!!"
Urban Clusters as Growth Foci: Evidence from the Analysis
of European Urban System
Boris A. Portnova
a
Department of Natural Resources & Environmental Management, University of
Haifa, Mt. Carmel, Haifa, 31905 Israel. E-mail: portnov@nrem.haifa.ac.il
Abstract
Urban clusters are geographic concentrations of urban places, some of which may include major cities. Unlike agglomerations, whose geographic boundaries are clearly delineated, urban clusters have 'variable' boundaries, with each urban settlement being part
of its 'own' cluster of populated places, located within its commuting range. As our study
indicates, the effect of clustering on urban growth is not uniform: It appears to be positive in low density clusters, and negative in densely populated ones. In particular, outside
densely populated areas, towns surrounded by other localities tend to evince higher rates
of population growth than their 'lone' counterparts.
Key words: Urban clustering, population growth, location
JEL codes: O18; R11
1. INTRODUCTION
In contemporary urban literature, several terms are used, often interchangeably, in referring to urban concentrations: agglomerations, conurbations, metropolitan areas, urban
clusters, etc. (Lowry, 1990). 'Agglomeration' is apparently the most commonly used
term, although not the most inclusive. Agglomerations are formed around major cities,
which function as their cores (Storper and Venables, 2004). The term 'metropolitan area'
basically refers to the same phenomenon as 'agglomeration', but is 'geo-functional;' it implies both dependence on the metropolitan core and proximity to it (Fujita et al., 2001).
Metropolitan areas usually combine one or several major cities and their hinterlands
(Fig. 1A), all of which depend on the core - for employment, physical infrastructures,
commerce, and sometimes governance (Fujita et al., 2001; Pastor et al., 2000). A 'conurbation' includes several large cities, surrounded by towns and villages, which, through
population growth and expansion, merge into a continuous built area; being polycentric
(Fig. 1B), a conurbation lacks a specific core, unlike metropolitan areas (Parr, 2004a,b).
<<< Figure 1 about here >>>
A general term for urban concentrations, whether they include major cities or not,
is 'urban clusters' (Portnov and Erell, 2001). In this study, an 'urban cluster' (UC) is defined as a group of urban settlements located within commuting range of each other,
which include major cities or, alternatively, is formed by localities of similar size. In es-
sence, agglomerations and conurbations are specific forms of UCs, found in densely
populated core areas, where urban settlement is mature and major cities are dominant.
An important distinction between agglomerations and urban clusters pertains to the
delineation of their borders. Although an agglomeration may spread a long way from its
core, sometimes as much as 50-100 or even 150 km (Bode, 2008), the 'rip' between its
geographic domain and areas beyond it is usually crisp: a town may either be inside or
outside an agglomeration (Cheshire and Hay, 1989; Karlsson and Olsson, 2006). In contrast, every town or city may be said to belong to some UC: The cluster may be restricted
to the town itself, if the area is sparsely populated and there are no other localities within
commuting range, or it may include additional places, if local urban settlement is more
mature. UCs thus have 'moving' boundaries, with every urban settlement being part of its
'own' cluster of places located within its commuting reach (see Fig. 1D).
Clustering and agglomeration have been objected to in-depth analysis in classical
studies of urban and industrial location (Weber, 1909; Christaller, 1933; Lösch, 1938;
Isard, 1956; Beckmann, 1968). In recent years, clusters of industries have attracted extensive research (Rogerson, 1998; Shilton and Craig, 1999; Wallcott, 1999; Boddy,
2000; Gordon and McCann, 2000). Yet studies of urban clustering remain rare. The few
which have been carried out, mainly refer to five aspects of the phenomenon: a) the
physical expansion of UCs (Fujita and Mori, 1997; Schweitzer and Steinbink, 1997; Portugali, 1999); b) the provision of services and facilities in UC's (Wellar, 1982, 1988;
McNiven et al., 2000); c) preconditions for the sustainable growth of small and mediumsize towns in UCs (Portnov and Erell, 1998, 2001; Portnov et al., 2000), and e) proximity
between cluster members as a factor of development similarities (Portnov, 2006). Regional development issues pertinent to urban clustering and agglomeration have also
been investigated in the literature dealing with 'spread' and 'backwash' effects occurring
around major population centers and affecting their rural hinterlands (Henry et al., 1997;
Partridge et al., 2007).1
As development differentials between densely populated metropolitan areas and
peripheral regions are increasing, overcoming inequalities in socio-economic development has become a key issue for urban and regional planners worldwide (Mera, 1995;
Puga, 1999; Felsenstein and Portnov, 2005). In many sparsely populated peripheral areas, the inhabitants are denied access to social amenities, which are available in denser
populated regions. As the population of a community increases, it crosses the threshold
for higher-level services, and starts offering richer opportunities for employment, education and leisure. In this respect, knowledge about the effect of urban clustering on the
development of urban areas may have important policy implications. For instance, it may
guide regional development policies aimed at enhancing urban growth in priority development areas.
Is population growth likely to be faster in urban clusters than in geographically
scattered urban settlements? Does the effect of urban clustering on the population
growth of towns differ between densely populated metropolitan areas and sparsely populated peripheral regions?
The present paper attempts to answer these questions on the basis of population
growth data on ca. 4,700 localities in 40 European countries. According to our findings,
a town surrounded by neighboring localities is likely to grow faster than its isolated
1 For an extensive review of theories and studies of urban clustering, see Portnov and Erell
(2001).
2
counterparts. This is especially relevant for the periphery, where being a part of a cluster
may make the difference between a growing place and stagnating one.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. We start with a brief discussion of the
processes whereby UCs are formed and then discuss some mechanisms which would explain why their growth rates are faster than those of dispersed urban settlements. In the
following sections, empirical data on Europe's urban system are used to compare population growth rates across settlements characterized by different levels of urban clustering.
2. FORMATION OF URBAN CLUSTERS
There are three distinctive (and often interrelated) processes whereby urban clusters are
formed. First, they may form in response to diseconomies of concentration in overgrown
population centers. Second, such clusters may make their appearance through the simultaneous growth and eventual merging of adjacent peri-urban localities and villages. Finally, urban clusters may be formed through deliberate planning, such as that which has
led, in several countries, to the establishment of new towns around major population centers (Galantay, 1975). In the following subsections, these 'cluster-generating' processes
will be discussed in brief.
Urban Spillover
As a city grows, the positive effects of agglomeration are likely to decline (Fujita et al.,
2001; Parr, 2004b). As a result, locations distant from the urban centre may become increasingly attractive to new firms, due to high inner-city rents, while the growing number of firms in the central city may intensify competition (Krugman, 1999; Fujita et al.,
2001). If the overall population keeps growing, new urban localities may emerge in the
expanding urban hinterland, generating new town clusters, or enlarging existing ones
(Fujita and Mori, 1997). The establishment of such new towns around major population
centers is often affected by the institutional framework and by land conservation policies. Thus, the 'green belt' policy in the U.K. effectively prevents the creation of new
communities around London and other major population centers (Cowan and Mac Donald, 1980). Furthermore, public ownership of land (e.g., in countries of the former Soviet
Union), or land deficit (Hong Kong, Israel and South Korea) may render the establishment of new communities around existing population centers rather unfeasible, causing
developers to opt for more remote hinterland areas. On the other hand, infrastructure investments, and especially highway rings built around major cities (e.g., in the U.S.A in
the 1960's), may effectively facilitate the creation and expansion of new urban communities in the metropolitan fringes, due to improved access (Friedrichs, 1985).
