BIS - The Real Effects of Debt
BIS - The Real Effects of Debt
BIS - The Real Effects of Debt
0.0078
(0.163) (0.028) (0.058) (0.19
4)
Household 0.0023 0.0043 0.0013
0.0055
(0.870) (0.756) (0.923) (0.70
9)
Including
financial flow
variables
Total 0.0103*
(0.051)
Government 0.0208*** 0.0240*** 0.0226*** 0.0218*** 0.0240***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000)
Private sector 0.0030 0.0051
(0.597) (0.300)
Corporate 0.0027 0.0043 0.0054 0.0023
(0.689) (0.459) (0.377) (0.75
6)
Household 0.0065 0.0047 0.0041 0.0057
(0.554) (0.632) (0.675) (0.61
0)
Reported coefficients are for the marginal impact of debt on the five-year forward average per capita growth rate from estimating
text equation (1). Numbers in parentheses are asymptotic p-values for the test that the coefficient estimate is equal to zero
computed using standard errors estimated using the Huber-White sandwich estimator. */**/*** indicate coefficient estimates
significantly different from zero at the 10/5/1% level.
Source: Authors calculations.
but fairly imprecise (with a p-value of 0.16). However, when we control for government debt
(column 7), the impact is strongly large and precisely estimated: a 10 percentage point
increase in corporate debt is associated with a reduction in subsequent average growth of
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
16/34
1112 basis points (and the p-value is 0.028). These findings suggest that corporate debt
makes growth worse during periods of financial stress. The fact that the impact is stronger
when we control for government debt means that high levels of private debt, in the presence
of large government debts, make the economy more vulnerable to shocks.
37
Finally, we check to see if the outstanding levels of public and private debt are capturing the
effects that high debt might have on the future flow of credit and, through this channel, on
growth. To do this, we add the average flow of private credit and government borrowing
(always as a share of GDP) to the regressions. The results are reported in the bottom panel
of Table 5. The existence of what might be termed the crowding-out effect, whereby higher
debt reduces the future availability of credit, is confirmed by separate regressions, in which
controlling for both country and period fixed effects we find (not reported here) that higher
levels of both public and private debt are negatively associated with future credit flows.
As for the consequences for the level of debt itself, the object of our primary interest,
controlling for the credit flow variables makes the estimated effects of total non-financial debt
and government debt larger (in absolute value) and more precise.
Threshold effects
In our preliminary discussions, we noted the possibility that, as it increases, indebtedness
can turn from good to bad from initially growth-enhancing (or neutral) to eventually growth-
reducing. Our interest is in looking for this effect in the data. We do this first by looking at a
simple picture and then at some statistical results.
Graph 3
Non-financial sector debt and output growth for 18 OECD countries
0
100
200
300
400
500
1.25
1.50
1.75
2.00
2.25
2.50
1
st
quartile 2
nd
quartile 3
rd
quartile 4
th
quartile
Non-financial debt, as a percentage of GDP
1
(lhs)
GDP, growth
2
(rhs)
1
The average of the quartiles.
2
Average growth within the quartiles.
Sources: OECD; Penn World Tables 7.0.
The picture is in Graph 3. We have split the sample of observations on per capita GDP
growth based on the distribution of the debt-to-GDP ratio. Mean per capita GDP growth rises
37
We also added government consumption as a share of GDP to the regressions in order to check whether the
effects of public debt would change. If government consumption has a negative impact on growth, then
omitting it may lead us to incorrectly conclude that public debt has a negative impact over and above the
effects of distortionary taxation and other disincentives imposed on the private sector, which might be proxied
by government consumption. It turns out that government consumption is always statistically insignificant in
our growth regressions. We also dropped the saving rate variable to check whether debt has a negative
impact on growth through capital accumulation. The estimates are little changed.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
17/34
as we move from the first to the third quartiles and then falls back in the fourth quartile.
Moreover, the difference between growth in the bottom and the top quartiles is small, so
there is no evidence that debt is necessarily bad for growth. Indeed, for sufficiently low
levels, debt may help foster capital deepening and allocative efficiency, thus boosting growth.
Yet the graph also suggests that, as debt approaches high levels, the effect of further
increases in debt on growth may begin to subside.
38
Although the graph suggests that there
is no big difference between high- and low-debt economies in terms of mean growth, it might
be that more sophisticated statistical techniques are needed to bring out any larger negative
effect on growth from high debt.
Turning to the regression, we ask whether the relationship between growth and debt is non-
linear. We look for this using the following empirical model, which incorporates threshold
effects but is otherwise identical to equation (1):
( ) ( )
k t t i t i t i t i t i t i t i t i k t t i
d I d d I d X y g
+ + + +
+ + + > + < + + =
, , , , , , , , , 1 ,
' c t t | | , (2)
where I(.) is an indicator variable that takes the value of 1 if debt is below a given threshold,
t; and zero otherwise. The indicator variable has the effect of splitting the debt variable into
two, allowing for the impact to differ above and below the threshold.
We look for threshold effects by including one debt variable at a time in equation (2). To
estimate the threshold, we estimate equation (2) for a series of values of debt-to-GDP and
then select the one that minimises the sum of squared residuals. To examine the statistical
significance of the estimated threshold, we can then use a likelihood ratio (LR) statistic,
computed as the difference between the sum of squared residuals of the model for a generic
value of the threshold and the sum of squared residuals corresponding to the estimated
threshold (scaled by the variance of the sample residuals).
39
We can illustrate how this procedure works for the case of public debt in the model with the
crisis variable. (In the absence of the threshold, this is the case reported in column 2 of the
top panel of Table 5.) Graph 4 reports the results for the LR statistic in this case. By
definition, this statistic equals zero at the estimated threshold level. The graph shows that
96% of GDP is the point estimate of the threshold level. At the 1% confidence level, the
threshold level lies between 92 and 99% of GDP that is, the level at which we estimate that
public debt starts to be harmful to growth may be as low as 92% of GDP and as high as 99%
(using 5% or 10% confidence levels would not change the interval much).
