: states and corporations are not subordinate to each other, but juxtaposed and intertwined; they use each other to increase their respective power positions. As such, we sketch a starting point for further research on the power of business in international politics, which will hopefully lead to a better understanding of the complex power structures that shape the contemporary international political economy. State power, corporate power and international politics revisited It goes largely undisputed that states and corporations are interdependent. Corporations rely on the state for the provision of security and the enforcement of property rights in order to be able to engage in business transactions. At the same time, states also depend on corporations for the employment of their citizens and as a basis for taxation. But the role of corporations in international politics remains a neglected issue. We distinguish between two major positions that theorise and investigate the role of corporate power in the analysis of international politics: on the one hand, the state-centric view pioneered especially by Robert Gilpin and, on the other, the transnational capitalism perspective exemplified by the 12 robinson and harris, “Towards a global ruling class?”, 17. THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 23 work of William I. Robinson.13 While the state-centrists emphasize the analytical priority of the nation state, the transnational capitalism approach downgrades its relevance for the analysis of globalisation. In this sense, both positions take different stands towards Strange’s core question of who holds power in the international system. Both are of course idealtypical summaries of more differentiated accounts, but they represent the main alteration of thinking that occurred with the breakthrough of globalisation in the 1980s. We acknowledge that there are more variations and relevant positions than our idealised two: approaches like James H. Nolt’s “corporatist” re-calibration of business power within the history of IR stand somewhere between the aforementioned positions.14 But, as will become clear in the following, our primary focus is not to renew IR theory, but to bring back the relevance of MNCs in international politics. To achieve this, we provide arguments for a dialogue between two positions that analyse this phenomenon from their specific angle. Nolt – and others, like Jeffry Frieden15 – analyse the translation of business power from domestic into international politics. We, however, narrow our focus down to the core question of understanding the role of corporations as actors within global power relations from a pragmatic and constructive angle. State-centrism and the challenge of multinational corporations Exponents of the state-centric perspective provided some of the first comprehensive analyses of the role of multinationals in international politics. Coming from the postwar period of “embedded liberalism”,16 Raymond Vernon’s seminal study laid out the multifold challenges for the nation state system arising from the growth of MNCs.17 In the very state-centric postwar world, shaped by capital controls, fixed exchange rates and limited free trade agreements, the nation state was able to regulate the national economy often via corporatist arrangements as in Western Europe. This changed with the end of Bretton Woods in 1971 and major advances in information and communication technologies; the transformations in international patterns of production led to the breakup of obstacles for cross-border financial flows.18 This profound structural change enabled corporations to internationalise: the flow of foreign direct investment (FDI) doubled from 1972 to 197519 and rose to unprecedented levels in the coming decades; the transnationalisation of production accelerated and MNCs became a major force in the new era of financialised capitalism. With this change in power relations away from the nation state, Vernon proposed to understand the realm of nation states and the realm of multinationals as “two systems [...], each potentially useful to the other, yet each containing features antagonistic to the other”.20 The aim of his approach was to outline the tensions and possible solutions that accompany the relations between these “systems”. But, although they were named multinationals, the companies Vernon and other scholars theorised about were mostly a North Atlantic phenomenon: until the late 1970s, the global FDI stock was largely split 13 Gilpin, “pe of the Multinational corporation”; Gilpin, Political Economy of International Relations; robinson, Theory of Transnational Capitalism. 14 nolt, International Political Economy. 15 Frieden, “Sectoral conflict and economic policy”. 16 ruggie, ”International regimes, Transactions, and change”. 17 Vernon, Sovereignty at Bay. 18 cox, “corporate power and democracy”, 3. 19 World Bank open Data, see https://data.worldbank.org. 20 Vernon, Sovereignty at Bay, 191. 24 M. BABIC ET AL. Figure 1. State-centric perspective on state and corporate power in the international system. Sx represent states, cx corporations. The relation between states can be conflicting (as between S2 and S3), cooperative (as between S1 and S2) or neutral (as between S1 and S3). corporations can play different roles, such as being shared by S1 and S2 (c2), used by S3 against S2 (c3) or used as an asset (“national champion”) of S1 (c1). between the US, UK and the Netherlands.21 Furthermore, it was the American state that successfully managed to transform the Bretton Woods order into the subsequent structure of neoliberal globalisation.22 Consequently, IR scholars at that time pointed out that “the MNC exists as a transnational actor today because it reflects perceived national interests of the world’s dominant power, the United States”.23 The “two systems” perspective was thus nuanced by a more state-centric view of the role of the MNC, which emphasized American hegemony in combination with corporate power as the main driver of globalisation. Gilpin summarized the development as “a complex pattern of relationships among corporations, home governments, and host countries that has increasingly politicized foreign investment both at home and abroad”.24 Although recognising the potential power of the MNC, this perspective can be evaluated as redefining national sovereignty in early times of globalisation. Thus, although redefined, sovereign states remain the main actors in the international system. Figure 1 represents the state-centric idea of the international environment as dominated by the nation state. In this realist and state-centric perspective, the role that corporations play is, at the most, one that influences the relevant relations between states, which can be, broadly speaking, cooperative, conflictive or neutral. Corporations can, for instance, be used to enhance relations between two countries (S1 and S2 in Figure 1) or to promote the geopolitical interests of state S2 against state S3. Although the contributions of scholars like Gilpin and Vernon, as realist international political economists interested in the subject of rising corporate power, were early works, the state-centrism in this perspective has not changed substantially since then. “The role of actors other than states” is described by Robert Keohane in 2009 as one 21 Jones, “Multinationals from 1930s to 1980s”, 88; see also Van der pijl, An Atlantic ruling class. panitch and Gindin, The Making of Global Capitalism, 147. 23 Gilpin, “pe of the Multinational corporation”, 190. 24 Gilpin, Political Economy of International Relations, 262. 