Tracer Marks
Tracer Marks
Tracer Marks
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
ARTICLE
TRACERMARKS:
A PROPOSED INFORMATION INTERVENTION
Margaret Chon
We can see now that information is what our world runs on:
the blood and the fuel, the vital principle.1
ABSTRACT
We live in a world of information. But paradoxically, we
simultaneously suffer from a scarcity of smart information:
information that is traceable and therefore reliable, trust-worthy,
and ultimately verifiable. Combining the insights of global
governance theory with behavioral economics, this Article
approaches this challenge from a knowledge governance
framework, sets forth various reasons for this unnecessary deficit,
and proposes an intervention to address ittracermarks.
Envisioned as a hybrid of trademarks and certifications marks,
tracermarks would encourage various stakeholders to disclose,
Donald and Lynda Horowitz Professor for the Pursuit of Justice, Seattle
University School of Law. This Article was prepared for presentation at IPILs 2015
National Conference in Santa Fe, New Mexico, and in part for an opening address at the
New Zealand Center for International Economic Law conference held at Victoria University
at Wellington. The Author thanks IPIL, Professor Greg R. Vetter of the University of
Houston Law Center, and the Presenters and Fellows in Santa Fe, for their many helpful
comments and suggestions. In addition, she would like to acknowledge the support of
research librarian Kerry Fitz-Gerald, Elizabeth OBrien (class of 2015), Maria Therese
Fujiye (class of 2016), and Stephanie Gambino (class of 2017). Numerous colleagues and
friends provided helpful feedback on various draft versions, especially Jhonny Pabon
Cadavid and Professors H. Toms Gmez-Arostegui and Dev Gangjee. For all of the above,
the Author expresses her sincere gratitude.
1.
JAMES GLEICK, THE INFORMATION: A HISTORY, A THEORY, A FLOOD 8 (2011).
101
102
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
103
2.
Mark A. Lemley, IP in a World Without Scarcity, 90 N.Y.U. L. REV. 46668 (2015).
3.
I am indebted to Christine Farley for this apt observation.
4.
Katherine J. Strandburg, Free Fall: The Online Markets Consumer Preference
Disconnect, 2013 U. CHI. LEGAL F. 95, 99100.
5.
See Scott R. Peppet, Regulating the Internet of Things: First Steps Toward
Managing Discrimination, Privacy, Security, and Consent, 93 TEX. L. REV. 85, 99116
(2014) (discussing various technologies in the Internet of Things and the resulting problems
of lack of consumer privacy and consent).
6.
Stephanie Clifford, Some Retailers Reveal Where and How That T-Shirt Is Made,
N.Y. TIMES, May 9, 2013, at A1 (discussing growing consumer demand for information
concerning working conditions in the production of clothing).
7.
Julie E. Cohen, Property as Institutions for Resources: Lessons from and for IP,
94 TEX. L. REV. (forthcoming 2015), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?ab
stract_id=2478051; see also BRETT FRISCHMANN, INFRASTRUCTURE: THE SOCIAL VALUE OF
SHARED RESOURCES 253 (2012).
104
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
105
106
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
16.
This assumption is pervasive so that the joke about the economists can opener
told to me many years ago by my undergraduate economic professor is familiar still. See On
a Desert Island, with Soup, HARV. U. PRESS: BLOG (Apr. 6, 2012, 12:38 PM),
http://harvardpress.typepad.com/hup_publicity/2012/04/on-a-desert-island-with-soup-schl
efer-assumptions-economists-make.html.
17.
Of course, this premise is derived upon the famous Arrow paradox: [A]
fundamental paradox in the determination of demand for information [is that] its value for
the purchaser is not known until he has the information, but then he has in effect acquired
it without cost. Kenneth J. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for
Invention, in NATL BUREAU OF ECON. RESEARCH, THE RATE AND DIRECTION OF INVENTIVE
ACTIVITY: ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL FACTORS 615 (1962), reprinted in KENNETH J. ARROW,
ESSAYS IN THE THEORY OF RISK-BEARING 152 (1974).