Simultaneous Growth
New urban clusters may start forming before the central city is 'overloaded.' In particular,
demographic growth may affect several rural communities located near large cities, turning them into urban places. When such a process occurs, clusters are formed, until the
municipal authority of the large city is extended to the new urban places. Historically,
such a process has happened to the villages which have ultimately become neighborhoods of Paris, London, New York City, etc. Small communities established around coal
mines and other loci of mineral deposits may also follow a path of 'growth and merging'.
Starting as small villages or hamlets, such mining communities expand into urban clusters (e.g., the Norilsk region of Russia) or 'blend' into uninterrupted urban contiguities
(such as the Ruhr region in Germany). Recently, tertiary industries (i.e., banking,
3
knowledge-intensive high technology industries, culture, entertainment and services)
have expanded in developed economies, evincing a strong preference for major cities
(Boddy, 2000; Andersson et al., 2006). Cities with such industries may cast a 'development shadow' or the so called 'Upas Tree' effect on other urban places and thus limit any
significant inter-regional spillover effect. Such a 'Upas' effect has been noted for Helsinki, Tel Aviv, and Dublin (Roper and Grimes, 2005). The expansion of the knowledge
economy, coupled with its increased need for 'face-to-face' communication (Storper and
Venables, 2004), is also likely to work in the same direction, i.e., towards limiting the
expansion of small urban communities in hinterland areas around metropolitan cores.
Establishment of New Towns
New settlement clusters may be formed to facilitate the co-ordination of communal activities, such as the operation of a complex irrigation system (Fedick, 1997). In premodern societies, clusters of urban and rural settlements were often nucleated around a
monastery or a castle, or, at other times, formed from settlements of tribal groups sharing
a common ancestor (Aston 1999). In modern societies, the factors leading to the establishment of new towns include the 'pull' of exploitable resources, and the 'push' of overcrowding (Galantay, 1975). Those established in response to the latter are often satellite
towns, clustering around older population centers, sometimes built as a government response to the failure (real or perceived) of market forces to 'counteract' the overconcentration of population and economic activity in a few major cities (Fouchier, 1998).
3. CLUSTERING AND URBAN GROWTH
The large distances often separating peripheral towns are likely to cause a shortage of
intra-regional educational and recreational infrastructures, as well as limiting job opportunities available within daily commuting range. Conversely, being part of a cluster of
towns may widen employment opportunities and even limit out-migration during economic downturns (Portnov and Erell, 2001).
Another growth-enhancing advantage of clustering may stem from the tendency of
migrants to choose their destinations hierarchically: first, between clusters of localities,
and second, between individual localities in a preferred cluster. The reason is that ordinary migrants, unlike those with political, business or other connections, often lack inside information on possible destinations or else lack the capacity to process it, and thus
tend to treat neighboring localities as clusters of opportunities (Fotheringham, 1991;
Fotheringham et al., 2000).
In the process of location decision-making, firms and individual entrepreneurs
may also prefer clusters to isolated settlements. Within such clusters, they may expect to
find a wider pool of skilled labor and more consumers than in isolated towns. Everywhere, but especially in sparsely populated areas, in which individual urban localities
tend to be small and distant from each other, clusters of neighboring towns may offer a
'safety net' for local residents based on joint infrastructures and employment opportunities (Portnov and Erell, 2001).
However, once the density of urban settlement has risen above a given threshold,
the establishment of additional urban communities may be detrimental to all of them, due
to overcrowding and to increasing diseconomies of agglomeration (Weber, 1909; Krugman, 1999; 1995; Fujita et al., 2001).
4. RESEARCH METHOD AND DATA SOURCES
4
To test our research hypothesis that the spatial clustering of urban localities helps explain their population growth, we used data on Europe's settlements. As of 1999, Europe
hosted close to 16,000 settlements with populations of 5,000+ residents; ca. 1,600 localities with more than 50,000 dwellers and nearly100 cities of more than 500,000 residents
(Geonames, 2007). This analysis only covers urban localities for which population
growth rates are available (ca. 4,700 municipalities). The places are spread over 40 countries and range between 2,000 and 7,000,000 residents (see Appendix 1).2
The data on the longitude and latitude of the settlements, and on their elevation
above sea level, were obtained from the Geonames Database, which contains such data
on urban and rural settlements worldwide (Geonames, 2007). Data on population growth
rates of urban localities of Europe were obtained from the City Population Database
(Brinkhoff, 2007), whereas proximity of individual urban localities to location landmarks
(the sea shore, and the closest city larger than 500,000 residents) was calculated in the
ArcGISTM software, using geographic layers obtained from the geo-coverage database
maintained by ESRI (2000).
5. STATISTICAL ANALYSIS
The effect of several factors on the annual population growth of urban localities was
analyzed by multiple regression analysis (MRA), using both Ordinary Least Squares
(OLS) and Spatial Lag (SL) models. Annual population growth was measured in two
ways: a) as absolute (i.e., unstandardized) rate of population growth (per 1,000 residents)
and b) as country-standardized population growth rate, i.e., the difference between the
population growth rate in a locality and that of the country as a whole. (The latter transformation was required to take into account country differences in population growth
rates, which are most notable between the countries of northern and southern Europe).3
The following factors served as explanatory variables: population size of localities
(ln); distance to the sea shore (km); distance to the closest major city (km), and the interaction term between a place's latitude (decimal degrees) and its elevation above the sea
level (meters). [In the absence of more specific climatic data the latter variable served as
proxy for climatic harshness].
To measure the clustering of localities, the Index of Clustering (IC), similar to that
proposed by Portnov et al. (2000), was used. This index was calculated in two separate
ways. First, in line with the definition suggested in the introductory section (see p. 2), the
Index of Clustering (IC) was calculated as the total population of the localities residing
within a given distance from a given town (after subtracting the town's own population).
In the following discussion, this index will be referred to as IC1. As an alternative, the
index of clustering (termed hereon IC2) was calculated as the logarithm of the ratio be2 Nearly all cities and towns of Europe with a population of 20,000+ residents are covered
by the study. Smaller localities are less fully represented, due to incomplete data on population growth. This limitation will be further discussed in the concluding section. For most
countries covered in this study, population data are available for 1990/91 and 2000/2001.
However, for some countries, the time span covered by the analysis differs slightly. Thus,
population data for Belorussia are only available for 1989 and 1998, whereas the data on
French urban settlements can be obtained for 1990 and 1999, etc. To facilitate comparative
analysis, we annualized population growth rates.
3 The results of regression modelling for country-standardized and unstandardized rates of
population growth were found to be similar. In the following discussion, only models for
absolute population growth rates are reported, for brevity's sake.
