Vertical N Horizontal Integration
Vertical N Horizontal Integration
Vertical N Horizontal Integration
The degree to which a firm owns its upstream suppliers and its downstream buyers is
referred to as vertical integration. Because it can have a significant impact on a
business unit's position in its industry with respect to cost, differentiation, and other
strategic issues, the vertical scope of the firm is an important consideration in corporate
strategy.
The concept of vertical integration can be visualized using the value chain. Consider a
firm whose products are made via an assembly process. Such a firm may consider
backward integrating into intermediate manufacturing or forward integrating into
distribution, as illustrated below:
Assembly
Assembly Assembly
Distribution Distribution Distribution
Two issues that should be considered when deciding whether to vertically integrate is
cost and control. The cost aspect depends on the cost of market transactions between
firms versus the cost of administering the same activities internally within a single firm.
The second issue is the impact of asset control, which can impact barriers to entry and
which can assure cooperation of key value-adding players.
Capacity balancing issues. For example, the firm may need to build excess
upstream capacity to ensure that its downstream operations have sufficient
supply under all demand conditions.
Potentially higher costs due to low efficiencies resulting from lack of supplier
competition.
Decreased flexibility due to previous upstream or downstream investments. (Note
however, that flexibility to coordinate vertically-related activities may increase.)
Decreased ability to increase product variety if significant in-house development
is required.
Developing new core competencies may compromise existing competencies.
Increased bureaucratic costs.
The following situational factors tend to make vertical integration less attractive:
The quantity required from a supplier is much less than the minimum efficient
scale for producing the product.
The product is a widely available commodity and its production cost decreases
significantly as cumulative quantity increases.
The core competencies between the activities are very different.
The vertically adjacent activities are in very different types of industries. For
example, manufacturing is very different from retailing.
The addition of the new activity places the firm in competition with another player
with which it needs to cooperate. The firm then may be viewed as a competitor
rather than a partner
Alternatives to Vertical Integration
There are alternatives to vertical integration that may provide some of the same benefits
with fewer drawbacks. The following are a few of these alternatives for relationships
between vertically-related organizations:
Horizontal Integration
The acquisition of additional business activities at the same level of the value chain is
referred to as horizontal integration. This form of expansion contrasts with vertical
integration by which the firm expands into upstream or downstream activities. Horizontal
growth can be achieved by internal expansion or by external expansion
through mergers and acquisitions of firms offering similar products and services. A firm
may diversify by growing horizontally into unrelated businesses.
The following are some benefits sought by firms that horizontally integrate:
Economies of scale - acheived by selling more of the same product, for example,
by geographic expansion.
Economies of scope - achieved by sharing resources common to different
products. Commonly referred to as "synergies."
Increased market power (over suppliers and downstream channel members)
Reduction in the cost of international trade by operating factories in foreign
markets.
Aside from legal issues, another concern is whether the anticipated economic gains will
materialize. Before expanding the scope of the firm through horizontal integration,
management should be sure that the imagined benefits are real. Many blunders have
been made by firms that broadened their horizontal scope to achieve synergies that did
not exist, for example, computer hardware manufacturers who entered the software
business on the premise that there were synergies between hardware and software.
However, a connection between two products does not necessarily imply realizable
economies of scope.
Finally, even when the potential benefits of horizontal integration exist, they do not
materialize spontaneously. There must be an explicit horizontal strategy in place. Such
strategies generally do not arise from the bottom-up, but rather, must be formulated by
corporate management.