Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Next Article in Journal
The Sustainability of Hospital Care in The Netherlands from a Labour Market Perspective: A Time Series Analysis of the Baumol Effect between 2000 and 2021
Next Article in Special Issue
Beyond Borders: The Effects of Immigrants on Value-Added Trade
Previous Article in Journal
Efficiency Analysis of Human Capital Investments at Micro and Large-Sized Enterprises in the Manufacturing Sector Using Data Envelopment Analysis
Previous Article in Special Issue
Understanding Economic Integration in Immigrant and Refugee Populations: A Scoping Review of Concepts and Metrics in the United States
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Economic Decision of International Migration: Two Empirical Evidences from the United States and Canada

1
Department of Urban and Regional Planning, School of Architecture and Planning, University at Buffalo, Buffalo, NY 14214, USA
2
MUREPA Korea LC., Ltd., Seongnam 13640, Republic of Korea
3
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, College of Agriculture and Life Sciences, Seoul National University, Seoul 08826, Republic of Korea
4
Department of Economics, College of Economics & Business Administration, Hanbat National University, Daejeon 34158, Republic of Korea
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2024, 12(8), 214; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies12080214
Submission received: 1 May 2024 / Revised: 18 June 2024 / Accepted: 6 August 2024 / Published: 21 August 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Economics of Migration)

Abstract

:
This study investigated whether economic motivations are a key factor in international migration decisions. Applying the selectivity-corrected expected income for migrants and stayers, the difference in expected income for an individual in origin and destination countries was analyzed. This study used data from the U.S. and Canada to empirically test the role of income gaps in migration decisions. The main difficulty in analyzing the role of the gaps lies in collecting both income streams for the same individual, since once an individual migrates to a different country, their potential income in the origin country cannot be observed; and vice versa for stayers. Therefore, directly applying the average income of migrants (conditionally relying on their observed characteristics) to estimate the income of stayers if they had migrated results in a biased estimate of stayers’ income. Hence, there is a need to account for selectivity in the migration decision and calculate selectivity-corrected income. The key finding in this study is that the expected income gap is positively associated with, and statistically significant for, international migration decisions for the U.S. and Canada. One of the main reasons may be the easy transfer of labor skills between countries that have similar labor environments and cultural backgrounds.

1. Introduction

International migration has increased globally, primarily because the continuing development of many modern systems such as transportation and telecommunications has lowered the cost of migration. Many recent studies have dealt with the diversity of issues associated with the emergence of international migration decisions, and much attention has been paid to the forces changing the structure of the world economy that generate uncertainties in the result of migration (Czaika et al. 2021). Theoretical models explaining international migration have explored the principal causes. Neoclassical economics and the new economics of labor migration (NELM) have dominated empirical applications (Kurekova 2011; Stark and Bloom 1985; Todaro and Smith 2006; McKenzie et al. 2013). Both approaches present similar explanations of the role of differences in expected economic outcomes in the international migration decision.
Despite rigorous theoretical arguments and well-trodden paths for international migration in both models (Borjas 1990; Greenwood and McDowell 1991; Massey et al. 1994; Sanderson and Kentor 2008), few empirical studies have carefully examined the reasons for international migration. In response to the dearth of empirical studies, this study investigated whether expected income gaps play a key role in affecting an individual’s decision to migrate between the U.S. and Canada. To achieve the research goal, the present study (1) combined two sets of individual-level data collected from both the United States (U.S.) and Canada, and (2) showed and compared the analyzed results of ‘the U.S. to Canada’ (US2CAN) and ‘Canada to the U.S.’ (CAN2US) migration cases. Even though the North American countries are geographically, culturally, and economically similar, the empirical applications analyzed for both countries are still difficult to find.
This paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides a theoretical background on international migration and is connected to Section 3, where empirical limitations in the study of international migration were addressed. Section 4 develops an econometric methodology for estimating the potential income of international migrants and stayers, including the counterfactual cases of the income of “migrants-had-they-stayed” and of “stayers-if-they-had-migrated”, respectively. Section 5 describes the data and variables employed in this study. Section 5 presents the estimation results, with particular attention being paid to the effect of expected income gaps stemming from international migration. The paper concludes with a summary and a discussion.

2. Motives for International Migration

The fundamental question in the theory of international migration is what entices individuals to migrate from one country to another. Different migration theories focus on different concepts, objectives, interests, and boundaries, but at the most basic level, all theories are based on an individual’s expectation of improved welfare after international migration (Borjas 1990; Massey et al. 1993). Migrants are assumed to move to a destination country that can afford them the highest net gain in income, employment opportunities, personal safety, and social well-being (Castle 2000; Kerr and Kerr 2011).
According to the neoclassical theory of migration, a difference in the present value of an individual’s future income between origin and various destination countries encourages migration to the destination country offering the highest present value of income (Borjas 2008; Mansoor and Quillin 2006). Therefore, the migrant flow comes from a pool of individuals who feel attracted to the economic benefits available in a destination country, such as a high level of income, employment, and quality of life (Borjas 1990). According to a microeconomic model of individual choice, if the expected difference in an individual’s economic benefit between origin and destination countries is large enough to cover the cost of migration over a timeline, international migration will ensue. International migration can, therefore, be conceptualized as a kind of human capital investment by migrants, since migration involves incurring immediate costs that are more than offset by the increase in the present value of migrants’ future incomes (Hass 2008).
Some theories also understand international migration in terms of economic forces operating beyond the individual level. Hass (2008) contends that the neoclassical theory of migration is too focused on the individual, resulting in a narrow theoretical framework that makes it difficult to deal with the complicated realities of international migration. According to the new theory of the economics of the labor market (Stark 1995), international migration depends on household income rather than individual income. The dual labor market theory argues that international migration is generated by the demand for low-level labor in developed countries which can be met by migrants (Constant and Massey 2005). The world systems theory understands international migration as a consequence of economic globalization and the penetration of capital across national boundaries (Castle and Miller 2003; Massey et al. 1993; Sassen 2005). Both dual labor market theory and world systems theory include explanatory variables at the national and/or international levels (Kurekova 2011).
Also, other conditions facilitate international migration (Kandel and Massey 2002). An interpersonal network connects migrants, former migrants, and stayers in origin and destination countries (Massey 1990a, 1990b; Massey et al. 1993). Such interpersonal networks provide information needed for migration and help international migration by reducing the cost of moving and eliminating uncertainties in the migration process (Haug 2008; Prices 2004). Non-economic reasons such as family reunion or a better welfare policy in the destination country are also important (Chiswick 1999; Kofman 2004; Mincer 1978). In many cases, as anticipated by neoclassical migration theory, it has been found that the welfare of immigrants improves after migration (Enchautegui 1997; Meyer 1998; Gelbach 2000; Massey and Zenteno 2000). Other studies, however, did not find this result (Walker 1994; Levine and Zimmerman 1999; Painter 1999). Part of the reason is that various destination countries in Europe, including Sweden, the Netherlands, Belgium and others, strictly regulate the welfare benefits that are available to immigrants to be integrated into the labor market (Koopmans 2010).
It should be noted that some willing individuals may be unable to migrate due to institutional or systematic limitations stemming from immigration policies (Greenwood 1995). Certain types of workers (e.g., unskilled workers) may not be eligible for entry to destination countries. Also, asymmetric information may hinder migration because potential employers in destination countries may be ignorant of the transferability of immigrants’ skills, resulting in fewer job offers (Katz and Stark 1984, 1987; Stark 1995).

3. Empirical Limitations in International Migration

Most migration studies have employed aggregate-level labor market data from destination countries (Greenwood et al. 1997; Greenwood and McDowell 1991). The high-level, aggregate studies generally reach conclusions that are dramatically different from studies based on individual-level data, as Robinson (1950) noted, due to the heterogeneity inherent to individual choice which is excluded from aggregate studies (DaVanzo and Hosek 1981; Bonin et al. 2008). Aggregate studies are often statistically biased and simplistic with inappropriate controls and non-random samples of migrants from one origin country, one destination country, one job site, or one social service agency (Massey et al. 1994). The limitations of aggregate studies make it difficult to test the neoclassical theory of migration.
While incorporating data on individual characteristics makes it possible to empirically test the neoclassical theory of migration (Bauer and Zimmermann 1999), only a few studies have employed individual-level data because such data are scarce or of poor quality to test international migration. Borjas (1987) used individual-level data to analyze migration from Puerto Rico to the U.S., but the study results are difficult to generalize because Puerto Ricans face no quotas or legal impediments migrating to the U.S. There are other major deficiencies in the existing empirical studies that used individual-level data. Most of them focused on geographically limited regions and were based on small samples (Taylor 1986, 1987, 1992; Stark and Taylor 1989; Massey and Espinosa 1997; Sana and Massey 2000; Massey and Zenteno 2000; Basok 2000; Gonzalez and Maloney 2005). Exceptions include Funkhouser (1992) who used individual data collected from the U.S. and El Salvador, and Bauer et al. (2002) who used Portuguese and German data; however, both studies considered migration between markedly different origin and destination countries.
So far, migration between countries with similar economic and cultural circumstances has not been investigated in the North American continent. In this regard, the present study has intellectual merit due to its empirical examinations of bi-directional migration between Canada and the U.S., countries that are close in geographic, economic, and cultural dimensions. This study also provides a model for the study of migration between similar countries elsewhere (e.g., from South Korea to Japan and European Union countries).

