Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Global Cement Industry Competitive

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

M PRA

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

Global Cement Industry: Competitive


and Institutional Dimensions
Tarek Selim and Ahmed Salem
June 2010

Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/24464/
MPRA Paper No. 24464, posted 27. August 2010 07:51 UTC

Global Cement Industry:


Competitive and Institutional Frameworks
BY

Tarek H. Selim and Ahmed S. Salem


The American University in Cairo
This version: June 2010

Abstract
The cement industry is a capital intensive, energy consuming, and vital industry for sustaining
infrastructure of nations. The international cement market while constituting a small share of world industry
outputhas been growing at an increasing rate relative to local production in recent years. Attempts to protect the
environment in developed countries especially Europehave caused cement production plants to shift to countries
with less stringent environmental regulations. Along with continually rising real prices, this has created a concerning
pattern on economic efficiency and environmental compliance.
This paper attempts to critically analyze the forces affecting pricing and production of cement from two
perspectives. Porters five forces serve as our tool to analyze the competitive forces that move the industry from a
market economy standpoint. On the other hand, the institutional economics framework serves to explain how
governments and policymakers influence the structure and production distribution in the global market. Our findings
suggest that the cement industry does not follow expected patterns of a market economy model. Additionally, it does
not fully behave along the institutional economics paradigm. Hence, neither perspective explains the pricing or
nature of the market on its own.
Combining market forces within an institutional setting provides a more clear understanding of price
dynamics and industry performance. We find that local regulation alone is insufficient to ensure market efficiency
due to weak institutional governance in developing countries aligned with private business interests of global cement
firms. Moreover, the global impact of local environmental non-compliance generates economic spillover effects that
cannot be corrected by market forces alone. Due to asymmetries in governance and structure, this paper
recommends the establishment of an independent international regulatory body for the cement industry that serves to
provide sustainable industry development guidelines within a global context.
JEL: L61-D43-F18
Keywords: cement global industry institutional economics Porter competition market niche

Global Cement Industry: Competitive and


Institutional Frameworks
BY

Tarek H. Selim and Ahmed S. Salem

1. The Case of Cement: Local Production with Global Impact


The international cement market is one of the least regulated markets on an international
scale whereas international cement trade has been growing intensively in recent decades. While
the amount of cement traded has increased, the percentage of internationally traded cement to
total cement production remains in single percent digits (5% to 7%). This means that most of
cement production exists to satisfy local consumption.
The problem this research will explore is identifying the most critical factors required to
regulate the growing market for international cement. Initial fact finding suggests that cement
production has recently been concentrating in the developing world (Miller, 2009). Such
increasing production of a capital-intensive (labor-saving) industry means that the impact the
cement market is having on the local labor markets is low compared to the impact it is having on
the capital market. Even though economic rents are considerable, cement is one of the most
polluting industries: 5% of the worlds total emission of greenhouse gases is caused by cement
production (Loreti, 2008). This means that the developing world is increasingly baring the
environmental burden.
Any solution suggested to the problems caused by the cement industry has to be
composed of three crucial elements. First, it must be implemented on an international scale.
Local solutions cannot solve the problem. The environmental impact of burning fuel necessary
to produce cement in China, if uncontrolled, will lead to global warming because of the emission
of greenhouse gases caused by the burning. The impact of global warming however is not limited
to China alone but may have an extended impact on countries even as far away as South Africa.
Second, the developed world has to create an incentives system that does not shift all production
to areas that are less regulated. While it is desirable for European and North American countries
to achieve green economies by closing down cement factories or enacting strict environmental
regulations, it is a major problem when such cement production is only shifted to countries with
looser environmental regulations (Miller, 2009). Third, corruption and hidden transaction costs
within developing nations exacerbate the problem. Whether it is the lack of strong environmental
regulations or weakly implemented competition laws, developing countries can be a haven for
poor environmental control and strong cartels especially in a very high fixed cost industry such
as cement (Mishkin, 2007 and Selim, 2009). Any solution that does not contain these three
elements should be considered lacking.
The growing production of cement calls on all countries and NGOs to begin seriously
considering a global policy to solve the problems posed by this industry. An effective global
policy can only be found if different actors cooperate. Being a capital-intensive industry that
utilizes scarce resources to operate (such as fuel) means that governments need to keep some sort
of an eye on production. Even though cement is locally produced the impact of the production is
global and the presence of lucrative opportunities to shift production sites makes the industry an
attractive one for governmental regulation. It is this interaction between the economic