5
tween the aggregate population of all towns and cities (j) located within commuting
range of urban place i (including the town's own population), and the urban place's 'remoteness', IRik, measured as the aerial distance from the town in question to the closest
major urban centre (k):4
IC 2i = ln[(
n
j =1
Pj ) / IRik ],
where Pj is population size of town j located within commuting range from locality
i, and n is the number of localities in i's 'commuting field.'5
IC2 thus has high values in central, densely populated areas, where distances from
major cities are small and the urban field - dense, while it has lower values in peripheral
areas, where towns are more scattered, often lying at considerable distances from each
other.
Two clarifications are required. At first sight, IC2 looks similar to the accessibility
index commonly used in urban and regional studies (see inter alia Tschopp and Axhausen, 2006; Andersson et al., 2006).6 The difference between the two measures is nevertheless considerable. The Accessibility Index emphasizes the access of a subject locality to residents of other towns, that is, it considers the locality in question as an opportunity available to residents of other urban places. In contrast, the Index of Clustering, used
in this study, emphasizes on the opportunities available to the residents of the subject
town within their commuting reach. Furthermore, IC2 adjusts for the geographic location
of the town in relation to major population centers, assuming that if a centrally located
town lacks urban places of similar size in its vicinity, its relative isolation may be compensated by proximity to a major urban centre. However, such 'compensation' is clearly
unavailable to residents of a similar town located in a more remote peripheral area. Thus,
despite its apparent simplicity, the IC2 index combines three important dimensions of
urban location, viz. intraregional isolation, remoteness, and commuting range.
Similar values of the IC2 index may exist for both densely populated areas distant
from population centers and sparsely populated areas close to such centers. Although
these two cases are not identical, the index suggests similarities these localities may exhibit with respect to population growth.
The values of IC1 and IC2 for each locality under study (ca. 4,700) were calculated
in the ArcGIS9TM software, using geographic layers of cities separated into the layer of
major cities (500,000+ residents) and those of smaller cities and of towns.
Although access time may seem to be the most accurate measure of inter-urban
proximity, we opted for aerial distances, which are commonly used in urban and re4 The definition of 'major city' depends on the function the city performs, and may thus vary
by country, depending on its land area, population size etc. In the analysis, we decided that
500,000 residents would be our population threshold for the 'major city' group. In calculating the IC2 index, all distances were measured from the centers of individual localities. To
avoid division by zero, for all major cities (i.e., localities with 500,000+ residents), IRik
value was conditionally set to 1.
5 In calculating the IC index, we set the 75 km range (ca. one decimal degree (dd)) as commuting threshold. It corresponds to the findings of previous studies of commuting patterns
on the continent (see inter alia Schwanen, 2002; Karlsson and Olsson, 2006).
6 In its general form, the accessibility of location i (Ai) is given to the following formula: Ai=
ln( Xjf(cij)), where Xj is the number of residents at location j, Cij is the generalized costs of
travel between locations i and j, and f is the weighting function for the generalized costs of
− λc
travel, e.g., e ij (Tschopp and Axhausen, 2006).
6
gional studies (see inter alia Henry et al., 1997; Partridge et al., 2007). Our decision was
motivated by the shortcomings of travel time between any two given places, such as considerable variation by season of the year (especially in countries with rainy and snowy
winters), and even by time of the day. Concurrently, if the infrastructure and quality of
service are more or less uniform throughout the study area, aerial distance may be a
fairly accurate measure of inter-urban proximity.
It is also noteworthy that in addition to being important development indicators in
their own right, each of the aforementioned development measures (i.e., population size
of localities, clustering etc.) may reflect more development aspects than it directly measures, as demonstrated in brief by the following argument.
The Index of Clustering (primarily IC1, but also IC2), we calculated as the total
population of places located in the fixed commuting range from a given locality, is in
fact, a direct measure of population density. Thus, according to Rappaport (2006), population density itself is a proxy for other development parameters, including quality of life
and local productivity. Actually, it is an especially important development measure because individuals are willing to endure severe crowding and high housing costs so as to
enjoy better commercial services and higher wages. In this sense, varying local population density may be perceived as the primary mechanism whereby local wages and house
prices adjust to equate utility and profits across localities.
The population size of localities affects their attractiveness and growth rates, because, quite often, they have to reach a given threshold, to ensure sufficient employment
diversity and adequate services (Alonso, 1971; Portnov and Erell, 2001).
Seashore proximity may also facilitate regional and international trade, allowing
urban localities to grow in a more sustained way and improve their overall economic performance (Fujita and Mori, 1997). Seashore proximity may be especially important in
countries lacking a developed inland transportation network (Gallup et al, 1999).
Large distances to major population centers, which tend to be the major markets
and sources of employment, often imply economic weakness and limited job opportunities (Ades and Glaeser, 1995; Fujita and Mori, 1997). Thus, remote localities tend to
grow slowly, being relatively unattractive to migrants and investors (Duranton, 1999).
The harsh climate of some geographic areas places limitations on interurban exchanges, as well as on human comfort and access to urban amenities. Moreover, towns
located on high elevations in northern latitudes, are often hindered in their access to national loci of employment and cultural life (Cheshire and Magrini, 2006).
The inclusion of these variables in the analysis thus makes the entire variable set
(restricted, due to data availability, to a relatively small number of explanatory variables)
fairly parsimonious.
In addition, individual countries were represented in the analysis by country dummies, i.e., dichotomous variables taking on the values 1 if a locality is in a given country
and 0 otherwise. The inclusion of these dummies helps adjust for intra-country differences, which may not be fully covered by the above 'global-level' variables (for brevity's
sake, regression estimates for countries' dummies are omitted in the following discussion).
Analysis Procedure
Normal distribution of the dependent variable is an important prerequisite for valid regression analysis. The analysis of regression residuals confirmed that their distribution
was fairly normal. The linearity of the relationship between dependent and independent
variables was also verified, and logarithmic transformation was used when required (e.g.,
7
for population size, IC1 and IC2), to improve the model’s fit and generality. We also
checked for multicollinearity and found the results satisfactory (Tol.>0.3).
We conducted the analysis in two stages. In the first, we estimated the regression
models using all our explanatory variables but the Index of Clustering. In the second
stage the Index of Clustering (IC) was added and the analysis was rerun. Our underlying
assumption was that if the proximity of a locality to its neighbors does matter, then adding IC to the list of predictors should improve the explanatory power of our population
growth models.
The investigation of regression residuals for the OLS models revealed significant
autocollinearity within up to the 80-90 km inter-town proximity range (Moran's I> 0.02;
P<0.05; see Fig. 2). This required the use of spatial dependency models. Three types of
such models – conditional autoregression (CAR), simultaneous autoregression (SAR)
and moving averages (MA) – were used in the analysis. (In the following discussion only
the best performing SL model of the SAR covariance family is reported). The analysis
was performed in the S+SpatialStatsTM software.
<<< Figure 2 about here >>>
The effect of individual location attributes (e.g., topography, proximity to networks, etc.) may depend on how much they stand out in their regional or national contexts. In a region or country where a given advantage or disadvantage are commonplace,
they are likely to have lesser effects than where they are uncommon (Polese and Shearmur, 2006; Portnov and Schwartz, 2007). To assess the importance of this relativity of
location attributes, location variables (proximity to the coast, proximity to major cities,
and climatic harshness) were successively represented in the analysis first by their 'absolute' and then the by their 'relative' values. To estimate the latter, 'absolute' values were
divided by the average values observed in each country and the quotient was used in rerunning the analysis.