4. Research Hypotheses

This study empirically tested the neoclassical theory of migration using data on individuals’ economic conditions and examined how individuals’ backgrounds and experiences within the origin and destination countries influence their migration decisions. In accordance with the theory, this study assumed that the ‘true’ gain from migration consists of a positive gap between the income of migrants and stayers and that this gap is a key factor in individual migration decisions.
One problem in the comparison of an individual’s future income in the origin and destination countries is that, for a migrant, their future income in the origin country is not observed. The problem occurs due to so-called self-selectivity, and hence, the uplift in income due to migration should be appropriately evaluated by clarifying the degree of economic development each country has achieved and estimating its influences on human capital and income. Therefore, for this study, data on each origin country is essential to derive a trustworthy test of the neoclassical theory at the individual level.
Using individual data, the present study empirically tested the key proposition of the neoclassical theory of migration: the expected income gain from migration is a key factor in individuals’ migration decisions. The empirical analysis begins with a reduced-form probit (RFP) model because this technique is widely applied in migration studies. However, RFP neglects the self-selectivity problem that arises from unobserved differences between migrants and stayers in personal characteristics that influence the migration decision. Failing to account for the impact of such unobserved differences between migrants and stayers can lead to biased estimates. So, in this study, a model is estimated that allows for such unobserved differences in personal characteristics and allows for the estimation of the expected incomes of migrants if they had stayed in their origin country and of stayers if they had migrated to the destination country (Heckman 1979). The nature of the correction process and the amended model are described in detail below.
Assuming individual economic rationality, the basic research hypothesis can be explained by Equation (1) (i.e., that the greater the expected income gap between the origin and destination countries, the greater the probability that an individual will choose to migrate):
M G > 0
where,
  • M = the probability of migration to a destination country; and
  • G = the difference in the present value of future incomes in origin and destination countries.
The application of the research hypothesis defined by Equation (1) is most straightforward when at least one of the following three conditions applies: (1) many characteristics, including economic conditions, culture, language, etc., are similar in the origin and destination countries; (2) migration costs are low due to a short travel distance; and (3) the two countries have a ‘free of entry visa’ agreement. These conditions apply to many empirical studies of either interstate or domestic migration. Yet, they also apply to international migration between the U.S. and Canada. We expect, therefore, that migration decisions from the U.S. to Canada (US2CAN) and from Canada to the U.S. (CAN2US) will prove suitable for an empirical test of the neoclassical theory of migration.
To test the research hypothesis, the RFB model is extended to create a probit model that includes an income gap variable for both types of migration (US2CAN and CAN2US). To take into account the impact of self-selection, the income gap variable for each individual is estimated using optimally estimated coefficients obtained from applying Heckman’s selection correction and Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE). The following section describes the data used for estimation, the econometric models, and the variables included in the models.

5. Econometric Model, Data and Variables

5.1. Migration Model

The neoclassical theory of migration predicts that an individual’s choice of location will be made to maximize the present value of their future lifetime income. In the extreme case of zero moving cost, an individual will choose to migrate when the present value of the future income in the destination country is greater than that in their origin country.
Let E i * O and E i * D be the present values of the lifetime income of an individual i in the origin country ( O ) and destination country ( D ), respectively. Allowing for a positive moving cost, individual i (=1, …, N) will choose to migrate if their income premium ( E i * D E i * O ) exceeds their migration costs C i , where migration costs include the material costs of traveling, the costs of lifestyle maintenance while moving and looking for a new job, the effort required to adapt to the new language and culture, the difficulties experienced in adapting to a new labor market, the psychological costs of severing old ties and forging new ones, and so on. That is, where the net benefit from migration is greater than zero,
E i * D E i * O C i > 0
According to the neoclassical theory of migration, an individual i compares the expected costs and benefits of migration to alternative destination countries and chooses to move to the destination country where their discounted, lifetime net benefit is expected to be maximized (Borjas 1990). If an individual’s income remains unchanged over an indefinite time ( E i O or E i D , respectively), the individual anticipates obtaining the expected income from the time of entry into the destination country or from the age of entry into the job market in the origin country ( t D i 0 or t O i 0 , respectively) until retirement age (that is, ∞);. Therefore, the present value of the expected income in each origin and destination country is presented in Equation (3) (Islam 1985).
E i * k = lim n i > t O i 0 n i E i k e ω i t d t = E i k ω i
where,
  • E i * k is an individual’s expected income in either origin (k = O) or destination country (k = D);
  • ω i is a discount rate factor for an individual i ;
  • n i is the working horizon (i.e., the time of entry to the destination country or from the age of entry into the job market in the origin country until retirement) for an individual i ;
  • t is the time factor; and
  • t k i 0 is an individual’s entering age to a job market either destination (k = D) or origin (k = O) country.
Thus, a migrant i will compare the present value of the expected income in the destination country ( E i * D ), with their expected loss of the present value of lifetime income in the origin country ( E i * O ) and the moving cost( C i ).
The behavior of a migrant i , then, is converted to Equation (4).
E i * D E i * O C i = E i * D E i * O ( 1 + P i )
where, P i C i E i * O is the ratio of moving costs to the present value of the migrant’s expected income in the origin country.
With a log-transformation, Equation (4) can be replaced via the first-order approximation of ln ( 1 + P i ) with the following convenient functional form
Y i     ln E i * D E i * O ( 1 + P i )
  ln E i D ln E i O P i
where,
  • Y i is a decision criterion of an individual migration; and
  • P i substitutes ln ( 1 + P i ) as a first-order approximation.
Moving costs are assumed to be proportional to income (Robinson and Tomes 1982).
One problem with this log-transformed model is that the unchanged income values E i D and E i O , and the cost, P i , cannot be measured directly at the same time for each individual. This is because E i D is only observed for the individual who migrated to the destination country and E i O is only observed for the individual who stayed in the origin country. To estimate the unobtainable income information in destination and origin countries, semi-logarithmic forms are introduced to E i D and E i O :
ln E i D = X i D β D + u i D , u i D   ~   N ( 0 , σ D ) ,
and
ln E i O = X i O β O + u i O , u i O   ~   N ( 0 , σ O ) ,
where,
  • X i D ( X i O ) = 1 * J vector of J variables that determine the present value of the expected income in the destination (origin) country for an individual i ;
  • β D ( β O ) = J * 1 column vector of coefficients representing the characteristics of the migrants (stayers), allowing the returns along with individual decisions; and
  • u i D ( u i O ) = the net effect of all other unobserved variables in X i , or specific characteristics only useful in the destination (origin) country, having zero mean with σ variance for origin and destination. Note that covariance of σ O D cannot be estimated even if it is assumed to be non-zero because information from only one country case is observed (Greene 1995, p. 638).
Also, if letting δ be the coefficient vector of variables Z i of individual opportunity costs of migration, P i is estimated via Equation (7).
P i = Z i δ + ε i , ε i   ~   N ( 0 , σ ε )
where,
  • Z i = the vector of variables determining the opportunity costs of migration for individual i , for example, age, marital status, household size, etc.;
  • δ = the column vector of estimated cost coefficients; and
  • ε i = the net costs of all other unobserved variables in Z i .
Selectivity biases are inherent in Equation (6a,b). All parameters in Equations (6) and (7) may be estimated by the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) method only if all observations are collected in both origin and destination countries. Yet, there remains the problem of the unobserved individual incomes for migrants in the origin country if they had not migrated and for stayers in the destination country if they had migrated. Therefore, Heckman’s (1979) technique is used to modify the semi-logarithmic equations to counter the bias introduced by the missing income information (Nakosteen and Zimmer 1982). Equation (6a) can be re-written as:
E ( ln E i D | X i D , Y i > 0 ) = X i D β D + E ( u i D | Y i > 0 )
Note that E ( u i D | Y i > 0 ) is generally non-zero due to the self-selectivity in the migration decision due to the correlation with expected income. Similarly, the subsample regression for stayers can be re-written as:
E ( ln E i O | X i O , Y i 0 ) = X i O β O + E ( u i O | Y i 0 )
To incorporate the migration decision into Equation (8a,8b), the migration choice equation of (5b) is substituted by Equations (6) and (7), and an RFP model is obtained (Maddala 1983).
Y i = X i D β D X i O β O Z i δ + u i D u i O ε i
  Ω i τ + ς i     ς i   ~   N ( 0 , σ ς )
where,
  • the transpose of τ , τ T = [ β D , β O , δ ];
  • Ω i = [ X i D , X i O , Z i ];
  • ς i = u i D u i O ε i ; and
  • σ ς = Var ( u i D u i O ε i ).
Based on these indicators, the correlation ρ D defined as ρ ( u i D σ D , ς i σ ς ) equals σ ς D σ D σ ς . Because σ ς cannot be estimated due to the omission of stayers, it is used for normalization (Greene 1995). Note σ ς D (= σ D σ ς ρ D ) is the covariance of u i D and ε i , and E ( u i D | ς i ) = σ ς D ς i (Maddala 1983, p. 367). Therefore, Equation (8a) is re-written as:
E ( ln E i D | X i D , Y i > 0 ) = X i D β D + ( σ D ρ D ) ϕ ( Ω i τ ) Φ ( Ω i τ )
= X i D β D + ( σ D ρ D ) λ i D
where,
  • the Inverse Mill’s Ratio (IMR) for the destination country λ i D = ϕ ( Ω i τ ) Φ ( Ω i τ ) (>0);
  • Φ ( * ) is the standard normal cumulative density function; and
  • ϕ ( * ) is the standard normal probability density function of Φ ( * ) .
Similarly, Equation (8b) is re-written as:
E ( ln E i O | X i O , Y i 0 ) = X i O β O + ( σ O ρ O ) ϕ ( Ω i τ ) 1 Φ ( Ω i τ )
= X i O β O + ( σ O ρ O ) λ i O
where,
  • the correlation ρ O = ρ ( u i O σ O , ς i σ ς ) = σ ς O σ O σ ς = σ ς O σ O ; and
  • IMR for the origin country, λ i O = ϕ ( Ω i τ ) 1 Φ ( Ω i τ ) (<0).
Therefore, the income equations for migrants and stayers, (6a,b), can be re-written as,
ln E i k = X i k β k + ( σ k ρ k ) λ i k + Γ i k
where: k = D for migrants, otherwise k = O.
Here, the mean values of both Γ i s are 0; however, because the observations in each case are omitted due to self-selection, Γ i s have heteroscedasticity. The λ i k in Equation (12) is also unknown. Therefore, the RFP model in Equation (9b) helps estimate λ i k . The estimated value ( λ ^ i k ), then, can be used to estimate the corresponding parameters of β k in Equation (12) using OLS. Starting from the consistent but not fully efficient estimators obtained from the Heckman procedure, the MLE method can be applied to obtain optimally estimated parameters in Equations (9b) and (12). The income coefficients, β ^ D and β ^ O , and the re-computed coefficients on λ ^ i D for migrants and λ ^ i O for stayers (and hence, σ ^ D , ρ ^ D , σ ^ O , and ρ ^ O ) are also estimated.
Here, a further explanation of the self-selectivity parameters ( λ ^ i D and λ ^ i O ) is needed. Since the coefficient on λ ^ i D ( λ ^ i O ) is a covariance of invisible errors between the migration decision and migrants’ (stayers’) income equations, both the significance and direction of the coefficient convey important implications. First, each income equation has heteroscedasticity due to selectivity bias but λ ^ i k corrects the bias. Second, if the coefficient on λ ^ i D is positive, it indicates ρ ^ D > 0 because σ ς D = σ D ρ D ; the invisible characteristics related to the migration decision affect income positively, meaning migrants can earn more, ceteris paribus, in the destination country than they would have earned in their origin country. For stayers, because the coefficient on λ ^ i O itself includes the negative direction, as shown in Equation (11b), the migration decision relates positively to stayers’ earned income if the direction is negative. Therefore, in ceteris paribus, stayers can earn more in their origin country than they could have earned in a destination country. Table 1 presents the direction of the coefficients on λ i between the expected income of migrants/stayers and their migration decision.
Finally, to directly test the research hypothesis presented in Equation (1), a new probit model that includes an income gap variable was introduced. A new variable G i (= ln E ^ i D ln E ^ i O ) was calculated from the estimated parameters in income Equation (12), substituting the RFP model. The results are presented in the last column of each result table.