(efficiency) and the political (institutional) that calls for finding a framework for evaluating
solutions that takes into account both ends.
2. What is Cement?
At the basic level cement is a binding substance that is intended for use in building or
construction material and can withstand varying environmental conditions. The four elements
necessary for its creation are iron, aluminum, silicon, and calcium. These elements are burned
together in a kiln and are finely pulverized to create the powder and used as an ingredient of
mortar and concrete we then call cement. This powder hardens once it is mixed with water but
water does not break the bond once it is formed. About 75% of cement production is used in
ready mixed concrete to be utilized in construction. The remaining 25% is used for paving roads
or extracting oil (Portland Cement Association, 2009).
The most common type of cement is Portland. This category is divided roughly into gray
and white: gray is the most well known most people refer to it when they say the word cement.
White is the aesthetic alternative of gray which is used in buildings that have an aesthetic
component: churches, museums, etc. Gray Portland is made from clinker and an additional
substance usually calcium sulfate. On the other hand, white Portland is made from limestone,
kaolin, and gypsum. A less common type of Portland cement is referred to as Pozzolana Portland
cement. It is used in buildings which expect to be exposed to constant high humidity or water
and it is made out of clinker, gypsum, and natural pozzolana a raw material of volcanic rocks
and ash. Finally, there is a special type of cement utilized in extraction of oil and withstands high
pressure areas called Oil-well cement (Cemex, 2010). While other types of cement exist, the
most important are gray and white Portland cement as they comprise the bulk of cement utilized
in constructing roads, buildings, and other structures.
3. Major Country Players
China leads the way in cement consumption and production around the world due to the
large scale developments and infrastructure buildup projects that the Chinese government is
undertaking. According to 2007 estimates the Chinese production hovers around 50% of world
total while the second closest rival Indiahovers around 6%. Table 1 details production of the
top ten nations. In addition to showing the production in the years 2006 and 2007 in columns 2
and 3, we have calculated in the fourth column the percent of market share of each country in the
year 2007 by dividing the amount produced in each country by the world total. In column five,
we calculate the percent increase in local production, whereas in column six we calculate the
percent increase in world share (2006-2007). Some rounding errors are expected as the world
total has been rounded. It is worthy to note that Thailand was very close to making it on the table
as its production nears that of Brazil and may exceed it in future years. Egypt on the other hand
produces about 1.1% of the worlds total.

Table 1: Top 10 Producing Nations of Cement


Country
Production, Production, Percent of
2006
2007
World,
2007
China
India
United States
Japan
Korea,
Republic of
Russia
Spain
Turkey
Mexico
Brazil
World Total

1,200,000
155,000
99,700
69,900
55,000

1,300,000
160,000
96,400
70,000
55,000

50%
6%
3.9%
2.6%
2.1%

Percentage
increase in
production
(2006- 2007)
8.3%
3.2%
-3.3%
-0.14%
0%

54,700
54,000
47,500
40,600
39,500
2,550,000

59,000
50,000
48,000
41,000
40,000
2,600,000

2.3%
1.9%
1.8%
1.5%
1.5%

7.9%
-7.4%
1.0%
0.98%
1.3%

Percentage
increase in
share (20062007)
3.0%
0%
-0.2%
-0.1%
-0.04%
0.2%
-0.2%
-0.01%
-0.01%
-0.01%

Source: UN Comtrade (Steinweg, 2008), Production figures are in thousand metric tons

Some of the slowdowns in production seen above are due to dramatic downward demand
shifts in the residential housing markets of the United States and Europe. However, public
projects are keeping the total cement production around the world on the rise. It is interesting to
note that production is concentrated in developing nations (at least 70% of world total production
is based in developing countries). With the exception of the US, Japan, and Spain, all other
nations in Table 1 are still in a developing phase. While the majority of the production is locally
consumed, a good chunk of the cement produced is exported. This means that some production
has shifted to these nations whether it is because of cheaper labor, less strict environmental
regulations, or subsidies (Mishkin, 2007 and Miller, 2009).
4. Exporting Nations
It is unsurprising that China leads the way in this category since Chinese cement
represents roughly 50% of world production. Below is a table detailing the total dollar value
traded by the top ten nations along with the amount of cement traded. Half of those nations are
not top producing nations. It is interesting to see that the exporting country list differs than the
producing country list. For example, the United States, Russia and Spain are on the top
producing list but not in the top 10 exporting countries. This is largely due to the fact that many
of the producing nations utilize their cement for internal consumption within the growing local
market. The third largest exporting nation also lies in Asia Japan. This suggests that the Asian
countries have a strong comparative advantage in producing cement (The Concrete Producer,
2006). It is also surprising to see Canada on the exporting countries list however it is probably
due to its proximity to the United States which is the worlds largest importer. Hence, export
markets tend to be regional in cement trade, but with significant variance in country
concentration relative to local production with the exception of China.

Table 2: The Top 10 Cement Exporting Countries (in order of amount exported)
Country
Value of Cement
Net Weight
Percentage export
Exports
(in metric tons)
intensity (country
export relative to total
world exports)
China
$1,180,621,971
36,129,658.562
37.9%
Thailand
$520,744,807
14,980,341.699
15.7%
Japan
$269,264,156
10,121,146.931
10.6%
Germany
$521,101,000
7,286,091.431
7.6%
Korea, Republic Of
$212,216,392
6,169,600.038
6.5%
Canada
$331,560,586
5,007,076.024
5.2%
India
$253,112,892
4,816,156.474
5%
Turkey
$250,240,781
3,803,691.757
4%
Malaysia
$137,963,081
3,721,707.074
3.9%
Greece
$184,186,904
3,354,438.405
3.5%
Source: UN Comtrade (Steinweg, 2008)
Production figures are in metric tons, 2006