22 THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 25 of the major challenges that “IPE should come to grips with”.25 While posed as a task for the future of the discipline, there is ample evidence that this future is already here. Transnational capitalism perspective: only corporate power counts? Scholars of transnational capitalism started to reject this state-centrism in critical accounts of the changing international environment in the 1980s and 1990s. In particular, they pointed at the growing size and overall dominance of corporate actors in the global political economy. As the global FDI stocks (as a percentage of world GDP) grew exponentially after the end of the Cold War (and more than doubled by the end of the decade)26 and transnational business communities started growing closer together, the emerging new world economic order was dubbed “transnational” or “global” capitalism.27 A key driver behind this accelerated corporate internationalisation is the growing number of cross-border mergers and acquisitions (M&A). Figure 2 shows how worldwide M&A has skyrocketed from around USD 500 billion per annum in the early 1990s to peaks of nearly USD 5,000 billion in 2007 and 2015. Concomitant to the persistent trend of growing overall worldwide M&A, the share of cross-border deals has continued to increase steadily since the 1980s and is, for the first time, approaching 50 percent in 2017. This surge in M&A has Figure 2. Global mergers & acquisitions 1985-2017 (bn USD). note: Data for 2017 is for the first quarter. Source: calculations by the authors based on Institute of Mergers, acquisitions and alliances, “M&a Statistics”, https://imaa-institute.org/mergers-and-acquisitions-statistics/. 25 Keohane, “The old Ipe and new”, 34. Subramanian and Kessler, The Hyperglobalization of Trade, 40. 27 Van apeldoorn, Transnational Capitalism and European Integration ; Sklair, The Transnational Capitalist Class; robinson and harris, “Towards a global ruling class?”; robinson, A Theory of Transnational Capitalism; carroll and Fennema, “a Transnational Business community?”; carroll, Making a Transnational Capitalist Class. 26 26 M. BABIC ET AL. contributed to the development that large MNCs have become bigger than most states in terms of revenue. The transnational capitalism literature looks at this growing transnationalisation from a perspective of transnationally integrating (and contested) hegemony, which also includes transnational elites.28 The “new constitutionalism” is advanced by these transnational elites, institutionalised global governance and legal practices that are often separate from the direct influence of nation states and their electorates on a global level.29 Hence, the comparatively high mobility of capital and organisational capacity of transnational elites changes global power relations in such a way that states can no longer be seen as the only relevant actors within this structure. In addition, more governance-oriented scholars point out the role of production and wealth networks in which corporations are embedded and which define the space required for exercising corporate power.30 These views of a new power position of corporations within the historical structure of transnational capitalism emphasize the relative autonomy of the firm vis-à-vis other social forces, especially the state. Thus “much of the time, within their own networks [firms] are the primary agent of governance and not necessarily dependent on other actors or social institutions for their legitimacy”.31 Fig. 3 describes the transnational capitalism perspective. Under this umbrella, we summarize all accounts that in one way or another understand corporate power as dominating the global environment today. Besides the seminal work of Robinson,32 this also includes other critical IPE perspectives like those of Stephen Gill and A. Claire Cutler,33 class-analytical analyses like those of Leslie Sklair34 and network-oriented accounts of global corporate power.35 These perspectives emphasize the dominance of corporate power within transnational capitalism. The relevant corporate actors are more or less detached from the Figure 3. Transnational capitalism perspective on state and corporate power in the international system. Sx represent states, cx corporations. corporate power is mostly detached from the realm of international politics and is exercised upon states. relations between states (e.g. conflicting between S1 and S3) and corporations (e.g. neutral between c2 and c2, cooperative between c1 and c2) exist separately. 28 Gill and law, “hegemony and power of capital”. Gill and cutler, “new constitutionalism and world order”. 30 May, “corporations as global governance institutions”; Seabrooke and Wigan, “Governance of global wealth chains”. 31 May, Ibid., 9. 32 robinson, A Theory of Transnational Capitalism. 33 Gill and cutler, “new constitutionalism and world order”. 34 Sklair, The Transnational Capitalist Class. 35 May, “corporations as global governance institutions”; carroll, Making a Transnational Capitalist Class; Dreiling and Darves, Agents of Neoliberal Globalization; Winecoff, “Structural power and the crisis”. 29 THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 27 Table A1. The global top 100 countries and corporations. Country/Corporation 1 United States 2 china 3 Japan 4 Germany 5 France 6 United Kingdom 7 Italy 8 Brazil 9 canada 10 Walmart (US) 11 Spain 12 australia 13 State Grid (cn) 14 netherlands 15 South Korea 16 china nat. petroleum (cn) 17 Sinopec Group (cn) 18 royal Dutch Shell (nl/GB) 19 Sweden 20 exxon Mobil (US) 21 Volkswagen (De) 22 Toyota Motor (Jp) 23 apple (US) 24 Belgium 25 Bp (GB) 26 Mexico 27 Switzerland 28 Berkshire hathaway (US) 29 India 30 norway 31 McKesson (US) 32 russia 33 austria 34 Turkey 35 Samsung electronics (Kr) 36 Glencore (ch/Je) 37 IcBc (cn) 38 Daimler (De) 39 Unitedhealth Group (US) 40 Denmark 41 eXor Group (IT/nl) 42 cVS health (US) 43 General Motors (US) 44 Vitol (nl/ch) 45 Ford Motor (US) 46 china constr. Bank (cn) 47 Saudi arabia 48 aT&T (US) 49 Total (Fr) 50 hon hai precision Ind. (TW) Revenue (USD bn) 3363 2465 1696 1507 1288 996 843 632 595 482 461 421 330 323 304 299 294 272 248 246 237 237 234 232 226 224 216 211 200 200 192 187 187 184 177 170 167 166 157 157 154 153 152 152 151 150 150 147 143 141 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 Country/Corporation General electric (US) cScec (cn) amerisourceBergen (US) agricultural Bank of china (cn) Verizon (US) chevron (US) e.on (De) aXa (Fr) Indonesia Finland allianz (De) Bank of china (cn) honda Motor (Jp) cargill (US) Japan post holdings (Jp) costco (US) argentina Bnp paribas (Fr) Fannie Mae (US) ping an Insurance (cn) Kroger (US) Société Générale (Fr) amazon.com (US) china Mobile comm. (cn) SaIc Motor (cn) Walgreens Boots alliance (US) hp (US) assicurazioni Generali (IT) cardinal health (US) BMW (De) express Scripts holding (US) nissan Motor (Jp) china life Insurance (cn) J.p. Morgan chase (US) Koch Industries (US) Gazprom (rU) china railway eng. (cn) petrobras (Br) Schwarz Group (De) Trafigura Group (nl/SG) nippon Telegraph and Tel. (Jp) Boeing (US) Venezuela china railway constr. (cn) Microsoft (US) Bank of america corp. (US) enI (IT) Greece nestlé (ch) Wells Fargo (US) Revenue (USD bn) 140 139 136 133 132 131 130 129 129 128 123 122 121 120 119 116 116 112 111 110 109 108 107 106 105 104 103 103 103 102 102 102 101 101 100 99 99 97 97 97 96 96 96 95 94 93 93 93 92 90 Source: calculations by the authors based on Forbes, “Fortune Global 500 list 2017”, http://fortune.com/global500/; and cIa, “The World Factbook 2017”, https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/. 