We also estimated separate regression models for settlements in high density clusters ( IC2(ln) 12) and for localities with lower values of clustering (IC2(ln)<12).7 In line
with our initial hypothesis, we expected that clustering would foster urban growth in peripheral areas with low levels of clustering, while having no effect or even hindering
such growth in more densely populated metropolitan regions.
6. RESULTS
The list of variables and the resulting models are reported in Tables 1 and 2, while the
descriptive statistics of the research variables are given in Appendix 2. In Model 1 the
location of the settlements is represented by absolute values of location variables (that is,
distance to the shore, proximity to major cities, etc.). The index of clustering (IC) is not
included in this model. Models 2 and 3 preserve the same 'setting', while IC1 (Model 2)
and IC2 (Model 3) are added as additional explanatory variables (see Table 1).
Models 4-6 (Table 1) are based on relative (i.e. country standardized) values of location variables and calculated first excluding the IC (Model 4) and, second, including it
(Model 5). Model 6 (Table 1) is calculated using the stepwise regression procedure and
reports only highly significant explanatory variables (P<0.01).
7The rationale for setting this particular inter-group break threshold is discussed in the following section.
8
Models 7-12 (Table 2) are calculated for settlements in dense clusters
((IC2(ln) 12)), and for those with lower values of clustering (IC2(ln)<12), respectively.
In the first model set (Models 7-8; Table 2), the IC is included, while in the second and
third sets, either IC (Models 9-10) or 'distance to the major' city (Models 11-12) are
omitted, to analyze how that affects the models' fit and generality. Lastly, Model 13 (Table 2) is a spatial lag model, estimated by the simultaneous autoregression (SAR)
method.
<<Tables 1-2 about here >>
Comparison of the first two sets of models (Model 1 vs. Models 2-3; Table 1) indicates that the inclusion of the Index of Clustering (IC) enhances their explanatory power,
with the effect of IC2 being more significant than that of IC1 (R2-adjusted=0.344 (Model
1) vs. R2-adjusted=0.346 (Model 2), and R2-adjusted=0.358 (Model 3). Although the R2
change appears marginal, the F test of regression residuals confirms that the improvement of the regression fit attributed to the inclusion of IC as an additional explanatory
variable (especially in the case of IC2), is statistically significant (P<0.01). Notably, both
IC1 and IC2 emerge as highly significant (albeit the significance level of IC1 is much
lower than that of IC2: t=3.967; Model 2 vs. t=10.197; P<0.001; Model 3).
Characteristically, most location-related variables (proximity to the seashore, major cities, etc.) turn out to be highly significant when their absolute values (Models 1-3;
Table 1) are replaced by country-standardized ones (Models 4-5; Table 1). However, this
change fails to affect the performance of the IC, which retains its significant positive sign
in the new models as well (t=6.856; P<0.001; Table 1). This result confirms our initial
hypothesis that for an urban place, cluster membership is generally conducive to growth.
Although multicollinearity levels among explanatory variables were monitored and
found to be within tolerable limits (Tol.>0.3), even this, relatively low, level of collinearity may adversely affect regression estimates. To rule out this possibility, we reran the
analysis using stepwise regression, which makes it possible to include only highly significant variables and minimize collinearity between them. The results are reported in
Table 1 (Model 6). Importantly, the distance to major cities was filtered out in these
models as statistically insignificant (P>0.10), while the index of clustering was retained
and increased its significance level, compared to the previous model run (t=7.858 (Model
6) vs. t=6.856 (Model 5; Table 1).
The scatter plot of IC2 vs. population growth rates of towns, shown in Figure 3, indicates, however, that in line with the initial research hypothesis, the relationship between the two variables is non-linear. In particular, if town growth rates appear to increase initially as clustering increases (see Fig. 3). However, upon reaching a certain
threshold (IC2=ca.160,000 (see Fig. 3); IC2(ln)=ca.12), the trend is reversed, i.e. further
increases in clustering lower population growth rates. The Chow test of regression residuals, reported in Table 4, confirms that the slopes of regression lines before and after
the IC2(ln)=12 break point are significantly different (Chow test=8.218; P<0.001; Table
3).8
8 Although several cutoff thresholds for the IC2 index were tested, the results were found to
be inferior to the IC2(ln)=12 threshold, eventually used in the analysis. In particular, alternative thresholds showed less difference between IC2 coefficients in the 'high' – 'low' density models. The results of these tests are not reported in the following discussion for brevity's sake.
9
<<< Figure 3 and Table 3 about here >>>
Running the models separately for settlements located in dense urban clusters
(Models 7, 9 and 11; Table 2) and those located in less densely populated ones (Models
8, 10 and 12: Table 3) sheds additional light on the clustering phenomenon. Strong differences appear in the effects of several variables, namely, distance to the closest major
city, latitude, and index of clustering (see Table 2). Thus, all else being equal, close
proximity to the major city has a negative effect on the population growth of individual
towns which are part of dense clusters (b= 0.664; P<0.01; Model 9) and a positive effect
(albeit statistically weak) on the performance of towns whose clusters are scattered (b=0. 034; P>0.10: Model 10). This trend change is, in fact, not surprising, considering that
most towns located in the former group appear to be close to major population centers
(D(mean)=21.85 km; D(max)=74.80 km; see Appendix 2), and are thus likely to experience the adverse effects of agglomeration, such as overpopulation, high rents, etc.
The effect of 'climatic harshness' appears to be weak for cities and towns located in
dense urban clusters (b=0.008; t=0.130; P<0.01; Model 7; Table 2) and strongly negative
for towns in less dense clusters (b= -0.069; t=-3.467; P<0.01; Model 8; Table 2). This
difference implies the existence of a 'compensatory' mechanism, whereby highly developed all-weather infrastructures around densely populated metropolitan centers help reduce adverse climatic effects on the daily life of urban dwellers (e.g., long periods of low
winter temperatures associated with e.g., high elevations and northernmost latitudes).
Notably, the effect of clustering on the population growth of individual towns appears to be negative in dense clusters (IC(ln): t=-0.323; t=-5.427; P<0.01; Model 11; Table 2) and positive elsewhere (t=0.064; t=5.001; P<0.01; Model 12; Table 2). This supports our initial hypothesis that urban clustering does not always favor the population
growth of individual towns. That is, in sparsely populated areas, clustering may contribute to each town's attractiveness to potential newcomers by offering a 'safety net' based
on joint infrastructures and employment opportunities. However, in densely populated
areas, especially around major population centers, additional communities might be detrimental to previously established ones, due to overpopulation and inter-town competition for potential migrants and businesses.
To quantify the effect of clustering on population growth of towns, we performed a
sensitivity test of the population growth models to plausible changes in the values of the
IC2 variable. The test was based on Models 11-12 (Table 2) and its results are reported in
Table 4. As Table 4 shows, in 'high density clusters,' the annualized rates of population
growth of individual towns appear to drop, ceteris paribus, in line with increasing values
of clustering (from 1.614% for IC2=10.800 to 1.094% for IC2=12.409). Concurrently, in
'low density clusters,' the opposite trend is observed, viz., population growth rates tend to
increase with increasing values of clustering: from 1.295% for IC2=8.038 to 1.387% for
IC2=9.473.