The above shows how small the international market really is when compared with the
total production of each country. In other words, highly producing countries do not necessarily
have a high surplus. Exporting countries are the ones who have a surplus, but such a surplus is
not indexed by their relative scale in local production. This is possibly due to the fact that they
have a comparative advantage in producing cement via a lower cost of extracting raw materials
(The Concrete Producer, 2006).
5. Importing Nations
The table below Table 3shows the dollar value of imported cement for the top ten
countries as well as the net weight (converted from kilograms to metric tons) of cement
imported. The United States leads the way in both aspects though some slowdown is expected
due to the financial turmoil in the housing market.
This table is even more striking the top 5 nations which consume about 55% of cement-are all located in Western Europe and North America. From the export-import contrast one can
see a trend of production in developing nations towards consumption in developed nations. The
only exception to this rule is Korea which appears in both the import and export list. This is
probably due to the fact that cement does not only refer to ready made powder but may also refer
to materials such as clinker which Korea may be importing to produce the cement it ships out.
The trend we see producing in developing nations for the use of developed nations-- can be
mainly attributed to environmental regulations in the EU which appear to send the production to
third world nations but the final product back to Europe. Additionally, due to the increasing cost
of European cement production it is clear that cement firms have chosen to move their
production sites to developing countries where labor cost is lower and production regulations are
less stringent.
The United States is by far the number one importer of cement as it imports 3 times that
of Spain the second largest importer. This means that the shortage within the cement market in

the US is very high and that national production does not supply the necessary demand. Other
than Syria, no other country appearing on this list is from the Middle East region. The two tables
exporting and importing country lists actually confirm that production and export is highly
intensive in the developing world with lower relative demand, while consumption mostly
happens in the developed world with lower relative supply. Such a Ricardian notion in global
cement trade necessitates a comparative advantage for developing countries based on lower
relative costs, with relaxed environmental regulations internalized within that cost.
Table 3: The Top 10 Cement Importing Countries (in order of total weight imported)
Country
Value of Cement
Net Weight
Percentage import
Imports
(in metric tons)
production intensity
(countrys net
production weight
relative to world total)
United States
$2,553,331,474
35,895,944.904
33.1%
Spain
$737,121,284
12,356,397.091
11.4%
Italy
$340,542,114
4,621,025.113
4.3%
Netherlands
$250,292,002
3,873,054.182
3.6%
France
$333,411,969
3,687,568.641
3.4%
Korea, Republic Of
$141,625,690
3,260,128.876
3%
Ghana
$163,413,617
3,230,817.192
3%
Singapore
$127,909,094
2,986,054.476
2.8%
Syria
$212,592,885
2,812,010.319
2.6%
Kazakhstan
$165,412,275
2,610,647.332
2.4%
Source: UN COM Trade 2006 (Steinweg, 2008)
All Figures have been converted to metric tons

6. Nature of the Market and Regional Pricing


The price of traded cement varies by country and region as multiple factors interplay.
While we talk in more detail about pricing over a time period in subsequent sections, the purpose
of this section is to provide a rough outline on pricing and to examine the critical regional pricing
factors of the cement market.
For the purpose of simplifying the analysis we have assumed that dividing the dollar
value of cement exported by the amount of cement exported will yield the price per metric ton
for that countrys cement. For example, dividing the dollar value of Chinese exports by their
total exports and doing the same for Thailand yields that Chinese cement is being sold for
roughly $32 per metric ton while Thai cement is being sold for $34. Japanese and Korean cement
are being sold within the same range the former being $27 and the latter $34. In contrast
German cement runs for $71 a ton while Canadian cement runs for $66.
From a regional pricing structure, one can divide cement prices into two regional
categories: Asian cement on one hand and European and North American (EU/NA) on the other.
It is somewhat disenchanting however to see that such cement prices are not reflected in the
prices for which cement is actually sold in the market. In other words, the actual price of a ton of
cement varies in a different way that can be analyzed by dividing the dollar amount paid by
importing nations by the amount of cement traded for each nation. By doing so, we have found
that the US pays an average of $71 per ton of cement while Singapore pays $42. Most European