28 M. BABIC ET AL. The global top 100 countries and corporations The increasing dimensions of the largest corporations as well as their ongoing internationalisation beg the question whether large MNCs have already equalled or maybe even surpassed the size of states. For this purpose, we compare the revenues of states (mainly taxes collected) with the revenues of corporations, as suggested by Jeffrey Harrod, who argued that we should see revenues (minus profits) as a “budget” of firms in analogy to governments.67 Admittedly, this is a crude proxy for power or influence, nonetheless it is instructive to juxtapose the financial scale of states and corporations directly. Note that we do not compare the GDP of countries with the revenues of corporations, as frequently done, because using this metric would entail a significant double counting. Moreover, GDP is a very broad measure and thus only partly influenced or controlled by the state, and the measurement of GDP is quite problematic and influenced by politics.68 Therefore, it is much more cogent to compare the revenues of states and corporations. Table A.1 shows that in 2016 the global top 100 comprised 29 countries and 71 corporations. Even though corporations clearly outnumber states in this ranking, states dominate the very apex. The top nine countries all have revenues of over USD 500 billion, a magnitude which will be difficult to reach for corporations in the foreseeable future. On the other hand, it is remarkable that a company like Walmart has higher revenues than Spain or Australia, and that Apple already has greater revenues than Belgium, Mexico and Switzerland. On balance, this ranking of states and corporations shows that MNCs have become very large socio-economic organisations in their own right. This rudimentary overview and comparison of the scale on which modern corporations and states operate underscores that in many ways, states have met their equals in the largest MNCs of today. respective nation states and dominate international politics as their owners and managers are tightly interwoven with state elites. The centres of power are moved to the transnational level, where national regulations and controls are suspended or at least limited. Towards a realistic understanding of corporate and state power Proponents of both the state-centric and the transnational capital perspective have good arguments to support their particular view of contemporary power relations in the global political economy. From a state-centric view, the transnationalisation of production does not imply the end of the nation state: there is substantial evidence that (some) states, as a specific form of political organisation, can translate their power into the new era of global capitalism. Sean Starrs36 and Jan Fichtner,37 for instance, have shown how transnational capitalism led to the globalisation of American economic power rather than to its decline. And arguably, the most relevant challenge to US hegemony is not a multinational, but the Chinese state. States also remain dominant players vis-à-vis corporate actors in certain strategic sectors through sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) and state-owned enterprises (SOEs). At the same time, the arguments for the transnational capitalism perspective are that the new global constellation structurally favours corporations over states. This shift has enabled the much more flexible and agile MNCs to influence global power relations in ways that increasingly 67 harrod, “The century of the corporation”. Mügge, “Studying macroeconomic indicators as ideas”. 36 Starrs, “american economic power hasn’t Declined”. 37 Fichtner, “perpetual decline or persistent dominance?”. 68 THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 29 diminish the agency of states in international politics.38 The resulting transnational space is occupied by corporate elites, professional corporate services and transnational patterns of production, trade and ownership that exclude (nation) state power to a great extent. In sum, the globalisation process has restricted the nation state’s space for agency and increased that of the MNC. Given this, there can be no serious empirical or theoretical doubt about the change in power relations between corporate and state power in the last decades. Our approach hence acknowledges the changed, but still relevant role of nation states on the one hand, and the profound structural transformation into transnational capitalism on the other. Our basic argument is that the specific dynamics playing out within these power relations need to be understood and explained in their actual context: even though we live in a world of transnational capitalism, state power has not disappeared, but merely been transformed. Contemporary phenomena in international politics are in this sense never determined by either state or corporate power, but need to be examined as shaped by power relations between the two of them. To prove this, first, we state the theoretical considerations that propose answers to the questions of who holds power in the global system, how these actors are to be framed analytically and how they are related to each other. Second, we outline an empirical strategy to identify and analyse the power relations between these actors in different situations with regard to international politics. This results in four core elements of our approach, of which three are theoretical and one the empirical consequence of these. They are meant to bridge the discussion between the two positions and lead to our realistic, juxtaposed and actor-relations focused approach to international power politics. First, regarding the realistic element of our approach, we understand the underlying realism of state-centrist accounts as a necessary element of corporate and state power in international politics. Power, interests and hegemony are for us the prevailing motives for (structural) change in the international environment. In this sense, we adopt parts of the realists’ assumption about the nature of (international) politics. At the same time, we connect this realism to transnational capitalism’s major contribution: the delineation of corporate power. We do not assume that the reasons corporations and states are engaging in the global system are identical, but that they are both driven by motives of interest enforcement and power extension. Where these interests meet or collide is where we can analyse them as phenomena of international politics. We thus extend the realist framework to the corporation as an actor in the international environment and consequently frame our approach as a realistic perspective. Second, this realistic perspective leads to a juxtapositioning of state and corporate actors as two relevant and empirically specifiable actors for the study of the international political economy. This bridges the state-centric idea of the relevance of identifiable actors and transnational capitalism’s emphasis on corporate power in international politics. We stress that this does not imply a complete similarity of state and corporate power (they are not ‘the same’); but that the concrete (empirical) constellations in which they meet, compete or cooperate for power should be analysed without pre-determining these power relations. In this sense, this juxtaposition is dynamic: in some cases, states are able to dominate 38 For offshore finance and corporate power, see especially Zucman, The Hidden Wealth of Nations. For the role of corporate power in the european Integration process, see van apeldoorn, Transnational Capitalism. 30 M. BABIC ET AL. corporations (as with state ownership) and in others corporate power is able to prevail over states (as may be the case with offshore finance39). We thus integrate corporate power in international politics by giving it a relevant place as a juxtaposed actor and do not subordinate it automatically to state power. Third, and related to the juxtaposition factor, we draw attention to the relevance of the relations between the juxtaposed actors as crucial for the analysis. These relations together constitute networks, reveal systematic patterns of action and strategy and allow for a comprehensive analysis of global relevance. This bridges the actor focus of state-centrism with the more network oriented analyses of the transnational capitalism perspective. We thus suggest that recognising the networked character of globalised power relations in which states and corporations are embedded as actors requires a theoretical and empirical focus on these relations rather than on the isolated strategies and attributes of the single actors. Fourth, and related to the third point, we use network analysis as the main tool to analyse these power relations. By framing states and corporations as actors (realistic), using a bottom-up, data-driven approach (juxtapositioned) and depicting global power relations in networks (actor-relations