Does Oil Hinder Democracy?
Does Oil Hinder Democracy?
Does Oil Hinder Democracy?
Ross, Michael Lewin, 1961World Politics, Volume 53, Number 3, April 2001, pp. 325-361 (Article)
INTRODUCTION
OLITICAL scientists believe that oil has some very odd properties. Many studies show that when incomes rise, governments tend
to become more democratic. Yet some scholars imply there is an exception to this rule: if rising incomes can be traced to a countrys oil
wealth, they suggest, this democratizing effect will shrink or disappear.
Does oil really have antidemocratic properties? What about other minerals and other commodities? What might explain these effects?
The claim that oil and democracy do not mix is often used by area
specialists to explain why the high-income states of the Arab Middle
East have not become democratic. If oil is truly at fault, this insight
could help explainand perhaps, predictthe political problems of oil
exporters around the world, such as Nigeria, Indonesia, Venezuela, and
the oil-rich states of Central Asia. If other minerals have similar properties, this effect might help account for the absence or weakness of democracy in dozens of additional states in sub-Saharan Africa, Latin
America, and Southeast Asia. Yet the oil impedes democracy claim
has received little attention outside the circle of Mideast scholars;
moreover, it has not been carefully tested with regression analysis, either within or beyond the Middle East.
I use pooled time-series cross-national data from 113 states between
1971 and 1997 to explore three aspects of the oil-impedes-democracy
claim. The first is the claims validity: is it true? Although the claim has
been championed by Mideast specialists, it is difficult to test by examining
only cases from the Middle East because the region provides scholars with
* Previous versions of this article were presented to seminars at Princeton University, Yale University, and the University of California, Los Angeles, and at the September 2000 annual meeting of the
American Political Science Association in Washington, D.C. For their thoughtful comments on earlier drafts, I am grateful to Pradeep Chhibber, Indra de Soysa, Geoffrey Garrett, Phil Keefer, Steve
Knack, Miriam Lowi, Ellen Lust-Okar, Lant Pritchett, Nicholas Sambanis, Jennifer Widner, Michael
Woolcock, and three anonymous reviewers. I owe special thanks to Irfan Nooruddin for his research
assistance and advice and to Colin Xu for his help with the Stata. I wrote this article while I was a visiting scholar at The World Bank in Washington, D.C. The views I express in this article, and all remaining errors, are mine alone.
326
WORLD POLITICS
INDEX
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
Brunei (1994)
Kuwait
Bahrain
Nigeria (1991)
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Angola (1996)
Yemen
Oman
Saudi Arabia
Qatar (1994)
Libya (1988)
Iraq (1983)
Algeria
Venezuela
Syria
Norway
Iran (1983)
Ecuador
Malaysia
Indonesia
Cameroon
Lithuania
Kyrgyz Republic (1996)
Netherlands
Colombia
OF
TABLE 1
OIL-RELIANT STATESA
47.58
46.14
45.60
45.38
45.14
45
38.58
38.43
33.85
33.85
29.74
23.48
21.44
18.84
15.00
13.46
11.95
8.53
5.91
5.69
5.63
4.48
4.25
3.14
3.13
a
Oil reliance is measured by the value of fuel-based exports divided by GDP. Most figures
are based on data for 1995 from World Bank (fn. 71).Figures for Brunei, Nigeria, Qatar,
Libya, Iraq, and Iran are the most recent available. Since 1995 figures for Angola and Kyrgyz Republic are not available, 1996 figures are reported.
little variation on the dependent variable: virtually all Mideast governments have been authoritarian since gaining independence. Moreover,
there are other plausible explanations for the absence of democracy in the
Mideast, including the influence of Islam and the regions distinct culture
and colonial history. Does oil have a consistently negative influence on democracy once one accounts for these and other variables?
Second, I examine the claims generality along two dimensions. One
is geographic. For obvious reasons the oil-impedes-democracy claim
has been explored most carefully by Mideast specialists: ten of the fifteen states most reliant on oil wealth are in the Middle East region (see
Table 1). But is oil an obstacle to democracy only in the Mideast, or does
it harm oil exporters everywhere? If the hypothesis is true for all oil-rich
INDEX
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
Botswana
Zambia
Bahrain
Chile
Angola (1996)
Papua New Guinea
Togo (1991)
Bolivia
Congo, Dem. Rep. (1983)
Jordan
Peru
Central African Republic
Iceland
Zimbabwe
Norway
Belgium
Canada
Australia
Lithuania
Jamaica
Slovak Republic
South Africa
Morocco
Cameroon
Kyrgyz Republic
OF
327
TABLE 2
MINERAL-RELIANT STATESa
35.11
24.97
16.39
12.63
11.5
10.13
7.79
5.53
7.00
5.28
3.84
3.16
3.11
3.00
2.49
2.23
2.22
2.20
1.96
1.87
1.74
1.69
1.65
1.62
1.56
Mineral reliance is measured by the value of nonfuel mineral exports divided by GDP.
Most figures are for 1995 based on data from World Bank (fn. 71). The figures for Congo
and Togo are the most recent available; the 1996 figure is reported for Angola, since no figure for 1995 is available.
328
WORLD POLITICS
governments use low tax rates and patronage to relieve pressures for
greater accountability; a repression effect, which argues that resource
wealth retards democratization by enabling governments to boost their
funding for internal security; and a modernization effect, which holds
that growth based on the export of oil and minerals fails to bring about
the social and cultural changes that tend to produce democratic government.
I also have two broader aims. The first is to encourage scholars who
study democracy to incorporate the Middle East into their analyses.
Many global studies of democratization have avoided the Mideast entirely.1 Influential studies by Przeworski and Limongi and Przeworski,
Alvarez, Cheibub, and Limongi simply drop the oil-rich Mideast states
from their database.2 There is, however, no sound analytical reason for
scholars of democracy to exclude these states from their research, and
doing so can only weaken any general findings. It also tends to marginalize the field of Middle East studies.
My second aim is to address the literature on the resource curse.
Many of the poorest and most troubled states in the developing world
have, paradoxically, high levels of natural resource wealth. There is a
growing body of evidence that resource wealth itself may harm a countrys prospects for development. States with greater natural resource
wealth tend to grow more slowly than their resource-poor counterparts.3 They are also more likely to suffer from civil wars.4 This article
suggests as well that there is a third component to the resource curse:
oil and mineral wealth tends to make states less democratic.
1
See, for example, Guillermo ODonnell, Philippe C. Schmitter, and Lawrence Whitehead, eds.,
Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Prospects for Democracy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Press, 1986); D. Larry Diamond, Juan J. Linz, and Seymour Martin Lipset, eds., Democracy in Developing Countries (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1988); Ronald Inglehart, Modernization and Postmodernization (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1997).