5.2. Data and Variables

5.2.1. Data

To test the research hypothesis, individual-level data for this study were drawn from the 1990 U.S. Public Use Micro Samples (PUMS A, 5 percent) and the 1991 Canadian Public Use Micro Files (PUMF, 3 percent) relating to migration between the U.S. and Canada. The details of the procedures for obtaining and preparing the data from each country are presented in Table 2. Briefly, the final data sets were prepared via the following three steps:
Step A included a process for the random sampling of stayers. To reduce the large group effect generally found in the origin data set, the number of stayers was controlled by sampling approximately three times the number of migrants in each country as stayers, and data on migrants were combined for each country.
Step B presents several constraints that filter the data prepared. Constant income values were also estimated here to be consistent with the econometric procedure, instead of using raw income values. To this purpose, the approach developed by Goodman and Kawai (1986) who applied a Box-Cox transformation where the lambda coefficient in the Box-Cox formula is fixed at 0.5 was used. This is a square-root transformation, and is known to provide the optimal estimate for expected income (Goodman 1988; Goodman and Kawai 1986; Watcher and Megbolugbe 1992). The sensitive tests for 0.5 were also consistent with them.
Step C restricts the migration period to a maximum of 15 years to avoid the predetermination of some variables’ characteristics, as highlighted in Table 2.
Details not reported in Table 2 but are worth mentioning are as follows. The income of the two countries was modified because the data were in U.S. and Canadian dollars. The Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)1 exchange rate was used to make the income variables commensurate. Also, to ensure comparability over time, the data were converted to a common year’s price level using the domestic Consumer Price Index (CPI) for each country2.
Individual-level variables featured in migration theories and in previous empirical studies of migration were selected for inclusion in the analysis as predictor variables. A summary of these variables is presented in Table 3. The variables are classified into two categories: income (Inc) and migration (Mig), and the last column in the table specifies into which category each variable falls. For example, the migration category variables include family size (NUMH), entry-age (EAGE), and its squared value (EAGE_SQ). The following paragraphs provide the specific reasons for selecting the independent variables used for migration and income equations.

5.2.2. Independent Variables

Age is one of the most important factors in the migration decision because it represents the life cycle effect (Long 1988). Neoclassical migration theory suggests that the older an individual is, the smaller the discounted benefit from migration (Molho 1986; Robinson and Tomes 1982; Islam 1985; Islam and Choudhury 1990; Newbold 1996; Lee and Roseman 1999; Lee et al. 2005). We selected two variables: age (AGE), which positively affects the migration decision and squared age divided by 100 (AGE_SQ), which may negatively affect the migration decision. The latter indicates that the marginal propensity for migration diminishes as the individual’s age increases. These age variables are also used in the income model.
In general, males (MALE) are more likely to migrate than females (Stark and Taylor 1991). Also, it should be noted that males, on average, earn a higher income than females (Jones and Kodras 1990; Ha and Lee 2001). However, fewer males migrate when more jobs are available in an origin country relative to a destination country.
Marital status (MARY) is positively correlated with income status, but negatively affects the migration decision. This is because married couples are more likely to be tied-stayers than single individuals (Mincer 1978; Roseman and Lee 1998; Lee and Zhee 2001). As Robinson and Tomes (1982) pointed out, however, if a regression model controls for the family (or household) size, the estimated coefficient may show a partial correlation with the family size; thus, singles may be tied-stayers as family members, especially when cared for by their parents. Because variables in a destination country cannot be predetermined before migration, the effect of marital status in the migration equation was controlled for by restricting the migration period to less than 15 years.
Education and occupation variables represent a prior investment of an individual in their own earning capacity. The likelihood of migration will increase with the individual’s education level, since a higher level of education is associated with a higher income in the destination country (Greenwood 1975; Krieg 1993). In addition to boosting economic status, education influences the likelihood of migration through improved information acquisition. It is generally assumed that potential migrants acquire the necessary information on destination countries via media, first-hand personal knowledge and/or their private connections through family, friends, and acquaintances. As an individual achieves a higher level of education, pathways to obtaining information on a destination country will improve.
Individual education and occupation levels are expected to eventually improve the individual socioeconomic status by compensating for the unidentified factors associated with their current income level. As shown in Table 3, the income equation in this study coded individual education as dummy variables (SC1, SC2, and SC0) while the migration equation as linear variables (YSCH and YSCH_SQ). The dummy variables in the income equation are intended to measure the sheepskin effects which are critical to measuring the economic achievements of migrants (Jaeger and Marianne 1996; Myers and Lee 1998). Also, the occupation variable is categorized into four groups (OCC1, OCC2, OCC3, and OCC0). Because individuals who have professional/managerial jobs may have a higher potential to succeed socioeconomically in the destination country than groups who are engaged in non-white collar occupations (Alba and Logan 1992), the outcome of the migration decision may differ according to the individual’s occupation.
Whether an individual lives in a metropolitan statistical area (MSA) may also influence the probability of migration between the U.S. and Canada (Lee and Zhee 2001). This is because residents in an MSA are exposed to a greater variety of information on the metropolitan life of other countries than non-MSA residents. Also, an employee hired in an MSA, on average, receives a higher salary than employees in non-MSA areas because the cost of living for MSA residents is generally higher. However, in the migration decision to Canada from the U.S., this variable may exert a negative effect because the overall U.S. job market may be more attractive than the overall Canadian job market.
The likelihood of migration decreases as an individual’s family responsibilities increase. Such family responsibilities increase with family size and the presence of aging parents and/or school-aged children (Lee and Roseman 1999). Thus, as shown in many previous studies, family size is a key factor affecting migration decisions (Robinson and Tomes 1982; Islam and Choudhury 1990; Islam 1985; Newbold 1996; Axelsson and Westerlund 1998). In this study, family size (NUMH) for both stayers and migrants was recalculated with an age restriction by only including individuals aged 15 years or more. Further, when calculating an individual’s family size, we excluded children born after migration. This is because family size is already predetermined and new migrants are only selected; hence, it was difficult to include the NUMH variable in the income equation. However, it should be noted that NUMH was used to estimate the expected income model because the migration period was not restricted in the expected income estimation.
Entry-age (EAGE) and its square (EAGE_SQ) variables also serve to determine the cost of migration. International migration decreases as the entering age into a destination country increases. Silva (1997) showed that age variables exert a greater impact on international migration than many other migrant characteristics. However, because the migration period is restricted to 15 years, entry-age may not be fully regarded in the labor market of the destination country and may be unrelated to an individual’s income.