importers pay the same amount as the US either due to high price of cement in neighboring
countries or high price of transportation that is not usually included in the amount of money
received by exporting nations. The average price of cement paid by importers is around $46 per
metric ton. The average price of cement received by exporters is about $40. This means that
about $6 per metric ton is being used for transportation, tariffs, or additional costs.
From such a pricing variation it is evident that multiple factors, in addition to relative
production cost, interplay together to determine the actual price of cement in the market such
as taxes, shipping costs, and institutional costs. Furthermore, it is clear that cement is a nonhomogeneous product in pricing. It is price differentiated by country of origin subdivided into
Asian and EU/NA. Korea still remains an interesting case as it exports and imports cement at
differing prices. It imports it at a price of $43 per metric ton and exports it at a price of $34.
While this may mislead us to assume that such prices mean that Korea probably imports finished
products and exports raw materials, we must not forget that imported dollar values include tariffs
paid to the country as well as transportation costs while exports do not include these values.
Such a pricing structure shows that Asian countries have a strong comparative advantage.
While Thailand for example has lower production scale compared to the US, it is able to become
the worlds second largest exporter of cement because of a strong comparative advantage. Lower
prices imply that the resources utilized for cement are utilized in the area where they are most
needed. In other words, Asian countries can and are producing cement at a lower absolute cost
and a lower opportunity cost to their nations. On the other hand, European nations are producing
cement at substantially higher prices and costs. This cost differentiation is due to three factors.
First, lower labor cost in Asian countries European countries have a high minimum wage and
stringent business/environmental regulations. Second, large subsidies from Asian governments.
Third, comparatively low price of machinery in Asian countries.
Even with high prices in European nations the demand for European cement is still very
high. This can be due to one of two factors. First, the generally high demand for cement and the
existence of a shortage. Second, the fact that neighboring countries are forced to buy cement
from areas closest to them to avoid high shipping costs. Hence, although cement is a
homogenous product, there exists cost differentiation in the global cement market based on
Asian vs. EU/NA regional pricing.
The demand for cement is considered to be price inelastic due to lack of apparent
substitutes. This can be seen with varying degrees across the world today. As the economies of
different countries are in recession and the construction business has been negatively impacted,
cement prices persistently increased in real terms. In the UAE, for example, the price of cement
has increased even though the real estate market is in turmoil. In Egypt, even though there has
been a reduction in steel prices in 2008-2009, cement prices soared. In North America and
Europe the prices are fluctuating but they are clearly on the rise (Portland Cement Association,
2009). This can be attributed to the fact that even when private enterprise is not using cement,
the governmental demand on it is high as it needs it for infrastructure build-up. What is more
intriguing is that while the cost of transportation has decreased due to the drop in oil and
subsequent fuel prices, the price of cement has actually increased in real terms. Such evidence
only serves to reaffirm the necessity of cement and the high demand relative to the supply that
can cause the industry to withstand severe economic slowdowns around the world. It also shows
the resilience of cement pricing to external shocks.

7. Environmental Impact
The process of producing cement causes negative environmental externalities at all levels
of production. To make clinker and mix it to prepare concrete the material must be grounded and
heated to more than 1500 oC. Such energy intensive production releases NOX (nitrogen oxides),
CO2 (carbon dioxide), and SO2 (sulfur dioxide). All of these gaseous materials cause harmful
effects on the environment and contribute to the global climate change on earth. Cement alone
contributes about 5% of the worlds total greenhouse gases (Adam, 2007 and Loreti Group,
2008). Not only do these gases contribute to global warming, they also contribute to poor air
quality that can cause weakening in human health and respiratory systems. When cement
factories become even more concentrated in the developing world, this means that children and
people living in these areas will be paying the price for construction firms to use the cement in
Europe or North America (Miller, 2009). Hence, the global cement industry can be characterized
as having global distributional inefficiency across space and time.
The environmental impact is further complicated through the harmful effects of resource
depletion. In order to make cement and burn the components at the aforementioned temperature,
the amount of fuel used oil or coalis very high. While clinker is not under the threat of being
depleted anytime soon, the economic costs of fuel resource depletion needed to make the cement
is under attack. Furthermore once the final product is produced, some solid wastes remain as a
result of the production process. Such solid waste, in countries with loose environmental
regulations or weak enforcement mechanisms, is thrown into the water or burned in an
uncontrolled location. This lack of oversight continues to cause levels of inequality that the
world cannot sustain in the long run.
These environmental challenges have gone uncontrolled because of the importance of
cement for developing countries due to industrialization, export proceeds, and infrastructure
requirements. The industry traditionally has gone under the radar unlike the aviation industry
that has been under attack for environmental impact. It is worth to mention here that industry
leaders have taken the lead, in real or artificial terms, to meet and discuss the impact of their
industry on the environment (Adam, 2007). Specifically, the World Business Council for
Sustainable Development (WBCSD) has started a Cement Sustainability Initiative (CSI) led by
global industry firms. However, action has yet to take place in an organized and succinct manner
that can prevent the long term environmental and health damage that is caused by the production
of cement on a global scale.
The environmental challenges posed to the world are exacerbated because of the lack of
substitutes for cement. Building hospitals, hotels, homes, schools, etc is a necessary component
for development and infrastructure build up. Without cement, building is virtually impossible.
However, according to the United States Geological Survey, virtually all Portland cement is
used either in making concrete or mortars and, as such, competes in the construction sector with
concrete substitutes such as aluminum, asphalt, clay brick, rammed earth, fiberglass, glass, steel,
stone, and wood (United States Geological Survey, 2008). In other words, some of these
materials can be utilized in higher proportions to decrease the use of concrete which has the
effect of decreasing the use of cement. Actual cement substitutes are a number of materials,
especially fly ash and ground granulated blast furnace slag, which develop good hydraulic
cementitious properties [the ability to set and harden under water by reacting with the lime
released by the hydration of Portland cement]. These (materials) are increasingly being used as
partial substitutes for Portland cement in some concrete applications (United States Geological
Survey, 2008). Any framework that will be used to solve the environmental problem must