2
Adam Przeworski and Fernando Limongi, Modernization: Theories and Facts, World Politics 49
( January 1997); Adam Przeworski, Michael Alvarez, Jos Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi,
What Makes Democracies Endure? Journal of Democracy 7 ( January 1996); idem,Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 19501990 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000).
3
Jeffrey D. Sachs and Andrew M. Warner, Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth,
Development Discussion Paper no. 517a (Cambridge: Harvard Institute for International Development, 1995); idem, The Big Push, Natural Resource Booms and Growth, Journal of Development
Economics 59 (February 1999); Carlos Leite and Jens Weidmann, Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption, and Economic Growth, IMF Working Paper, WP/99/85 (1999); Michael
L. Ross, The Political Economy of the Resource Curse, World Politics 51 ( January 1999); R. M. Auty,
Resource Abundance and Economic Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001).
4
Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, On Economic Causes of Civil War, Oxford Economic Papers 50
(October 1998); Indra de Soysa, The Resource Curse: Are Civil Wars Driven by Rapacity or
Paucity? in Mats Berdal and David M. Malone, eds., Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil
Wars (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 2000).
329
I begin by outlining the oil-impedes-democracy claim and the limitations of previous work on the topic. I then draw on earlier case studies of oil-rich states to specify three causal mechanisms that might
explain how oil makes governments more authoritarian. The next section presents a model of regime types and describes the research design.
I then present the results of the validity and generality tests and follow
that with a discussion of the results of tests on the causal mechanisms
and a conclusion.
THE CONCEPT OF THE RENTIER STATE
Area specialists often describe most of the governments of the Mideast
and North Africa as rentier states, since they derive a large fraction of
their revenues from external rents.5 More than half of the governments
revenues in Saudi Arabia, Bahrain, the United Arab Emirates, Oman,
Kuwait, Qatar, and Libya have, at times, come from the sale of oil. The
governments of Jordan, Syria, and Egypt variously earn large locational
rents from payments for pipeline crossings, transit fees, and passage
through the Suez Canal. Workers remittances have been an important
source of foreign exchange in Egypt, Yemen, Syria, Lebanon, Tunisia,
Algeria, and Morocco, although these rents go (at least initially) to private actors, not the state. The foreign aid that flows to Israel, Egypt, and
Jordan may also be considered a type of economic rent.
Economists in the early twentieth century used the term rentier
state to refer to the European states that extended loans to nonEuropean governments.6 Mahdavy is widely credited with giving the
term its current meaning: a state that receives substantial rents from
foreign individuals, concerns or governments.7 Beblawi later refined
this definition, suggesting that a rentier state is one where the rents are
paid by foreign actors, where they accrue directly to the state, and where
only a few are engaged in the generation of this rent (wealth), the majority being only involved in the distribution or utilization of it.8
5
Throughout this article I use the term Middle East to include North Africa. I adopt the World
Banks definition of this region: Algeria, Bahrain, Egypt, Iran, Iraq, Israel, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon,
Libya, Malta, Morocco, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Syria, Tunisia, United Arab Emirates, and Yemen.
6
According to Lenin, The rentier state is a state of parasitic, decaying capitalism, and this circumstance cannot fail to influence all the socio-political conditions of the countries concerned. V. I.
Lenin, Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism, in Robert C. Tucker, ed., The Lenin Anthology
(New York: W. W. Norton, 1975).
7
Hussein Mahdavy, The Patterns and Problems of Economic Development in Rentier States: The
Case of Iran, in M. A. Cook, ed., Studies in Economic History of the Middle East (London: Oxford University Press, 1970), 428.
8
Hazem Beblawi, The Rentier State in the Arab World, in Hazem Beblawi and Giacomo Luciani, eds., The Rentier State (New York: Croom Helm, 1987), 51. Note that this definition excludes
330
WORLD POLITICS
Claims about the rentier state can be sorted into two categories:
those that suggest oil wealth makes states less democratic and those
that suggest oil wealth causes governments to do a poorer job of promoting economic development. Often the two are conflated. This article focuses on the first claim.
According to Anderson, The notion of the rentier state is one of the
major contributions of Middle East regional studies to political science.9 Indeed, some scholars of democracy now use a version of this
argument to account for the otherwise puzzling states of the Middle
East. Huntington, for example, suggests that the democratic trend may
bypass the Middle East since many of these states depend heavily on
oil exports, which enhances the control of the state bureaucracy.10
Others have adapted the rentier state idea to oil-rich countries outside the Middle East.11
The claim that oil wealth per se inhibits democratization has not
been subjected to careful statistical tests, however, as most quantitative
studies of democracy simply overlook it as an explanatory variable. And
the handful that even acknowledge that oil-rich states have odd properties do little to explain why. Przeworski and his collaborators, for example, drop countries from their database if their ratio of fuel exports
to total exports in 19841986 exceeded fifty percentan eccentric criterion that excludes six oil-rich states, all of which are located on the
Arabian Peninsula.12 Barros study of democracy includes a dummy
variable for states whose net oil exports represent a minimum of twothirds of total exports and are at least equivalent to approximately one
percent of world exports of oil.13 The Barro oil dummy is statistically
significant and negatively correlated with democracy. But as in the
analyses of Przeworski et al., the dummy variable uses an arbitrary cutworkers remittances. As Chaudhry notes, large flows of remittances have different political implications than do large oil rents. See Kiren Aziz Chaudhry, The Price of Wealth: Economies and Institutions
in the Middle East (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1997).
9
Lisa Anderson, The State in the Middle East and North Africa, Comparative Politics 20 (October 1987), 9.
10
Samuel P. Huntington, The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century (Norman:
University of Oklahoma Press, 1991), 3132.
11
See, for example, Olle Trnquist, Rent Capitalism, State, and Democracy: A Theoretical Proposition, in Arief Budiman, ed., State and Civil Society in Indonesia, Monash Papers on Southeast Asia,
no. 22 (1990); Douglas A. Yates, The Rentier State in Africa: Oil Rent Dependency and Neocolonialism in
the Republic of Gabon (Trenton, N.J.: Africa World Press, 1996); Terry Lynn Karl, The Paradox of
Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1997); John Clark, PetroPolitics in Congo, Journal of Democracy 8 ( July 1997); idem, The Nature and Evolution of the State
in Zaire, Studies in Comparative International Development 32 (Winter 1998).
12
See Przeworski et al. (fn. 2, 2000), 77.