6. Results

The US2CAN and CAN2US regression results are presented in Table 3 and Table 4, respectively. Each table contains four regression equations estimated using the following approaches: RFP model, OLS income models with self-selectivity of migrants and stayers (OLS-S), migration choice and income models re-estimated efficiently by MLE on the basis of the OLS estimators (MLE model), and a new migration choice model with a new variable representing the income gap (Gap model). Simulation results to show the effect of the expected income difference (i.e., the gap) on the probability of international migration were calculated at different education levels, as presented in Figure 1.

6.1. The U.S. to Canada

When comparing the RFP model to the Gap model, the χ 2 (chi-squared) or negative twice the difference in the log-likelihood (−2LL) statistics can be used to assess the model fit between the models. It needs to be noted that the −2LL information in the MLE model is much greater than that of RFP because the MLE model includes three models. Therefore, comparing the χ 2 statistics for RFP and the Gap model is proper. The Gap model was better estimated than the former because when adding only income gap to RFP, the χ 2 ( 1 ) of the Gap model is higher than the critical value at the one percent significance level (that is, χ 2 ( 1 ) = 6510.7 − 6490.2 > 6.635) for US2CAN. Consistently, the pseudo R 2 in the Gap model was higher than the adjusted R 2 of RFP.
Also, the coefficients in the two income equations with self-selectivity variables ( λ ^ i D and λ ^ i O ) estimated using OLS provide information on the selection bias, and the associated estimated parameters ( β ^ D and β ^ O ). In the MLE model, all variables are significant at the one percent level except OCC2 and OCC3 in the income model for migrants, which is consistent with the results of previous studies.
Based on the MLE and the Gap model results, the age variables (AGE and AGE_SQ) are significant at the one percent significance level. Because the former is positive and the latter is negative, the probability of migration increases as age increases but at a decreasing rate. This result is consistent with the neoclassical theory of migration. The coefficient on the MALE variable was negative, which implies that a male is unlikely to migrate to Canada, perhaps because the U.S. provides superior job opportunities. The two coefficients on schooling (YSCH and YSCH_SQ) were significant at the one percent level: YSCH was positively and YSCH_SQ negatively associated with the probability of migration. This indicates that more educated individuals are more likely to migrate, but that the positive impact of education on the probability of migration decreases as the level of education increases.
In the RFP model, all three occupational category dummy variables are significantly and negatively associated with the migration decision, indicating Americans are not willing to migrate to Canada. However, the estimated coefficient on OCC1 changed to be non-significant, and that of OCC3 (i.e., primary or simple secondary transportation, machining, or processing jobs) is positively significant in the Gap model. This indicates that individuals who are employed in OCC3 in the U.S. may be more likely to migrate to Canada, perhaps because they expect to earn more in Canada. Interestingly, however, working in service sectors (OCC2) was negatively associated with migration decisions. This may be because service jobs are more locally dependent and because individuals in the sector are often in a more tightly knit human network such as through family ties or relationships with other workers who may be an important source of job opportunities in the service sector. Regarding OCC1, the result implies that the migration decision of an individual who has a relatively high-status job would depend on various factors such as the expected income gap in the job markets and other social benefits both in the U.S. and Canada. However, as also indicated by the OCC1 coefficient estimated in the MLE and Gap models, relatively high-status employees (OCC1) in the U.S. are reluctant to migrate to Canada because individuals in the OCC1 sector may expect to earn more by staying in the U.S. Also, the coefficient on NUMH, which was not significantly related to migration in the RFP model, is significant in the MLE estimation, implying that the probability of migration decreases as the household size gets larger.
Turning to consideration of the MARY variable, a single individual in the U.S. would be less likely to move to Canada because s/he has a more attractive alternative in domestic migration within the U.S. This may reflect family ties or even preferable weather conditions within the U.S. The coefficient on MSA in the Gap model is significant but not in RFP, suggesting that Americans living in urban areas are reluctant to migrate to Canada. Consistently, entry-age and its square term (divided by 100) were significantly correlated with the migration decision, showing negative and positive directions, respectively. The findings from the entry-age variables imply that the experiences of individuals in the U.S. induce less inclination to migrate to Canada, while the marginal propensity increases slightly as entry-age increases.
Testing the hypothesis suggested in Section 2 by adding the expected income gap variable, G i , to the RFP model yields some interesting results: First, the G i coefficient affects the migration decision positively and significantly, supporting the research hypothesis suggested in Equation (1). Second, the magnitude of the other socioeconomic variables decreased in the Gap model compared to the RFP model, indicating that the variable G i may be encroaching upon the effects of the other variables in the equation.
Table 6 presents a summary of the selection biases estimated in the income equations for migrants and stayers ( λ ^ i D and λ ^ i O ). The positive and significant coefficients for the US2CAN migrants indicate that the migrants would earn more in Canada than they would have earned if they had stayed in the U.S. For stayers, the negative coefficient on λ ^ i O indicates that the stayers would have earned more in the U.S. than they would have earned in Canada had they migrated. These results indicate that the decisions made by both migrants and stayers were economically rational.

6.2. Canada to the U.S.

Canada is, in many ways, similar to the U.S., but the U.S. job market is generally perceived to be more competitive, and the environmental (e.g., weather) conditions in the U.S. are superior to those in Canada. The results are shown in Table 5.
In the migration equation using MLE, the absolute values of the coefficients for all variables are slightly greater than those in the RFP equation. The Gap model presents some interesting differences in coefficient values; for example, the coefficient on MALE is positive at the one percent significance level in the Gap equation. This indicates that males would be more likely to migrate to the U.S. than females when controlling for the expected income gap. Consistent with US2CAN, the expected income gap (G) in CAN2US has a positive coefficient; however, its effect is smaller than that of US2CAN, demonstrating that Canadians are less sensitive to the income gap than Americans in the migration decision.
The CAN2US case results yield some interesting points. The coefficients on AG, AG_SQ, YSCH, and YSCH_SQ are all significant at the one percent significance level, suggesting that the marginal propensity to migrate diminishes as age and years of schooling increase. These findings are consistent with the human capital model of migration and with the results in the RFP model found in US2CAN. Also, the coefficient on marital status (MARY) was significantly positive, consistent with US2CAN. The entry-age variables were also consistent with US2CAN, but less affected by the change of entry-age, suggesting Canadian workers’ migration decisions are less age-dependent.
The coefficient on household size (NUMH) is negative at the one percent significance level, confirming that family size increases reduce individual mobility, as suggested by neoclassical migration theory. Further, individuals residing in MSAs may be more likely to move to the U.S. because of their broad exposure to information on the U.S., which is perceived as an economically and environmentally more attractive place than Canada. This result helps explain why the coefficient on the MSA variable in US2CAN was negative. In contrast to US2CAN, all OCC variables were positive, indicating that competitive individuals in Canada who are able to acquire better jobs in the U.S. are more likely to migrate.
In the OLS income equations, the coefficients on all independent variables for migrants were significant at the one percent level, except the occupation dummy variables. The results for the stayers were also consistent with those in US2CAN. Interestingly, the effect of job type on income in CAN2US differed from that in US2CAN. Although Canadian migrants are competitive in their home country, they may not necessarily be competitive in the U.S. job market. Generally, the U.S. job market is much more competitive, and Canadian migrants may have limited access to the U.S. job market. This possible explanation is consistent with asymmetric information theory. Further, despite its lack of statistical significance, the negative coefficient on λ ^ i D provides an additional indication of asymmetric access to the job market. As suggested in Table 6, Canadian migrants would earn less, ceteris paribus, in the U.S. than they would have earned in their own country had they not migrated. The significant correlation, ρ ^ D , in the income equation of migrants in MLE also supports that there may be a disparity in the income of Canadian migrants. Also, the negative coefficient on λ ^ i O indicates, ceteris paribus, that the stayers would earn more in Canada than the potential income they would have earned in the U.S. if they had migrated. This result is reasonable because the individual capabilities that Canadian residents hold would be better revealed in the smaller but more familiar Canadian job market rather than in the larger, more competitive U.S. job market.