38
The results are mostly unaltered when we use the median instead of the mean debt and growth values. We
also split the annual observations using the debt brackets employed by Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) in their
recent analysis of public debt and growth. Using a different dataset, which covers 20 advanced economies
over 19462009, they find that over the 90% threshold public debt tends to be associated with much lower
GDP growth than at lower levels: GDP growth is about 1 percentage point lower at the median and almost
4 percentage points lower at the mean compared with the lowest debt burden group (debt ratios less than
30% of GDP) (see their Figure 2). By contrast, in our sample and using the same brackets for the debt-to-GDP
ratio as Reinhart and Rogoff (2010), we do not find any significant differences in either the mean or median
growth. Our sample, however, is much more limited than theirs: it starts from a much later date and excludes
the latest financial crisis; it covers two countries fewer; and it uses GDP per capita growth rather than GDP
growth, and general government debt rather than central government debt.
39
Hansen (1999) has developed threshold regression methods for non-dynamic panel data models with fixed
effects. Since we are not aware of well established methods to estimate threshold effects in dynamic panel
data models, we follow his suggested inference methods.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
18/34
Graph 4
Likelihood ratio statistic
0
10
20
30
40
50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 106 113 120
Government debt threshold
L
R
LR Statistic 1% Critical value
5% Critical value
10% Critical value
The LR statistic is constructed as ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
2
/ o t t t SSR SSR LR =
, where ( ) t t SSR min arg = ; SSR is the sum of squared
residuals obtained by estimating text equation (2) for different values of the threshold variable.
Table 6 reports results from estimating this threshold model for government, corporate and
household debt separately, with and without the crisis variable. Focusing on the results
where we do not control for crises, we estimate the threshold for government debt at 84% of
GDP. And, when government debt rises to this level, an additional 10 percentage points of
GDP drives trend growth down by some 1015 basis points.
Before continuing, it is worth noting that the impact of public debt on growth could in part
reflect the quality of government. That is, poor governments do a number of things that slow
their economies, and debt is a consequence. We note, however, that because we include
country fixed effects, it would have to be a deterioration in the quality of governance that was
responsible. Unfortunately, we have found no straightforward way of controlling for bad
government.
40
Turning to corporate debt, and again focusing on the results where we do not control for
banking crises, we find two thresholds. One is around 75% and the second is close to 90%.
41
Our estimate is that there is a range between the two thresholds over which
accumulation of corporate debt is relatively neutral. But once that debt reaches the higher of
the thresholds, there is a negative impact on growth. The coefficients suggest, however, that
the economic impact is in the order of half that for government debt.
Finally, there is household debt. The results suggest that we have pushed the data to the
limit. While we find a threshold of 84%, and that the impact of household debt on growth is
first positive and then negative, our estimates lack statistical precision. In fact, the p-values
for the test of whether the coefficients are zero is nearly one half. So, while we may believe
that there is a point beyond which household debt is bad for growth, we are unable to reliably
estimate that point using the historical record available to us.
40
One possibility would be to use the size of government itself, on the reasonable assumption that bad
government leads to bloated public expenditure. However, well run societies may well opt for larger
governments. Corruption measures seem more promising. For example, Kaufmann (2010) provides intriguing
evidence that industrial countries budget deficits over the period 200609 were negatively associated with
measures of perceived corruption. We leave further examination of this issue for future research.
41
We compute the threshold point estimates sequentially. We first look for multiple minima in the sum of
squared residuals of the estimated model. If we find more than one minimum, we fix the first point and repeat
the search for a new point that minimises the sum of squared residuals, and so forth.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
19/34
Table 6
Threshold effects
Threshold estimate Coefficients
Government debt
Controlling for crises 96% <96% >=96%
0.0065 0.0138***
(0.232) (0.004)
Not controlling for crises 84% <84% >=84%
0.0074 0.0133*
(0.382) (0.057)
Corporate debt
Controlling for crises 73% <73% >=73%
0.0119 0.0047
(0.156) (0.474)
Controlling for crises
(2 threshold points)
73%; 99% <73% >=73% &
<99%
>=99%
0.0055 0.0019 0.0038
(0.151) (0.399) (0.208)
Not controlling for crises
(2 threshold points)
73%; 88% <73% >=73% &
<88%
>=88%
0.0041 0.0044 0.0059**
(0.221) (0.260) (0.041)
Household debt
Controlling for crises 84% <84% >=84%
0.0069 0.0065
(0.618) (0.658)
Not controlling for crises 84% <84% >=84%
0.0049 0.0115
(0.733) (0.458)
Reported threshold estimates are obtained by minimising the sum of squared residuals in text equation (2). Reported
coefficients are for the marginal impact of debt on the five-year forward average per capita growth rate from estimating text
equation (2). Numbers in parentheses are asymptotic p-values for the test that the coefficient estimate is equal to zero
computed using standard errors estimated using the Huber-White sandwich estimator. */**/*** indicate coefficient estimates
significantly different from zero at the 10/5/1% level.
Source: Authors calculations.
5. Prospects and challenges
Several industrial countries already have debt levels that, according to the empirical
evidence presented in the previous section, might be growth-damaging. Or, they soon will
be.
As we noted in a previous paper (Cecchetti et al (2011)), public debt ratios are currently on
an explosive path in a number of industrial countries. To prevent further deterioration, these
countries will need to implement drastic policy changes that reduce current deficits, as well
as future contingent and implicit liabilities. Yet stabilisation might not be enough, especially if
it is at a level high enough to damage growth.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
20/34
Unfortunately, the unprecedented acceleration of population ageing that many industrial
countries now face may make this task even more difficult. First, ageing drives government
expenditure up and revenue down, directly worsening debt. But, as our results in the
previous section suggest, there is an additional effect: rising dependency ratios put further
downward pressure on trend growth, over and above the negative effects of debt.