13
Robert J. Barro, Determinants of Democracy, Journal of Political Economy 107 (December 1999).
331
point to distinguish between oil states and nonoil states and implies that oil has little or no influence on regime type until some threshold is reached.
Qualitative studies of the oil-impedes-democracy hypothesis also
have important limitations. The vast majority have been country-level
case studies of oil-rich states in the Mideast. Although many have been
empirically rich and analytically nuanced, the Mideast is nevertheless a
difficult place to test this claim, since virtually all oil-rich Mideast governments have been highly authoritarian since gaining independence.
The absence of variation on the dependent variableas well as on
Islam, an important control variablehas made testing difficult. It has
also allowed Mideast specialists to neglect tasks that would help
sharpen and refine the oil-impedes-democracy claimdefining the key
variables better, specifying the causal arguments in falsifiable terms, and
outlining the domain of relevant cases to which their arguments apply.
As a result, the notion of the rentier state has suffered from a bad case
of conceptual overstretch: assertions about the influence of oil on Middle East politics have become so general that their validity has been diluted. As Okruhlik observes, The idea of the rentier state has come to
imply so much that it has lost its content.14
One way to restore the usefulness of an overstretched concept is by
testing it statistically. I thus evaluate one core facet of the rentier state
conceptthe oil-impedes-democracy claimwith three questions.
First, is there a statistically valid correlation between oil and authoritarianism once other germane variables are accounted for? Second, can the
claim be generalized both beyond the Middle East and beyond the case
of oil? Finally, if oil thwarts democracy, what is the causal mechanism?
Proponents of the oil-impedes-democracy hypothesis naturally suggest both that it is valid and that it can be generalized to oil exporters
outside the Middle East. Some also imply that other types of commodities have similar effects. Nothing in Beblawis definition, which is
widely accepted among Mideast specialists, restricts the set of rentier
states to oil exporters. In fact, the definition appears to cover many
mineral exporters on the grounds that (1) minerals tend to generate
rents, (2) the rents are largely captured by states via export taxes, corporate taxes, and state-owned enterprises, and (3) mineral extraction
employs relatively little labor. The same definition, however, implies
that exporters of agricultural commodities will not be rentier states.
14
Gwenn Okruhlik, Rentier Wealth, Unruly Law, and the Rise of Opposition, Comparative Politics 31 (April 1999), 308.
332
WORLD POLITICS
333
taxes.19 Some Mideast scholars have looked for similar correlations between variations in tax levels and variations in the demand for political
accountability. Crystal found that the discovery of oil made the governments of Kuwait and Qatar less accountable to the traditional merchant
class.20 Brands study of Jordan argued that a drop in foreign aid and remittances in the 1980s led to greater pressures for political representation.21 Yet not all Middle East specialists have been persuaded:
Waterbury argues that neither historically nor in the twentieth century is
there much evidence [in the Middle East] that taxation has evoked demands that governments account for their use of tax monies. Predatory
taxation has produced revolts, especially in the countryside, but there has
been no translation of tax burden into pressures for democratization.22
A second component of the rentier effect might be called the
spending effect: oil wealth may lead to greater spending on patronage, which in turn dampens latent pressures for democratization.23
Entelis, for example, argues that the Saudi Arabian government used
its oil wealth for spending programs that helped reduce pressures for
democracy.24 Vandewalle makes a similar argument about the Libyan
government.25 And Kessler and Bazdresch and Levy find that the
Mexican oil boom of the 1970s helped prop upand perhaps prolongone-party rule.26 While all authoritarian governments may use
19
Charles Tilly, ed., The Formation of National States in Western Europe (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975); Robert Bates and Da-Hsiang Donald Lien, A Note on Taxation, Development,
and Representative Government, Politics and Society 14 ( January 1985); Philip T. Hoffman and
Kathryn Norberg, eds., Fiscal Crises, Liberty, and Representative Government, 14501789 (Stanford,
Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1994).
20
Jill Crystal, Oil and Politics in the Gulf: Rulers and Merchants in Kuwait and Qatar (New York:
Cambridge University Press, 1990).
21
Laurie A. Brand, Economic and Political Liberalization in a Rentier Economy: The Case of the
Hashemite Kingdom of Jordan, in Iliya Harik and Denis J. Sullivan, eds., Privatization and Liberalization in the Middle East (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1992).
22
John Waterbury, Democracy without Democrats? The Potential for Political Liberalization in
the Middle East, in Ghassan Salam, ed., Democracy without Democrats? The Renewal of Politics in the
Muslim World (New York: I. B. Tauris, 1994), 29.
23
Lam and Wantchekon develop a formal model that makes a similar point, that resource wealth
can impede democracy by enhancing the distributive influence of an elite. Ricky Lam and Leonard
Wantchekon, Dictatorships as a Political Dutch Disease (Manuscript, Department of Political Science, Yale University, January 1999).
24
John P. Entelis, Oil Wealth and the Prospects for Democratization in the Arabian Peninsula:
The Case of Saudi Arabia, in Naiem A. Sherbiny and Mark A. Tessler, eds., Arab Oil: Impact on the
Arab Countries and Global Implications (New York: Praeger, 1976).
25
Dirk Vandewalle, Libya since Independence: Oil and State-Building (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1998).
26
Carlos Bazresch and Santiago Levy, Populism and Economic Policy in Mexico, 197082, in
Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards, eds., The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991); Timothy P. Kessler, Global Capital and National Politics:
Reforming Mexicos Financial System (Westport, Conn.: Praeger, 1999).
334
WORLD POLITICS
their fiscal powers to reduce dissent, these scholars imply that oil wealth
provides Middle East governments with budgets that are exceptionally
large and unconstrained.27 Rulers in the Middle East may follow the
same tactics as their authoritarian counterparts elsewhere, but oil revenues could make their efforts at fiscal pacification more effective.
The third component might be called a group formation effect. It
implies that when oil revenues provide a government with enough
money, the government will use its largesse to prevent the formation of
social groups that are independent from the state and hence that may
be inclined to demand political rights. One version of this argument is
rooted in Moores claim that the formation of an independent bourgeoisie helped bring about democracy in England and France.28 Scholars examining the cases of Algeria, Libya, Tunisia, and Iran have all
observed oil-rich states blocking the formation of independent social
groups; all argue that the state is thereby blocking a necessary precondition of democracy.29
A second version of the group-formation effect draws on Putnams
argument that the formation of social capitalcivic institutions that lie
above the family and below the statetends to promote more democratic governance.30 Scholars studying the cases of Algeria, Iran, Iraq,
and the Arab Gulf states have all suggested that the governments oil
wealth has impeded the formation of social capital and hence blocked a
transition to democracy.31
Whether Mideast states use their oil revenues to deliberately inhibit
group formation is a matter of some disagreement. In the case of Libya,
First suggests there is not a consistent policy against the development of
27
Lisa Anderson, Peace and Democracy in the Middle East: The Constraints of Soft Budgets,
Journal of International Affairs 49 (Summer 1995).