balance the importance of continuing cement production for development with the heightened
need to keep our environment safe for future generations.
8. Applying Porters Five Forces: The Competitive Dimension
To begin analyzing different frameworks that we can use to assess solutions for the
growing environmental impact of the cement industry and the market regulations needed, a better
understanding about the forces that critically affect the industry must be distilled.
Porters five forces provides a competitive forces framework that allows us to better
understand the different dimensions that govern market competition. Porters five forces are: (1)
rivalry, (2) threat of substitutes, (3) buyer bargaining power, (4) supplier bargaining power, and
(5) barriers to entry and exit (Porter, 2008).
Rivalry within the cement industry is moderate. The structure of the market tends to be
oligopolistic in different regions around the world. In other words only a few firms control the
market in many different countries. This is due to the high fixed cost (approximately 10 million
dollars a plant). This creates a highly concentrated firm environment with limited rivalry. On the
other hand, cement products are not differentiated. This means that competition between existing
firms can get intense. When consumers do not bare a cost by switching from one firm to another
(low switching costs) and when the product lacks differentiation, this creates a haven for
competition and intense rivalry. The combination of the above factors result in moderate rivalry
within the global cement industry.
The second force is the threat of substitutes. Lack of substitutes other products that are
not within the same industry but can be used insteadmeans that the industry does not face a
credible threat of competition. This represents the reality of the cement industry. No product
exists to date that can substitute effectively for cement. While construction firms can use less
cement in exchange for using other materials that have some cementitious quality, that
substitution effect is negligible on the market price of cement (United States Geological Survey,
2008). An industry is only threatened if another industry produces a similar product (e.g.
aluminum cans vs. plastic bottles), or if consumers of that product can decrease the ratio of their
use of that product and use another product i.e. minimal partial substitution. Both of these
choices are virtually non-existent to cement consumers, hence the threat of substitutes is very
low.
The third force of competition is buyer bargaining power. This refers to the effect
customers can exert on a particular industry. Pure buyer power exists when only one buyer exists
in the market (monopsony). In this case power is entirely in the hands of the buyer. In the cement
industry, facts suggest that this effect is minimal. The power of consumers is limited due to the
lack of substitutes, the small number of cement firms (oligopoly), and the inelastic demand that
consumers have for the product. Buyers are said to be powerful if they are highly concentrated,
purchase a large amount of the product, or if there is product standardization. The last effect
exists but its impact is weak because of persistent shortages in the cement market. Given the fact
that the buyers in the cement market lack the characteristics that give them power over producing
firms, the competitive level of the industry judged through this force is very low. Firms have an
easier time setting price while buyers act generally as price takers.
Supplier bargaining power is the fourth force that Porter argues influences industries.
Suppliers if powerful can extract some of the profits that producing firms are making off of
consumers by raising the prices of raw materials. In the inputs market for the cement industry,
suppliers are concentrated but buyers are also concentrated. This means that initial bargaining is

practically on equal footing. Suppliers of cement industry are divided into two categories:
suppliers of transportation and suppliers of raw materials (clinkers). Cement manufacturers have
argued that price hikes in the cement industry are due to increases in the price of both
transportation and raw materials. This means that suppliers are powerful enough to force new
prices on the cement industry. However, the weakness of the final consumers relative to both
implies that the burden is mostly shifted to the price of the final product. In general suppliers are
powerful if there is a credible forward integration threat (suppliers can buy producing firms),
suppliers are concentrated (no switching opportunity), the cost is prohibitive to switch suppliers,
and/or if a supplier can rally up the final consumer (such as fair trade farmers). In the case of
cement the power of suppliers comes from their concentration regionally and from the high cost
in switching between suppliers. It is not easy for a cement firm to buy clinker from China and
ship it to Egypt or vice versa. This means that local raw material production must be utilized and
that local or regional suppliers have high bargaining power.
The final force that Porter uses to measure forces of competition within an industry is
barriers to entry and exit. High barriers to entry mean that firms already in the industry do not
fear outside competition. This means that rivalry amongst firms is not intense. In fact,
incentives for intra-industry cooperation in this case, or backhanded collusions such as cartels,
are highly plausible. Barriers to exit on the other hand means that firms already in the market are
locked in. This can result from the firms inability to sell the assets if it decides to leave the
industry. Barriers to entry and exit can be seen in four different ways. First, government creates
barriers by limiting the number of licenses it sells for production. Cement is energy intensive as
well as highly polluting; therefore entry to such a market has to be highly regulated in the eyes of
many governments. Second, patents create entry barriers. Patents on new production methods or
machines create difficulties for firms to enter. However, the cement industry is not a patentdependent industry, unlike other industries such as pharmaceuticals. Third, assets needed to
produce cement cannot be easily utilized for another industry (i.e. the cement industry is highly
asset specific). This means that if a firm decides to enter into the market it must realize that a
cease in its production will be very costly. Finally, economies of scale can prevent entry. For
cement firms, neutralizing the high fixed costs requires a minimum efficient scale of production
that creates a strong barrier to entry. Overall, the cement industry has high barriers to entry and
high barriers to exit.
Porters five forces is a framework that looks at rivalry and consumer-firm-industry
relations from a market forces perspective. In the case of cement it is clear that the final
consumer has little say in the price because of the high inelastic demand. Production is very
costly and regulated in most areas which keep rivalry in moderation. The power of suppliers of
raw materials and cement firms forces the burden of price hikes to shift to the consumers. This
conclusion must be taken into account when comparing Porters model with the institutional
viewpoint, in order to come up with an effective framework to analyze policies related to the
cement industry in general.
Figure 1 depicts the five competitive forces that shape the global cement industry.
Rivalry is moderate, the effect of substitutes is weak, buyer power is minimal, supplier power is
high, and entry/exit barriers are both high. In essence, the vertical supply chain has pricing power
over final consumers, whereas the horizontal dimension of competition is lacking due to lack of
the possibility of differentiated advantages in production. Inelastic demand neutralizes the
consumer power associated with product standardization, whereas proximity of raw materials to
production sites generate regional cement clusters.