6.3. Simulation

To show the results from another perspective, a new set of migration propensity, education and income variables were estimated based on the regression results in Table 4 and Table 5 and used in simulations. In general, education is positively associated with migration propensity and income (Lee and Roseman 1997, 1999; Lee and Zhee 2001). Migration propensity generally increases as education level increases because more educated people often have better access to information on the U.S. Education will also increase the income gap.
The simulation results in Figure 1, for both the US2CAN and CAN2US cases, illustrate the positive impact of education on both migration likelihood and income status, with both generally rising with an individual’s education level. In sum, more educated people are more likely to migrate because they expect a higher rate of return in the destination country, and since the U.S. has a more attractive labor market, more highly educated people from Canada are more likely to migrate to the U.S.

7. Conclusions and Limitations

International migration decisions are made in uncertain contexts because information about the destination countries is incomplete and the abilities that an individual holds may not be fully transferable to a destination country (Czaika et al. 2021). Also, in conducting studies of international migration, finding and processing data for both countries is a challenge.
The present study empirically modeled the international migration decisions using individual-level data from the U.S. and Canada and tested the predictions of the neoclassical theory of migration, which conceptualizes international migration as a way to maximize an individual’s lifetime income. To properly and empirically address our research hypotheses, we prepared a dataset drawn from both the U.S. and Canada. While the present study experienced some limitations due to limited data accessibility, it nonetheless enabled us to estimate an ‘opportunity income’ that individuals might have made if their migration decision had been different; that is, the income of migrants-had-they-stayed and stayers-had-they-migrated.
The key findings of this study are as follows: the expected income gap is positively associated with the likelihood of migration at a statistically significant level for both the U.S. to Canada and Canada to U.S. migration cases. The results indicate that the ease of transferring labor skills from an origin country to a destination country can be one of the major reasons for migration decisions, even in the case of international migration. These results support the hypothesis that international migration is motivated by a desire to achieve a higher lifetime income through migration.
Even so, further research is required. First, this study focused on individual-level international migration, but migration is often a family affair (Mann et al. 1988; Cromartie and Stack 1989; Johnson and Roseman 1990; Lee and Roseman 1997; Roseman and Lee 1998; Lee and Zhee 2001). However, the assessment of family migration decisions is more complicated because it involves a collection of individuals, including school children or multiple workers who might have been unemployed after migration. Nevertheless, the study of whole family migration decisions merits further work.
Also, this study uses data that are more than 30 years old (i.e., the 1990 U.S. PUMS and 1991 Canadian PUMF) due to the difficulty in collecting more recent data. While the findings are still adequate to test the neoclassical theory of migration, another study using more recent data could be used to compare with findings from this study so as to see if its findings still apply.
Third, it would be valuable to better understand how non-economic factors affect the international migration decision, especially focusing on international migration from a ‘developing’ country to a ‘developed’ country. Cases that encompass different cultures, languages, and economic development status are needed to understand if the expected income gap is as important a decision factor as it was in the present study.
Finally, a multi-dimensional analysis of the migration decision should be undertaken (Czaika et al. 2021). While migration theories stress the expected economic benefit as the main migration determinant, there are a host of non-economic factors, such as network theory, asymmetric information, family reunion, advanced welfare system, and systematic inherent exclusion, that may also influence the decision. However, there is a dearth of studies incorporating such non-economic factors. The limitations stemming from the difficulty in obtaining raw data to cover diverse factors influencing international migration between countries can be complemented by qualitative techniques. Interviews and case studies can explain unidentified individual characteristics beyond the factors identified with the currently available data and quantitative analysis influencing migration (Martin 2003). An anthropological perspective from the past can also shed light on patterns of international migration beyond merely presenting circumstances about international migration (Horevitz 2009).
The migration decision is a complex one, and the incorporation of the diverse contexts and motivations of migrants and stayers is required to reveal the multifaceted nature of migratory behavior.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.P. (Jiyoung Park) and S.L.; methodology, J.P. (Jiyoung Park); software, J.P. (Jiyoung Park); validation, J.P. (Jiyoung Park), S.L. and J.P. (Jonghoon Park); formal analysis, J.P. (Jiyoung Park); investigation, J.P. (Jonghoon Park); resources, J.P. (Jiyoung Park) and S.L.; data curation, J.P. (Jonghoon Park); writing—original draft preparation, J.P. (Jiyoung Park); writing—review and editing, J.P. (Jiyoung Park), S.L. and J.P. (Jonghoon Park); visualization, J.P. (Jonghoon Park); supervision, S.L.; project administration, S.L.; funding acquisition, J.P. (Jiyoung Park). All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This study has been conducted with the support of the Korea Environment Industry & Technology Institute through the “Climate Change R&D Project for New Climate Regime” funded by the Korea Ministry of Environment, gran number [2022003570008].

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Upon request, the authors will provide the data used for this study.

Acknowledgments

The authors especially appreciate Michael Shelly gave his invaluable support and comments on this study. Also, we appreciate the three anonymous reviewers who contributed to improving this study. However, any opinions, findings, conclusions, or recommendations in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of supporters.

Conflicts of Interest

Author Jiyoung Park was employed by the company MUREPA Korea LC. The remaining authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Notes

1
The Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) exchange rate is calculated by determining the amount of national currency required to purchase a given basket of goods and services in each of two countries and then taking the ratio of the two amounts. The PPP exchange rate has the advantage over the market exchange rate (i.e., the rate of exchange between two currencies in currency markets) that it reflects the amount of goods and services that an individual can purchase with a given amount of money in each country. When incomes expressed in national currencies are compared using a PPP exchange rate, a better measure of relative living standards is obtained (Paul and Francette 2002). For the historical data of the PPPs, see https://www.oecd.org/en/data/indicators/purchasing-power-parities-ppp.html?oecdcontrol-00b22b2429-var3=2003 (accessed on 1 March 2003).
2
The U.S. is divided into four regions (North Central, Southern, Northeastern, and Western regions); Canada into ten regions (see http://www.bls.gov/cpi/ (accessed on 1 June 2024) for the U.S. regional CPI; and https://www150.statcan.gc.ca/n1/pub/62-001-x/2010001/t080-eng.htm (accessed on 1 June 2024) for the Canadian regional CPI). The author recalculated the weighted regional CPIs, based on the average national CPIs of the two countries.