28
Barrington Moore, Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966).
29
On Algeria, see Clement Henry Moore, Petroleum and Political Development in the Maghreb,
in Sherbiny and Tessler (fn. 24); on Libya, see Ruth First, Libya: Class and State in an Oil Economy,
in Petter Nore and Terisa Turner, eds., Oil and Class Struggle (London: Zed Press, 1980); also on Libya,
see Vandewalle (fn. 25); on Tunisia, see Eva Bellin The Politics of Profit in Tunisia: Utility of the Rentier Paradigm? World Development 22 (March 1994); and on Iran, see Hootan Shambayati, The Rentier State, Interest Groups, and the Paradox of Autonomy: State and Business in Turkey and Iran,
Comparative Politics 26 (April 1994).
30
Robert Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1993).
31
On Algeria, see John P. Entelis, Civil Society and the Authoritarian Temptation in Algerian
Politics, in Augustus Richard Norton, ed., Civil Society in the Middle East, vol. 2 (Leiden: E. J. Brill,
1995); on Iran, see Farhad Kazemi, Civil Society and Iranian Politics, in Norton; on the Gulf states,
see Jill Crystal, Civil Society in the Arab Gulf States, in Norton; on Iraq, see Zuhair Humadi, Civil
Society under the Bath in Iraq, in Jillian Schwedler, ed., Toward Civil Society in the Middle East?
(Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1995). Other scholars have argued that the weakness of civil society
in the Middle East has hampered a transition to democracy, without suggesting that oil wealth is the
source of this weakness.
335
an indigenous bourgeoisie, but the growth of this class is in practice constrained by the states own economic ventures and its links with international capital.32 Chaudhry, by contrast, argues that in the 1970s the
Mideast governments used their oil revenues to develop programs that
were explicitly designed to depoliticize the population. . . . In all cases,
governments deliberately destroyed independent civil institutions while
generating others designed to facilitate the political aims of the state.33
Collectively, the taxation, spending, and group-formation effects
constitute the rentier effect. Together they imply that a states fiscal
policies influence its regime type: governments that fund themselves
through oil revenues and have larger budgets are more likely to be authoritarian; governments that fund themselves through taxes and are
relatively small are more likely to become democratic.
THE REPRESSION EFFECT
A close reading of case studies from the Mideast, Africa, and Southeast
Asia suggests that oil wealth and authoritarianism may also be linked
by repression. Citizens in resource-rich states may want democracy as
much as citizens elsewhere, but resource wealth may allow their governments to spend more on internal security and so block the populations democratic aspirations. Skocpol notes that much of Irans
pre-1979 oil wealth was spent on the military, producing what she calls
a rentier absolutist state.34 Clark, in his study of the 1990s oil boom in
the Republic of Congo, finds that the surge in revenues allowed the
government to build up the armed forces and train a special presidential
guard to help maintain order.35 And Gause argues that Middle East democratization has been inhibited in part by the prevalence of the
mukhabarat (national security) state.36
There are at least two reasons why resource wealth might lead to
larger military forces. One may be pure self-interest: given the opportunity to better arm itself against popular pressures, an authoritarian
government will readily do so. A second reason may be that resource
wealth causes ethnic or regional conflict; a larger military might reflect
the governments response. Mineral wealth is often geographically con32
336
WORLD POLITICS
Although modernization theory does not address the question of resource wealth per se, an implicit corollary is that if economic development does not produce these cultural and social changes, it will not
result in democratization. As Inglehart notes: Is the linkage between
development and democracy due to wealth per se? Apparently not: if
democracy automatically resulted from simply becoming wealthy, then
Kuwait and Libya would be model democracies.40 In other words, if
resource-led growth does not lead to higher education levels and
37
337
greater occupational specialization, it should also fail to bring about democracy. Unlike the rentier and repression effects, the modernization
effect does not work through the state: it is a social mechanism, not a
political one.
The rentier, repression, and modernization effects are largely complementary. The rentier effect focuses on the governments use of fiscal
measures to keep the public politically demobilized; the repression effect stresses the governments use of force to keep the public demobilized; and the modernization effect looks at social forces that may keep
the public demobilized. All three explanations, or any combination of
them, may be simultaneously valid.41
MODEL SPECIFICATION AND RESEARCH DESIGN
To test the oil-impedes-democracy claim, I present a model to predict
regime types and test it using a feasible generalized least-squares
method with a pooled time-series cross-national data set, which includes data on all sovereign states with populations over one hundred
thousand between 1971 and 1997. The model includes five causal variables that according to previous studies are the most robust determinants of democracy. It also includes variables that measure a states oil
and mineral wealth to see if they add explanatory power.
The basic regression model is:
Regimei,t = a1 + b1(Oili,t-5 ) + b2(Mineralsi,t-5 ) + b3(Log Incomei,t-5 )
+ b4 (Islami ) + b5(OECDi ) + b6(Regimei,t-5 ) + b7(Year1 ) . . . + b33(Year26 )
where i is the country and t is the year.
The dependent variable, Regime, is derived from the Polity98 data
set constructed by Gurr and Jaggers.42 Gurr and Jaggers compile two
010 interval scale variables, DEMOC and AUTOC; the former differentiates between states that are relatively democratic, while the latter
variable differentiates between authoritarian states. Since the two indicators contain separate, nonoverlapping types of information about
each country year, I combine them into a single measure by subtracting
41
A fourth explanation has been offered by U.S. vice president Richard Cheney, a political scientist
by training: The problem is that the good Lord didnt see fit to put oil and gas reserves where there are
democratic governments. Cited in David Ignatius, Oil and Politics Mix Suspiciously Well in
America, Washington Post, July 30, 2000, A31.
42
Each of the variables is defined more precisely in Appendix 1. Ted R. Gurr and Keith Jaggers,
Polity 98: Regime Characteristics, 18001998, http://www.bsos.umd.edu/cidcm/polity/, 1999 (consulted March 1, 2000).
338
WORLD POLITICS
339
because many states with great mineral wealth also have large Muslim
populations, not only in the Middle East but also in parts of Asia (Indonesia, Malaysia, Brunei) and Africa (Nigeria). The simple correlation
between Oil and Islam is 0.44.