Graph 5 reports dependency ratios, measured as the young and old in society (the non-
working-age population) as a percentage of the working-age population, for advanced and
emerging market economies. The left-hand panel of the graph shows that a majority of
industrial countries are now close to a turning point similar to the one experienced by Japan
in the early 1990s. After having declined and remained relatively stable, total dependency
ratios will increase rapidly in these countries over the next few decades.
Emerging market economies are also ageing. But, with the exception of Central and Eastern
Europe, they lag advanced economies by at least two to three decades. This means that
these economies will continue to enjoy a demographic dividend: as they catch up with richer
economies, their young workforces should continue to support strong growth and saving.
Graph 5
Total dependency ratio
1
Advanced economies Emerging economies
0
20
40
60
80
100
1975 2000 2025 2050 2075 2100
More developed regions
Europe
Japan
United States
0
20
40
60
80
100
1975 2000 2025 2050 2075 2100
Less developed regions
Central and Eastern Europe
Latin America and the Caribbean
Africa
Asia
1
Non-working-age population as a percentage of working-age population.
Source: United Nations, World Population Prospects, 2010 revision.
Recent studies have combined the implications of current fiscal deficits with the estimates of
future increases in health and pension spending in an effort to project public debt to
2040. While they differ in their optimism, these studies all show that, under unchanged fiscal
policy, debt-to-GDP ratios will explode in all but a few countries.
42
The consequences are striking. Debt quickly rises to more than 100% of GDP a level
clearly consistent with negative consequences for growth. And, in a number of countries
Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States the projections rise much further. In the
euro area, the public debt ratio will also rise, albeit less rapidly than in the UK or US,
reflecting the fact that many countries face only a modest rise in the future costs of ageing.
In addition to putting further pressures on public finances, ageing itself might also reduce per
capita growth, making it potentially even more difficult for a country to sustain a given level of
42
See eg Auerbach (2011), Cecchetti et al (2011), Gagnon (2011) and IMF (2011).
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
21/34
debt. With unchanged public policies, the ever greater amount of resources that will be
channelled to the elderly through pension and health care spending will increase.
Furthermore, older people save less than people in younger age groups. The exact timing at
which saving might be reduced and the impact on real interest rates are controversial,
depending on public policies and saving in the emerging world, among other things.
43,
44
That said, the fact that ageing is asynchronous around the world may help more advanced
and highly indebted countries to smooth the consequences. There are at least three reasons
for that. First, immigration can partly slow the shrinking of labour forces in advanced
economies. Second, as incomes and wealth rise, emerging economy savings may continue
to flow to countries with more advanced financial markets and lower-risk assets, keeping
interest rates down and permitting their capital stocks to grow.
45
And finally, trade may also
reduce the need for more radical changes in the composition of demand that ageing might
otherwise bring with it.
Such benefits of globalisation should help countries adopt the necessary reforms needed to
reduce their public debt while at the same time helping the private sector through the
abundance of the supply of savings and the continuous low real interest rates globally to do
the necessary post-crisis balance sheet repair.
6. Conclusions
While the attention of policymakers following the recent crisis has been on reducing systemic
risk stemming from a highly leveraged financial system, the challenges extend beyond that.
Our examination of debt and economic activity in industrial countries leads us to conclude
that there is a clear linkage: high debt is bad for growth. When public debt is in a range of
85% of GDP, further increases in debt may begin to have a significant impact on growth:
specifically, a further 10 percentage point increase reduces trend growth by more than one
tenth of 1 percentage point. For corporate debt, the threshold is slightly lower, closer to
90%, and the impact is roughly half as big. Meanwhile for household debt, our best guess is
that there is a threshold at something like 85% of GDP, but the estimate of the impact is
extremely imprecise.
A clear implication of these results is that the debt problems facing advanced economies are
even worse than we thought. Given the benefits that governments have promised to their
populations, ageing will sharply raise public debt to much higher levels in the next few
decades. At the same time, ageing may reduce future growth and may also raise interest
rates, further undermining debt sustainability. So, as public debt rises and populations age,
growth will fall. As growth falls, debt rises even more, reinforcing the downward impact on an
already low growth rate. The only possible conclusion is that advanced countries with high
43
In theory, ageing has an ambiguous effect on capital intensity. The reduction of labour forces might increase
capital-to-labour ratios. Indeed, some studies suggest that ageing at the global level will continue to put
downward pressure on global real interest rates for many years to come (see eg Attanasio et al (2007) and
Krueger and Ludwig (2007)). On the other hand, with unchanged policies, the need to finance ever larger age-
related spending may lead to a shortage of capital, which would put upward pressure on real interest rates
(see eg Fehr et al (2005)).
44
Ageing may also adversely affect asset prices. For example, a recent study by Takts (2010) finds that ageing
may have a negative impact on house prices.
45
On emerging markets demand for safe assets, see Caballero et al (2008) and Caballero (2010). More
generally on the ex ante excess saving in emerging markets and its implications for global real interest rates,
see Bernanke (2005) and Bernanke et al (2011).
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
22/34
debt must act quickly and decisively to address their looming fiscal problems. The longer
they wait, the bigger the negative impact will be on growth, and the harder it will be to adjust.
It is important to note that our finding of a threshold for the effects of public debt on growth
does not imply that authorities should aim at stabilising their debt at this level. On the
contrary, since governments never know when an extraordinary shock will hit, it is wise to
aim at keeping debt at levels well below this threshold.
As with government debt, we have known for some time that when the private sector
becomes highly indebted, the real economy can suffer.