References

  1. Alba, Richard D., and John R. Logan. 1992. Assimilation and Stratification in the Homeownership Patterns of Racial and Ethnic Groups. International Migration Review 26: 1314–41. [Google Scholar]
  2. Axelsson, Roger, and Olle Westerlund. 1998. A panel study of migration, self-selection and household real income. Journal of Population Economics 11: 113–26. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
  3. Basok, Tanya. 2000. Migration of Mexican Seasonal Farm Workers to Canada and Development: Obstacles to Productive Investment. International Migration Review 34: 79–97. [Google Scholar]
  4. Bauer, Thomas, and Klaus F. Zimmermann. 1999. Assessment of Possible Migration Pressure and Its Labor Market Impact Following EU Enlargement to Central to Eastern Europe. A Study for the Department of Education and Employment, UK, IZA, Research Report. Bonn: IZA. [Google Scholar]
  5. Bauer, Thomas, Pedro T. Pereira, Michael Vogler, and Klaus F. Zimmermann. 2002. Portuguese Migrants in the German Labor Market: Selection and Performance. International Migration Review 36: 467–91. [Google Scholar]
  6. Bonin, Holger, Werner Eichhorst, Christer Florman, Mette O. Hansen, Lena Skiold, Jan Stuhler, Konstantinos Tatsiramos, Henrik Thomasen, and Klaus Zimmermann. 2008. Geographic Mobility in the European Union: Optimising Its Economic and Social Benefits. IZA, NIRAS consultants, AMS, Research Report. Bonn: IZA. [Google Scholar]
  7. Borjas, George J. 1987. Self-Selection and the Incomes of Immigrants. American Economic Review 77: 531–53. [Google Scholar]
  8. Borjas, George J. 1990. Friends or Strangers: The Impact of Immigrants of the U.S. Economy. New York: Basic Books, Inc. [Google Scholar]
  9. Borjas, George J. 2008. Labor Economics, 4th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin. [Google Scholar]
  10. Castle, Stephen. 2000. International migration at the beginning of the twenty-first century: Global trends and issues. UNESCO 2000: 269–81. [Google Scholar]
  11. Castle, Stephen, and Mark J. Miller. 2003. The Age of Migration, 3rd ed. New York: Guilford Press. [Google Scholar]
  12. Chiswick, Barry R. 1999. Are Immigrants Favorably Self-selected? An Economic Analysis. In Migration Theory: Talking Across the Disciplines. Edited by Caroline D. Brettell and James F. Hollifield. New York: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  13. Constant, Amelie, and Douglas S. Massey. 2005. Labor market segmentation and the earnings of German guestworkers. Population Research and Policy Review 24: 489–512. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Cromartie, John, and Carol B. Stack. 1989. Reinterpretation of Black Return and Nonreturn Migration to the South 1975–80. Geographical Review 79: 297–310. [Google Scholar]
  15. Czaika, Mathias, Jakub Bijak, and Toby Prike. 2021. Migration Decision-Making and Its Key Dimensions. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 697: 15–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. DaVanzo, Julie, and James R. Hosek. 1981. Does Migration Increase Wage Rates? An Analysis of Alternative Techniques for Measuring Wage Gains to Migration. In The Natioanl Institute of Child Health and Human Development. New York: National Institutes of Health. [Google Scholar]
  17. Enchautegui, Maria E. 1997. Welfare Payments and Other Economic Determinants of Female Migration. Journal of Labor Economics 15: 529–54. [Google Scholar]
  18. Funkhouser, Edward. 1992. Mass Emigration, Emittances, and Economic Adjustment: The Case of El Salvador In the 1980s. In Immigration and the Work Force. Edited by George J. Borjas and Richard B. Freeman. Chicage: The University of Chicage Press. [Google Scholar]
  19. Gelbach, Jonah B. 2000. The Lifecycle Welfare Migration Hypothesis: Evidence from the 1980 and 1990 Censuses. Working Paper 00-01. College Park: University of Maryland. [Google Scholar]
  20. Gonzalez, Patricio A., and William F. Maloney. 2005. Migration, Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in Mexico. World Bank Economic Review 19: 449–72. [Google Scholar]
  21. Goodman, Allen C. 1988. An Economic Model of Housing Price, Permanent Income, Tenure Choice, and Housing Demand. Journal of Urban Economics 23: 327–53. [Google Scholar]
  22. Goodman, Allen C., and Masahiro Kawai. 1986. Functional Form, Sample Selection, and Housing Demand. Journal of Urban Economics 20: 155–67. [Google Scholar]
  23. Greene, William M. 1995. Limdep Version7.0 User’s Manual. Plainview: Econometric Software, Inc. [Google Scholar]
  24. Greenwood, Michael J. 1975. Research on internal migration in the United States: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature 13: 397–433. [Google Scholar]
  25. Greenwood, Michael J. 1995. Comment on ‘Frontier Issues in International Migration’, by Stark. Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994: 387–92. [Google Scholar]
  26. Greenwood, Michael J., and John M. McDowell. 1991. Differentiable Economic Opportunity, Transferability of Skills and Immigration to the U.S. and Canada. The Review of Economics and Statistics 78: 612–23. [Google Scholar]
  27. Greenwood, Michael J., Mahmood Hussain, John M. McDowell, and Steven S. Zahniser. 1997. The Influence of Social Programs in Source Countries on North American Immigration. Paper presented at the 36th annual meeting of the Western Regional Science Association, Waikoloa, HI, USA, February 23–27. [Google Scholar]
  28. Ha, Seong-Kyu Ha, and Seong-Woo Lee. 2001. IMF and the Crisis of the Marginalized Urban Sector in Korea. Journal of Contemporary Asia 31: 196–213. [Google Scholar]
  29. Hass, Hein D. 2008. Migration and Development: A Theoretical Perspective. International Migration Institute Working Paper. Oxford: International Migration Institute. [Google Scholar]
  30. Haug, Sonja. 2008. Migration Networks and Migration Decision-Making. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 34: 585–605. [Google Scholar]
  31. Heckman, James. 1979. Sample bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47: 153–62. [Google Scholar]
  32. Horevitz, Elizabeth. 2009. Understanding the Anthropology of Immigration and Migration. Journal of Human Behavior in the Social Environment 19: 745–58. [Google Scholar]
  33. Islam, Muhammed N. 1985. Self-selectivity problems in interregional and interindustry migration in Canada. Environment and Planning A 17: 1515–32. [Google Scholar]
  34. Islam, Muhammed N., and Saud A. Choudhury. 1990. Self-section and intermunicipal migration in Canada. Regional Science and Urban Economics 20: 495–72. [Google Scholar]
  35. Jaeger, David A., and Page E. Marianne. 1996. Degrees Matter: New Evidence on Sheepskin Effects in the Returns to Education. The Review of Economics and Statistics 76: 733–40. [Google Scholar]
  36. Johnson, James H., Jr., and Curtis C. Roseman. 1990. Increasing Black Outmigration from Los Angeles: The role of Household Dynamics and Kinship System. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 80: 205–22. [Google Scholar]
  37. Jones, John P., III, and Janet E. Kodras. 1990. Restructured Regions and Families: The Feminization of Poverty in the U.S. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 80: 163–83. [Google Scholar]
  38. Kandel, William, and Douglas S. Massey. 2002. The Culture of Mexican Migration: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. Social Forces 80: 981–1004. [Google Scholar]
  39. Katz, Eliakim, and Oded Stark. 1984. Migration and Asymmetric Information: Comment. American Economic Review 74: 533–34. [Google Scholar]
  40. Katz, Eliakim, and Oded Stark. 1987. International Migration Under Asymmetric Information. The Economic Journal 97: 718–26. [Google Scholar]
  41. Kerr, Sari P., and William R. Kerr. 2011. Economic Impacts of Immigration: A Survey. NBER Working Paper. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. [Google Scholar]
  42. Kofman, Eleonore. 2004. Family-related migration: A critical review of European Studies. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 30: 243–62. [Google Scholar]
  43. Koopmans, Ruud. 2010. Trade-Offs between Equality and Difference: Immigrant integration, Multiculturalism and the Welfare State in Cross-National Perspective. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 36: 1–26. [Google Scholar]
  44. Krieg, Randall G. 1993. Black-white regional migration and the impact of education: A multinomial logit analysis. The Annals of Regional Science 27: 211–22. [Google Scholar]
  45. Kurekova, Lucia M. 2011. Theories of migration: Conceptual review and empirical testing in the context of the EU East-West flows. Paper presented at Interdisciplinary Conference on Migration, Economic Change, Social Change, University College, London, UK, April 6–9. [Google Scholar]