The third control variable is OECD, a dummy that is coded 1 for
states that are members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (excluding newer members Mexico and South
Korea) and 0 for all others. Previous researchers have found that the advanced industrialized states of the OECD are significantly more likely to
be democratic in the postWorld War II era than the states of the developing world, even after the influence of income and other factors are
accounted for.49 There is no consensus on why this is so. It has variously
been attributed to the Wests unique historical trajectory;50 the cultural
influence of Protestantism;51 the residual effects of Western colonialism
on non-Western states;52 and a world system that constrains the
prospects of states in the non-Western periphery.53 Conceivably any
antidemocratic effects from Oil and Minerals might be spurious and
merely reflect the location of most fuel- and mineral-exporting states
in the non-Western world. The OECD dummy helps account for any of
these Western-specific effects, without taking a position on the mechanisms behind it.
The fourth control variable is Regimet-5, which is the dependent variable lagged by five years. Placing it on the right-hand side of the model
has three purposes. First, the most important influence on a states
regime type may often be its own peculiar history; Regimet-5 helps capture any country-specific historical or cultural features that may be
missed by the other right-hand-side variables. Second, including
Regimet-5 helps turn the equation into a change model, transforming
the dependent variable from regime type to the change in a countrys
regime type over a given five-year period. This helps ensure that the restates with large Islamic populations, Nigeria and Indonesia, have recently moved toward democracy,
and some of the most important prodemocracy forces in other Islamic states (including Algeria, Egypt,
Jordan, and Malaysia) are often classified as Islamic traditionalists or fundamentalists. It is instructive to recall that until the third wave of democratization began in the mid-1970s, democracy and
Catholicism were negatively correlated.
49
See Burkhart and Lewis-Beck (fn. 45); Londregan and Poole (fn. 43); Przeworski and Limongi
(fn. 2).
50
See Moore (fn. 28).
51
See Lipset (fn. 38); Huntington (fn. 10).
52
See Robert A. Dahl, Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition (New Haven: Yale University Press,
1971).
53
See Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World-System (New York: Academic Press, 1974); Bollen
(fn. 15); Burkhart and Lewis-Beck (fn. 45).
340
WORLD POLITICS
341
TABLE 3
RESOURCE WEALTH AND DEMOCRACYa
(DEPENDENT VARIABLE IS REGIME)
Regime
Oil
Minerals
Income (log)
Islam
OECD
Food
Agriculture
Observations
States
Log likelihood
.253***
(.0203)
.0346***
(.0051)
.0459***
(.00778)
.922***
(.105)
.018***
(.00208)
1.47***
(.308)
.894***
(.00846)
.0078***
(.0024)
.00718*
(.00317)
.119***
(.0342)
.0031***
(.000665)
.176*
(.0781)
.25***
(.0203)
.0339***
(.00506)
.0438***
(.0081)
.935***
(.106)
.0178***
(.0021)
1.42***
(.305)
.0244*
(.0102)
.246***
(.0204)
.0393***
(.00543)
.0455***
(.00804)
.965***
(.107)
.0173***
(.00211)
1.44***
(.308)
2182
113
3129
2178
113
3123
2183
113
3133
2498
115
3283
.042
(.0239)
* significant at the 0.05 level; ** significant at the 0.01 level; *** significant at the 0.001 level
a
All independent and control variables are entered with five-year lags, except in column
2, where they are entered with a one-year lag. Standard errors are in parentheses below the
coefficients. Feasible Generalized Least Squares regressions run with Stata 6.0; corrected
for first-order autocorrelation using a panel-specific process. Each regression is run with
dummy variables for every year (but one) covered by the data.
The results of the basic model are reported in Table 3, column 1. All
of the variables are highly significant with the expected signs.57 Both
Oil and Minerals have strong antidemocratic effects; these effects are of
roughly the same magnitude, although the Minerals coefficient is somewhat larger.58
57
Most of the coefficients for the year dummies are also significant: for years 197189 the coefficients
are negative and range from marginally to highly significant; for 1990 the coefficient is negative but not significant; and for years 199196 the coefficients are positive, although all but one (1994) are not significant.
58
These results were unaffected by the inclusion of other variables that are sometimes significant in
democracy regressions, including educational attainment, status as a former British colony, Catholic
population, and trade openness. Only the last variable was significant. When run with a randomeffects process, a Hausman test produces a chi2 of 466 and a P value of 0.000. When run with a fixedeffects process, however, none of the right-hand-side variablesexcept for the lagged dependent
variable and Log Incomeare significant.
342
WORLD POLITICS
Regime
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
FIGURE 1
IMPACT OF OIL EXPORTS ON REGIME
a
This figure shows the net predicted impact of oil exports on the 010 variable Regime, for a
hypothetical country of twenty million people with a per capita income of $1,720 dollars a year, which
is the sample mean. Note the scale on the Y-axis is negative.
343
Regime
0
0
5000
10000
15000
20000
25000
30000
FIGURE 2
IMPACT OF $10 BILLION ANNUAL RISE IN OIL EXPORTS ON REGIME, BY INITIAL
PER CAPITA INCOME
a
This figure shows the net predicted impact of a $10 billion rise in oil exports on the 010 variable
Regime, by initial per capita income, for a hypothetical country with a population of twenty million,
with no prior oil exports. Note the scale on the Y-axis is negative.
high levels, this test suggests the opposite: barrel for barrel, oil harms
democracy more in oil-poor countries than in oil-rich ones.
The test also implies that oil and mineral wealth cause greater damage to democracy in poor countries than in rich ones (see Figure 2).
Imagine a country whose per capita income is $800 a yearabout the
level of Chad, Mozambique, and Yemenwith a population of twenty
million and no oil exports. Suppose prospectors find an oil field that
produces $10 billion of petroleum each year, all of which is exported.
The new oil would simultaneously boost per capita income (a prodemocratic effect) and raise the Oil variable (an antidemocratic effect).