focused), we propose a fine-grained, precise and empirically rich way of understanding the role of states and corporations in contemporary international politics. Network analysis, as a tool to represent empirical reality, thus comes closest to our theoretical considerations explained above. In addition, recent advances in network analytic techniques combined with rapidly emerging new and large relational datasets on state and corporate behaviour now open up new avenues for systematic, empirical research into global power relations. This can include various relations such as ownership relations, value chains, shared elite members, membership in international organisations, policy planning groups and so on. We utilise the recent coming together of large datasets on corporate ownership and new analytical methods for large-scale (network) analysis.40 The fine-grained, firm-level large-scale data we are now able to study allows us to understand global power relations systematically and comprehensively. Furthermore, this thorough empirical focus closes a methodological gap that accompanies analyses of global capitalism, namely the use of aggregated national data to explain transnational trends. With new large-scale firm-level data, we can now use a bottom-up approach that avoids the national/transnational divide and analyses the relations directly instead of indirectly using national statistics.41 With respect to the other two positions described, our approach can thus be represented as follows and as shown in Figure 4. MNCs and states are, in this sense, foci of social forces competing for power and enforcement of their interests within global capitalism. They are embedded in relations represented as networks of power that combine different features, that is, they can be ownership, elite and/or other networks. This implies breaking with the popular idea of states and ‘markets’ as opposed principles or systems in the international environment. Figure 4 represents this realistic perspective. We do not frame corporations as subordinate, but juxtaposed to states in the global system. Likewise, we understand the relations between them as varied: a 39 novel insights on the interplay between (offshore) jurisdictions and Mncs can be found in Garcia-Bernardo et al., “Uncovering offshore Financial centers”. heemskerk and Takes, “The corporate elite community Structure”; heemskerk et al., “Big Data in corporate networks”; Vitali et al., “The network of corporate control”. 41 For a discussion and application of this approach with regard to global elite formation, see heemskerk et al. “Where is the global corporate elite?”. 40 THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 31 Figure 4. a realistic perspective on state and corporate power in the international system. cx and Sx are corporate, respectively state actors that meet each other as juxtaposed in the global system. The resulting relations can be conflicting (e.g. c1 and c3), cooperative (e.g. c2, S3 and S2) or neutral. state-owned corporation C1 could be cross-border owned by state S1 and thus support the geopolitical ambitions of S1 against state S2. Likewise, state S3 could be threatened by the activities of C1 and decide to join S2 in antagonizing C1. One step further, multinational C3 could use the jurisdiction of S1 for tax avoidance, which leads to an advantage over its competitor C1 and so on. Our theoretical extensions and empirical implementations are summarized in Table 1. Taken together, the theoretical elements and their empirical implementation bridge rather separate accounts of international politics and can thus help to lay out a research agenda that recognises and places corporate power research in the realm of international politics in a comprehensive, fine-grained and empirically and theoretically powerful way. Within this framework, states and corporations can both subjugate or dominate each other in specific constellations. In the following section, we exemplify the case of state ownership and its consequences for global power relations. As we will see, these relations are not merely one-dimensional, but involve patterns of mutual dependency and domination: states can own and control firms in order to participate in global capitalism; and firms can create ties through internationalisation that have a feedback on state power. In this sense, our example is a site of inquiry, where we can observe this two-way nature of relations between state and corporate power within global politics. Table 1. our theoretical and empirical contribution for a dialogue between state centrism and corporate power research. Extension Realistic approach Juxtaposition of states and corporations Actor-relations focus Theoretical Reasoning Bringing in state-centric realism and extending it to the role of corporate power. Understanding the global environment as agency space for different actors that are not per se different in their abilities to exercise power. International actors are always related to each other and these (power) relations are instructive for the analysis. Empirical Implementation Framing both states and corporations as relevant actors within global relations. Bottom-up, data-driven approach: assumed power capacities are case-dependent and not to be determined prior to the analysis. Using a network approach and studying these networks in order to understand global power relations. 32 M. BABIC ET AL. State capitalism and the global network of transnational state-owned enterprises In recent times, different ‘emerging powers’ such as Brazil, China and Russia have been associated with a development model that embraces high degrees of corporate state ownership. Often framed as anti-free market capitalism alternatives, scholars have labelled these models as “state capitalism”, “political capitalism” or “state-led market economy”.42 At their core, these labels suggest a growth model that stands in contrast to ideal-type Western liberal economies; one that is characterised by “a variety of formal and informal cooperative relationships between various public authorities and individual companies”.43 State capitalism is typically studied from a comparative capitalism (CC) perspective that analyses particular institutional settings encompassing the formal and informal relationships between business and the state, such as high levels of state ownership, low labour protection standards and comparatively lower FDI levels.44 The main interest lies in understanding the specificities of the institutional arrangements within particular countries, in line with the varieties of capitalism literature.45 While this is certainly a valid approach, it leaves us with little understanding of the consequences of state capitalism for international politics. How can we explain global political economic dynamics; what are their forms and effects? Existing accounts discuss these questions on a rather unsystematic level. Diagnoses like the “return of statism”46 or the “end of the free market”47 warn that the rise of state capitalism has severe implications for international politics. But the rather anecdotal evidence and ambiguous concepts do not capture the specifics of these state-corporate relations and their consequences for the global political economy. This is a good example of the hiatus that remains when we do not consider corporations as a valid subject of research in IR, and when one prioritizes the national in the study of global politics. In accordance with our actor-relations approach, we suggest that labels like state capitalism be left aside and that we look at the transnationalisation of state capital in the form of state ownership of firms. This makes it possible to re-focus away from the specificities of particular national political economies (the domain of CC) to the global sphere, and hence overcome theoretical and methodological nationalism that does not allow for the research of systemic consequences. We understand both states and corporations as actors that enforce and enable the transnationalisation of capital. The translation of the geopolitical (or financial or other) interest of states in the global system can be advanced via transnational state-owned enterprises (TSOEs), but then states are dependent on the ability, performance and will of corporations (or, in fact, their managers) to do so. This is therefore not a one-way relationship and both actors are therefore juxtaposed. Utilising the recent wealth of available data on corporate ownership, we can now map SOEs comprehensively and in particular global TSOEs. With this, we are able to go beyond anecdotal evidence and develop a systematic empirical analysis of how state capitalism plays out in the global political economy. Our account serves to illustrate the benefits of 42 respectively Musacchio and lazzarini, Reinventing State Capitalism; Schwartz, “political capitalism and Wealth Funds; lambin, Rethinking the Market Economy. 