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
107
18.
David W. Barnes, Congestible Public Property and Impure Public Goods, 9 NW. J.
TECH. & INTELL. PROP. 533, 53640 (2011).
19.
Id. at 54142 ([S]imultaneous source-indicating use of a mark by a business
competitor would diminish the utility derived by the mark owner . . . .).
20.
David W. Barnes, The Incentives/Access Tradeoff, 9 NW. TECH. & INTELL. PROP.
96, 10910 (2010).
21.
See Daniel L. McFadden, The New Science of Pleasure 4 (Natl Bureau of Econ.
Research, Working Paper No. 18687, 2013), http://www.nber.org/papers/w18687
(describing the classical economic conception of decision-making as fundamentally static,
with the consumer making a once-and-for-all utility maximizing choice of market goods).
22.
George A. Akerlof, The Market for Lemons: Qualitative Uncertainty and the
Market Mechanism, 84 Q.J. ECON. 488, 489 (1970); Joseph E. Stiglitz, Information and the
Change in the Paradigm in Economics, Part 1, AM. ECONOMIST, Fall 2003, at 6, 1516.
23.
Ariel Katz, Beyond Search Costs: The Linguistic and Trust Functions of
Trademarks, 2010 BYU L. REV. 1555, 156263.
24.
Phillip Nelson, Information and Consumer Behavior, 78 J. POL. ECON. 311, 312
(1970) (distinguishing between search goods and experience goods with the examples of a
dress, which can be tried on immediately, versus a can of tuna fish, which has to be opened
in order for the fish to be evaluated).
108
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
109
110
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
37.
See FTC v. Royal Milling Co., 288 U.S. 212, 21518 (1933).
38.
J. Shahar Dillbary, Getting the Word Out: The Informational Function of
Trademark, 41 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 991, 102526 (2009) [hereinafter Dillbary, Getting the Word
Out] (citations omitted).
39.
See generally Hanson & Kysar, supra note 8.
40.
See id. at 637, 64647, 658, 74748.
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
111
41.
See Adam Kirsch, Why Whole Foods Is Popping up in Novels, DAILY BEAST (May
10, 2015, 12:01 AM), http://thedailybeast.com/articles/2015/05/10/why-whole-foods-is-pop
ping-up-in-novels.html?via=twitter_page.
42.
Margaret Chon, Slow Logo: Brand Citizenship in Global Value Networks, 47 U.C.
DAVIS L. REV. 935, 941 (2014) [hereinafter Chon, Slow Logo]. As I argued there, the term
supply in supply chain in the existing literature does not fully account for the value of
intangible components often shaped by IP and the activities of those who are technically
not suppliers of component parts, such as highly discerning and participatory consumers
who are also embedded within these global networks. Nor does the term chain within
supply chain quite describe the myriad directions and scope of global networked
transactions. Multiple and nested informational transactions are required in order for these
markets to function without a high degree of misrepresentation or fraud. This complex
informational environment is not only a feature of the production core but also of the
distribution and consumption ends of the network. While different industries have different
nodes and relationships between them, the basic issue of creating and maintaining trust
mechanisms is constant across otherwise disparate global value networks.
43.
See, e.g., GARY GEREFFI & KARINA FERNANDEZ-STARK, CTR. ON GLOBALIZATION,
GOVERNANCE & COMPETITIVENESS, GLOBAL VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS: A PRIMER (2011)
(explaining dynamics of complex industrial interaction between actors in global
production); Gary Gereffi, John Humphrey & Timothy Sturgeon, The Governance of Global
Value Chains, 12 REV. INTL POL. ECON. 78 (2005) [hereinafter Gereffi, Humphrey &
Sturgeon, Global Value Chains] (proposing theoretical underpinnings of global value chains
based on different economic considerations).
44.