Figure 1:
The Five Competitive Forces that
Shape the Global Cement Industry

The above diagram explains Porters five competitive forces as they relate to the global cement industry. A plus sign means that the force has an
effect on the cement industry in intensifying rivalry. A minus sign means that it plays an opposing role. An (N) means that the force has neutral or
no relevance to the industry.

9. The Institutional Economics Dimension


The market niche is a newly developed concept by institutional economists and it refers
to the segment of the market in which production supply meets with the highly inelastic portion
of demand, the latter being elastic at price extremes. It is widened or narrowed through product
innovation, advertising, (and) after sales services (Kasper & Streit, 1998). In other words, it is
that segment in a market which does not respond to little variation in pricing. Whether it is due to
the necessity of the product or loyalty for the product, a niche is the single most important
segment for which different firms try to compete.
The consumers of Portland cement can be divided into three categories: governments,
construction firms, and individual home owners. Assuming a downward sloping aggregate
demand curve, individual home owners would be the consumers on the demand curve that are
most elastic. Whether it is utilizing cement for repair or for home expansion, this segment will
always respond to price changes. On the more inelastic portion of the curve lie the construction
firms and the government. Government projects are time sensitive and generally relate to
infrastructure build up. This means that sensitivity to price is almost negligible as the time
constraint of project implementation dictate the governments consumption of cement.
Construction firms will not respond to small changes in price but may respond if crashes (or
shocks) occur in the housing market. However, the presence of the niche government and big
firmsmeans that the price of cement can be affected little by individual decisions. Pricing for
the niche takes place separately than that for individual consumers because the impact of pricing
is quite different. This differs than the generic pricing model in that the institutional framework
(Kasper and Streit, 1998) applied to cement firms divides consumers into different sensitivity
groups and shows that the demand curve is not fully uniform but rather can be affected by
different groups within the same market. Figure 2 depicts a typical market niche and shows how
the demand curve can behave according to institutional economics.
Understanding how pricing can be tailored to different consumers will help in shaping a
framework to judge the regulation or deregulation of the cement industry. Having a strong hold
on the market niche means that firms in the cement industry will respond little to market
mechanisms. Whether it be large subsidies from the government or guarantees of large projects,
such activities lead to unintentional price fixing through institutional means. If cement firms
were insecure with the niche the fear that governments or buyers may switch to other firms
then cement producers would be more sensitive to pricing as determined by the market
mechanism.
In order for us to test the hypothesis of institutional economics as applied to the global
cement industry, we decided to collect data on four countries: Thailand (second largest exporter),
China (largest producer/exporter), France (European production center for cement), and Spain
(second largest importing country but not on the top ten list of cement exporters). After selecting
these countries we gathered data about their cement production in 3 different years 2006-2008
for the former three and 2005-2007 for Spain (2008 data was not available). After collecting this
data we calculated the (average) price elasticity for the different countries in real terms. Since we
are examining demand elasticity we assumed that what this country exports constitutes what the
world effectively demands from that country given that all of what is exported is being
consumed. Quantities used in the calculation were obtained from the UN Commodity Trade
Statistics.
Results show three different critical points of demand elasticity. Thailands average price
elasticity of demand is 1.08 which means that demand for Thai cement is unitary elastic. Chinese
and French cement, in contrast, are found to be highly inelastic at 0.10 and 0.14, respectively.
Spanish cement is highly elastic at 4.44. Correlating these elasticities with real cement prices
which we call price points- we derive that the demand curve for cement within the institutional

framework has a double-kink as obtained from our calculations (see Figures 2 and 3). Thailand
with the unitary elastic demand had the lowest price ($26 per metric ton) while Spain had the
highest price ($141 per metric ton) and the highest elasticity. China and France respectively fell
in the middle ($41 and $63) even though the demand for their cement proved to be inelastic.
These price points were then re-tested (and re-indexed) with US cement import/export data
found from the United States Geological Survey, and results were found almost fully
conforming. The final result for the cement market niche argument, based on the institutional
economics dimension, is shown in Figure 3.
Based on the above calculations, it is implied that at the lowest price level ($26) the
demand is unitary elastic and at the highest ($141) the demand is elastic. The middle range
between $41 and $63 is where the market is inelastic or where the niche lies. Countries
producing and exporting the highest quantities have the most inelastic portion of the demand
curve almost fully covered. This is the market niche.
If we draw this demand curve it will be easy to notice that the institutional proposal does
not completely fit into the cement market data. The demand curve begins at low quantity and
high price corresponding with a high elasticity and then as quantity grows (scale expands) we
seem to enter the inelastic range and lower prices at the critical price of $63. The inelastic market
niche then occurs between $41 and $63. Where our derived curve differs from that of the
institutional economists is that at low prices (Thailand) quantity drops and the line becomes
unitary elastic. In other words, unlike what institutional economists would suggest [i.e. that at the
lowest portion of the curve quantity increases, price decreases and the demand is elastic], the
findings seem to suggest that quantity and price drop together in the cement market data.
Some reasons for the discrepancy between the institutionalist demand curve and the one
derived in this paper is probably due to the fact that there is a minimum quantity at which you
will be considered a real player in the market (i.e. in the niche area). If unable to reach this
minimum level, you are actually considered out of the market. This explains why any pricing
outside the niche correlates with low quantity. Furthermore, players outside the niche price
according to location i.e. there exists regional price differentiation outside the niche. This
explains why Asian pricing is different than European pricing even though both produce at
similarly low quantities. For the market niche players, the relative price difference is lower
because market niche competition is more intense. This re-affirms that the institutional niche
concept correctly elucidates the price dynamics as applied within the global cement market.