43 nölke, “Introduction: Towards State capitalism 3.0”, 4. 44 nölke et al., “Implications of large emerging economies”. 45 hall and Soskice, Varieties of Capitalism; Becker, “Measuring change of capitalist varieties”. 46 Kurlantzick, State Capitalism. 47 Bremmer, The End of the Free Market. THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 33 our realistic actor-relations approach. Our findings reflect the potential structural power positions of states and corporations in the global system. We consequently do not engage in detailed discussions, whether this is an expression of actual geopolitical strategy by those actors or not. In fact, the discussion as to what extent TSOEs influence the economy of other states and are a means toward achieving geopolitical goals creates a lot of controversy.48 In order to answer this, we would need to investigate the details of this phenomenon, for example, what (sectoral) strategies states apply, which specific corporations are involved, how they behave strategically and so on. We leave this for future work. The following depiction of outgoing and incoming state investment illustrates how relations between two (or more) states can potentially be affected by the positioning and agency of the actors involved (states and corporations) in the international environment. Outward investment: which states own globally? Figure 5 presents an original snapshot of the extent of transnational state owned enterprises across the globe. We trace those corporations that are majority-owned by a state (a state is the ultimate global owner with 50 percent ownership or more) and have an operating revenue of more than zero. In this way, we make sure that the TSOEs we include are definitely under state control (which is not always the case for under 50 percent ownership), actually exist and are relevant firms with an operating revenue. For practical purposes, in our analysis of TSOEs we disregard the many differentiations between the various state ownership models. We consider all possible ownership relations, be they direct ownership, or through investment vehicles, pension funds, one or multiple state agencies, SWFs and the like. We retrieved data on corporate ownership from Bureau van Dijk’s Orbis database, which includes information on approximately 200 million firms worldwide.49 Through our approach, we were able to identify 258,215 state-owned enterprises worldwide, of which 77,921 have an operating revenue of more than zero. The large majority of SOEs operate domestically in typical sectors of public services such as utilities, healthcare and transportation. However, a sizable group of state-owned enterprises are qualitatively different as they operate in foreign countries. We were able to identify 5,994 cases of such TSOEs. A TSOE can be seen to create a direct tie from the state that owns the company to the state where the SOE is based. Both figures 5 and 6 give a visual representation of this network of 5,994 TSOE ties. Figure 5 shows the extent of cross-border state ownership globally. We can clearly identify the dominant position of China, which owns about 19.5 percent of all TSOEs (Table 2). This empirically corroborates other accounts of the role of the state in the Chinese economy and its internationalisation strategy.50 Equally, the central position of Russia (owning 9.5 percent) reflects the Russian model of state-centric economic development, including strong ownership ties to Ukraine, Turkey and Cyprus. Perhaps more strikingly, we recognise a central position of core European countries, with France owning 14.5 percent of all TSOEs, and Germany 7.7 percent. This strong position of the two core countries in Europe echoes 48 Sultan Balbuena, Internationalisation of State-owned Enterprises. https://www.bvdinfo.com/it-it/our-products/company-information/international-products/orbis. See Garcia-Bernardo and Takes, “The effects of Data Quality”, on the issue of data quality. 50 Mcnally, “china’s reemergence and the Ipe”. 49 34 M. BABIC ET AL. Figure 5. The global network of transnational state-owned enterprise by weighted outdegree. a directed edge exists if a state (sender) owns a corporation that is domiciled in another state’s territory (receiver). edges are weighted by the number of TSoes. node size is proportional to weighted outdegree. node colour (in the printed version: node layout) reflects community membership based on modularity maximization. edge colour reflects sender’s country community (not in the printed version). note: The layout is Gephi’s Geolayout, so the position of the nodes represents their geographical location. THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 35 Table 2. The top 10 global owners by weighted outdegree. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Country china France russia Germany arab emirates austria Singapore norway Finland Sweden Outdegree (weighted) 1168 870 564 461 305 197 195 162 161 134 Source: This table is based on the calculations from the analysis in Figure 5. the traditionally strong role of the state in these coordinated market economies. A closer look reveals that the majority of French and German TSOEs are focused on the transportation sector (222 ties from Germany, 360 from France). In the German case, these ties are foremost formed by Deutsche Bahn’s subsidiary, Schenker, which is also the top company in terms of operating revenue. This first mapping of cross-border state ownership already reveals that the TSOE phenomenon clearly goes beyond emerging markets and is prevalent in the industrialised West as well. Interestingly, the other two BRIC countries show comparatively low numbers. Brazil, with 0.5 percent, and India, with 0.38 percent, are far from being as dominant international owners as China and Russia. The BRIC narrative thus does not hold true for the global picture of internationalised state ownership. The set of TSOE relations binds these countries together in a global network. Obviously, some states are more connected to each other than to others and assembled in pockets or communities in this network. We used a community detection algorithm to identify those states that are more invested in each other.51 The nodes in Figures 5 and 6 are coloured52 by their community membership. The community structure again underscores China’s global dominance: the Chinese-led Asian community (colour: red53) reaches out to South America, Africa and Australia, so Chinese state ownership is geographically widely spread. As an example, China owns 5.2 percent of all TSOEs in the Anglo-American sphere of influence,54 and also reaches out to Brazil and central Europe. Another striking feature of the community structure is the focused North European group (blue55) and the far more extensive West European/African/Middle Eastern group (purple56) with Germany and France, respectively, as dominant owners. The blue group is restricted to Germany, Scandinavia, the Baltics and parts of Eastern Europe, whereas the France-dominated purple group reaches out to Africa, the Middle East, and North America. Russia (green57) is a big, but locally limited owner without relevant far-reaching ties. Similarly, the orange group entailing Austria and some central Eastern European countries forms a regionally focused community. This cluster 51 For related examples of this approach, see heemskerk and Takes, “The corporate elite community Structure”; heemskerk et al., “corporate elite after the crisis”. 