46
But, what should we do about it?
Current efforts focus on raising the cost of credit and making funding less readily available to
would-be borrowers. Maybe we should go further, reducing both direct government subsidies
and the preferential treatment debt receives. In the end, the only way out is to increase
saving.
46
See eg Tang and Upper (2010) for a study of debt deleveraging following systemic banking crises.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
23/34
Appendix 1: Description and sources of data used in the paper
A. Non-financial sector debt
The time series constructed are generally taken from national balance sheet statistics (flow
of funds) as available either from the OECD website or from national sources/databases
(eg Federal Reserve Flow of Funds, Bank of Japan Flow of Funds). The target dataset is
annual frequency beginning in 1980, for 18 OECD countries. The countries included in the
sample are the following: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France,
Germany, Greece, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, the
United Kingdom and the United States.
The sectors covered are (i) households and non-profit institutions serving households
(NPISHs) (S14 + S15); (ii) non-financial corporations (S11); and (iii) general government
(S13), as defined in the System of National Accounts (SNA 2008) or its previous version
(SNA 1993). For simplicity, debt is defined as the following (for all apart from the United
States): gross liabilities for households and general government, and total liabilities less
shares and other equities for non-financial corporations. For the United States, the item
credit market instruments on the liabilities side is taken for each sector.
The debt series are mostly at market value and on a non-consolidated basis, so may differ
from other sources. For many countries (all except Canada, Japan, Spain and the United
States), the data under SNA 1993 are not available from 1980. Hence, these are
extended/backdated
47
using data from old compilations. For example, for Italy and Sweden,
old flow of funds data can be retrieved from their national websites. For France, Germany
and the United Kingdom, old data are taken from old national sources.
For some countries, flow of funds data do not go back far enough, so we use other
sources/proxy series. For non-financial corporations, an old OECD publication entitled Non-
financial enterprises financial statements and bank credit data have been used to backdate
the series.
48
For the household sector, bank credit/loans to households have been used. For
general government, the IMFs historical public debt database (2010) has been used and the
data gaps interpolated.
49, 50
B. Other data used in the panel model
Gross national savings sourced from IMF, World Economic Outlook. Data on population, real
GDP per capita and openness in current prices from Penn World Tables. Average number of
years spent in school of population aged 15 and over taken from Barro and Lee
(2000) (available only up to 2000 and every five years, interpolated by repeating the last
available value). Data on consumer prices, overall dependency ratio and liquid liabilities as a
share of GDP sourced from World Bank, World Development Indicators. Crisis dates taken
from Carmen M Reinhart.
51
47
Backdating is based on the first common period link method, where the level of the new series and growth
rates of old series are reflected in the final time series. For Denmark and Norway, no backdates of household
credit are available.
48
Using bank credit may have limitations, as credit from capital markets is excluded.
49
See Abbas et al (2010), http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.cfm?sk=24332.0. In general, the levels
from the Flow of Funds total liabilities (which are the final series used) are higher than those from IMF public
debt data, as there are more items included in the former. The data gaps/missing values are normally one to
two years.
50
Our debt database reflects data availability up to early 2011.
51
http://terpconnect.umd.edu/~creinhar/Courses.html.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
24/34
Appendix 2: Sectoral composition of non-financial debt
Table A2.1
Household debt
As a percentage of GDP
Levels Changes
2
1980 1990 2000 2010
1
198090 19902000 200010
United States 52 64 74 95 12 10 21
Japan 60 82 87 82 22 5 5
Germany 59 61 73 64 2 13 9
United Kingdom 37 73 75 106 36 2 31
France 27 46 47 69 18 2 22
Italy 6 21 30 53 15 9 23
Canada 56 63 67 94 7 4 27
Australia 42 46 74 113 5 27 39
Austria 41 41 47 57 0 6 10
Belgium 35 38 41 56 3 3 15
Denmark 95 152 57
Finland 29 48 35 67 19 14 33
Greece 8 9 20 65 1 11 45
Netherlands 43 49 87 130 6 38 43
Norway 64 94 31
Portugal 15 23 75 106 7 52 31
Spain 24 41 54 91 17 13 37
Sweden 53 61 51 87 8 10 36
Total of above
Median 39 47 65 94 8 8 31
Weighted average
3
46 60 69 90 14 9 18
Simple average 37 48 61 93 11 11 27
G7 43 59 65 87 16 6 16
Other advanced 32 39 58 97 7 14 34
Memo: Std deviation 17 20 21 28
1
Some figures refer to 2009.
2
In percentage points of GDP.
3
Based on 2005 GDP and PPP exchange
rates.
Sources: OECD; national data, authors estimates.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
25/34
Table A2.2
Non-financial corporate debt
As a percentage of GDP
Levels Changes
2
1980 1990 2000 2010
1
198090 19902000 200010
United States 53 65 66 76 12 1 9
Japan 176 215 178 161 39 37 17
Germany 46 35 91 100 11 56 9
United Kingdom 64 88 93 126 23 6 33
France 99 106 123 155 7 17 32
Italy 48 66 96 128 17 30 32
Canada 109 106 111 107 4 5 4
Australia 44 82 74 80 38 8 6
Austria 86 78 82 99 8 4 17
Belgium 73 86 136 185 12 51 49
Denmark 72 78 90 119 6 13 28
Finland 101 102 121 145 1 19 25
Greece 59 47 51 65 12 3 15
Netherlands 98 119 140 121 21 21 19
Norway 84 105 148 174 21 43 26
Portugal 93 50 114 153 42 63 39
Spain 120 97 133 193 23 36 60
Sweden 109 174 191 196 66 17 4
Total of above
Median 85 87 112 126 9 17 21
Weighted average
3
79 92 99 113 13 7 12
Simple average 85 94 113 128 9 19 19
G7 85 97 108 109 12 11 13
Other advanced 85 93 116 138 7 24 23
Memo: Std deviation 33 44 37 44
1
Some figures refer to 2009.