Figure 2: The Institutionalist Viewpoint

price

elastic
Supply
A

Supply

Inelastic
(Market
Niche)

elastic

MARKET
DEMAND
(INSTITUTIONAL
ECONOMICS
VIEWPOINT)

quantity

This graph shows the demand curve for an industry based on the institutional economics viewpoint.
Note that demand sensitivity to price is not uniform: as price increases, quantity decreases significantly
(approaching the niche), then becomes more inelastic (market niche area), then decreases significantly
again (moving away from the niche). The demand curve is elastic at the top and bottom and inelastic in
the middle. This middle area represents the market niche (Kasper and Streit, 1998).

Figure 3: Global Cement Industry within the Institutionalist Viewpoint

price
$141/ton

Cement
Supply

$63/ton

$41/ton

$26/ton

Cement
Supply

Inelastic
CEMENT
DEMAND
(Market
Niche)
Institutionalist
Dimension

quantity

This graph represents the derived demand of the global cement industry based on the institutionalist viewpoint. This is
in contrast to the generalist institutional economics graph in Figure 2. From top to bottom, the first segment represents
the high price low quantity elastic portion of the demand curve with a price range from $141/ton to $63/ton. The
second segment between prices of $63 and $41 represents the inelastic market niche segment of the market. The third
segment represents unitary elasticity with a low quantity low price range between $26/ton and $41/ton. The fourth
segment with price below $26/ton represents elastic demand at the very low quantity low price range.

10. Effective Regulatory Control: A Call for a Proposal


It is evident that Porters competitive forces and the institutional economics framework
do not independently offer a holistic picture of the global cement industry. Hence, each approach
on its own cannot be used as a policy evaluation tool for effective regulation of the market.
Porters five forces do not fully explain the inner workings of the market except from a
rationality standpoint. The changing role of government and environmental groups is not directly
assessed. Moreover, the involvement of exogenous players outside the industrial supply chain- or
even behind the scene shifting instruments - are not fully accounted for. On the other hand, the
institutional economics framework explains segmented demand behavior in the market pricing
mechanism but cannot on its own account for the rational forces of competition which led to
such price variations. Therefore, we propose that both dimensions be taken together in order to
efficiently manage the interaction between global players in the industry and create an effective
regulatory policy framework to monitor the growing global cement market.
The cement industry is a crucial industry for infra-structure buildup which is necessary
for economic growth. Left unchecked however it can cause detrimental long run sustainability
problems: impact on climate change, health hazards, as well as excessive energy resource
depletion. As stated in our introduction, any solution to the cement industry must have a global
enforcing mechanism. Any local solution to the problem will not work on its own. As an
example, when the European Union restricted cement production in order to protect the
environment, major firms just shifted their production sites to developing countries (Hardy,
2008). In addition, governments in the developing world cannot be the only regulatory body over
the cement industry firms. Due to the necessity of the product, firms have a major bargaining
power against most governments. Also, hidden transaction costs can cause a slow down in the
enforcement of laws and regulations designed to protect the sustainability of the global industry.
The insurance of fair competition practices across borders is also necessary to curb predatory
oligopolistic behavior in the cement industry. Big business can easily take advantage of the lack
of fair competition laws that may exist in developing countries (Miller, 2009). In a high barrier
industry that is not very closely monitored, the room for cartel behavior such as the recent case
found in Egypt is readily observed (Mishkin, 2007). Without appropriate fair competition
mechanisms, businesses can easily collude and engage in behavior contrary to fair consumer
rights and to efficient long run resource sustainability (Hardy, 2008).
Since the cement industry cannot be left unchecked and unregulated on the global scale,
we propose that the option of cooperative regulation must be explored. Specifically, one of the
solutions that we strongly believe warrants examination is the creation of an international
regulatory body for the cement industry. This body should be composed of international
representatives from: (1) cement firms (business), (2) cement associations
(independent/business), (3) real estate and construction groups (business/government), (4)
consumer rights groups (independent/government), (5) environmental agencies (government),
and (6) environmentalist groups (independent). Establishing an interactive platform with the
objective of continuous communication between the above stakeholders will generate
enforcement mechanisms that tackle critical regulatory issues pertinent to the global cement
industry. Among such critical issues would be consumer protection, competition policy,
institutional governance, environmental pollution, and fair market practices.
The inner workings of the proposed regulatory body need to be examined in a separate
research undertaking. However, in this paper we have provided the necessary tools for
understanding significant economic dimensions in the global cement industry from the
competitive and market niche viewpoints.