52 In the printed version, the nodes have different layouts instead of colours. 53 In the printed version: grey nodes with slightly dashed border (like cn). 54 We framed the following countries as belonging to anglo-america: australia, Bermudas, canada, United Kingdom, Ireland, cayman Islands, the US and Virgin Islands. For a deeper discussion see Fichtner, “perpetual decline or persistent dominance?”. 55 In the printed version: grey nodes without border (like De). 56 In the printed version: square, grey nodes without border (like Fr). 57 In the printed version: grey nodes with strongly dashed border (like rU). 36 M. BABIC ET AL. Figure 6. The global network of transnational state-owned enterprise by weighted indegree. a directed edge exists if a state (sender) owns a corporation that is domiciled in another state’s territory (receiver). edges are weighted by the number of TSoes. node size is proportional to weighted indegree. node colour (in the printed version: node layout) reflects community membership based on modularity maximization. edge colour reflects receiver’s country community (not in the printed version). note: The layout is Gephi’s Geolayout, so the position of the nodes represents their geographical location. THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 37 Table 3. The top 10 of global state ownership target states by weighted indegree. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Country United Kingdom Germany France Ukraine australia Brazil Sweden Italy netherlands Spain Indegree (weighted) 841 476 375 346 296 262 252 235 231 207 Source: This table is based on the calculations from the analysis in Figure 6. entails the former Yugoslavian republics and thus reflects the still relevant economic ties between those countries. Inward investment: where do states own globally? Since we conceptualised TSOEs as a directed relation from one state via a corporation to another state, we can also visualise the network to underscore which states are targeted by other state-owners. In Figure 6, the node size indicates how popular a state is as a target for TSOE investments by other states. It highlights that, in general, transnational state ownership targets rather ‘safe’ jurisdictions, with European countries making up the majority in the Top 10 (Table 3), but Anglo-America also popular (the UK and Australia in the top 10, and the US 13th and Ireland 15th).58 Both Germany and France are preferred destinations of TSOEs. Besides being active transnational owners, the core European countries seem to attract state capital systematically and thus form “hubs” for transnational state investment. This is in line with recent observations that German and French policymakers show high interest and support for overseas SWF investments in their economies as a source of patient capital59 (and portfolio investment was not even included in the analysis, something that would probably have strengthened the tendency). The case of the Ukraine (5th in indegree) is mostly explained by a high number of Russian TSOEs, ranging from energy companies to banks. Other non-European countries such as Brazil also appear as a preferred destination, especially for Chinese TSOEs, which might have further implications for the BRIC perspective: what does it mean for the power relations between two members, if one is heavily invested in the other? At the beginning of 2017, the Chinese TSOE State Grid – the largest utility company worldwide and in 13th place on the largest states/corporations list (see Table A1) – took over the third largest Brazilian energy firm, CPFL. Further important Chinese overseas investments in Brazil are food giant COFCO or Sinochem Brazil. Whether these kinds of activities should be understood as enhancing economic cohesion or as a leveraged Chinese power position towards Brazil, needs to be determined in more detailed studies. 58 Fichtner, “perpetual decline or persistent dominance?”. Thatcher and Vlandas, “new sources of patient capital”. 59 38 M. BABIC ET AL. What does this mean for international politics? For the study of international politics, four major points can be derived from this explorative but systematic inward and outward state ownership analysis. First, the role of the ‘statist’ BRIC countries needs to be put into perspective, since only China and Russia appear to be seriously involved in transnationalisation through TSOEs. The notion that these countries represent a major bloc challenging the ‘Washington consensus’ free-market politics is, in this perspective, possibly overstated. Reasons for this comparatively low involvement of Brazilian and Indian TSOEs may be that, as in the case of Brazil, a large part of state participation stays under the 50 percent ownership threshold (as in the cases of the mining multinational Vale or meat producing giant JBS, with lower state stakes). Further research, incorporating different threshold ownership levels or case studies can shed more light on state transnationalisation through minority ownership investments. Second, China dominates the network with its TSOEs that are spread around the world. This includes subsidiaries of conglomerates such as the mentioned State Grid or Sinochem Group, but also acquisitions like the Italian tire manufacturer Pirelli. The strategy of stateled transnationalisation has been investigated in the case of National Oil Companies, which is closely tied to geopolitical ambitions of energy security.60 This explains only one part of the complete cross-border state ownership picture, however, which needs to be analysed further.61 Given the widespread ownership profile, we can conclude that Chinese TSOEs give China a strong base in the global environment. Third, we see that the phenomena of transnational state ownership (and its hosting) are not restricted to state capitalist countries, but are to be found in Europe. Germany and France have a strong focus on the transportation sector in their cross-border state ownership and also function as hubs for inward and outward state investment as they are the preferred targets of non-European state ownership investments (especially China and Russia). This position will be important for future discussions of the geopolitical implications of Chinese (and possibly Russian) state ownership expansion. Fourth, the preferred targets of state investment remain safe jurisdictions like European core countries and the Anglo-American sphere. This suggests that state ownership transnationalisation is strongly connected to the structure of transnational capitalism: TSOEs target the same safe havens as non-state investment. As Robinson argued for the transnationally oriented BRICS elites,62 this integration into already existing structures of global capitalism can be observed in different segments of ‘statist’ economies. From this, we can conclude that states use TSOEs to integrate into transnational capitalism, thereby creating politically relevant ties around the world. With this empirical example, we hope to have underscored that our realistic, actor-relations oriented framework helps to develop a practical, systematic, and original empirical strategy to study global power relations. States use corporations and are dependent on them to create geopolitically relevant transnational ownership ties. 60 See e.g. the contributions by De Graaff, “a global energy network?” as well as amineh and Guang, “Geopolitics of chinese oil companies”. 61 For this, see also Meunier et al., “hosting chinese investment in europe”. 62 robinson, “Transnational state and the BrIcS”. THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 39 Conclusion Susan Strange boldly condemned conventional International Relations scholars as “Flat Earthers”, who refuse to acknowledge that next to states, multinational corporations play a key role in the international political economy and hence are crucial to understanding global politics. We wholeheartedly agree with Strange’s call for bringing the corporation back to the centre of scholarly attention in the fields of IR and IPE. During the past decade, we have been confronted with numerous puzzling and unexpected events that warrant acknowledgement of the role of corporations in international politics. Obviously, the 2008 financial crisis and its causes and consequences is the most prominent of these events, but certainly not the only one. In this contribution, we have highlighted an empirical example that underscores the need for an actor-relations oriented, realistic analytical framework in which state-corporation relations are centre stage: the inward and outward movement of TSOE investment. We have argued that only a proper analytical focus on corporations as actors, embedded in global power relations, can pave the way for a systematic understanding of their (structural) power in the global system. In the study of international politics, we need to consider corporations as a social force analytically equivalent to states. We illustrated this need in our empirical example. With regard to the phenomenon of transnationalisation of state ownership, we showed how the state as an owner can use firms to build up a power potential to penetrate other sovereign economies by reaching outside its own borders. Furthermore, we saw that some insights from the CC literature, such as China’s exceptional development model and its consequences for the global economic order, can be recognised in the transnational state ownership network. The scope of this article does not allow us to delve further into these questions, but it does make it possible to ask them in a systematic way. It also allows us to show the agency potential of firms: the transnationalisation of large transnational state owners is achieved via the firms that form the ties we depicted in the inward and outwards state investment discussion. The fine-grained, actor-oriented framework that takes corporations into account can help us understand the particularities of these observations better. The example of TSOEs is, in many respects, rather arbitrary: our choice was inspired by our ongoing research agenda and interests. While we hope that some readers may be inspired to do further work on this particular issue, the aim of this contribution goes beyond the specificities of the empirical illustration. State ownership of MNCs predominantly represents one side of our argument: how states use corporations for their interests; the other side is how MNCs use states to advance their interests. Due to space constraints, we could not elaborate on this complementary perspective here, but one obvious example is offshore finance.63 This pivotal phenomenon involves both states and corporations as active and juxtaposed actors: offshore financial centres (or tax havens) have commercialised their sovereignty in order to attract financial activities from foreign private individuals and MNCs, mostly at the expense of ‘onshore’ states. MNCs utilise tax havens to minimise their global tax payments and to avoid regulation and accountability. Recent contributions have shown that using firm-level network data makes it possible to produce novel insights into the interplay between (offshore) jurisdictions and MNCs.64 63 palan et al., Tax Havens. Garcia-Bernardo et al., “Uncovering offshore Financial centers”. 64 40 M. BABIC ET AL. We see the persistent reluctance to integrate (structural) corporate power into the study of international politics as part of a broader problem. The structural power of business “languished for two decades in the less fashionable circles in contemporary political science” and as a consequence arguably developed a “labeling problem, if not a toxic brand name recognition”.65 Consequently, there is a sizable literature that investigates states versus markets, but astoundingly little scholarly work in IR and IPE that moves beyond the broad concept of markets and investigates its actors. This reflects the rather sticky “tendency to analytically prioritize the actions of policymakers over those of market participants” in explaining politico-economic phenomena.66 The bias stems, as Benjamin Braun puts it, from political economists’ limited understanding of the political sphere: ‘market participants’ such as corporations are not perceived as analytically important (or not ‘political’ enough) for political economy analysis. In response, we positioned our approach as a concrete and empirically fruitful advancement of two approaches: the state-centric and the transnational capitalism perspectives. Rather than analytically prioritizing states over corporations and policymakers over market participants, we need to acknowledge that corporations and states are juxtaposed actors in an international environment that exercise power over each other in specific spatiotemporal settings. The example we provided serves to validate this perspective and allows for original empirical strategies that can help to understand how power in the international sphere plays out in concrete terms. This initial exploration is already leading to new questions and puzzling findings. As such, we believe our approach points at a fruitful and urgent field of research. Acknowledgements The authors greatly appreciate the excellent assistance of Oumaima Majiti and the comments from Frank W. Takes and Javier Garcia-Bernardo, as well as from two anonymous reviewers. This research received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (grant no. 638946). Notes on contributors Milan Babic is PhD candidate at CORPNET, Amsterdam Institute for Social Science Research, University of Amsterdam. Jan Fichtner is postdoctoral researcher at CORPNET, Amsterdam Institute for Social Science Research, University of Amsterdam. Email: j.f.fichtner@uva.nl Twitter: @fichtner_jan Eelke M. Heemskerk is Associate Professor at CORPNET, Amsterdam Institute for Social Science Research, University of Amsterdam. Email: e.m.heemskerk@uva.nl Twitter: @UvACORPNET ORCID Milan Babic http://orcid.org/0000-0002-9179-8120 http://orcid.org/0000-0001-7675-400X Jan Fichtner http://orcid.org/0000-0001-7356-5318 Eelke M. Heemskerk 65 culpepper, “Structural power and political science”, 392, 405. Braun, “From performativity to political economy”, 258. 66 THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 41 References Amineh, M.P., and Y. Guang. “Geopolitics of Transnationalization of Chinese National Oil Companies”. Perspectives on Global Development and Technology 13, no. 5–6 (2014): 495–535. Becker, U. “Measuring change of capitalist varieties: Reflections on method, illustrations from the BRICs”. New Political Economy 18, no. 4 (2013): 503–32. Braun, B. “From performativity to political economy: index investing, ETFs and asset manager capitalism”. New Political Economy 21, no. 3 (2016): 257–73. Bremmer, I. The End of the Free Market. Who Wins the War between States and Corporations? London: Penguin Books, 2010. Brinkmann, R.L., and J.E. Brinkmann. “Corporate power and the globalization process”. International Journal of Social Economics 29, no. 9 (2002): 730–52. Carroll, W.K. The Making of a Transnational Capitalist Class. Corporate Power in the 21st Century. London/New York: Zed Books, 2010. Carroll, W.K., and M. Fennema. “Is There a Transnational Business Community?” International Sociology 17, no. 3 (2002): 393–419. Cox, R.W. “Introduction: corporate power and the threat to democracy”. In Corporate Power and Globalization in US Foreign Policy, edited by R.W. Cox: 1–10. London: Routledge, 2012. Crouch, C. The Strange Non-death of Neo-liberalism. New York: Wiley, 2011. Culpepper, P.D. “Structural power and political science in the post-crisis era”. Business & Politics 17, no. 3 (2015): 391–409. De Graaff, N. “A global energy network? The expansion and integration of non-triad national oil companies”. Global Networks 11, no. 2 (2011): 262–83. Dreiling, M.C., and D.Y. Darves. Agents of Neoliberal Globalization. Corporate Networks, State Structures and Trade Policy. Cambridge: University Press, 2016. Fichtner, J. “Perpetual decline or persistent dominance? Uncovering Anglo-America’s true structural power in global finance”. Review of International Studies 43, no. 1 (2017): 3–28. Fichtner, J. “The anatomy of the Cayman Islands offshore financial center: Anglo-America, Japan, and the role of hedge funds”. Review of International Political Economy 23, no. 6 (2016): 1034–63. Frieden, J. “Sectoral conflict and foreign economic policy, 1914–1940”. International Organization 42, no. 1 (1988): 59–90. Fuchs, D.A. Business power in global governance. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2007. Garcia-Bernardo, J., J. Fichtner, E.M. Heemskerk and F.W. Takes. “Uncovering Offshore Financial Centers: Conduits and Sinks in the Global Corporate Ownership Network”. Scientific Reports 7, article 6246 (2017). https://www.nature.com/articles/s41598-017-06322-9. Garcia-Bernardo, J., and F.W. Takes. “The Effects of Data Quality on the Analysis of Corporate Board Interlock Networks”. Working Paper, 21 December 2016. http://arxiv.org/abs/1612.01510 Gill, S., and A.C. Cutler. “New constitutionalism and world order: general introduction”. In New Constitutionalism and World Order, edited by S. Gill: 1–22. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014. Gill, S., and D. Law. “Global Hegemony and the Structural Power of Capital”. International Studies Quarterly 33, no. 4 (1989): 475–99. Gilpin, R. “Review: The Political Economy of the Multinational Corporation: Three Contrasting Perspectives”. The American Political Science Review 70, no. 1 (1976): 184–91. Gilpin, R. The Political Economy of International Relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1987. Hall, P.A., and D. Soskice. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001. Harrod, J. “The Century of the Corporation”. In Global Corporate Power, edited by C. May: 23–46. London: Lynne Rienner, 2006. Heemskerk, E.M., M. Fennema and W.K. Carroll. “The global corporate elite after the financial crisis: evidence from the transnational network of interlocking directorates”. Global Networks 16, no. 1 (2016): 68–88. 42 M. BABIC ET AL. Heemskerk, E.M., and F.W. Takes. “The Corporate Elite Community Structure of Global Capitalism”. New Political Economy 21, no. 1 (2016): 90–118. Heemskerk, E.M., F.W. Takes, J. Garcia-Bernardo, and M.J. Huijzer. “Where is the global corporate elite? A large-scale network study of local and nonlocal interlocking directorates”. Sociologica, 2 (2016): 1–31. Heemskerk, E.M., K. Young, F.W. Takes, B. Cronin, J. Garcia-Bernardo, V. Popov, K.W. Winecoff, L.F. Henriksen, A. Laurin-Lamothe. “The Promise and Perils of Using Big Data in the Study of Corporate Networks: Problems, Diagnostics and Fixes”. Global Networks, forthcoming. Jones, G. “Multinationals from the 1930s to the 1980s”. In Leviathans: Multinational Corporations and the New Global History, edited by A.D. Chandler and B. Mazlish: 81–104. Cambridge: University Press, 2005. Klein, N. No Logo. Taking Aim at the Brand Bullies. New York: Picador, 2000. Keohane, R. “The old IPE and the new”. Review of International Political Economy 16, no. 1 (2009): 34–46. Kurlantzick, J. State Capitalism. Oxford: University Press, 2016. Lambin, J.-J. Rethinking the Market Economy. New Challenges, New Ideas, New Opportunities. Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan, 2014. Marsh, D., and C. Lewis. “The Political Power of Big Business: A Response to Bell and Hindmoor”. New Political Economy 19, no. 4 (2014): 628–33. May, C. “Who’s in charge? Corporations as institutions of global governance”. Palgrave Communications 1 (2015): 1–10. McNally, C.A. “Sino-Capitalism: China’s Reemergence and the International Political Economy”. World Politics 64, no. 4 (2012): 741–76. Meunier, S., B. Burgoon, and W. Jacoby. “The politics of hosting Chinese investment in Europe – an introduction”. Asia Europe Journal 12, no. 1–2 (2014): 109–26. Musacchio, A., and S.G. Lazzarini. Reinventing State Capitalism. Leviathan in Business, Brazil and Beyond. Harvard: University Press, 2014. Mügge, D. “Studying macroeconomic indicators as powerful ideas”. Journal of European Public Policy 23, no. 3 (2016): 410–27. Nolt, J. International Political Economy: The Business of War and Peace. New York: Routledge, 2015. Nölke, A. “Introduction: Toward State Capitalism 3.0”. In Multinational Corporations from Emerging Markets. State Capitalism 3.0, edited by A. Nölke: 1–14. London/New York: Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan, 2014. Nölke, A., T. ten Brink, S. Claar and C. May. “Domestic structures, foreign economic policies and global economic order: Implications from the rise of large emerging economies”. European Journal of International Relations 21, no. 3 (2015): 1–30. Palan, R. “Tax Havens and the Commercialization of State Sovereignty”. International Organization 56, no. 1 (Winter, 2002): 151–76. Panitch, L., and S. Gindin. The Making of Global Capitalism. The Political Economy of American Empire. London: Verso, 2013. Robinson, W.I. A Theory of Transnational Capitalism. Production, Class, and State in a Transnational World. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press, 2004. Robinson, W.I. “The transnational state and the BRICS: a global capitalism perspective”. Third World Quarterly 36, no. 1 (2015): 1–21. Robinson, W.I., and J. Harris. “Towards a global ruling class? Globalization and the transnational capitalist class”. Science & Society 64, no. 1 (2000): 11–54. Ruggie, J.R. “International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order”. International Organization 36, no. 2 (1982): 379–415. Schwartz, H. “Political Capitalism and the Rise of Sovereign Wealth Funds”. Globalizations 9, no. 4 (2012): 517–30. Seabrooke, L., and D. Wigan. “The governance of global wealth chains”. Review of International Political Economy 24, no. 1 (2017): 1–29. Sklair, L. The Transnational Capitalist Class. New York: Wiley, 2001. THE INTERNATIONAL SPECTATOR 43 Starrs, S.K. “American Economic Power Hasn’t Declined – It Globalized! Summoning the Data and Taking Globalization Seriously”. International Studies Quarterly 57, no. 4 (2013): 817–30. Strange, S. “Big Business and the State”. Millennium Journal of International Studies 20, no. 2 (1991): 245–50. Subramanian, A., and M. Kessler. The Hyperglobalization of Trade and its Future. Working Paper Series WP 13-6. Washington DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics, 2013. Sultan Balbuena, S. Concerns Related to the Internationalisation of State-Owned Enterprises: Perspectives from regulators, government owners and the broader business community, OECD Corporate Governance Working Papers, no. 19. Paris: OECD Publishing, 2016. https://doi. org/10.1787/5jm0xvx0b223-en. Thatcher, M., and T. Vlandas. “Overseas state outsiders as new sources of patient capital: Government policies to welcome Sovereign Wealth Fund investment in France and Germany”. Socio-Economic Review 14, no. 4 (2016): 647–68. Van Apeldoorn, B. Transnational Capitalism and the Struggle over European Integration. London/ New York: Routledge, 2002. Van Apeldoorn, B. and N. de Graaff. “The Corporation in Political Science”. In The Corporation. A Critical, Multi-Disciplinary Handbook, edited by G. Baars and A. Spicer: 134–59. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2017. Van Apeldoorn, B., N. de Graaff and H. Overbeek. “The Reconfiguration of the Global State-Capital Nexus”. Globalizations 9, no. 4 (2012): 471–86. Van der Pijl, K. The making of an Atlantic ruling class. London: Verso, 2012 [1984]. Vernon, R. Sovereignty at Bay. The Multinational Spread of US Enterprises. London: Penguin, 1971. Vitali, S., J.B. Glattfelder and S. Battiston. “The Network of Global Corporate Control”. PLoS ONE 6, no. 10 (2011): 1–10. Winecoff, W.K. “Structural power and the global financial crisis: a network analytical approach”. Business & Politics 17, no. 3 (2015): 495–525. Zucman, G. The Hidden Wealth of Nations: The Scourge of Tax Havens. Chicago: Chicago University Press, 2014.