<<< Table 4 about here >>>
In general, the use of spatial lag models (Table 2: Model 13) does not substantially
change the outcome of the analysis. In particular, the index of clustering retains its statistical significance (P<0.001) even after taking the spatial dependency of residuals into
account.
7. CONCLUSIONS
The positive effect of clustering on the population growth of individual towns may be
due to several reasons. First, both private investors and migrants may make their location
10
decisions hierarchically: initially between town clusters, and then, between individual
towns in a 'preferred' cluster. Second, a town's membership' in a cluster may widen employment opportunities for its residents, limiting out-migration during economic downturns.
According to Christaller’s (1933) Central Place Theory (CPT), development processes are not necessarily linked to location externalities, with the centrality of an urban
place being determined solely by retailing functions it contains. The proposed approach
to understanding of the effect of clustering on urban growth leads us to a different conclusion. In particular, as our study indicates, the effect of clustering on urban growth is
not uniform: It appears to be positive in low density clusters, and negative in densely
populated ones. This conclusion is in line with the findings of country-specific studies
(Portnov and Erell, 1998, 2001; Portnov et al., 2000), which indicated that increased
clustering does not always foster urban growth: The performance of towns appears to
improve initially with increased clustering and then decline as the density of the urban
field increases further. In our analysis, this trend was indicated by is switching of the IC2
coefficient from positive to negative with an increase in IC2. The explanation may be
straightforward: initial clustering in a region enhances urban growth, but further clustering may lead to over-concentration, thus limiting the growth potential of individual
towns.
The relationship between urban clustering and the population growth of individual
towns resemble Weber’s (1909) agglomeration function, according to which, after a
critical point is reached, and diseconomies of concentration (congestion costs, and the
bidding-up of land and labor prices etc.) come into play, generating centrifugal forces,
which stir economic development and migration away from established population centers towards less densely populated areas (Fujita et al. 2001). However, the difference
between the 'agglomeration-based' approach, advocated by the 'new economic geography,' and the 'cluster-based' approach remains substantial.
Although an agglomeration may spread a long way from its core, the 'rip' between
its geographic domain and areas beyond it is usually crisp: a town may either be inside or
outside an agglomeration (Cheshire and Hay, 1989; Karlsson and Olsson, 2006). In contrast, according to the cluster-based approach we advocate, urban clusters have 'variable'
boundaries, with each urban settlement being part of its 'own' cluster of populated
places, located within its commuting range. The cluster may be restricted to the town
itself, if the area is sparsely populated and there are no other localities within commuting
range, or it may include additional places, if local urban settlement is more mature.
The Index of Clustering, we used in this study to measure the effect of clustering
on urban growth, may look similar, at least at first glance, to the Accessibility (Market
Potential) Index, commonly used in urban and regional studies (see inter alia Tschopp
and Axhausen, 2006; Andersson et al., 2006). However, the difference between the two
measures is nevertheless substantial. While the Accessibility Index emphasizes the access of a subject locality to residents of other towns (that is, it considers the locality in
question as an opportunity available to residents of other urban places), the Index of
Clustering, puts an emphasis on the opportunities available to the residents of the subject
town within their commuting reach.
Furthermore, the Index of Clustering adjusts for the geographic location of the
town in relation to major population centers, assuming that even if a centrally located
town lacks urban places of similar size in its vicinity, its relative isolation may be compensated by proximity to a major urban center. Thus, despite its apparent simplicity, the
11
IC index combines three important dimensions of urban location, viz. intraregional isolation, remoteness, and commuting range.
Although further studies of time-related changes in UCs are needed to confirm the
generality of the observed trends, and additional indicators of urban development (e.g.,
export-based employment, ratio of manufacturing employment to total employment,
housing prices, etc.) may be well worth considering in future studies, our initial findings
suggest that focusing development resources on selected urban clusters, particularly in
under-populated peripheral areas, may be useful in the promotion of urban growth.
Finally, we need to acknowledge that geographic location, in general, and urban
clustering, in particular, are not the sole factors of urban growth. Other factors, such as
population makeup, availability of local natural resources, agricultural hinterland, physical infrastructures, development policies, and macro-economic situation in the country as
a whole, may affect the long-term performance of individual towns. However, urban
clustering does appear to affect urban development, as demonstrated by the present
analysis.
8. REFERENCES
Ades, Alberto F., and Edward L. Glaeser. 1995. "Trade and Circuses: Explaining Urban Giants,"
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1), 195-227.
Alonso, William. 1971 (1977 reprint), "The Economics of Urban Size," in J. Friedman and W.
Alonso (eds.), Regional Policy: Theory and Applications, Cambridge, Massachusetts: The
MIT Press, pp. 334-450.
Andersson Martin, Gråsjö Urban, and Charlie Karlsson. 2006. "Industry R&D Location – the
Role of Accessibility to University R&D and Institution of Higher Education," Centre of
Excellence for Science and Innovation Studies (CESIS) Working Paper No.68, Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm/Jönköping, Sweden.
Aston, Michael. 1999. Interpreting the Landscape: Landscape Archaeology and Local History,
London: Routledge.
Beckmann, Martin J. 1968. Location Theory, NY: Random House.
Boddy, Martin. 2000. "Technology, Innovation, and Regional Economic Development in the
State of Victoria," Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 18(3), 301-319.
Bode, Eckhardt. 2008. "Delineating Metropolitan Areas Using Land Prices," Journal of Regional
Science (in press).
Brinkhoff, Thomas (2007) City Population Database (http://www.citypopulation.de).
Cheshire, Paul C. and Dennis G. Hay. 1989. Urban Problems in Western Europe: An Economic
Analysis. London: Unwin Hyman.
Cheshire, Paul C. and Stefano Magrini. 2006. "Population Growth in European Cities: Weather
Matters – But only Nationally," Regional Studies, 40(1), 23–37.
Christaller, Walter. 1933 (1966 English edition). Central Places in Southern Germany, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall Inc.
Cowan, Robert, and Kelvin MacDonald. 1980. "Changing Views on Town Planning in Great
Britain," Annals of the Academy of Political and Social Science, 451, 130-141.
12
Duranton, Gilles. 1999. "Distance, Land, and Proximity, Economic Analysis and the Evolution
of Cities". Research Papers in Environmental and Spatial Analysis No. 53, Department of
Geography & Environment, London School of Economics.
ESRI. 2000. ESRI Data & Maps, Redlands, CA: Environmental Science Research Institute.
Fedick, Scott L. 1997. "Settlement," in P.Oliver (ed.), Encyclopedia of Vernacular Architecture
of the World, Oxford: Cambridge University Press, pp. 170-172.
Felsenstein, Danniel, and Boris A. Portnov (eds.). 2005 Regional Disparities in Small Countries,
Heidelberg etc.: Springer Verlag.
Fotheringham, A. Stewart, Champion, Tony, Wymer, Colin, and Mike Coombes. 2000. "Measuring Destination Attractivity: A Migration Example," International Journal of Population Geography, 6(6), 391-422.