2
In percentage points of GDP.
3
Based on 2005 GDP and PPP exchange
rates.
Sources: OECD; national data, authors estimates.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
26/34
Table A2.3
Government debt
As a percentage of GDP
Levels Changes
2
1980 1990 2000 2010
1
198090 19902000 200010
United States 46 71 58 97 25 13 39
Japan 53 66 145 213 13 78 68
Germany 31 42 61 77 10 20 16
United Kingdom 58 42 54 89 16 12 35
France 34 46 73 97 12 27 24
Italy 54 93 126 129 39 33 4
Canada 71 109 115 113 39 6 3
Australia 43 46 37 41 3 8 4
Austria 36 59 76 82 23 17 6
Belgium 61 140 121 115 79 19 6
Denmark 36 77 73 65 41 5 8
Finland 16 23 67 57 7 44 9
Greece 26 83 124 132 57 42 7
Netherlands 65 97 67 76 33 30 9
Norway 43 38 44 65 6 6 21
Portugal 36 68 63 107 33 6 45
Spain 27 49 71 72 21 22 1
Sweden 58 54 77 58 4 24 20
Total of above
Median 43 63 72 97 22 15 7
Weighted average
3
46 66 78 104 20 12 31
Simple average 44 67 81 93 23 14 13
G7 50 67 90 107 17 23 26
Other advanced 41 67 75 85 26 8 5
Memo: Std deviation 15 29 31 29
1
Some figures refer to 2009.
2
In percentage points of GDP.
3
Based on 2005 GDP and PPP exchange
rates.
Sources: OECD; national data, authors estimates.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
27/34
Appendix 3: Detailed results for growth regressions
Table A3.1 Growth regressions with debt and crisis variables
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)
VARIABLES growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05
National gross saving to GDP 0.0409 0.0550* 0.0430 0.0648** 0.0408 0.0689* 0.0635* 0.0437 0.0622* 0.0630* 0.0685*
(0.026) (0.030) (0.027) (0.030) (0.025) (0.035) (0.030) (0.027) (0.032) (0.031) (0.033)
Change in population 0.4482 0.2540 0.4183 0.3689 0.4531 0.3593 0.2684 0.3907 0.2883 0.2687 0.3658
(0.362) (0.349) (0.385) (0.342) (0.371) (0.344) (0.362) (0.401) (0.349) (0.362) (0.346)
Schooling 0.0051*** 0.0033 0.0054*** 0.0034 0.0051*** 0.0035* 0.0042* 0.0054*** 0.0042* 0.0042** 0.0035*
(0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Log of real per capita GDP 0.1565*** 0.1635*** 0.1865*** 0.1568*** 0.1566*** 0.1591*** 0.1870*** 0.1872*** 0.1857*** 0.1868*** 0.1590***
(0.015) (0.018) (0.014) (0.015) (0.014) (0.017) (0.015) (0.015) (0.015) (0.016) (0.017)
Trade openness 0.0311** 0.0326** 0.0341** 0.0305** 0.0311** 0.0306** 0.0312** 0.0343** 0.0308** 0.0312** 0.0304**
(0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.013) (0.012) (0.013) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.013)
Inflation rate 0.0049 0.0239 0.0176 0.0150 0.0049 0.0139 0.0268 0.0181 0.0267 0.0270 0.0139
(0.018) (0.021) (0.016) (0.017) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.017) (0.019) (0.019) (0.018)
Total dependency ratio 0.1955*** 0.1814*** 0.2195*** 0.1972*** 0.1971*** 0.1925*** 0.2142*** 0.2117*** 0.2204*** 0.2145*** 0.1950***
(0.044) (0.045) (0.041) (0.045) (0.045) (0.043) (0.041) (0.040) (0.042) (0.039) (0.043)
Liquid liabilities to GDP 0.9935 1.1207 1.2387*** 1.0038 0.9995 0.9530 1.2702*** 1.2166*** 1.2968*** 1.2753*** 0.9643
(0.693) (0.662) (0.387) (0.683) (0.647) (0.783) (0.368) (0.373) (0.445) (0.432) (0.724)
Banking crisis 0.0134*** 0.0116*** 0.0135*** 0.0132*** 0.0135*** 0.0129*** 0.0136*** 0.0130*** 0.0141*** 0.0136*** 0.0131***
(0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005)
Total non-financial debt 0.0078
(0.006)
Government debt 0.0167*** 0.0180** 0.0174*** 0.0175*** 0.0180**
(0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006)
Private debt 0.0016 0.0023
(0.007) (0.006)
Corporate debt 0.0006 0.0030 0.0023 0.0008
(0.007) (0.006) (0.007) (0.008)
Household debt 0.0050 0.0033 0.0027 0.0047
(0.014) (0.012) (0.012) (0.013)
Constant 1.6429*** 1.6854*** 1.9714*** 1.6102*** 1.6441*** 1.6717*** 1.9243*** 1.9781*** 1.9136*** 1.9225*** 1.6709***
(0.157) (0.195) (0.155) (0.153) (0.153) (0.179) (0.153) (0.161) (0.158) (0.169) (0.177)
Observations 383 354 383 354 383 354 354 383 354 354 354
R-squared 0.749 0.766 0.772 0.757 0.749 0.757 0.780 0.773 0.779 0.780 0.757
Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
28/34
Table A3.2 Growth regressions adding financial flow variables
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)
VARIABLES growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05
National gross saving to GDP 0.0240 0.0038 0.0193 0.0269 0.0241 0.0301 0.0071 0.0186 0.0098 0.0083 0.0298
(0.020) (0.021) (0.016) (0.025) (0.020) (0.027) (0.018) (0.017) (0.021) (0.020) (0.028)
Change in population 0.8203* 0.5437 0.6365* 0.8679* 0.8600* 0.8272* 0.5065 0.5574 0.6071 0.5045 0.8615*
(0.444) (0.490) (0.363) (0.464) (0.456) (0.458) (0.406) (0.392) (0.370) (0.409) (0.470)
Schooling 0.0021 0.0021 0.0033 0.0022 0.0021 0.0023 0.0032 0.0035 0.0031 0.0032 0.0023