  46. Lee, Seongwoo, and Curtis C. Roseman. 1997. Independent and Linked Migrations: Determinants of African-American Interstate Migration, 1985–1990. Growth and Change 28: 309–34. [Google Scholar]
  47. Lee, Seongwoo, and Curtis C. Roseman. 1999. Migration Determinants and Employment Consequences of White and Black Families, 1985–1990. Economic Geography 75: 109–33. [Google Scholar]
  48. Lee, Seongwoo, and Woosuk Zhee. 2001. Independent and Linked Migration: Individual Returns of Employment Opportunity and Household Returns to Poverty for African-American Interstate Migration. The Annals of Regional Science 35: 605–35. [Google Scholar]
  49. Lee, Seongwoo, Dowell Myers, Seong-Kyu Ha, and Hae R. Shin. 2005. What If Immigrants Had Not Migrated? Determinants and Consequence of Korean Immigration to the US. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64: 609–36. [Google Scholar]
  50. Levine, Phillip B., and David J. Zimmerman. 1999. An Empirical Analysis of the Welfare Magnet Debate Using the NLSY. Journal of Population Economics 12: 391–409. [Google Scholar]
  51. Long, Larry. 1988. Migration and Residential Mobility in the United States. New York: Russel Sage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  52. Maddala, Gangadharrao S. 1983. Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Economics. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 257–91. [Google Scholar]
  53. Mann, Evelyn S., Joseph J. Salvo, and James E. Banks. 1988. The Household and Family Context of Outmigration from New York City. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America, New Orleans, LA, USA, April 21–23. [Google Scholar]
  54. Mansoor, Ali M., and Bryce R. Quillin. 2006. Migration and Remittances. Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. Washington, DC: The World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  55. Martin, Philip. 2003. Economic Integration and Migration The Mexico-US Case. WIDER Discussion Paper, No. 2003/35. Helsinki: The United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER). ISBN 9291904538. [Google Scholar]
  56. Massey, Douglas S. 1990a. Social Structure, household strategies, and the Cumulative Causation if Migration. Population Index 56: 3–26. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
  57. Massey, Douglas S. 1990b. The social and Economic Origins of Immigration. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 510: 60–72. [Google Scholar]
  58. Massey, Douglas S., and Kristin E. Espinosa. 1997. What’s driving Mexico-US migration? A theoretical, empirical and policy analysis. American Journal of Sociology 102: 939–99. [Google Scholar]
  59. Massey, Douglas S., and Rene Zenteno. 2000. A validation of the ethnosurvey: The case of Mexico-US migration. International Migration Review 34: 766–93. [Google Scholar]
  60. Massey, Douglas S., Joaquin Arango, Graeme Hugo, Ali Kouaouci, Adela Pellegrino, and J. Edward Taylor. 1993. Theories of International Migration: A Review and Appraisal. Population and Development Review 19: 431–66. [Google Scholar]
  61. Massey, Douglas S., Joaquin Arango, Graeme Hugo, Ali Kouaouci, Adela Pellegrino, and J. Edward Taylor. 1994. An Evaluation of International Migration Theory: The North American Case. Population and Development Review 20: 699–751. [Google Scholar]
  62. McKenzie, David, John Gibson, and Steven Stillman. 2013. A land of milk and honey with streets paved with gold: Do emigrants have over-optimistic expectations about incomes abroad? Journal of Development Economics 102: 116–27. [Google Scholar]
  63. Meyer, Bruce D. 1998. Do the Poor Move to Receive Higher Welfare Benefit? JCPR Working Paper 58, December 1998. Evanston: Northwestern University/University of Chicago Joint Center for Poverty Research. [Google Scholar]
  64. Mincer, Jacob. 1978. Family Migration Decisions. Journal of Political Economy 86: 749–73. [Google Scholar]
  65. Molho, Ian. 1986. Theories of Migration: A review. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 33: 396–419. [Google Scholar]
  66. Myers, Dowell, and Seongwoo Lee. 1998. Immigration Trajectories into Homeownership: A Temporal Analysis of Residential Assimilation. International Migration Review 32: 593–625. [Google Scholar]
  67. Nakosteen, Robert A., and Michael A. Zimmer. 1982. The Effects on Earnings in Interregional and Interindustry Migration. Journal of Regional Science 22: 325–41. [Google Scholar]
  68. Newbold, Bruce K. 1996. Income, Self-Selection and Return and Onward Interprovincial Migration in Canada. Environment and Planning A 28: 1019–34. [Google Scholar]
  69. Painter, Gary. 1999. Do Households Move to Obtain Higher Benefits? A “Natural Experiment” Approach. Working Papers of Lusk Center 1999-112. Los Angeles: USC Lusk Center for Real Estate. [Google Scholar]
  70. Paul, Schreyer, and Koechlin Francette. 2002. Purchasing Power Parities 1999 Benchmark Results. Available online: www.SourceOECD.org (accessed on 1 March 2003).
  71. Prices, Ludger. 2004. Determining the causes and durability of transitional labour migration between Mexico and the Unitied States: Some empirical findings. International Migration 42: 3–39. [Google Scholar]
  72. Robinson, Chris, and Nigel Tomes. 1982. Self-selection and interprovincial migration in Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics 15: 474–502. [Google Scholar]
  73. Robinson, William S. 1950. Ecological correlations and the behavior of individuals. American Sociological Review 15: 351–57. [Google Scholar]
  74. Roseman, Curtis C., and Seongwoo Lee. 1998. Linked and Independent African American Migration from Los Angeles. Professional Geographer 50: 204–14. [Google Scholar]
  75. Sana, Mariano, and Douglas S. Massey. 2000. Seeking Social Security: An Alternative Motivation for Mexico-US Migration. International Migration 38: 3–24. [Google Scholar]
  76. Sanderson, Matthew W., and J. Kentor. 2008. Foreign Direct Investment and International Migration: A Cross-National Analysis of Less-Developed Countries, 1985–2000. International Sociology 23: 514–39. [Google Scholar]
  77. Sassen, Saskia. 2005. Regulating Immigration in a Global Age: A New Policy Landscape. Parallax 11: 35–45. [Google Scholar]
  78. Silva, Arnold D. 1997. Incomes of Immigrant Classes in the Early 1980s in Canada: A Reexamination. Canadian Public Policy-Analyses de Politiques 23: 179–202. [Google Scholar]
  79. Stark, Oded. 1995. Frontier Issues in International Migration. Paper presented at World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994, Washington, DC, USA, April 28–29; pp. 361–86. [Google Scholar]
  80. Stark, Oded, and David. E. Bloom. 1985. The New Economics of Labor Migration. The American Economic Review 75: 173–78. [Google Scholar]
  81. Stark, Oded, and J. Edward Taylor. 1989. Relative Deprivation and International Migration. Demography 26: 1–14. [Google Scholar]
  82. Stark, Oded, and J. Edward Taylor. 1991. Migration Incentives, Migration Types: The Role of Relative Deprivation. The Economic Journal 101: 1163–78. [Google Scholar]
  83. Taylor, J. Edward. 1986. Differential Migration, Networks, Information and Risk. Human Capital and Development 4: 147–71. [Google Scholar]
  84. Taylor, J. Edward. 1987. Undocumented Mexico-U.S. Migration and the Returns to Households in Rural Mexico. American Agricultural Economics Association 69: 626–38. [Google Scholar]
  85. Taylor, J. Edward. 1992. Incomes and Mobility of Legal and Illegal Immigrant Workers in Agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74: 889–96. [Google Scholar]
  86. Todaro, Michael P., and Stephen Smith. 2006. Economic Development. Boston: Addison Wesley. [Google Scholar]
  87. Walker, James R. 1994. Migration among Low-Income Households: Helping the Witch Doctors Reach Consensus. Discussion Paper 94-1031. Wisconsin: Institute For Research on Poverty. [Google Scholar]
  88. Watcher, Susan M., and Isaac F. Megbolugbe. 1992. Racial and ethnic disparities in Homeownership. Housing Policy Debate 3: 333–70. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Simulation Results of Migration Propensity. Note: Ed_Level means the education level that individuals achieved.
Figure 1. Simulation Results of Migration Propensity. Note: Ed_Level means the education level that individuals achieved.
Economies 12 00214 g001
Table 1. Cross Tab on Expected Incomes and Migration Decisions: Direction of Coefficients on λ i (= ρ ).
Table 1. Cross Tab on Expected Incomes and Migration Decisions: Direction of Coefficients on λ i (= ρ ).
Yi = 1Yi = 0
Exp( ln E i D ) > Exp( ln E i O )++
Exp( ln E i D ) < Exp( ln E i O )
Table 2. Data Preparation Procedure.
Table 2. Data Preparation Procedure.