11. Conclusion
It is fundamental for governments and cement firms alike to recognize the importance of
finding a coordinated international approach that can direct the global cement industry towards
both economic efficiency and environmental compliance. Policy makers need to realize that
there are three specific forces, with corresponding effects, that actually govern this interesting
but peculiar market. These are summarized below in Table 4.
Table 4: Critical Forces Governing the International Cement Market
Force
Effect
(1) Absolute Cost advantage Prevents new firms from entering because
incumbent multinationals control such an
advantage
(2) Substitutability
Keeps the power of the buyer (consumer) weak
relative to cement firms reinforcing the above
advantage
(3) Industry Concentration
Curbs rivalry providing a haven to back handed
collusion in the local governance structure of the
industry and creates competition compliance
concerns
In order to keep the power of cement firms in check and sustain economic and natural
resources for future generations, governments and different stakeholder groups must organize
themselves into an international regulatory body. This body should be comprised of consumer
rights groups, environmentalist groups, independent cement associations, cement businesses,
related industries, and policy representatives from different governments. The bottom line of
such an organization is to design regulatory frameworks in order to reach a sustainable level of
industry development within a global context. In essence, current local asymmetries in
governance and structure within the cement industry should be neutralized, or at least
coordinated, on a global scale.
This paper calls for a concrete proposal to address global enforcement mechanisms for
effective regulatory control over the global cement industry. A proposed body will act as an
effective oversight system where corruption can happen and collusion may occur. The
development of the global cement industry is necessary in so far as it provides the
implementation of fair market practices and the protection of the environment to citizens around
the world.
REFERENCES
Adam, D. (2007, October 12th). The unheralded polluter: cement industry comes clean on
its impact. The Guardian. Retrieved on November 6, 2008 from
http://www.guardian.co.uk/environment/2007/oct/12/climatechange
Cemex (2010). Types of cement. Retrieved on February 14, 2010 from
http://www.cemex.com/ps/ps_ce_tc.asp
Concrete Producer (June, 2006). Seeing to 2020: Asia has experienced the world's
largest increases in cement consumption. Retrieved July 15, 2009 from
http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m0NSY/is_6_24/ai_n16497840/

Dumiz, H. & Jeunemaetre, A. (2000). Understanding And Regulating The Market At A


Time Of Globalization. UK-USA: Palgrave.
Hardy, J. (2008). European Anti-Trust Law: European Commission Investigates Cartels
in Cement Industry. Retrieved on October 10, 2009 from http://www.eu-competitionlaw.co.uk/2008/11/european-commission-investigates.html
Kasper, W. & Streit, M. E. (1998). Institutional Economics: Social Order and Public
Policy. United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Loreti Group (2008). Greenhouse gas emission reductions from blended cement
production. Retrieved on November 10, 2009 from http://www.climateregistry.org/
resources/docs/protocols/issue-papers/Blended-Cement.pdf
Midwest Construction, Cement construction to grow 43% by 2030; cement consumption is
expected to nearly double by 2030 as the U.S. population grows. LexisNexis Academic.
Retrieved from http://0-www.lexisnexis.com.lib.aucegypt.edu/us/lnacademic
Miller, J. (2009, April 27th). Cement makers decry emissions rules. New York Times.
Retrieved from http://greeninc.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/04/27/cement-makers-decryemissions-proposal/
Mishkin, S. (December, 2007). The market for cement is thriving, as producers ramp up
production to keep domestic prices low. Business Today. Retrieved on November 15,
2008 from http://www.businesstodayegypt.com/article.aspx?ArticleID=7792
Porter, M. E. (1998). Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and
Competitors. Boston MA: Free Press.
Porter, M. E. (2008). The Five Competitive Forces That Shape Strategy, Boston
MA: Harvard Business Review, Harvard Business Publishing.
Portland Cement Association (2009). PCA Market Research on Cement, Concrete and
Construction: Department of Labor. Retrieved on February 9, 2010 from
http://www.cement.org/market/
Quick MBA. Porter's Five Forces: A Model for Industry Analysis, retrieved on June 26,
2009 from http://www.quickmba.com/strategy/porter.shtml Retrieved 2/17/2010
Selim, T. (ed.) (2009). Egypt energy and the environment: critical sustainability
perspectives. London, UK: Adonis & Abbey Publishers.
Steinweg, T. (2008). Cement: Sector scan. Amsterdam: SOMO. Retrieved on October 6,
2008 from http://somo.nl/publications-en/Publication_2533
United Nations Trade Statistics: Industrial Commodities Division (2008).
http://comtrade.un.org

United States Geological Survey (1996-2008). Minerals Statistics Division. Retrieved on


January 10, 2009 from http://minerals.usgs.gov/minerals/pubs/commodity/cement/
World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD), Cement Sustainability
Initiative. Retrieved on June 18, 2010 from http://www.wbcsdcement.org/

You might also like