The model predicts that after five years the government would become
less democratic, losing about .93 on the 010 democracy scale. A comparable discovery in a state whose initial per capita income was
$1,720the sample meanwould lose .54 points; if the per capita income were $8,000about the level of Mexico and Malaysiathe same
oil field would be associated with a drop of just .16 in Regime. This pattern is consistent with the observation that large oil discoveries appear
344
WORLD POLITICS
345
TABLE 4
RESOURCE WEALTH AND DEMOCRACYa
(DEPENDENT VARIABLE IS REGIME)
1
.209***
(.0205)
.0209***
(.00512)
.0265***
(.00718)
.789***
(.117)
.00538
(.0033)
1.6***
(.31)
.227***
(.0203)
.0138*
(.00557)
.0336***
(.00761)
.895***
(.112)
.013***
(.00238)
1.39***
(.286)
Mideast
.255***
(.0203)
.0333***
(.00511)
.0439**
(.00802)
.947***
(.105)
.0178***
(.00209)
1.41***
(.306)
.828*
(.406)
SSAfrica
Arabian Peninsula
3.65***
(.386)
1.62***
(.2)
2183
113
3133
2183
113
3086
Regime
Oil
Minerals
Income (log)
Islam
OECD
Large States
Observations
States
Log likelihood
.998***
(.194)
3.74***
(.49)
2183
113
3100
* significant at the 0.05 level; ** significant at the 0.01 level; *** significant at the 0.001 level
a
All independent and control variables are entered with five-year lags. Standard errors
are in parentheses below the coefficients. Feasible Generalized Least Squares regressions
run with Stata 6.0; corrected for first-order autocorrelation using panel-specific process.
Each regression is run with dummy variables for every year (but one) covered by the data.
346
WORLD POLITICS
For the final test, I use a new dummy, Arabian Peninsula, in place of
the Mideast dummy; it was coded 1 for the seven states of the Arabian
Peninsula (Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman, Saudi Arabia, Qatar, the United
Arab Emirates, and Yemen) and 0 otherwise. Conceivably the Mideast
dummy is too broad, since it attempts to capture the effects of residing
in a region that is socially and geologically diverse. The antidemocratic
effects of oil might be somewhat more restricted to the Arabian Peninsula, which is dominated by monarchies, sparsely populated, and endowed with spectacular oil wealth. Using Arabian Peninsula instead of
Mideast reduces the problem of collinearity with Islam, although Arabian Peninsula and Oil remain highly collinear (simple correlation
=.74). Still, while including the Arabian Peninsula dummy reduces the
magnitude of the Oil coefficient by about 60 percent, Oil remains significant at the 0.05 level.
These tests support both the validity and the generality of the oilimpedes-democracy claim. They suggest the following: that a states reliance on either oil or mineral exports tends to make it less democratic;
that this effect is not caused by other types of primary exports; that it is
not limited to the Arabian Peninsula, to the Middle East, or to sub-Saharan Africa; and that it is not limited to small states. These findings
are generally consistent with the theory of the rentier state.
Area specialists might also feel vindicated in noting that in these
tests the most powerful impediments to democracy include the variables Regimet-5, Mideast, and Arabian Peninsula, which represent the accumulation of historical and cultural factors in each country, and in the
Arabian Peninsula and Mideast regions, that are not captured by income, resource wealth, Islam, or non-Western status. This underscores
the critical importance of case studies in explaining regime types.
CAUSAL MECHANISMS
To test the three causal mechanisms I add to the basic model a series of
intervening variables, lagged by one year. Adding new variables reduces
the sample size from 2,183 observations to between 2,183 and 426 observations. As the sample shrinks, it becomes increasingly skewed toward states that are relatively wealthy, democratic, and Western,
introducing a pronounced sample bias. To minimize this problem, after
running each of the following regressions, I run a second regression
using the same reduced sample, but without the intervening variable. I
then compare the two regressions. If the intervening variable is valid, it
should be statistically significant, andif the Oil and Minerals variables
347
348
WORLD POLITICS
TABLE 5
THE RENTIER EFFECTa
(DEPENDENT VARIABLE
Regime
Oil
Mineral
Income (log)
Islam
OECD
Taxes
Government
Consumption
Government/GDP
Observations
States
Log likelihood
IS REGIME )
.259***
(.021)
.0223***
(.00647)
.0157
(.0113)
1.005***
(.104)
.0165***
(.00205)
1.19***
(.272)
.02***
(.00373)
.243***
(.0211)
.0323***
(.00544)
.0463***
(.00677)
.889***
(.112)
.0191***
(.00218)
1.57***
(.314)
.251***
(.0203)
.0351***
(.00511)
.0369***
(.00675)
.857***
(.106)
.0161***
(.00212)
1.53***
(.303)
.0305***
(.00866)
1698
104
2320
2121
110
3036
.0332***
(.00739)
2168
111
3107
* significant at the 0.05 level; ** significant at the 0.01 level; *** significant at the 0.001 level
a
Independent and control variables are entered with five-year lags; intervening variables
(Taxes, Government Consumption, Government/GDP) are entered with one-year lags. Standard errors are in parentheses below the coefficients. Feasible Generalized Least Squares
regressions run with Stata 6.0; corrected for first-order autocorrelation using panel-specific
process. Each regression is run with dummy variables for every year (but one) covered by
the data.
349
should be less disposed to fund themselves through personal and corporate taxes, given their unpopularity.
The effect of taxes on regime types turns out to be strictly short
term: when Taxes is introduced into the model with a two- or threeyear lag, its coefficient quickly drops in size and loses significance. This
implies that tax increases have only short-term effects on democracy:
people tend to respond to tax hikes right away or not at all.64
The Government Consumption variable is also highly significant in
the hypothesized direction (Table 5, column 2). When Government
Consumption is included in the model, Oil and Minerals drop slightly,
by 7 and 6 percent, respectively. The spending effect appears to last
longer than the taxation effect: the Government Consumption variable
has much the same effect on regime type after three years as it does
after one.
These results are not likely caused by endogeneity. While there is evidence that regime type influences levels of government consumption,
it is in the opposite direction found here: democratic governments tend
to favor higher levels of social spending than their authoritarian counterparts.65
Finally, Government/GDP is also highly significant with the hypothesized sign: the larger the government, the less movement toward democracy over the following five years. Its inclusion has no effect on the
Oil variable but produces a 12 percent drop in the Minerals variable
(Table 5, column 3).
In short, the results are consistent with all three aspects of the rentier
effect.
REPRESSION EFFECT
I use two variables to test the hypothesis that resource wealth causes
governments to arm themselves more heavily against popular pressures.
The first is Military/GNP, which measures the size of the military budget as a fraction of GNP. The data were originally collected by the Arms
Control and Disarmament Agency (ACDA) of the U.S. government and
64
Note that other studies have found that a governments reliance on personal and corporate tax
revenues is strongly and negatively influenced by per capita income: poor states tend to rely on trade
taxes, rich ones on personal and corporate taxes. See William Easterly and Sergio Rebelo, Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth, Journal of Monetary Economics 32 (December 1993); Howell H. Zee, Empirics of Cross-Country Tax Revenue Comparisons, World Development 24 (October 1996). Since per
capita income is included in the model, the actual effect of Taxes on regime types is probably larger
than the coefficient in this regression suggests.