Fotheringham, A. Stewart. 1991. "Migration and Spatial Structure: The Development of the
Competing Destinations Model," in J. Stillwell and P. Congdon (eds.), Migration Models:
Macro and Micro Approache., London and New York: Belhaven Press, pp. 57-72.
Fouchier, Vincent. 1998. Les Densités Urbaines et le Développement Durable. Le cas de l’Ilede-France et des Villes Nouvelles, Editions du Secrétariat Général du Groupe Central des
Villes Nouvelles, Paris.
Friedrichs, Jürgen (ed.). 1985. Stadtenwicklungen in West und Ost Europa. Berlin and New
York: Walter de Gruyter.
Fujita, Masahisa and Tomoya Mori. 1997. "Structural Stability and Evolution of Urban Systems," Regional Science and Urban Economics, 27, 399-442.
Fujita, Masahisa, Krugman Paul, and Anthony J. Venables. 2001. The Spatial Economy: Cities,
Regions, and International Trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Galantay, Ervin Y. 1975. New Towns: Antiquity to the Present. NY: Braziller.
Gallup, John L., Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Mellinger. 1999. "Geography and Economic Development," International Regional Science Review, 22, 179-232.
Geonames (2007) Geonames Project Database (http://www.geonames.org).
Gordon, Ian and Philip McCann. 2000. "Industrial Clusters: Complexes, Agglomeration and/or
Social Networks?" Urban Studies, 37(3), 513-532.
Henry, Mark S., Barkley, David L. and Shuming Bao. 1997. "The Hinterland's Stake in Metropolitan Growth: Evidence from Selected Southern Regions," Journal of Regional Science,
37(3), 479-501.
Isard, Walter. 1956. Location and Space-Economy: A General Theory Relating to Industrial Location, Market Areas, Land Use, Trade, and Urban Structure. Cambridge, MA:
The M.I.T. Press.
Karlsson, Charlie, and Michael Olsson. 2006. "The Identification of Functional Regions: Theory,
Methods, and Applications," Annals of Regional Science, 40(1), 1–18.
Krugman, Paul. 1999. "The Role of Geography in Development," International Regional Science
Review, 22(2), 142-161.
13
L sch, Auguste. 1938 (1971 English Edition). The Economics of Location. New Haven and
London: Yale University Press.
Lowry, Ira S. 1990. "Supplement: Resources, Environment, and Population: Present Knowledge, Future Options," Population and Development Review, 16, 148-176.
McNiven Chuck, Puderer, Henry and Darryl Janes. 2000. "Census Metropolitan Area and Census Agglomeration Influenced Zones (MIZ): A Description of the Methodology," Geography Working Paper Series No. 2000-2, Statistics Canada.
Mera, Koichi. 1995. "Polarization and Politico-Economic Change: A Reflection on the Japanese
and U.S. Cases," Papers in Regional Science, 74(1), 175-185
Parr, John B. 2004a. "The Polycentric Urban Region: A Closer Inspection," Regional Studies,
38(3), 231-240.
Parr, John B. 2004b. "Economies of Scope and Economies of Agglomeration: The Goldstein
Gronberg Contribution Revisited," The Annals of Regional Science, 38(1), 1-11.
Partridge, Mark, Bollman, Ray D., Olfert, M. Rose, and Alessandro Alasia. 2007. "Riding the
Wave of Urban Growth in the Countryside: Spread, Backwash, or Stagnation?" Land Economics, 83(2), 128-152.
Pastor, Manuel, Dreier, Peter, Grigsby III, J.Eugene, and Marta Lopez-Garza. 2000. Regions
that Work: How Cities and Suburbs can Grow Together. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Polese, Mario and Richard Shearmur. 2006. "Growth and Location of Economic Activity: The
Spatial Dynamics of Industries in Canada 1971-2001," Growth and Change, 37(3): 362–
395.
Portnov, Boris A. 2006. "Urban Clustering, Development Similarity, and Local Growth: A Case
Study of Canada," European Planning Studies, 14(9), 1287-1314.
Portnov, Boris A., and Evyatar Erell.. 2001. Urban Clustering: The Benefits and Drawbacks of
Location, Aldershot: Ashgate.
Portnov, Boris A., and Moshe Schwartz. 2007. "On the Relativity of Urban Location," Regional
Studies (in press).
Portnov, Boris A., and Evyatar Erell. 1998. "Clustering of the Urban Field as a Precondition for
Sustainable Population Growth in Peripheral Areas: The Case of Israel," Review of Urban
and Regional Development Studies, 10(2), 123-141.
Portnov, Boris A., Erell, Evyatar, Bivand, Roger and Astrid Nilsen. 2000. "Investigating the Effect of Clustering of the Urban Field on Sustainable Growth of Centrally Located and Peripheral Towns," International Journal of Population Geography, 6, 133-54.
Portugali, Juval. 1999. Self-Organization and the City. Berlin etc.: Springer.
Puga, Diego. 1999. "The Rise and Fall of Regional Inequalities," European Economic Review,
43(2), 303-334.
Rappaport, Jordan. 2006. "Moving to Nice Weather," Regional Science and Urban Economics,
37, 375-398.
14
Rogerson, Christian M. 1998. "High-technology and Infrastructure Development: International
and South African Experiences," Development South Africa, 15(5), 875-905.
Roper, Stephen and Seamus Grimes. 2005. "Wireless Valley, Silicon Wadi and Digital Island -Helsinki, Tel Aviv and Dublin and the ICT global Production Network," Geoforum, 36
(3), 297-313.
Schwanen, Tim. 2002. "Urban Form and Commuting Behaviour: A Cross-European Perspective," Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie, 93(3), 336–343.
Schweitzer, Frank, and Jens Steinbink. 1997. "Urban Cluster Growth: Analysis and Computer
Simulation of Urban Aggregations," in F. Schweitzer (ed.), Self-organization of Complex
Structures: From Individual to Collective Dynamics, London: Gordon and Breach, pp.
501-518.
Shilton, Leon and Stanley Craig. 1999. "Spatial Patterns of Headquarters," Journal of Real Estate Research, 17(3), 341-64.
Storper, Michael, and Anthony J. Venables. 2004. "Buzz: Face-to-face Contact and the Urban
Economy,'' Journal of Economic Geography, 4(4), 351-370.
Tschopp, Martin, and Kay W. Axhausen. 2006. "Transport Infrastructure ands Spatial Development in Switzerland between 1950 and 2000," Working paper, Institute for Transport
Planning and Systems (IVT) ETH Zurich.
Walcott, Susan M. 1999. "High-tech in the Deep South: Biomedical Firm Clusters in Metropolitan Atlanta," Growth and Change, 30(1), 48-74.
Weber, Alfred. 1909 (1929 reprint). Theory of the Location of Industries, Chicago and London:
The University of Chicago Press.
Wellar, Barry. 1982. "Urban Impact Assessment in Public Policy Process: The Canadian Record,
1968-1982," Canadian Journal of Regional Science / Revue Canadienne des Sciences Regionales, 1, 39-65.
