PS2 Sol
PS2 Sol
PS2 Sol
n
i
i
s HHI
1
2
. If each firm is divided into k smaller
firms, then the HHI will become
,
_
,
_
n
i
i
n
i
i
k
s
k
s
k HHI
1
2
1
2
which is 1/k of the original HHI.
Exercise 9.5
Suppose you know only the value of the market shares for the largest m firms in a given
industry. Although you do not possess sufficient information to compute the Herfindahl index,
you can find a lower and an upper bound for its value. How?
You can calculate the lower bound (i.e., lowest possible concentration level) by assuming that in
addition to the m firms there is a very large number of firms each with a very small market
share. With very small market shares, squaring the share makes the terms even smaller, so the
lower bound is just
m
i
i
s HHI
1
2
. For the upper bound, assume that all the remaining firms are
essentially as large as the m-th firm (remember, you know the largest m firms). Then each of
these firms has a market share of sm and there are
m
m
i
i
s s k / 1
1
,
_
,
_
+ +
m
i
i m
m
i
i m
m
i
i
s s s k s s HHI
1 1
2 2
1
2
1 * * .
Exercise 10.7
A market consists of two population segments, A and B. An individual in segment A has
demand for your product q = 50 - p. An individual in segment B has demand for your product q
= 120 - 2p. Segment A has 1000 people in it. Segment B has 1200 people in it. Total cost of
producing q units is C = 5000 + 20q.
a) What is total market demand for your product?
Segment A people will not buy if the price is at or above 50. Segment B people will not buy if
the price is at or above 60. Thus the demand for the product is equal to the demand from both
segments if the price is less than 50, equal to the demand from segment if the price is between
50 and 60, and equal to 0 if the price is greater than 60. It can be written as follows:
( ) ( )
( )
60
60 50
50
0
2400 144000 2 120 1200
3400 194000 2 120 1200 50 1000
<
<
'
p if
p and p if
p if
p p
p p p
q
b) Assume that you must charge the same price to both segments. What is the profit-
maximizing price? What are your profits?
MC = 20.
If P > 50 (and less than 60 -- obviously you wouldn't set p > 60), the inverse demand curve is
p = 60 - q/2400 so MR = 60 - q/1200. Setting MR = MC we get 20 = 60 - q/1200. Simplifying
this leads to q = 48,000. At this quantity, p = 40. But if p = 40, then the inverse demand is
actually p = 57.06 - Q/3400 and the MR = 57.06 - q/1700. Setting MR = MC we get 20 = 57.06 -
q/1700. Simplifying leads to q = 63,002 which in turn leads to a profit maximizing price of p =
38.53. Profits are (38.53 - 20) 63,002 - 5000 = 1,166,427.06 - 5000 = 1,116,427.06
c) Imagine now that members of segment A all wear a scarlet "A" on their shirts or blouses
and that you can legally charge different prices to these people. What price do you
charge to the scarlet "A" people? What prices do you charge to those without the scarlet
"A"? What are your profits now?
The market can now be segmented. In Market A, the inverse demand is p =50 - q/1000 so MR
= 50 - q/500. Setting MR = MC, 20 = 50 - q/500. Thus q = 15,000 and p = 35. For Market B,
p = 60 - q/2400 so MR = 60 - q/1200. Setting MR = MC we get 20 = 60 - q/1200. Simplifying
this leads to q = 48,000. At this quantity, p = 40. Profits = (35 - 20)15,000 + (40-20) 48,000 -
5000 = 225,000+960,000 - 5000 = 1,118,000.
Exercise 10.8
Coca-Cola recently announced that it is developing a "smart" vending machine. Such machines
are able to change prices according to the outside temperature.
Suppose for the purposes of this problem that the temperature can be either "high" or "low". On
days of "high" temperature, demand is given by Q = 280 - 2p, where Q is the number of cans of
Coke sold during the day and p is the price per can measured in cents. On days of "low"
temperature, demand is only Q = 160 - 2p. There are an equal number of days with "high" and
"low" temperature. The marginal cost of a can of coke is 20 cents.
a) Suppose that Coca-Cola installs a "smart" vending machine and thus is able to charge
different prices for Coke on "hot" and "cold" days. What price should Coca-Cola charge
on a "hot" day? What price should Coca-Cola charge on a "cold" day?
On a hot day, the inverse demand curve is p = 140 - q/2. Thus MR = 140 - q. Setting MR = MC
we get 20 = 140 - q or q = 120. Thus p = 80. On a cold day the inverse demand curve is p = 80
- q/2 so MR = 80 - q. Setting MR = MC we get 20 = 80 - q or q = 60. Thus p = 50.
b) Alternatively, suppose that Coca-Cola continues to use its normal vending machines
which must be programmed with a fixed price, independent of the weather. Assuming
that Coca-Cola is risk neutral, what is the optimal price for a can of Coke?
Expected demand = (280 - 2p + 160 - 2p)/2 = 220 - 2p. Thus p = 110 - q/2 and MR = 110 - q.
Setting MR = MC we get 20 = 110 - q or q = 90. Thus p = 65.
c) What would Coca-Cola's profits be under constant and weather-variable prices? How
much would Coca-Cola be willing to pay to enable its vending machine to vary prices
with the weather, that is, to have a "smart" vending machine?
Under price discrimination expected profits per day are = ((80 - 20)120 + (50 - 20)60)/2 = 4500
(in cents, or $45). Without price discrimination profits per day (65 - 20)90 = 4050 or $40.50.
Coke will make and extra 4.50 per day per machine if it can develop the smart vending machine
technology.