(0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002)
Log of real per capita GDP 0.1644*** 0.1746*** 0.2026*** 0.1670*** 0.1650*** 0.1691*** 0.2046*** 0.2049*** 0.2014*** 0.2053*** 0.1688***
(0.015) (0.019) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.018) (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.019) (0.017)
Trade openness 0.0184 0.0149 0.0118 0.0181 0.0185 0.0178 0.0103 0.0111 0.0112 0.0103 0.0179
(0.013) (0.012) (0.012) (0.013) (0.012) (0.014) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.013)
Inflation rate 0.0035 0.0019 0.0009 0.0049 0.0032 0.0067 0.0016 0.0012 0.0010 0.0021 0.0060
(0.023) (0.025) (0.019) (0.023) (0.023) (0.024) (0.021) (0.020) (0.022) (0.023) (0.024)
Total dependency ratio 0.1888*** 0.1849*** 0.2320*** 0.1965*** 0.1958*** 0.1890*** 0.2270*** 0.2244*** 0.2350*** 0.2263*** 0.1948***
(0.047) (0.046) (0.042) (0.047) (0.046) (0.047) (0.042) (0.039) (0.041) (0.038) (0.045)
Liquid liabilities to GDP 1.1373* 1.2306** 1.3937*** 1.1389* 1.1720* 1.0664 1.4142*** 1.3595*** 1.4461*** 1.4002*** 1.1031
(0.626) (0.575) (0.375) (0.622) (0.594) (0.692) (0.354) (0.351) (0.442) (0.419) (0.670)
Banking crisis 0.0079*** 0.0059** 0.0089*** 0.0086*** 0.0085*** 0.0079** 0.0077*** 0.0081*** 0.0087*** 0.0076*** 0.0085**
(0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003)
Five-year forward average of
private borrowing to GDP 0.0437* 0.0259 0.0288* 0.0461* 0.0458* 0.0437* 0.0206 0.0242 0.0267 0.0204 0.0456*
(0.023) (0.027) (0.016) (0.025) (0.024) (0.024) (0.020) (0.019) (0.017) (0.021) (0.025)
Five-year forward average of
government borrowing to GDP 0.0567 0.0950*** 0.0939*** 0.0546 0.0537 0.0588 0.1138*** 0.1019*** 0.1018*** 0.1140*** 0.0555
(0.034) (0.031) (0.028) (0.040) (0.034) (0.040) (0.034) (0.031) (0.032) (0.035) (0.042)
Total non-financial debt 0.0103*
(0.005)
Government debt 0.0208*** 0.0240*** 0.0226*** 0.0218*** 0.0240***
(0.004) (0.006) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005)
Private debt 0.0030 0.0051
(0.006) (0.005)
Corporate debt 0.0027 0.0043 0.0054 0.0023
(0.007) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007)
Household debt 0.0065 0.0047 0.0041 0.0057
(0.011) (0.010) (0.010) (0.011)
Constant 1.7571*** 1.8342*** 2.1818*** 1.7318*** 1.7630*** 1.7976*** 2.1482*** 2.2080*** 2.1131*** 2.1538*** 1.7958***
(0.170) (0.208) (0.154) (0.154) (0.157) (0.198) (0.169) (0.183) (0.165) (0.203) (0.193)
Observations 362 354 362 354 362 354 354 362 354 354 354
R-squared 0.798 0.803 0.825 0.793 0.799 0.793 0.823 0.827 0.821 0.823 0.793
Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
29/34
Table A3.3 Growth regressions without crisis variable
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)
VARIABLES growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05 growth05
National gross saving to GDP 0.0395 0.0431 0.0414 0.0479 0.0414 0.0562 0.0462 0.0446 0.0502 0.0558 0.0611*
(0.026) (0.033) (0.029) (0.029) (0.026) (0.035) (0.033) (0.030) (0.035) (0.037) (0.035)
Change in population 0.2109 0.0966 0.1800 0.1896 0.1650 0.2296 0.0905 0.1094 0.1654 0.0897 0.1854
(0.306) (0.303) (0.281) (0.321) (0.296) (0.330) (0.298) (0.283) (0.306) (0.301) (0.324)
Schooling 0.0051** 0.0019 0.0054*** 0.0015 0.0051** 0.0017 0.0022 0.0054*** 0.0021 0.0025 0.0020
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Log of real per capita GDP 0.1621*** 0.1729*** 0.1916*** 0.1567*** 0.1601*** 0.1634*** 0.1851*** 0.1936*** 0.1844*** 0.1898*** 0.1641***
(0.017) (0.020) (0.020) (0.019) (0.019) (0.021) (0.021) (0.019) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022)
Trade openness 0.0407** 0.0452** 0.0437*** 0.0445** 0.0401** 0.0444** 0.0455** 0.0433** 0.0456** 0.0451** 0.0439**
(0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.017) (0.016) (0.017) (0.016) (0.015) (0.016) (0.017) (0.018)
Inflation rate 0.0157 0.0401 0.0282 0.0313 0.0146 0.0292 0.0429 0.0287 0.0402 0.0397 0.0272
(0.026) (0.026) (0.024) (0.026) (0.026) (0.024) (0.025) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.025)
Total dependency ratio 0.1637*** 0.1533*** 0.1870*** 0.1521*** 0.1431** 0.1658*** 0.1670*** 0.1614*** 0.1856*** 0.1624*** 0.1464***
(0.054) (0.051) (0.052) (0.049) (0.056) (0.049) (0.049) (0.052) (0.049) (0.048) (0.049)
Liquid liabilities to GDP 0.3023 0.7008 0.5382 0.5013 0.2907 0.4208 0.7387 0.5598 0.6512 0.6486 0.3842
(1.028) (0.880) (0.809) (1.050) (1.013) (1.095) (0.783) (0.711) (0.917) (0.828) (1.083)
Total non-financial debt 0.0116**
(0.005)
Government debt 0.0164** 0.0169** 0.0191*** 0.0136* 0.0165**
(0.007) (0.007) (0.006) (0.008) (0.007)
Private debt 0.0054 0.0093**
(0.005) (0.004)
Corporate debt 0.0082 0.0117** 0.0109* 0.0078
(0.006) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006)
Household debt 0.0023 0.0043 0.0013 0.0055
(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)
Constant 1.6835*** 1.7789*** 2.0059*** 1.6251*** 1.6615*** 1.6877*** 1.9234*** 2.0268*** 1.9139*** 1.9616*** 1.6876***
(0.193) (0.212) (0.212) (0.201) (0.211) (0.208) (0.217) (0.211) (0.218) (0.232) (0.224)
Observations 383 354 383 354 383 354 354 383 354 354 354
R-squared 0.683 0.726 0.705 0.710 0.690 0.706 0.730 0.719 0.720 0.731 0.712
Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli The real effects of debt
30/34
References
Abbas, A, N Belhocine, A ElGanainy and M Horton (2010): A historical public debt
database, IMF Working Papers, no. 10/245.
Aghion, P, D Hemous and E Kharroubi (2011): Cyclical fiscal policy, credit constraints, and
industry growth, BIS Working Papers, no 340, February.
Akerlof, G and R Shiller (2010): Animal spirits: how human psychology drives the economy,
and why it matters, Princeton University Press.
Anderson, T and C Hsiao (1981): Estimation of dynamic models with error components,
Journal of the American Statistical Association, no 76, pp 598606.
Arellano, M and S Bond (1991): Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo
evidence and an application to employment equations, Review of Economic Studies, no 58,
pp 27797.
Arellano, M and O Bover (1995): Another look at the instrumental variables estimation of
error component models, Journal of Econometrics, no 68, pp 2952.
Attanasio, O, S Kitao and G Violante (2007): Global demographic trends and social security
reform, Journal of Monetary Economics, no 54, pp 14498.
Auerbach, A (2011): Long-term fiscal sustainability in major economies, paper presented at
the 10th BIS Annual Conference, Lucerne, June.
Barro, R (1979): On the determination of the public debt, Journal of Political Economy,
no 87, pp 94071.
Barro, R and J Lee (2000): International data on educational attainment: updates and
implications, CID Working Papers, no 42, April.
Barro, R and X Sala-i-Martin (2004): Economic growth, second edition, MIT Press.
Beck, T and A Demirg-Kunt (2009): Financial institutions and markets across countries
and over time: data and analysis, World Bank Policy Research Working Papers, no 4943.
Beck, T, A Demirg-Kunt and R Levine (2000): A new database on financial development
and structure, World Bank Economic Review, no 14, pp 597605.
Bekaert, G, C Harvey and C Lundblad (2001): Emerging equity markets and economic
development, Journal of Development Economics, no 66, pp 465504.
(2005): Does financial liberalization spur growth?, Journal of Financial Economics,
no 77, pp 355.
Benito, A, M Waldron, G Young and F Zampolli (2007): The role of household debt and
balance sheets in the monetary transmission mechanism, Bank of England Quarterly
Bulletin, 47(1), pp 708.
Bernanke, B (2005): The global saving glut and the US current account deficit, speech at
the Sandridge Lecture, Richmond, 10 March.
Bernanke, B, C Bertaut, L DeMarco and S Kamin (2011), International capital flows and the
returns to safe assets in the United States, 20032007, International Finance Discussion
Papers, no 1014.
Bernanke, B and M Gertler (1990): Financial fragility and economic performance, Quarterly
Journal of Economics, no 105, pp 87114.
Bernanke, B, M Gertler and S Gilchrist (1999): The financial accelerator in a quantitative
business cycle framework, in J Taylor and M Woodford (eds), Handbook of
Macroeconomics, chapter 21, Elsevier, pp 134193.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli
31/34
Borio, C and P Disyatat (2011): Global imbalances and the financial crisis: link or no link?,
BIS Working Papers, no 346, May.
Borio, C, C Furfine and P Lowe (2001): Procyclicality of the financial system and financial
stability: issues and policy options, in Marrying the macro and microprudential dimensions of
financial stability, BIS Papers, no 1, March.
Caballero, R (2010): The other imbalance and the financial crisis, NBER Working Papers,
no 15636.
Caballero, R, E Farhi and P Gourinchas (2008): An equilibrium model of global imbalances
and low interest rates, American Economic Review, vol 98, no 1, pp 35893.
Cecchetti, S, A Flores-Lagunes and S Krause (2005): Assessing the sources of changes in
the volatility of real growth, in C Kent and D Norman (eds), The changing nature of the
business cycle, proceedings of the Research Conference of the Reserve Bank of Australia,
November, pp 11538.
Cecchetti, S, M Mohanty and F Zampolli (2011): The future of public debt, in S Gokarn (ed),
Challenges to central banking in the context of the financial crisis, New Delhi: Academic
Foundation, pp 183217.
Cecchetti, S and K Schoenholtz (2011): Money, banking and financial markets, third edition,
New York, McGraw-Hill Irwin.