Wellar, Barry. 1988. "Review and Recommendations: Definitions and Concepts of Urban Centers, Population Thresholds, and Proximity/Accessibility to Services as Criteria for Determining Tax Benefit Eligibility," Ottawa: Department of Finance, Task Force on Tax Benefits for Northern and Isolated Areas.
Wheeler, Christopher H. 2003. Evidence on Agglomeration Economies, Diseconomies, and
Growth, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18(1), 79-104.
15
TABLE 1: Factors Affecting the Annual Rates of Population Growth of Urban Localities in Europe (Model – MRA; Country-normalized Location Variables)
Variable
(Constant)
Population size (ln)
Distance to sea shore
Distance to major city
Climatic harshness
Latitude
Index of clustering (ln)
Country dummies (39)
No of cases
R2
Adjusted R2
Std. Error of the Estimate
a
Model 1
5.285
(12.402**)
-0.103
(-6.301**)
0.005
(0.448)
-0.245
(-1.015)
-0.004
(-1.928)
-0.066
(-9.912**)
-
Tol.a
Model 3
4.389
(10.196**)
-0.147
(-8.765**)
1.55E-04
(1.006)
0.002
(6.752)
-0.004
(-1.777)
-0.067
(-10.151**)
0.132
(10.197**)
Model 4
6.080
(13.520**)
-0.114
(-6.983**)
0.054
(2.620**)
-0.092
(-4.432**)
-0.077
(-4.096**)
-3.525
(-10.836**)
-
4667
0.350
0.344
4667
0.352
0.346
4667
0.364
0.358
4667
0.355
0.349
4667
0.362
0.355
4667
0.356
0.352
1.001
0.999
0.990
0.997
0.992
0.995
0.794
0.715
0.975
0.952
0.701
Model 5
5.069
(10.759**)
-0.145
(-8.593**)
0.042
(2.022**)
0.110
(3.045**)
-0.067
(-3.605**)
-3.371
(-10.388**)
0.106
(6.856**)
Tol.a
Model 2
4.549
(9.802**)
-0.099
(-6.085**)
6.94E-05
(0.446)
1.68E-04
(0.930)
-0.004
(-1.740)
-0.063
(-9.304**)
0.040
(3.967**)
Tolerance (collinearity diagnostic); *0.05 significance level; ** 0.01 significance level; t-statistics are in parentheses.
Model 1: Unstandardized rates of population growth; non-standardized location variables;
Model 2: Unstandardized rates of population growth; non-standardized location variables (Index of Clustering (IC1) added);
Model 3: Unstandardized rates of population growth; non-standardized location variables (Index of Clustering (IC2) added);
Model 4: Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables;
Model 5: Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables (Index of Clustering (IC) added);
Model 6: Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables (model – stepwise regression).
16
0.738
0.709
0.323
0.698
0.947
0.198
Model 6
4.528
(12.345**)
-0.141
(-8.709**)
-0.049
(-3.055**)
-3.338
(-10.456**)
0.067
(7.858**)
Tol.a
1.246
1.405
1.029
1.017
1.543
TABLE 2: Factors Affecting the Annual Rates of Population Growth Across Localities with High (IC2(ln) 12) and Low (IC2(ln)<12) Values of Clustering
(Models 7-12) and Spatial Lag Regression (Models 13: All Sample; Dependent Variable - Absolute Rates of Population Growth)
Variable
(Constant)
Population size (ln)
Distance to sea shore
Distance to major city
Climatic harshness
Latitude
Index of Clustering (ln)
Country dummies
No of cases
R2
Adjusted R2
rho
Log-likelihood
SEEa
F
Model 7
7.670
(4.499**)
-0.127
(-2.855**)
0.042
(0.755)
0.040
(0.158)
0.008
(0.130)
-1.332
(-1.137)
-0.316
(-4.370**)
Model 8
4.811
(9.077**)
-0.103
(-5.274**)
0.028
(1.188)
0.152
(3.916**)
-0.069
(-3.467**)
-3.612
(-10.450**)
0.125
(6.204**)
Model 9
4.771
(3.004**)
-0.248
(-7.068**)
0.018
(0.315)
0.664
(3.182**)
0.045
(0.745)
-1.160
(-0.980)
-
Model 10
6.262
(13.098**)
-0.093
(-4.726**)
0.035
(1.502)
-0.034
(-1.390)
-0.075
(-3.726**)
-3.888
(-11.287**)
-
Model 11
7.752
(4.777**)
-0.126
(-2.869**)
0.043
(0.770)
0.007
(0.112)
-1.339
(-1.145)
-0.323
(-5.427**)
Model 12
5.603
(11.413**)
-0.098
(-5.012**)
0.029
(1.266)
-0.071
(-3.545**)
-3.764
(-10.939**)
0.064
(5.001**)
Model 13
5.385
(10.173**)
-0.146
(-9.128**)
0.028
(1.192)
0.128
(3.059**)
-0.086
(-4.497**)
-3.573
(-9.573**)
0.091
(5.662**)
840
0.319
0.289
0.879
10.749**
3837
0.386
0.379
1.003
52.817**
840
0.303
0.273
0.889
10.273**
3837
0.380
0.373
1.008
52.622**
840
0.319
0.290
0.879
11.078**
3837
0.383
0.376
1.005
53.467**
4667
* Indicates a 0.05 significance level; ** Indicates a 0.01 significance level; t-statistics are in parentheses; a standard error of the estimate.
Model 7: 'High density clusters' (IC2(ln) 12);Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables;
Model 8: 'Low density clusters' (IC2(ln)<12); Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables.
Model 9: 'High density clusters' (IC2(ln) 12); Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables (IC2 excluded);
17
0.032
-19500
0.967
Model 10: 'Low density clusters' (IC2(ln)<12); Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables (IC2 excluded).
Model 11: 'High density clusters' (IC2(ln) 12); Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables (Distance to major city excluded);
Model 12: 'Low density clusters' (IC2(ln)<12); Unstandardized rates of population growth; country-normalized location variables (Distance to major city excluded).
Model 13: All sample of localities (Method - Simultaneous autoregression (SAR)).
18
TABLE 3: Chow's Test of Similarity of Regression Coefficients (Model
– Two-variable Regression; Dependent Variable – Annualized Population Growth Rates; Predictor – Index of Clustering (IC2))
Set
All clusters
'High density clusters' a
'Low density clusters' a
No of
cases
4667
840
3837
B0
t
B1
t
0.631
0.827
0.573
33.795**
21.615 **
21.370**
-6.36E-008
-1.37E-007
6.23E-007
-1.914*
-4.397**
0.930
** Indicates a .01 significance level; * indicates a .05 significance level;
a
see footnote to Table 2 (Models 7-8)
19
Chow
test
8.218**
TABLE 4: Sensitivity Test of the Population Growth Models to Plausible Changes in the
Values of IR and IC2
'High density clusters'
IRik (km)a
IC2
20
12.409
1.094
30
12.004
1.225
40
11.716
50
'Low density clusters'
Growth rate, % % change IRik (km)a
IC2
Growth rate, % % change
100
9.473
1.387
11.970
140
9.136
1.365
-1.553
1.318
7.585
180
8.885
1.349
-1.178
11.493
1.390
5.469
220
8.684
1.337
-0.952
60
11.310
1.449
4.237
260
8.517
1.326
-0.800
70
11.156
1.499
3.436
300
8.374
1.317
-0.691
80
11.023
1.542
2.878
340
8.249
1.309
-0.608
90
10.905
1.580
2.467
380
8.138
1.302
-0.544
100
10.800
1.614
2.154
420
8.038
1.295
-0.492
Cumulative percent:
40.196
Cumulative percent:
-6.817
Note: Based on Models 11-12 (Table 2). The values of 'control' variables are set to their mean levels in the dataset,
viz.: Population size (ln) =10.8 ('High density clusters'); Population size (ln) =10.37 ('Low density clusters'); Cluster
size= 4,900,000 residents ('High density clusters'); Cluster size= 1,300,000 residents ('Low density clusters'); Distance to sea shore = 1 (country normalized); Climatic harshness = 1 (country normalized); Latitude = 1 (country
normalized).
a
Index of Remoteness (distance from the center of town i to the center of the closest major city (k) with 500,000+
residents).
20
APPENDIX 1
Number of localities under study, their population sizes and average annualized rates of population
growth
Annual mean
Country
No of
Population of localities, residents
rate of populocalities
lation growth
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
(%)
Albania
15
70,657
14,848
374,801
1.78
Austria
79
44,890
5,851
1,569,316
0.45
Belgium
113
51,859
19,696
1,019,022
0.31
Bosnia and Herzegovina
23
73,936
3,613
696,731
0.96
Bulgaria
38
100,439
19,958
1,152,556
-0.42
Byelorussia
27
168,647
19,135
1,742,124
0.66
Croatia
27
66,979
4,725
698,966
0.41
Cyprus
10
70,795
7,835
200,452
2.81
Czech Republic
67
69,523
1,776
1,165,581
-0.31
Denmark
103
30,764
4,909
1,089,957
0.56
Estonia
24
35,604
3,763
394,024
-0.37
Finland
45
52,141
5,580
558,457
2.25
France
377
57,208
1,087
2,138,551
0.24
Germany
896
50,881
1,007
3,383,782
0.58
Greece
56
71,704
1,131
729,137
1.14
Hungary
61
72,694
18,580
1,708,087
-0.08
Iceland
18
12,513
1,059
113,906
0.91
Irish Republic
22
79,442
9,164
1,024,027
1.38
Italy
426
64,857
1,268
2,563,241
0.34
Latvia
32
42,893
2,264
742,572
0.05
Lithuania
39
53,382
9,867
542,366
-0.37
Luxembourg
19
6,825
1,508
76,684
1.14
Macedonia
27
37,952
16,267
474,889
3.61
Malta
17
10,297
5,053
21,676
0.92
Moldova
35
37,064
3,829
635,994
-0.18
Netherlands
160
59,884
17,144
741,636
0.72
Norway
37
55,702
9,561
811,688
0.85
Poland
189
86,652
18,677
1,651,676
0.61
Portugal
76
41,785
4,066
517,802
1.07
Romania
104
85,502
1,841
1,877,155
0.88
Russiaa
270
112,613
1,473
4,039,745
0.52
Serbia
15
95,833
1,379
1,273,651
1.38
Slovakia
33
57,295
21,343
423,737
0.11
Slovenia
35
20,711
1,064
255,115
0.31
Spain
251
86,308
19,172
3,117,977
1.75
Sweden
95
50,429
10,168
1,253,309
0.25
Switzerland
115
23,603
1,277
341,730
0.44
Turkey
135
178,389
14,137
3,517,182
3.26
Ukraine
130
106,478
2,467
2,514,227
-0.64
United Kingdom
426
83,007
1,136
7,421,209
0.36
Total:
4,667
a
only urban settlements located in the westernmost part of the country are covered by the analysis
21
APPENDIX 2
Descriptive statistics of the research variables
Variable
Population growth rate (unstandardized)
Population growth rate
(country-standardized)
Population size (ln)
Distance to sea shore (km)
Distance to major city (km)
Climatic harshness
Latitude (dd)
Distance to sea shore*
Distance to major city*
Climatic harshness*
Latitude*
IC1 (ln)
IC2 (ln)
Number of cases
Min.
-4.56
All localities
Max.
Mean
13.40
0.62
S.D.
1.24
Min.
-3.80
-4.02
13.14
0.51
1.17
-3.78
8.60
6.91
0.00
0.00
-0.29
27.92
0.00
0.00
0.71
-0.46
0.00
0.35
4667
15.82
1285.04
1517.55
76.35
69.97
7.20
11.33
1.28
13.33
16.37
16.37
10.46
133.47
114.37
8.19
48.84
1.00
1.00
1.00
0.99
13.98
9.92
1.00
153.47
128.77
9.07
5.90
0.83
0.71
0.05
0.93
2.06
2.12
7.35
0.03
0.00
-0.26
36.72
0.00
0.00
0.83
-0.46
0.00
11.78
978
15.82
1217.96
74.80
40.86
60.18
4.47
1.17
1.11
7.55
16.37
16.37
* Country-normalized values
22
'High density clusters'
Max.
Mean
8.73
0.75
'Low density clusters'
Max.
Mean
13.40
0.59
S.D.
1.07
Min.
-4.56
S.D.
1.27
0.60
1.08
-4.02
13.14
0.49
1.20
10.80
100.49
21.85
5.74
48.97
1.08
0.30
1.01
0.83
15.43
12.79
1.09
100.94
16.74
6.65
4.45
0.86
0.26
0.03
0.76
1.12
0.80
6.91
0.00
6.52
-0.29
27.92
0.00
0.03
0.71
-0.37
0.00
0.35
3689
13.10
1285.04
1517.55
76.35
69.97
7.20
11.33
1.28
13.33
16.03
11.78
10.37
142.21
138.90
8.84
48.81
0.98
1.19
1.00
1.04
13.59
9.16
0.96
163.51
134.29
9.50
6.23
0.82
0.67
0.05
0.96
2.08
1.66
FIGURE 1: Basic Concepts Pertinent to Geographic Concentrations of Urban Settlements.
A – Agglomeration; B – Conurbation; C- Metropolitan area; D – Urban clusters
A – major city; b – local town; c – road network; d – agglomeration/conurbation boundary; e - functional dependency; f – urban clusters
23
14
0.14
12
0.12
10
0.1
8
0.08
6
0.06
4
0.04
2
0.02
0
0
-2
-0.02
-4
-0.04
-6
28 0 -2 9 0
26 0 -2 7 0
24 0 -2 5 0
22 0 -2 3 0
20 0 -2 1 0
18 0 -1 9 0
16 0 -1 7 0
14 0 -1 5 0
12 0 -1 3 0
10 0 -1 1 0
80 -90
60 -70
40 -50
20 -30
0-1 0
Lag, km
Moran's I
Z-Normal I
FIGURE 2: Spatial Autocorrelation of Population Growth Rates (Moran's I Index and its Z-statistic)
24
Z-Norm al I
M oran's I
0.16
FIGURE 3: Index of Clustering (IC2) vs. Population Growth of Towns
(Trend line is estimated by the Loess fit method - 20% point Epanechnikov kernel)
25