U.S. and Canada
U.S.ObservationCanadaObservation
Step A1990 PUMS A (0.05%)124,7771991 Ind. PUMF (3%)809,654
Random Sample (5%)
(Stayers)
6218Random Sample (2%)
(Stayers)
16,066
U.S. in Canada
(Migrants)
8791Canadian in U.S.
(Migrants)
43,159
Number of Cases Used15,009Number of Cases Used59,225
Step BData Filtering:
AGE > 15
Total Income > 0
Household Size > 0
Data Filtering:
AGE > 15
Total Income > 0
Household Size > 0
Data prepared for estimating expected Income11,364Data prepared for estimating expected Income47,162
Step C Combined data11,364Combined data47,162
0 < Years of
Immigration
of American < 15
0 < Years of
Immigration
of Canadian < 15
Valid household type Valid household type
Migrants to Canada2413Migrants to US5945
Stayers in U.S.4058Stayers in Canada11,393
Total 6471Total 17,338
MigrantsStayersTotal MigrantsStayersTotal
Mean income17,976.420,617.919,632.9 28,686.417,072.721,054.9
Modified
mean
income 1
17,884.620,643.119,614.528,657.517,045.421,027.1
Expected mean income 216,327.517,375.016,984.422,534.216,269.218,417.4
Notes: 1. Modified mean incomes were modified using a Purchasing Power Parity exchange rate and the regional and annual Consumer Price Indices. 2. The expected mean income is calculated from the coefficients of the modified income regression estimated with square root Box-Cox transformation (that is, λ = 0.5). Other demographic and socioeconomic independent variables include white or not; living in MSA or not; household or not; number of households; number of laborers in each household; male or female; age dummy variables (16–25, 26–35, 36–45, 46–55, 56–65, 66–75); married or not; widowed, divorced, separated or not; stayers or not; education dummy variables; self-employer or not; existence of additional incomes such as interest or rental income; and owner or not.
Table 3. Description of Variables.
Table 3. Description of Variables.
DescriptionCategory 1
Dependent
MIG1 = immigrants, 0 = otherwise
LNTINClog of expected incomes of an individual modified by PPP and by year and regional CPIs
Independent
Demographic
AGEYears in age (> 15)Inc, Mig
AGE_SQ(Ag * Ag)/100Inc, Mig
MALE1 = male, 0 = otherwise Inc, Mig
MARY1 = the married, 0 = otherwiseInc, Mig
NUMHhousehold size (before migration for migrants) Mig
Economic
YSCHtotal years of schooling switched to years from the education attainment categoryMig
YSCH_SQ(YSCH * YSCH)/100Mig
SC1high school =< the level of schooling < BAInc
SC2the level of schooling >= BAInc, Mig
SC0otherwise (Ref.)
OCC1managerial, professional, and administrativeInc, Mig
OCC2occupations related to sales, services occupationsInc, Mig
OCC3primary occupation and simple secondary occupations related to processing, transporting and machiningInc, Mig
OCC0otherwise (Ref.)
EAGEage − (years since migration), if mig = 1
YSCH + 6, if mig = 0
Mig
EAGE_SQ(EAGE * EAGE)/100Mig
Gincome gap (= ln E ^ i D ln E ^ i O )Mig
Regional
MSA1 = located in MSA or CMSA, 0 = otherwiseInc, Mig
Note: 1. Inc = Income equation, Mig = Immigration Equation.
Table 4. The Result of International Migration: ‘the U.S. to Canada’.
Table 4. The Result of International Migration: ‘the U.S. to Canada’.
Reduced-form
Probit (RFP)
OLS with Selectivity (OLS-S)MLEProbit with Income
Difference (Gap)
MigrantsStayersMigrationMigrantsStayers
Dep. Var.Yi ln E i D ln E i O Yi ln E i D ln E i O Yi
Var.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.
Con.8.6122***0.98556.2550***0.05126.3953***0.04817.7277***0.94886.2578***0.04716.5658***0.035210.9115***1.1196
AGE0.4598***0.04750.0944***0.00240.0889***0.00200.4948***0.06300.0943***0.00230.0847***0.00160.3816***0.0500
AGE_SQ−0.8307***0.0789−0.0834***0.0025−0.0778***0.0020−0.8666***0.1097−0.0833***0.0023−0.0754***0.0017−0.7712***0.0794
MALE−0.5178***0.06660.6323***0.01350.6700***0.0119−0.4002***0.06710.6328***0.01590.6478***0.0118−0.4109***0.0707
YSCH1.9088***0.1072 1.9347***0.0742 2.0118***0.1112
YSCH_SQ−7.0990***0.4024 −7.1486***0.2958 −7.5971***0.4235
SC1 0.3725***0.01880.3850***0.0127 0.3729***0.01570.3958***0.0110
SC2 0.8766***0.02280.8253***0.0182 0.8770***0.02440.8518***0.0193
OCC1−0.4401***0.15490.1017***0.02550.1473***0.0207−0.3197**0.13470.1023***0.02370.1353***0.0181−0.1412 0.1677
OCC2−1.0760***0.16920.0560 0.03700.1110***0.0220−0.9503***0.14310.0575 0.03900.0683***0.0176−0.9506***0.1705
OCC3−0.2534*0.15340.0302 0.02560.1093***0.0214−0.1295 0.13350.0299 0.02220.1044***0.01870.4470**0.2174
MARY0.2503***0.07300.0779***0.01490.0521***0.01200.4392***0.03680.0805***0.01570.0723***0.01170.1655**0.0756
MSA−0.0992 0.06760.2615***0.01410.2038***0.0110−0.1058 0.11810.2618***0.01400.2002***0.0102−0.6541***0.1406
NUMH−0.0217 0.0343 −0.0937**0.0307 −0.0192 0.0345
EAGE−2.9100***0.1471 −2.8995***0.0732 −2.9088***0.1480
EAGE_SQ7.6130***0.3754 7.5340***0.0687 7.5993***0.3772
λ 0.0727***0.0129−0.3666***0.0392
G 8.8730**1.9656
σ 0.3224***0.00400.3023***0.0033
ρ 0.1996***0.0405−0.4175***0.0483
χ26490.2*** 6510.7***
−2LogL2057.7 1351.5 1589.7 5082.65 2037.2
N6471 2413 4058 6471
adj. R20.7592 0.8139 0.8034 0.7617
Notes: 1. ***, p < 0.01; **, p < 0.05; *, p < 0.10. 2. The adjusted R2s in probit equations indicate the pseudo R2s calculated from the McFadden’s approach.
Table 5. The Empirical Results for International Migration: ‘Canada to the U.S.’.
Table 5. The Empirical Results for International Migration: ‘Canada to the U.S.’.
Reduced-form
Probit (RFP)
OLS with Selectivity (OLS-S) MLEProbit with Income
Difference (Gap)
MigrantsStayersMigrationMigrantsStayers
Dep. Var.Yi ln E i D ln E i O Yi ln E i D ln E i O Yi
Var.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.coeff. S.E.
Con.6.9520***0.48066.1953***0.03915.1714***0.03725.2708***0.48016.2077***0.03415.4143***0.02873.9161***0.7814
AGE0.2906***0.02400.1152***0.00190.1356***0.00160.3914***0.02990.1150***0.00170.1272***0.00140.3434***0.0264
AGE_SQ−0.6130***0.0403−0.1137***0.0022−0.1206***0.0017−0.7617***0.0531−0.1136***0.0019−0.1143***0.0015−0.6339***0.0407
MALE−0.0442 0.03430.6721***0.00960.7812***0.00860.0341 0.03710.6717***0.01140.7756***0.01000.3003***0.0775
YSCH0.6546***0.0374 0.7069***0.0145 0.7128***0.0394
YSCH_SQ−2.0288***0.1383 −2.2179***0.0726 −2.2023***0.1434
SC1 0.3309***0.01340.4007***0.0097 0.3305***0.01200.4107***0.0096
SC2 0.8447***0.01520.8322***0.0154 0.8442***0.01650.8987***0.0187
OCC10.8429***0.1220−0.0021 0.02360.1154***0.01620.9146***0.1015−0.0032 0.02050.1326***0.01581.3119***0.1544
OCC21.1873***0.1250−0.0601**0.02430.0456**0.01971.2662***0.1048−0.0622***0.02030.0830***0.02081.6985***0.1623
OCC30.3528***0.12180.0065 0.02580.1034***0.01550.4310***0.10060.0075 0.02190.0785***0.01340.6048***0.1317
MARY−0.1223***0.04040.1445***0.01060.0430***0.00970.6037***0.04070.1438***0.01170.0676***0.01030.2616***0.0656
MSA−1.7786***0.03850.2828***0.01220.2423***0.00890.3019***0.03800.2811***0.01080.2604***0.00870.2065***0.0412
NUMH−0.1223***0.0179 −0.1713***0.0178 −0.1230***0.0180
EAGE−1.7786***0.0512 −1.7960***0.0343 −1.7875***0.0516
EAGE_SQ4.6702***0.1290 4.6871***0.0964 4.6931***0.1300
λ −0.0100 0.0095−0.4596***0.0198
G 3.3834***0.6831
σ 0.3486***0.00150.4345***0.0028
ρ −0.0561**0.0230−0.4083***0.0244
χ215,148.6*** 15,173.0***
−2LogL7144.8 4427.9 12,565.6 24,318.2 7120.1
N17,337 5945 11,392 17,337
adj. R20.6795 0.7984 0.7455 0.6806
Notes: 1. ***, p < 0.01; **, p < 0.05; *, p < 0.10. 2. The adjusted R2s for the probit equations were calculated using McFadden’s method.
Table 6. The Direction of the Estimated Coefficients on λ i   ( = ρ ) from the Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE).
Table 6. The Direction of the Estimated Coefficients on λ i   ( = ρ ) from the Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE).
US->CanadaYi = 1Yi = 0
Exp( ln E i D ) > Exp( ln E i O )+ ***
Exp( ln E i D ) < Exp( ln E i O ) − ***
Canada->USYi = 1Yi = 0
Exp( ln E i D ) > Exp( ln E i O )
Exp( ln E i D ) < Exp( ln E i O )− ***
Note: ***, p < 0.01; **, p < 0.05; *, p < 0.10.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Park, J.; Lee, S.; Park, J. The Economic Decision of International Migration: Two Empirical Evidences from the United States and Canada. Economies 2024, 12, 214. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies12080214

AMA Style

Park J, Lee S, Park J. The Economic Decision of International Migration: Two Empirical Evidences from the United States and Canada. Economies. 2024; 12(8):214. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies12080214

Chicago/Turabian Style

Park, Jiyoung, Seongwoo Lee, and Jonghoon Park. 2024. "The Economic Decision of International Migration: Two Empirical Evidences from the United States and Canada" Economies 12, no. 8: 214. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies12080214

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop