Public Debt and Low Interest Rate
Public Debt and Low Interest Rate
Public Debt and Low Interest Rate
Olivier Blanchard ∗
∗
Peterson Institute for International Economics and MIT (oblanchard@piie.com) Pre-
liminary. Do not quote. AEA Presidential Lecture, to be given in January 2019. Spe-
cial thanks to Larry Summers for many discussions and many insights. Thanks for com-
ments, suggestions, and data to Simcha Barkai, Charles Bean, Philipp Barrett, John Camp-
bell, John Cochrane, Carlo Cottarelli, Peter Diamond, Stanley Fischer, Francesco Giavazzi,
Larry Kotlikoff, Lorenz Kueng, Thomas Philippon, Jim Poterba, Robert Solow, Jaume Ven-
tura, Philippe Weil, Jeromin Zettelmeyer, and my PIIE colleagues. Thanks for outstanding
research assistance to Thomas Pellet, Colombe Ladreit, and Gonzalo Huertas.
2
Abstract
The lecture focuses on the costs of public debt when safe interest
rates are low. I develop four main arguments.
First, I show that the current situation in which, in the United States,
safe interest rates are expected to remain below growth rates for a long
time, is more the historical norm than the exception. If the future is
like the past, this implies that debt rollovers, that is the issuance of debt
without a later increase in taxes may well be feasible. Put bluntly, public
debt may have no fiscal cost
Second, even in the absence of fiscal costs, public debt however re-
duces capital accumulation, and may have welfare costs. I show that
welfare costs may be smaller than typically assumed. The reason is that,
in effect, the safe rate is the risk-adjusted rate of return on capital. If it
is lower than the growth rate, it indicates that the risk-adjusted rate of
return to capital is in fact low. The average risky rate however also plays
a role. I show how both the average risky rate and the average safe rate
determine welfare outcomes.
Third, I look at the evidence on the average risky rate, i.e. the average
marginal product of capital. While the measured profit rate has been
and is still quite high, the evidence from asset markets suggests that the
marginal product of capital may be lower, with the difference reflecting
either mismeasurement of capital or rents. This matters for debt: The
lower the marginal product, the lower the welfare cost of debt.
Fourth, I discuss a number of arguments against high public debt,
and in particular the existence of multiple equilibria where investors
believe debt to be risky, and by requiring a risk premium, increase the
fiscal burden and make debt effectively more risky. This is a very rel-
evant argument, but it does not have straightforward implications for
the appropriate level of debt.
My purpose in the lecture is not to argue for more public debt, espe-
cially in the current political environment. It is to have a richer discus-
sion of the costs of debt and of fiscal policy than is currently the case.
3
Since 1980, interest rates on U.S. government bonds have decreased steadily.
They are now lower than the growth rate, and according to current forecasts,
this is expected to remain the case for the foreseeable future. For example,
10-year nominal rates hover around 3%. Given a target inflation rate of 2%
for the Fed, this implies real rates around 1%, substantially lower than the
forecasts of real growth over the next ten years. Inflation-indexed bonds
send a similar message, with yields on 10-year and even 30-year bonds around
1%.
The question this paper asks is what the implications of such low rates
should be for government debt policy. It reaches strong, and, I expect, sur-
prising, conclusions. Put (too) simply, the signal sent by low rates is that not
only debt may not have a substantial fiscal cost, but also that it may have
limited welfare costs.
Given that these conclusions are at odds with the widespread notion that
government debt levels are much too high and must urgently be decreased,
the paper considers several counterarguments, ranging from distortions, to
the possibility that the future may be very different from the recent past, to
multiple equilibria. All these arguments have merit, but they imply a differ-
ent discussion from that dominating current discussions of fiscal policy.
The lecture is organized as follows.
Section 1 looks at the past behavior of U.S. interest rates and growth rates.
It concludes that the current situation is actually not unusual. While interest
rates on public debt vary a lot, they have on average, and in most decades,
been lower than growth rates. If the future is like the past, the probability
that the US government can do a debt rollover, that is issue debt and achieve
a decreasing debt to GDP ratio without ever having to raise taxes later is high.
That debt rollovers may be feasible does not imply however that they are
desirable. Even if higher debt does not give rise later to a higher tax burden,
it still has effects on capital accumulation, and thus on welfare. Whether
4
is less than the growth rate, but the average marginal product of capital ex-
ceeds the growth rate, the two effects have opposite signs, and the effect of
the transfer on welfare is ambiguous. The section ends with an approxima-
tion which shows most clearly the relative role of each of the two rates. The
net effect may be positive, if the safe rate is sufficiently low, and the average
marginal product is not too high.
With these results in mind, Section 3 turns to numerical simulations based
on the Diamond model extended to allow for technological uncertainty. Peo-
ple live for two periods, working in the first, and retiring in the second. They
have separate preferences vis a vis intertemporal substitution and risk. This
allows to look at different combinations of risky and safe rates, depending on
the degree of uncertainty and the degree of risk aversion. Production is CES
in labor and capital, and subject to technological shocks: Being able to vary
the elasticity of substitution between the two turns out to be important as
this elasticity determines the strength of the second effect on welfare. There
is no technological progress, nor population growth, so the average growth
rate is equal to zero.
I show how the welfare effects of a transfer can be positive or negative,
and how they depend in particular on the elasticity of substitution between
capital and labor. In the case of a linear technology (equivalently, an infi-
nite elasticity of substitution between labor and capital), the rates of return,
while random, are independent of capital accumulation, so that only the
first effect is at work, and the safe rate is the only relevant rate in determin-
ing the effect of the transfer on welfare. I then show how a lower elasticity of
substitution implies a more negative second effect, leading to an ambiguous
welfare outcome.
I then turn to debt and show that a debt rollover differs in two ways from
a transfer scheme. First, with respect to feasibility. So long as the safe rate
remains less than the growth rate, debt to GDP decreases over time; a se-
6
Easing. The current (August 2018) 1-year T-bill nominal rate is 2.4%, sub-
stantially below the current nominal growth rate, 5% quarter over quarter.
The gap between the two is expected to narrow, but most forecasts and
market signals have interest rates remaining below growth rates for a long
time to come. Despite a strong fiscal expansion putting pressure on rates in
an economy close to full employment, the current 10-year nominal rate is
around 3%, while forecasts of nominal growth over the same period are be-
tween 4 and 5%.1 Looking at real rates instead, the current 10-year inflation-
indexed rate is around 1%, while most forecasts of real growth over the same
period range from 1.5 to 2.5%.2
These forecasts come with substantial uncertainty. Some argue that these
low rates reflect “secular stagnation” forces that are likely to remain relevant
for the foreseeable future (for example, Summers (2015), Rachel and Sum-
mers (2018)). Others point to factors such as aging in advanced economies,
better social insurance or lower reserve accumulation in emerging markets,
which may lead eventually to higher rates (for extensive surveys, see for ex-
ample Lukasz and Smith 2015, Lunsford and West (2017)).
Interestingly and importantly however, historically for the United States
government, interest rates lower than growth rates have been more the rule
than the exception, making the issue of what debt policy should be under
this configuration of more than temporary interest.3 ).
Evidence on past interest rates and growth rates has been put together
by, among others, Shiller (1992) and Jorda et al (2017). While the basic con-
1
Some forecasts, reflecting the strong fiscal expansion in an economy close to potential,
have the interest rate being roughly equal to or slightly higher than the growth rate for a few
years in the near future.
2
Since 1800, 10-year rolling sample averages of U.S. real growth have always been posi-
tive, except for one observation, centered in 1930.
3
Two other papers have examined the historical relation between interest rates and
growth rates, both in the United States and abroad, and draw some of the implications for
debt dynamics: Mehrotra(2017), and Barrett (2018).
9
clusions reached below hold over longer periods, I shall limit myself here to
the post-1950 period.4 Figure 1 shows the evolution of nominal GDP growth
rate and the 1-year Treasury bill rate. Figure 2 shows the evolution of nomi-
nal GDP growth rate and the 10-year Treasury bond rate. Together, they have
two basic features:
Nominal growth rate and 1‐year T‐bill rate
1‐year T‐bill rate nominal growth rate
16
14
12
10
‐2
‐4
• On average, over the period, nominal interest rates have been lower
than nominal growth rates.5 The 1-year rate has averaged 4.7%, the 10-
year rate has averaged 5.6%, while nominal GDP growth has averaged
6.3%.6
4
There is a striking difference not so much in the level but in the stochastic behavior of
rates pre- and post-1950, with a sharp decrease in volatility post-1950.
5
Equivalently, if one uses the same deflator, real interest rates have been lower than the
real growth rate. Real interest rates are however often computed using CPI inflation rather
than the GDP deflator.
6
Using Shiller’s numbers for interest rates and historical BEA series for GDP, over the
longer period 1871 to 2018, the 1-year rate has averaged 4.6%, the 10-year rate 4.6% and
nominal GDP growth 5.3%.
10
16
Nominal growth rate and 10‐year bond rate
14 nominal 10‐year rate nominal growth rate
12
10
‐2
‐4
• Both the 1-year rate and the 10-year rate were consistently below the
growth rate until the disinflation of the early 1980s, Since then, both
nominal rates and nominal growth have declined, with rates declin-
ing faster than growth, even before the Great Financial Crisis. Over-
all, while nominal rates vary substantially from year to year, the 1-year
rate has been lower than the growth rate for all decades except for the
1980s. The 10-year rate has been lower than the growth rate for 4 out
of 7 decades.
Many, but not all, holders of government bonds pay taxes on the interest
paid, so the interest cost of debt is actually lower than the interest rate itself.
There is no direct measure of those taxes, and thus I proceed as follows.
I measure the tax rate of the marginal holder by looking at the difference
between the yield on AAA municipal bonds (which are exempt from Federal
taxes) and the yield on a corresponding maturity Treasury bond, for both 1-
year and 10-year bonds. Assuming that the marginal investor is indifferent
between holding the two, the implicit tax rate on 1-year treasuries is given
by τ1t = 1 − imt1 /i1t , and the implicit tax rate on 10-year Treasuries is given by
τ10t = 1 − imt10 /i10t .8 The tax rate on 1-year bonds peaks at about 50% in the
late 1970s (as inflation and nominal rates are high, leading to high effective
tax rates) down to close to zero until the Great Financial Crisis, and have
increased slightly since 2017. The tax rate on 10-year bonds follows a similar
pattern, down from about 40% in the early 1980s to close to zero, with a small
7
Fed holdings used to be very small relative to total debt, and limited to short maturity
T-bills. As a result of quantitative easing, they have become larger and skewed towards long
maturity bonds, implying a lower maturity of debt held by private investors than of total
debt.
8
This is an approximation. On the one hand, the average tax rate is likely to exceed this
marginal rate. On the other hand, to the extent that municipal bonds are also partially ex-
empt from state taxes, the marginal tax rate may reflect in part the state tax rate in addition
to the Federal tax rate.
12
increase since 2016. 9 Taking into account the maturity structure of the debt,
I then construct an average tax rate in the same way as I constructed the
interest rate above, by constructing τt = αt ∗ τ1,t + (1 − αt ) ∗ τ10,t
Not all holders of Treasuries pay taxes however. Foreign holders, private
and public (such as central banks), Federal retirement programs and Fed
holdings are not subject to tax. The proportion of such holders has steadily
increased over time, reflecting the increase in emerging markets’ reserves (in
particular China’s), the growth of the Social Security Trust Fund, and more
recently, the increased holdings of the Fed, among other factors. From 15%
in 1950, it now accounts for 64% today.
Using the maturity adjusted interest rate from above, it , the implicit tax
rate, τt , and the proportion of holders likely subject to tax, βt , I construct an
“adjusted interest rate” series according to:
iadj,t = it (1 − τt ∗ βt )
Its characteristics are shown in Figures 3 and 4. Figure 3 plots the ad-
justed rate against the 1-year and the 10-year rates. Figure 4 plots the ad-
justed tax rate against the nominal growth rate. They yield two conclusions:
• First, over the period, the average adjusted rate has been lower than
either the 1-year or the 10-year rates, averaging 3.8% since 1950. This
however largely reflects the non neutrality of taxation to inflation in
the 1970s and 1980s, and which is much less of a factor today. Today,
the rate is roughly half way between the 1-year and the 10-year rate,
slightly under 2%.
• Second, the adjusted rate has been substantially lower than the nomi-
9
The computed tax rates are actually negative during some of the years of the Great Fi-
nancial Crisis, presumably reflecting the effects of Quantitative Easing. I put them equal to
zero for those years
13
1‐year rate, 10‐year rate, adjusted rate
16
14
12
10
Nominal GDP growth and adjusted interest rate
16
14
12
10
‐2
‐4
Adjusted rate Nominal GDP growth
The third potential issue is Jensen’s inequality. The dynamics of the ratio
14
1 + radj,t
dt = dt−1 + xt
1 + gt
where dt is the ratio of debt to GDP (with both variables either in nominal
or in real terms if both are deflated by the same deflator), and xt is the ratio
of the primary deficit to GDP (again, with both variables either in nominal
or in real terms). The evolution of the ratio depends on the relevant product
of interest rates and growth rates (nominal or real) over time.
Given the focus on debt rollovers, that is the issuance of debt without a
later increase in taxes or reduction in spending, suppose we want to trace
debt dynamics under the assumption that xt remains equal to zero.10 Sup-
pose that ln[(1 + radj,t )/(1 + gt )] is distributed normally with mean µ and vari-
ance σ 2 . Then, the evolution of the ratio will depend not just on exp µ but
on exp(µ + (1/2)σ 2 ). We have seen that, historically, µ was between -1% and
-2%. The standard deviation of the log ratio over the same sample was equal
to 2.8%, implying a variance of 0.05%, thus too small to affect the conclu-
sions substantially. Jensen’s inequality is thus not an issue here.11
In short, if we assume that the future will be like the past (a big if admit-
tedly), debt rollovers—that is increases in debt without a change in the pri-
mary surplus—appear feasible. While the debt ratio may increase for some
time due to adverse shocks to growth or positive shocks to the interest rate,
it will eventually decrease over time. In other words, higher debt does not
imply a higher fiscal cost.
In this light, it is interesting to do the following counterfactual exercise.
Assume that the debt ratio in year t was what it actually was, but that the
10
Given that we subtract taxes on interest from interest payments, the primary balance
must also be computed subtracting those tax payments.
11
The conclusion is nearly the same if we do not assume log normality, but rather boot-
strap from the actual distribution.
15
primary balance was equal to zero from then on, so that debt in year t + n
was given by:
i=n
Y 1 + radj,t+i
dt+n = dt
i=1
1 + gt+i
Figures 5 and 6 show what the evolution of the debt ratio would have
been, starting at different dates in the past. For convenience, the ratio is
normalized to 100 at each starting date, so 100 in 1950, 100 in 1960, and so
on. Figure 5 uses the non-tax adjusted rate, Figure 6 uses the tax-adjusted
interest rate.
Figure 5 shows how, for each starting date, the debt ratio would eventu-
ally have decreased, even in the absence of a primary surplus. The decrease,
if starting in the 1950s, 1960s, or 1970s, is quite dramatic. But it also shows
that a series of bad shocks, such as happened in the 1980s, can increase the
debt ratio to higher levels for a while. Figure 6, which I believe is the more
appropriate one, gives an even more optimistic picture, where the debt ratio
rarely would have increased, even in the 1980s—the reason being the higher
16
Figure 6: Debt dynamics, with zero primary balance, starting in year t, using
adjusted rate
100
80
% of GDP
6040
20
where C1 and C2 are consumption in the first and the second period re-
spectively. (As I shall limit myself for the moment to looking at the effects
of the transfer on utility in steady state, there is no need for now for a time
index.) Their first and second period budget constraints are given by
C1 = W − K − D ; C2 = R K + D
,
where W is the wage, K is saving (equivalently, next period capital), D is
the transfer from young to old, and R is the rate of return on capital.
Production is given by a constant returns production function. I ignore
population growth and technological progress, so the growth rate is equal to
zero.
Y = F (K, N )
18
(1 − β) U 0 (C1 ) = βR U 0 (C2 )
dU = [−(1 − β)U 0 (C1 ) + βU 0 (C2 )] dD + [(1 − β)U 0 (C1 ) dW + βKU 0 (C2 ) dR]
The first term in brackets, call it dUa , represents the direct effect of the
transfer, the second term, call it dUb , the effect of the transfer through the
induced change in wages and rates of return.
Consider the first term, the effect of debt on utility given labor and capi-
tal prices. Using the first-order condition gives:
Take the second term, the effect of debt on utility through the changes in
W and R. An increase in debt decreases capital and thus decreases the wage
and increases the rate of return on capital. What is the effect on welfare?
Using the factor price frontier relation dW = −KdR, rewrite this second
term as:
19
• Putting the two effects together leads to the well known conclusion that
if the marginal product is less than the growth rate (which here is equal
to zero), an intergenerational transfer has a positive effect on welfare
in steady state.
ple are risk averse, the average safe rate will be less than the average marginal
product of capital. The basic question becomes:
What is the relevant rate we should look at for welfare purposes? Put
loosely, is it the average marginal product of capital ER, or is it the average
safe rate ERf , or it is some other rate altogether?
The model is the same as before, except for the introduction of uncer-
tainty:
People born at time t have expected utility given by: (I now need time
subscripts as the steady state is stochastic):
Yt = At F (Kt−1 , N )
At time t, the first order condition for utility maximization is given by:
f
Rt+1 E[U 0 (C2,t+1 ] = E[Rt+1 U 0 (C2,t+1 )]
21
dUt = [−(1−β)U 0 (C1,t )+βEU 0 (C2,t+1 )] dD+[(1−β)U 0 (C1,t ) dWt +βKt E(U 0 (C2,t+1 ) dRt+1 )]
As before, the first term in brackets, call it dUat , reflects the direct effect
of the transfer, the second term, call it dUbt , reflects the effect through the
change in wages and rates of return to capital.
Take the first term, the effect of debt on utility given prices. Using the
first order condition gives:
So:
f
dUat = β(1 − Rt+1 )EU 0 (C2,t+1 ) dD (3)
So, to determine the sign effect of the transfer on welfare through this first
f
channel, the relevant rate is indeed the safe rate. In any period in which Rt+1
is less than one, the transfer is welfare improving.
The explanation is straightforward: The safe rate is, in effect, the risk
adjusted rate of return on capital.13 The intergenerational transfer gives a
higher rate of return to people than the risk adjusted rate of return on capi-
tal.
13
The low safe rate is sometimes explained as a result of a shift of the IS curve to the
left, requiring a lower rate to maintain output at potential (Summers 2018). It should be
clear that this is another way of saying the same thing. The shift of the IS curve must be
due either to an increase in saving, or a decrease in investment due to either higher risk or
higher profitability.
22
In general, this term will depend both on dKt−1 (which affects dWt ) and
on dKt (which affects dRt+1 ). If we evaluate it at Kt = Kt−1 = K and dKt =
dKt+1 = dK, it can be rewritten, using the same steps as in the certainty case,
as:
f
dUbt = [β(1/η) α Rt+1 E[U 0 (C2,t+1 )]] (Rt − 1) dK (4)
Thus the relevant rate in assessing the sign of the welfare effect of the
transfer through this second term is the risky rate, the marginal product of
capital.
Putting the two sets of results together: If the safe rate is less than one,
and the risky rate is greater than one—the configuration which appears to
be relevant today—the two terms now work in opposite directions: The first
term implies that an increase in debt increases welfare. The second term
implies that an increase in debt instead decreases welfare. Both rates are
thus relevant.
dU/dD = [(1 − ERf ) − (1/η) α ERf (ER − 1)] βE[U 0 (C2 )](−dK/dD)
so that:
23
1
dK/dD = −
1 − βα(1/η)ER
Note that, if the production is linear, and so η = ∞, the second term in
equation (6) is equal to zero, and the only rate that matters is ERf . Thus,
if ERf is less than one, a higher transfer increases welfare. As the elastic-
ity of substitution becomes smaller, the price effect becomes stronger, and,
eventually, the welfare effect changes sign and becomes negative.
In the Cobb-Douglas case, using the fact that ER ≈ (1 − α)/(αβ), (the ap-
proximation comes from ignoring Jensen’s inequality) the equation reduces
to the simpler formula:
Suppose that the average annual safe rate is 2% lower than the growth
rate, so that ERf , the gross rate of return over a unit period—say 25 years—is
0.9825 = 0.6, then the welfare effect of a small increase in the transfer is pos-
itive if ER is less than 1.66, or equivalently, if the annual average marginal
product is less than 2% above the growth rate.
Short of a much richer model, it is difficult to know how reliable these
rough computations are as a guide to reality.
Surely, the model overstates the deviation from Ricardian equivalence.
To the extent that the effect of the transfer has less of an effect on capital
accumulation, this implies a smaller value of dK/dD and thus a substantially
smaller second effect, a substantially more favorable welfare outcome.
24
Surely also, the return to capital, given the price risk associated with hold-
ing shares, is substantially more risky than the return to labor, and this may
lead to a quantitatively different trade-off. Be that as it may, it suggests that
the welfare effects of a transfer may be not even be adverse, or, if adverse,
may not be very large.14
1 1−γ
(1 − β) ln C1t + β ln E(C2t+1 )
1−γ
The log-log specification implies that the intertemporal elasticity of sub-
stitution is equal to 1. The coefficient of relative risk aversion is given by γ.
As the strength of the second effect above depends on the elasticity of
substitution between capital and labor, I assume a CES production function,
with multiplicative uncertainty:
ρ
Yt = At (bKt−1 + (1 − b)N ρ )1/ρ = At (bKt−1
ρ
+ (1 − b))1/ρ
capital share in the Cobb-Douglas case)to 1/3. For reasons explained below,
I choose the annual value of σa to be a high 4% a year, which implies a value
√
of σ of 25 ∗ 4% = 0.20.
Because the strength of the second effect above depends on the elastic-
ity of substitution, I consider two different values of η, η = ∞ which corre-
sponds to the linear production function case, and in which the price effects
of lower capital accumulation is equal to zero, and η = 1, the Cobb-Douglas
case, and the case which is generally seen as a good description of the pro-
duction function in the medium run.
The central parameters are, on the one hand, β and µ, and on the other,
γ.
The parameters β and µ determine (together with σ, which plays a mi-
nor role) the average level of capital accumulation and the average marginal
product of capital, the average risky rate. In general, both parameters matter.
In the linear production case however, the marginal product of capital is in-
dependent of the level of capital, and thus depends only on µ; thus, I choose
µ to fit the average value of the marginal product. In the Cobb-Douglas case,
the marginal product of capital is instead independent of µ and depends
only on β; thus I choose β to fit the average value of the marginal product of
capital.
The parameter γ determines, together with σ the spread between the
risky rate and the safe rate. In the absence of transfers, the following rela-
tion holds between the two rates:
f
ln Rt+1 − ln ERt+1 = −γσ 2
This relation implies however that the model suffers from a strong case
of the equity premium puzzle (see for example Kocherlakota (1996)). If we
think of σ as the standard deviation of TFP growth, and assume that, in the
27
data, TFP growth is a random walk (with drift), this implies an annual value
of σa of about 2%, thus a value of σ over the 25-year period of 10%, and thus
a value of σ 2 of 1%. Thus, if we think of the annual risk premium as, say,
5%, which implies a value of the right hand side of about 1.22, this implies
a value of γ, the coefficient of relative risk aversion of 122, which is clearly
implausible. One of the reasons why the model fails so badly is the symme-
try in the degree of uncertainty facing labor and capital, and the absence of
price risk associated with holding shares (as capital fully depreciates within
the 25-year period). If we take instead σ to reflect the standard deviation of
yearly rates of stock returns, say 15% a year (its historical mean), and assume
stock returns to be uncorrelated over time, then σ over the 25-year period is
equal to 75%, implying values of γ around 2.5. There is no satisfactory way to
deal with the issue within the model, so as an uneasy compromise, I choose
σ = 20%. Given σ, γ is determined for each pair of average risky and safe
rates.16
16
Extending the model to allow uncertainty to differ for capital and labor is difficult to
do (except for the case where production is linear and one can easily capture capital or
labor augmenting technology shocks. In this case, the qualitative discussion of the previous
section remains relevant.)
28
1.5
0.5
-0.5
-1
4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1 -1.5 -2
0.5 -0.5 -1
0 0.5 0
1
-1
-2
-3
4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5 -2
1 -1.5
-1
0.5 -0.5
0 0
0.5
1
29
Figures 9 and 10 do the same, but now for the Cobb-Douglas case.17 They
yield the following conclusions: Both effects are now at work, and both rates
matter: A lower safe rate makes it more likely that the transfer will increase
welfare; a higher risky rate makes it less likely. For a small transfer (5% of
the endowment), an annual safe rate 2% lower than the growth rate leads to
an increase in welfare so long the risky rate is less than 5% above the growth
rate. A safe rate 1% lower than the growth rate leads to an increase in welfare
so long the risky rate is less than 2.5% above the growth rate. For a larger
transfer, (20% of the endowment), the trade-off is less attractive. For welfare
to increase, a safe rate of 2% less than the growth rate requires that the risky
rate be less than 3% above the growth rate; a safe rate of 1% below the growth
rate requires that the risky rate be less than 2% above the growth rate.
1.5
0.5
-0.5
-1
-1.5
4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1 -2
-1.5
0.5 -1
-0.5
0 0
0.5
1
-2
-4
-6
-8
4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1 -2
-1.5
0.5 -1
-0.5
0 0
0.5
1
31
f
C2t+1 = Rt+1 Kt + DRt+1
f
C2t+1 = Rt+1 Kt + Dt Rt+1
Dt = Rtf Dt−1
18
In my paper with Philippe Weil (Blanchard Weil 2001), we characterized debt dynamics,
based on an epsilon increase in debt, under different assumptions about technology and
preferences. We showed in particular that, under the assumptions in the text, debt would
follow a random walk with negative drift. We did not however look at welfare implications.
33
again arbitrarily and too strongly, that all debt is paid back through a tax on
the young.19 This exaggerates the effect of failure on the young in that pe-
riod, but is simplest to capture.
In the linear case, the higher debt and lower capital accumulation have
no effect on the risky rate, and a limited effect on the safe rate, and all paths
show declining debt. Four periods out (100 years), all of them have lower
debt than at the start.
Figure 11: Linear production function. Debt evolutions under a debt rollover
D0= 18% of endowment
Debt Share of Savings, Linear OLG With Uncertainty
ER=2% ERf=-1% initdebt =16.875%
20 -----,f--------------'--------------'-------------'---------------+-
18
16
en
-�rn 14
,,......_
<l)l:f:
.... '----'
�
en 12
�
10
6-----,f-------------�------------r---------------r---------------+-
0 25 50 75 100
Time (year)
In the Cobb-Douglas case, with the same values of ER and ERf absent
debt, bad shocks, which lead to higher debt and lower capital accumulation,
lead to increases in the risky rate, and by implication, larger increases in the
safe rate. The result is that, for the same shocks, 5% of paths fail over the
first four periods. Are these Ponzi gambles—as Ball, Elmendorf and Mankiw
have called them—worth it at least from a fiscal viewpoint? If the probability
of failure is low enough, they might well be.
19
The alternative would be a tax on the old. This however would make public debt risky
throughout, and lead to a much harder problem to solve.
34
30
en 25
b.()
�
-�rn
o-
4-.
i:f: 20
....
<l)
'----'
�en
...,
..0
<l)
� 15
10
-----,f-- -r-
5 -----------�------------r------------- --------------+-
0 25 50 75 100
Time (year)
Figure 13: Linear production function. Welfare effects of a debt rollover D0=
18% of endowment
Linear OLG With Uncertainty
ER=2% ERf=-1% initdebt =16.875%
0.6 -t-------------�------------�------------�------------+--
0.5
0.4
� �0.3
0.1
0-t-------------�------------�------------�------------+--
0 25 50 75 100
Time (year)
2
....,
i;
"::)
0
'"'
0
"
(1)
....,
0
,;:;
-
(1)
-2
....,
o:l
al
... �
....,;,:.;
�
....,
-4
;:I
....,
(1)
o:l
b.O
'"'
(1) -6
b.O
b.O
�
-8
-10 -----,f--------------r--------------r--------------r---------------+-
0 25 50 75 100
Time (year)
36
creased throughout. For the generation receiving the initial transfer asso-
ciated with debt issuance, the effect is clearly positive and large. For later
generations, while they are, at the margin, indifferent between holding safe
debt or risky capital, the inframarginal gains (from a less risky portfolio) im-
ply slightly larger utility. But the welfare gain is small (0.3), compared to the
initial welfare effect on the young from the initial transfer, (7).
In the Cobb-Douglas case however, this positive effect is more than offset
by the price effect, and while welfare still goes up for the first generation, it is
negative thereafter. In the case of successful debt rollovers, the adverse wel-
fare cost decreases with debt over time. In the case of unsuccessful rollovers,
the adjustment implies a larger welfare loss when it happens.2021
So, if we take the Cobb Douglas case to be more representative, are these
Ponzi gambles—as Ball, Elmendorf and Mankiw have called them—worth it
at least from a fiscal viewpoint? Probably not, if deficit finance and debt have
no other benefits, but if they do (more in the last section), if the probability
of failure is low enough, they might well be.
The argument developed in the previous two sections showed that the wel-
fare effects of an intergenerational transfer—or an increase in debt, or a debt
rollover—depend both on how low the average safe rate and how high the
average marginal product of capital are relative to growth rate. The higher
the average marginal product of capital, for a given safe rate, the more ad-
verse the effects of the transfer. In the simulations above (reiterating the
caveats about how seriously we should take the quantitative implications of
20
If debt is repaid over time, then, given the concavity of utility functions, clearly the wel-
fare cost is smaller.
21
Why the welfare cost is higher for later periods is still a mystery. Working on it.
37
that model), the welfare effects of an average marginal product far above the
growth rate typically dominated the effects of an average safe slightly below
the growth rate, implying a negative effect of the transfer (or of debt) on wel-
fare.
Such a configuration would seem to be the empirically relevant one. Look
at Figure (15). The blue line gives the evolution of the (before corporate
taxes) profit rate of US non-financial corporations, defined as the ratio of
their net operating surplus to their capital stock measured at replacement
cost, since 1950. Note that, while this profit rate declined from 1950 to the
late 1970s, it has been rather stable since then, around a high 10%, so 6 to
8% above the growth rate. (see Appendix E for details of construction and
sources)
Look at the red line however. The line gives the evolution of the ratio
of the same profit series, now to the market value of the same firms, con-
structed as the sum of the market value of equity plus other liabilities, minus
financial assets. Note how it has declined since the early 1980s, going down
from roughly 10% then to about 5% today. Put another way, the ratio of the
market value of firms to their measured capital at replacement cost, known
as Tobin’s q, has roughly doubled since the early 1980s, going roughly from
1 to 2.
There are two ways of explaining this diverging evolution, and both have
implications for the average marginal product of capital, and,as result, for
the welfare effects of debt. They have been and are the subject of much
research, triggered by an apparent increase in markups and concentration
in many sectors of the U.S. economy (e.g. DeLoecker and Eeckhout (2017),
Guti‘errez and Philippon (2017), Philippon (2018), Barkai (2018))
The first explanation is unmeasured capital, reflecting in particular in-
tangible capital. To the extent that the true capital stock is larger than the
measured capital stock, this implies that the measured profit rate overstates
38
18
16
14
12
10
0
1950 1953 1956 1959 1962 1965 1968 1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016
Figure 15: Profit over replacement cost, Profit over market value since 1950
the true profit rate, and by implication overstates the marginal product of
capital. A number of researchers have explored this hypothesis, and their
conclusion is that, even if the adjustment already made by the Bureau of
Economic Analysis is insufficient, intangible capital would have to be im-
plausibly large to reconcile the evolution of the two series: Measured intan-
gible capital as a share of capital has increased from 6% in 1980 to 15% to-
day. Suppose it had in fact increased by 25%. This would only lead to a 10%
increase in measured capital, far from enough to explain the divergent evo-
lutions of the two series.22
The second explanation is increasing rents, reflecting in particular the
increasing relevance of increasing returns to scale and increased concentra-
tion. If, so the profit rate reflects not only the marginal product of capital,
but also rents. The market value of firms reflects not only the value of capital
but also the present value of rents. If we take all of the increase in the ratio of
the market value of firms to capital at replacement cost to reflect an increase
in rents, the doubling of the ratio implies that rents account for roughly half
22
Further discussion can be found in Barkai 2018.
39
of profit.23
As on each of the issues raised in this lecture, many caveats are in order,
and they are being taken on by current research. Movements in Tobin’s q,
the ratio of market value to capital, are often difficult to explain.24 Yet, the
evidence is fairly consistent with a decrease in the average marginal product
of capital, and by implication, a smaller welfare cost of debt.
So far, I have considered the effects of debt when debt was used to finance
intergenerational transfers in a full employment economy. This was in order
to focus on the basic mechanisms at work. But it clearly did not do justice
to the potential benefits of debt finance, nor does it address other potential
costs of debt left out of the model. The purpose of this last section is to dis-
cuss potential benefits and potential costs. As this touches on many aspects
of the economy and many lines of research, it is informal, more in the way
of remarks and research leads than definitive answers about optimal debt
policy.
Start with potential benefits. The standard argument for deficit finance
in a country like the United States is its potential role in increasing demand
and reducing the output gap when the economy is in recession. The Great
23
A rough arithmetic exercise: Suppose V = qK + P DV (R), where V is the value of
firms, q is the shadow price of capital, R is rents. The shadow price is in turn given by
q = P DV (M P K)/K. Look at the medium run where adjustment costs have worked out,
so q = 1. Then V /K − 1 = P DV (R)/P DV (M P K). If V /K doubles from 1 to 2, then this
implies that P DV (R) = P DV (M P K), so rents account for half of total profits.
24
In particular, what makes me slightly uncomfortable with the argument is the behavior
of Tobin’s q from 1950 to 1980, which roughly halved. Was it because of decreasing rents
then?
40
Financial crisis, and the role of both the initial fiscal expansion and the later
turn to fiscal austerity, has led to a resurgence of research on the topic. Re-
search has been active on three fronts:
The first has revisited the size of fiscal multipliers. Larger multipliers im-
ply a smaller increase in debt for a given fiscal expansion. Looking at the
Great Financial crisis, two arguments have been made that multipliers were
higher during that time. First, lower ability to borrow by both households
and firms implied a stronger effect of current income as opposed to future
income on spending, and thus a stronger multiplier. Second, at the effective
lower bound, monetary authorities did not feel they should increase interest
rates in the response to the fiscal expansion. 25
The second front, explored by DeLong and Summers (2012) has revisited
the effect of fiscal expansions on output and debt in the presence of hys-
teresis. They have shown that even a small hysteretic effect of a recession
on later output might lead a fiscal expansion to actually reduce rather than
increase debt in the long run, with the effect being stronger, the stronger the
multipliers and the lower the safe interest rate.26 Note that this is a differ-
ent argument from the argument developed in this paper: The proposition
is that a fiscal expansion may not increase debt, while the argument of the
paper is that an increase in debt may have small fiscal and welfare costs. The
two arguments are clearly complementary however.
The third front has been that public investment has been too low, often
being the main victim of fiscal consolidation, and that the marginal prod-
uct of public capital is high. The relevant point here is that what should be
compared is the risk adjusted rate of return on public investment to the risk
25
For a review of the empirical evidence up to 2010 see Ramey (2011). For more recent
contributions, see, for example, Mertens (2018) on tax multipliers, and the debate between
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) and Ramey and Zubairy (2018.)
26
I examined the evidence for or against hysteresis in Blanchard (2017). I concluded that
the evidence was not strong enough to move priors, for or against, very much.
41
cause some of the factors underlying low rates fade over time. Or it may be
because public debt increases to the point where the equilibrium safe rate
actually exceeds the growth rate. In the formal model above, a high enough
level of debt, and the associated decline in capital accumulation, may well
lead to an increase in the safe rate above the growth rate, leading to positive
fiscal costs and higher welfare costs. Indeed, the trajectory of deficits under
current fiscal plans is indeed worrisome. Estimates by Sheiner (2018) for ex-
ample suggest, despite the assumption that the safe rate remains below the
growth rate, we may see an increase in the ratio of debt to GDP of close to
60% of GDP between now and 2043. If so, using a standard back of the enve-
lope number that an increase in debt of 1% of GDP increases the safe rate by
2-3 basis points, this would lead to an increase in the safe rate of 1.2 to 1.8%,
enough to reverse the inequality.
History may indeed not be a reliable guide to the future. As the debates
on secular stagnation and the level of the long run Wicksellian rate (the safe
rate consistent with unemployment remaining at the natural rate) indicate,
the future is indeed uncertain,and this uncertainty should be taken into ac-
count. The evidence on indexed bonds suggests however two reasons to
be relatively optimistic. The first is that, to the extent that the U.S. govern-
ment can finance itself through inflation-indexed bonds, it can lock in a rate
of 1% over the next 30 years, a rate far below even pessimistic forecasts of
growth over the same period. The second is that investors seem to give a
small probability to a major increase in rates. Looking at 10-year inflation-
indexed bonds, and using realized volatility as a proxy for implied volatility,
suggests that the market puts the probability that the rate will be higher than
200 bp in five years, at around 12%.28 Thus, debt may indeed be more costly
rate. In the data, the relation between growth rates and interest rates is much weaker.
28
√ The daily standard deviation is around 3bp, implying a 5-year standard deviation of
1250 ∗ 2 − 3bp = 70-105 bp. This implies that the probability that the rate, which today is
100bp, is larger than 200bp is about 15%.
43
in the future. The welfare results above however are continuous, and for rea-
sonably small positive differences between the interest rate and the growth
rate, the welfare effects may remain small. The basic intuition remains the
same: The safe rate is the risk adjusted rate of return on capital. If it is low,
lower capital accumulation may not have major adverse welfare effects.
29
It feels less relevant for the United States than for other countries, emerging market
countries in particular. But, as debt to GDP ratios increase, it may not be irrelevant.
30
Under either formal or informal dynamics, the good equilibrium is stable, while the bad
equilibrium is unstable. However, what may happen in this case, is that the economy moves
to a position worse than the bad equilibrium, with interest rates and risk premia increasing
towards infinity. A straightforward extension of the model above, showing the nature of the
two equilibria, is sketched in Appendix F.
44
equilibrium. Suppose investors worry about risk and increase the required
rate. As the required rate goes to infinity, the state will default. But suppose
that, even if it defaults, debt is low enough that, while it cannot pay the stated
rate, it can pay the safe rate. This in turn implies that investors, if they are
rational, should not and will not worry about risk. This however raises two
issues. First, it may be difficult to assess what such a safe level of debt is: it
is likely to depend on the nature of the government, on its ability to increase
and maintain a primary surplus. Second, the safe level of debt may be very
low, much lower than current levels of debt in the United States and in Eu-
rope. If multiple equilibria are present at, say 100% of GDP, they are likely
to still be present at 90% as well; going however from 100% of GDP to 90%
requires a major fiscal contraction and potentially a large economic con-
traction, if, for example, it cannot be fully offset by expansionary monetary
policy. As Giavazzi and Pagano, and Lorenzoni and Werning have shown,
other dimensions of debt and fiscal policy, such as the maturity of debt or
the aggressiveness of the fiscal rule, are likely to be more important than the
level of debt itself, and allow to preserve the good equilibrium.
6. Conclusions
The lecture has looked at the fiscal and welfare costs of higher debt in an
economy where the safe interest rate is less than the growth rate. It has ar-
gued that this is a relevant empirical configuration, and indeed has been the
norm in the United States over the recent and more distant past. It has ar-
gued that both the fiscal and welfare costs of debt may then be small, smaller
than is generally taken as given in current policy discussions. It has consid-
ered a number of counterarguments, which are indeed valid, and may imply
larger fiscal and welfare costs. The purpose of this lecture is most definitely
not to argue for higher debt per se, but to allow for a richer discussion of debt
45
References
[1] Alan Auerbach and Yury Gorodnichenko. Measuring the output re-
sponses to fiscal policy. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy,
4(2):1–27, 2012.
[2] Laurence Ball, Douglas Emendorf, and N. Gregory Mankiw. The deficit
gamble. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30(4):699–720, Novem-
ber 1998.
[3] Simcha Barkai. Declining labor and capital shares. 2018. ms, LSE.
[5] Olivier Blanchard. Should we reject the natural rate hypothesis? Journal
of Economic Perspectives, 32(1):97–120, Winter 2018.
[6] Olivier Blanchard and Philippe Weil. Dynamic efficiency, the riskless
rate, and debt ponzi games under uncertainty. Advances in Macroeco-
nomics, pages 1–23, November 2001.
[7] Guillermo Calvo. Servicing the public debt: The role of expectations.
American Economic Review, 78(4):647–661, September 1988.
[8] Jan De Loecker and Jan Eeckhout. The rise of market power and the
macroeconomic implications. August 2017. ms, Princeton.
[11] Larry Epstein and Stanley Zin. Substitution, risk aversion, and the tem-
poral behavior of consumption and asset returns. a theoretical frame-
work. Handbook of the Fundamentals of Financial Decision Making,
pages 207–239, 2013.
[12] Francesco Giavazzi and Marco Pagano. Confidence crisis and pub-
lic debt management. 1990. Capital Markets and Debt Manage-
ment. Mario Draghi and Rudiger Dornbusch (eds.) Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
[14] Oscar Jorda, Katharina Knoll, Dmitry Kuvshinov, Moritz Schularicl, and
Alan Taylor. The rate of return on everything, 1870-2015. December
2017. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2017-25.
[15] Narayana Kocherlakota. The equity premium: It’s still a puzzle. Journal
of Economic Literature, 34(1):42–71, March 1996.
[16] Guido Lorenzoni and Ivan Werning. Slow moving debt crises. July 2018.
ms, MIT.
[17] Rachel Lukasz and Thomas Smith2015. Secular drivers of the global
real interest rate. 1(2), December 2015. Staff Working Paper, Bank of
England.
[18] Kurt Lunsford and Kenneth West. Some evidence on secular drivers of
us safe real rates. 2017. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working
Paper 17-23.
[19] Neil Mehrotra. Implications of low productivity growth for debt sus-
tainability. 1(2), November 2017. manuscript, Brown University.
48
[20] Karel Mertens. The near term growth impact of the tax cuts and jobs
act. March 2018. FRB Dallas.
[22] Lukasz Rachel and Lawrence Summers. The equilibrium real interest
rate in advanced economies: The role of of government policies and
current account imbalances. July 2018. ms, Harvard and LSE.
[25] Louise Sheiner. The effects of low productivity growth on fiscal sustain-
ability. May 2018. ms, Peterson Institute for International Economics.