65
David S. Brown and Wendy Hunter, Democracy and Social Spending in Latin America,
198092, American Political Science Review 93 (December 1999).
350
WORLD POLITICS
cover 101 states between 1985 and 1995.66 Since resource-rich states
tend to have government budgets that are atypically large relative to the
size of their economies, this is a better indicator than military spending as a fraction of government spending.
The second variable is Military Personnel, which measures the size of
the military as a fraction of the labor force; it includes some paramilitary forces if those forces resemble regular units in their organization,
equipment, training, or mission. The data are also from ACDA and are
available from 1985 to 1995 for 105 of the states in the database. Unlike the Military/GNP measure, this indicator helps control for variations
in military wages and the presence of conscription across states.
When Oil, Minerals, and Income are regressed on Military/GNP directly (with a five-year lag), the behavior of oil exporters and mineral
exporters diverges. Oil exports are indeed positively and significantly
correlated with military spending, as the repression hypothesis suggests;
but mineral exports are negatively and significantly associated with
military spending. Neither variable is significantly linked with Military
Personnel.
When Military/GNP is placed in the basic model of regime types, its
coefficient is negative and marginally significant at the 0.10 level; its inclusion produces a 6 percent drop in the Oil coefficient (Table 6). The
Military Personnel coefficient is negative and highly significant, although it paradoxically induces a 7 percent rise in Oil. In both samples
the Minerals coefficient is not significant and cannot be interpreted.
Overall, it appears that oil wealth may be linked to higher levels of
military spending, which in turn tends to impede democracy, as the repression effect suggests. But there is no evidence of a similar pattern for
mineral wealth; nor is there evidence to support the claim that oil or
mineral wealth leads to higher levels of military personnel.
Why do oil-rich governments invest as much as they do on their
militaries? Is it to repress popular pressures, or is it a response to higher
levels of instability? To address this question I use data from the Political Risk Services Group, a private firm that uses subjective measures to
gauge investment risks for its clients. It produces a 06 measure of Ethnic Tensions, which measures the degree of tension within a country attributable to racial, nationality, or language divisions. Scores are
available for 102 states between 1982 and 1997. Higher values indicate
less ethnic tension. When added to the modelfirst separately, then
66
Since the data cover only eleven years, the maximum number of possible observations for these regressions drops from 3,752 to 1,642.
351
TABLE 6
THE REPRESSION EFFECTa
(DEPENDENT VARIABLE
Regime
Oil
Minerals
Income (log)
Islam
OECD
Military/GNP
Military Personnel
Ethnic Tensions
Observations
States
Log likelihood
IS REGIME )
.414***
(.032)
.0591***
(.00566)
.0169
(.0272)
.848***
(.132)
.0173***
(.00266)
.071
(.332)
.0366
(.0197)
.334***
(.0314)
.0679***
(.00632)
.00344
(.0179)
.822***
(.145)
.0158***
(.00235)
.00168
(.355)
.34***
(.0262)
.0517***
(.00609)
.000964
(.0201)
.824***
(.117)
.0263***
(.00251)
.0957
(.3)
.09**
(.0304)
841
101
1228
874
105
1293
.0254
(.0485)
1167
102
1642
* significant at the 0.05 level; ** significant at the 0.01 level; *** significant at the 0.001 level
a
All independent and control variables are entered with five-year lags; intervening variables (Military/GNP, Military Personnel, Ethnic Tensions) are entered with one-year lags.
Standard errors are in parentheses below the coefficients. Feasible Generalized Least
Squares regressions run with Stata 6.0; corrected for first-order autocorrelation using panelspecific process. Each regression is run with dummy variables for every year (but one) covered by the data.
352
WORLD POLITICS
Daniel Lerner, The Passing of Traditional Society (New York: Free Press, 1958); Deutsch (fn. 38).
Inglehart (fn. 1).
69
Lipset (fn. 38).
68
353
TABLE 7
THE MODERNIZATION EFFECTa
(DEPENDENT VARIABLE
Regime
Oil
Minerals
Income (log)
Islam
OECD
Men in
Industry
Women in
Industry
Men in
Services
Women in
Services
Observations
States
Log likelihood
IS REGIME )
.529***
(.0316)
.0182
(.0221)
.146*
(.0666)
.251
(.305)
.0121
(.0082)
.752*
(.419)
.0733***
(.0143)
.462***
(.0408)
.116
(.0202)
.112
(.0635)
.565*
(.271)
.0154**
(.00545)
.652
(.432)
.513***
(.0336)
.0187
(.0207)
.0952
(.0657)
.408
(.343)
.0232***
(.00652)
1.13**
(.372)
.604***
(.0324)
.0315
(.0234)
.115
(.0714)
3.8
(.344)
.000534
(.0104)
.391
(.419)
.0814***
(.0166)
.0685***
(.0155)
626
75
878
615
75
772
622
76
835
.0185***
(.00512)
629
76
921
* significant at the 0.05 level; ** significant at the 0.01 level; *** significant at the 0.001 level
a
All independent and control variables are entered with five-year lags; intervening variables (Men in Industry, Women in Industry, Men in Services, Women in Services) are entered
with one-year lags. Standard errors are in parentheses below the coefficients. Feasible Generalized Least Squares regressions run with Stata 6.0; corrected for first-order autocorrelation using panel-specific process. Each regression is run with dummy variables for every
year (but one) covered by the data.
munications Union and are available for 113 and 110 states, respectively, and cover virtually all country years in the data set.
Finally, Lipset also suggested that higher levels of urbanization will
lead to higher levels of democracy. To measure urbanization I use the
fraction of a states population currently living in urban areas. The data,
collected by the United Nations, are available for all 113 states.
The results from these regressions are reported in Tables 7, 8, and 9.
All of the variables measuring occupational specialization are highly
354
WORLD POLITICS
TABLE 8
THE MODERNIZATION EFFECTa
(DEPENDENT VARIABLE
Regime
Oil
Minerals
Income (log)
Islam
OECD
Male Secondary
Enrollment
Female Secondary
Enrollment
College Enrollment
Observations
States
Log likelihood
IS REGIME )
.378***
(.0449)
.0158
(.00966)
.0251
(.0431)
.258
(.296)
.0393***
(.00507)
.159
(.345)
.004
(.00856)
.378***
(.0451)
.0168
(.00952)
.0255
(.0433)
.364
(.29)
.0385***
(.00479)
.187
(.336)
.34***
(.0334)
.033***
(.00991)
.0517
(.0325)
.678***
(.19)
.0348***
(.00407)
.0759
(.436)
.000812
(.00882)
426
48
566
426
48
563
.00289
(.0105)
688
96
1109
* significant at the 0.05 level; ** significant at the 0.01 level; *** significant at the 0.001 level
a
All independent and control variables are entered with five-year lags; intervening variables (Male Secondary Enrollment, Female Secondary Enrollment, College Enrollment) are entered with one-year lags. Standard errors are in parentheses below the coefficients. Feasible
Generalized Least Squares regressions run with Stata 6.0; corrected for first-order autocorrelation using panel-specific process. Each regression is run with dummy variables for
every year (but one) covered by the data.