Checherita, C and P Rother (2010): The impact of high and growing government debt on
economic growth. An empirical investigation for the euro area, European Central Bank
Working Papers, no 1237, August.
Cukierman, A and A Meltzer (1989): A political theory of government debt and deficits in a
neo-Ricardian framework, American Economic Review, vol 79, no 4, pp 71332.
Dynan, K, D Elmendorf and D Sichel (2006): Can financial innovation help to explain the
reduced volatility of economic activity?, Journal of Monetary Economics, no 53, pp 12350.
Dynan, K and D Kohn (2007): The role of US household indebtedness: causes and
consequences, Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series,
2007-37, August.
Eggertson, G and P Krugman (2011): Debt, deleveraging, and the liquidity trap: a Fisher-
Minsky-Koo approach, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, unpublished manuscript,
February.
Eichengreen, B, R Feldman, J Liebman, J von Hagen and C Wyplosz (2011): Public debts:
nuts, bolts and worries, Geneva Report on the World Economy, no 13, CEPR, August.
Fehr, H, S Jokisch and L Kotlikoff (2005): The developed worlds demographic transition
the roles of capital flows, immigration, and policy, in R Brooks and A Razin (eds), Social
security reform financial and political issues in international perspective, Cambridge
University Press.
Friedman, M (1981): Debt and economic activity in the United States, in M Friedman (ed),
The changing roles of debt and equity in financing US capital formation, University of
Chicago Press.
(1986): Increasing indebtedness and financial stability in the United States, in Debt,
Financial Stability and Public Policy, a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City, pp 2752.
(1987): New directions in the relationship between public and private debt, NBER
Working Papers, no 2186, March.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli
32/34
Gagnon, J (2011): The global outlook for government debt over the next 25 years:
implications for the economy and public policy, Peterson Institute for International
Economics, Washington DC, June.
Hansen, B (1999): Threshold effects in non-dynamic panels: estimation, testing, and
inference, Journal of Econometrics, no 93, pp 34568.
Huber, P (1967): The behavior of maximum likelihood estimates under non-standard
conditions, in Proceedings of the Fifth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and
Probability, Berkeley, University of California Press, vol 1, pp 22133.
International Monetary Fund (2011): Shifting gears: tackling challenges on the road to fiscal
adjustment, Fiscal Monitor, April.
Islam, N (1995): Growth empirics: a panel data approach, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
no 110, pp 112770.
Judson, R and A Owen (1999): Estimating dynamic panel data models: a guide for
macroeconomists, Economic Letters, no 65, pp 915.
Kaufmann, D (2010): Can corruption adversely affect public finances in industrialized
countries?, Brookings Institution, April.
Keen, M, A Klemm and V Perry (2010): Tax and the crisis, Fiscal Studies, no 31, pp 4379.
Kiyotaki, N and J Moore (1997): Credit cycles, Journal of Political Economy, no 105,
pp 21148.
Krueger, D and A Ludwig (2007): On the consequences of demographic change for rates of
returns to capital, and the distribution of wealth and welfare, Journal of Monetary
Economics, no 54, pp 4987.
Kumar, M and J Woo (2010): Public debt and growth, IMF Working Papers, no 10/174,
July.
Levine, R (2005): Finance and growth: theory, evidence and mechanisms, in P Aghion and
S Durlauf (eds), Handbook of economic growth, vol 1, part 1, Amsterdam: North Holland,
pp 865934.
Modigliani, F and S Cao (2004): The Chinese saving puzzle and the life-cycle hypothesis,
Journal of Economic Literature, no 42, pp 14570.
Myers, S (2010): Capital structure, Journal of Economic Perspectives, no 15, pp 81102.
Nickell, S (1981): Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects, Econometrica, no 49,
pp 141726.
Obstfeld, M and K Rogoff (2009): Global imbalance and the financial crisis: product of
common causes, paper prepared for the Federal Reserve Bank of San Franciscos
conference on Asia and the Global Financial Crisis.
Reinhart, C and K Rogoff (2008): Banking crises: an equal opportunity menace, NBER
Working Papers, no 14587, December.
(2009): This time is different. Eight centuries of financial folly, Princeton University
Press.
(2010): Growth in time of debt, American Economic Review Papers & Proceedings,
no 100, pp 5738.
Rogers, W (1993): Regression standard errors in clustered samples, Stata Technical
Bulletin, no 13, pp 1923; reprinted in Stata Technical Bulletin Reprints, no 3, pp 8894.
Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli
33/34
Shin, H (2009): Global imbalances, twin crises and the financial stability role of monetary
policy, paper prepared for the KIEP/CEPR conference on The World Economy with the G20,
Seoul, 20 November.
Stock, J, J Wright and M Yogo (2002): A survey of weak instruments and weak identification
in generalized method of moments, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, no 20,
pp 51829.
Takts, E (2010): Ageing and asset prices, BIS Working Papers, no 318, August.
Tang, G and C Upper (2010): Debt reduction after crises, BIS Quarterly Review,
September.
Waldron, M and F Zampolli (2010a): Household debt, house prices and consumption in the
United Kingdom: a quantitative theoretical analysis, Bank of England Working Papers,
no 379.
(2010b): The rise in home prices and household debt in the UK: potential causes and
implications, chapter 5 in S Smith and B Searle (eds), The Blackwell companion to the
economics of housing. The housing wealth of nations, Wiley-Blackwell.
White, H (1980): A heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct
test for heteroscedasticity, Econometrica, no 48, pp 81730.
Woodford, M (1990): Public debt as private liquidity, American Economic Review, vol 80,
no 2, pp 38288.
(2003): Interest and prices: foundations of a theory of monetary policy, Princeton
University Press.
(2011): Financial stability and monetary policy, presentation at the NBER Summer
Institute, July.