355
TABLE 9
THE MODERNIZATION EFFECTa
(DEPENDENT VARIABLE
1
Regime
Oil
Minerals
Income (log)
Islam
OECD
Telephones
TVs
Life
Expectancy
Urban
Observations
States
Log likelihood
IS REGIME )
.196***
(.0225)
.04***
(.00551)
.0085
(.0152)
.882***
(.134)
.023***
(.00231)
1.75***
(.351)
.413***
(.0516)
.0247
(.039)
.0376
(.0605)
1.07***
(.315)
.0104
(.0168)
.041
(.412)
.253***
(.0203)
.0346***
(.00509)
.0441***
(.008)
.983***
(.149)
.0174***
(.00213)
1.51***
(.31)
.00096
(.00079)
.00378
(.0616)
.194***
(.0232)
.0463***
(.00609)
.00929
(.016)
1.24***
(.119)
.0194***
(.00214)
2.96***
(.482)
.00543***
(.00118)
1830
113
2830
1831
110
2676
777
103
857
.00278
(.005)
2183
113
3133
* significant at the 0.05 level; ** significant at the 0.01 level; *** significant at the 0.001 level
a
All independent and control variables are entered with five-year lags; intervening variables (Telephones, TVs, Life Expectancy, Urban) are entered with one-year lags. Standard errors are in parentheses below the coefficients. Feasible Generalized Least Squares
regressions run with Stata 6.0; corrected for first-order autocorrelation using panel-specific
process. Each regression is run with dummy variables for every year (but one) covered by
the data.
356
WORLD POLITICS
357
pressures; and a modernization effect, in which the failure of the population to move into industrial and service sector jobs renders them less
likely to push for democracy. The links between mineral wealth and authoritarianism are more elusive: the mineral exporters appear to suffer
from a rentier effect but not a repression effect, and there is only weak
evidence that they are afflicted by a modernization effect.
Collectively, these findings should help vindicate two very different
theories of comparative politics: modernization theory, which after
falling out of favor in the 1970s and 1980s made a strong comeback in
the 1990s; and the theory of the rentier state, which has long been
championed by Middle East area specialists but overlooked by scholars
of democratization.
They also highlight the value of bringing cross-national quantitative
studies into closer contact with area studies. Global studies of democracy have generally overlooked the Mideast, a practice that is difficult
to justify methodologically (since it arbitrarily truncates the researchers
sample of states) and one that has contributed to a belief that the Middle East region is sui generis. Of course, the history and culture of the
Mideast are exceptional: note the enormous coefficient on the Mideast
dummy variable in Table 4. But excluding Middle Eastern states from
large-N studies of democracy can only widen the gap between area
studies and the rest of political science. It also deprives mainstream political science of the many insights developed by area studies scholars
insights that, like the oil-impedes-democracy claim, may turn out to
have general applications.
Finally, these findings have implications for the fate of resource-rich
states across the developing world. Many of the worlds most troubled
states have high levels of oil and mineral wealth. Earlier studies have
shown that resource wealth tends to reduce economic growth and to increase the likelihood of civil war. This article suggests there is a third
component to resource curse: authoritarian rule.
These three effects may interact in pernicious ways, creating a resource trap. Authoritarian governments may be less able to resolve domestic conflicts and hence more likely to suffer from civil war. Slow
growth may make domestic unrest tougher to resolve; civil wars, in
turn, wreak economic havoc. There is nothing inevitable about the resource curse: states like Malaysia, Chile, and Botswana have done relatively well despite their oil and mineral wealth. Yet most others have
foundlike King Midasthat their resource wealth can be an unexpected source of grief.
358
WORLD POLITICS
359
David B Barrett, ed., World Christian Encyclopedia (New York: Oxford University Press, 1982).
360
WORLD POLITICS
361
GNP. The data cover 198595; they were originally collected by the Arms
Control and Disarmament Agency (ACDA) of the U.S. government.
Military Personnel measures the size of the military as a percentage
of the labor force; it includes some paramilitary forces if those forces
resemble regular units in their organization, equipment, training, or
mission. The data are also from ACDA and cover 198595.
Ethnic Tensions is a 06 interval-level variable that measures the degree of tension within a country attributable to racial, nationality, or
language divisions. The data cover 97 states between 1982 and 1997;
the codings are carried out by a private firm, the Political Risk Services
Group, and published in their monthly International Country Risk
Guide; they are also available as the IRIS-3 computer database. The
monthly data have been changed into annual data by taking the mean
of the twelve monthly values.
APPENDIX 2:
SUMMARY OF VARIABLES
Variable
Obs.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min
Regime
Log Income
Oil
Minerals
3752
3316
2322
2865
4528
4336
2511
2504
814
798
810
813
607
607
1272
4372
1527
3129
3040
2325
3538
2277
1298
1440
1739
4.48
7.45
5.5
2.25
.163
25
5.73
1.68
29.4
15.5
39
52
57.7
58
16.9
46.1
62.5
106
151
50.9
15.2
23.8
4.36
1.84
3.791
3.79
1.2
14.1
5.8
.369
36.6
6.23
2.88
12.7
8.99
14.3
25.6
27.9
29.9
16.9
25
11.7
154
169
18.7
6.51
11.9
6.64
2.6
1.633
0
4.53
0
0
0
0
0
0
.4
0
5
9
3
1.3
.1
2.24
31.2
.1
0
0
.897
0
0
0
0
OECD
Islam
Food
Agriculture
Men in Industry
Women in Industry
Men in Services
Women in Services
Male Secondary
Female Secondary
College
Urban
Life Expectancy
Telephones
TVs
Taxes
Govt. Consumption
Government/GDP
Military/GNP
Military Personnel
Ethnic Tensions
Max
10
10.43
115.6
55.1
1
99.7
45.9
31.6
66.9
50.2
69.3
100
98.6
98.5
97.7
100
79.8
691
838
101
76.2
91.2
102
29.6
6