GEREFFI & FERNANDEZ-STARK, supra note 43, at 78; Gereffi, Humphrey &
Sturgeon, Global Value Chains, supra note 43, at 7980.
112
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
45.
TIM BTHE & WALTER MATTLI, THE NEW GLOBAL RULERS: THE PRIVATIZATION OF
REGULATION IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 2122 (2011); LISBETH SEGERLUND, MAKING
CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY A GLOBAL CONCERN: NORM CONSTRUCTION IN A
GLOBALIZING WORLD 11315 (2010) (discussing fair trade labeling and other voluntary
standards).
46.
See GEREFFI & FERNANDEZ-STARK, supra note 43, at 811.
47.
Gereffi, Humphrey & Sturgeon, Global Value Chains, supra note 43, at 81; see
also Eric L. Lane, Greenwashing 2.0, 38 COLUM. J. ENVTL. L. 279, 30304 (2013) (discussing
B2B deceptive practices disrupting the clean energy supply chain).
48.
See Chon, Slow Logo, supra note 42, at 94548, 953.
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
113
49.
See id. at 963.
50.
George Ritzer & Nathan Jurgenson, Production, Consumption, Prosumption: The
Nature of Capitalism in the Age of the Digital Prosumer, 10 J. CONSUMER CULTURE 13, 29
30 (2010).
51.
Chon, Slow Logo, supra note 42, at 937; see also Anne Barron, Intellectual
Property and the Open (Information) Society, in THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY 5, 1617 (Matthew David & Deborah Halbert eds., 2015) (discussing the theory
that the digital revolution will lead to new forms of intellectual property law).
52.
See Jonathan E. Schroeder, Brand Culture: Trade Marks, Marketing and
Consumption, in TRADEMARKS AND BRANDS: AN INTERDISCIPLINARY CRITIQUE 161, 161
(Lionel Bently et al. eds., 2008).
53.
See David Vaver, Brand Culture: Trade Marks, Marketing and Consumption
Responding Legally to Professor Schroeders Paper, in TRADE MARKS AND BRANDS: AN
INTERDISCIPLINARY CRITIQUE 177, 197 (Lionel Bently et al. eds., 2008).
54.
See Gereffi, Humphrey & Sturgeon, Global Value Chains, supra note 43, at 81.
55.
See FERNANDEZ-STARK, BAMBER & GEREFFI, supra note 29, at 8.
114
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
56.
WORLD INTELLECTUAL PROP. ORG., BRANDS REPUTATION AND IMAGE IN THE
GLOBAL MARKETPLACE 117 (2013), http://wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/intproperty/944
/wipo_pub_944_2013.pdf.
57.
Cohen, supra note 7, at 23.
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
115
116
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
117
68.
See Nelson, supra note 24, at 31314.
69.
Ralph S. Brown, Jr., Advertising and the Public Interest: Legal Protection of Trade
Symbols, 57 YALE L.J. 1165, 1186 (1948).
70.
See infra text accompanying notes 11626; see also Chon, Marks of Rectitude,
supra note 67, at 2332 (describing how certification marks can ultimately lead to consumer
confusion).
71.
Dillbary, Trademarks, supra note 31, at 34142.
72.
See Barton Beebe, Search and Persuasion in Trademark Law, 103 MICH. L. REV.
2020, 2025 (2005) (differentiating between the rational consumer and consumer as fool);
Graeme B. Dinwoodie & Dev S. Gangjee, The Image of the Consumer in European Trade
Mark Law 10, 12 (Univ. of Oxford Legal Research Paper Series, Paper No. 83/2014, 2015),
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2518986 (assessing the Court of Justice of the European Unions
articulation of the average consumer).
73.
Daniele Giovannucci, Elizabeth Barham & Richard Pirog, Defining and
Marketing Local Foods: Geographical Indications for US Products, 13 J. WORLD INTELL.
PROP. 94, 10710 (2010); see also OPEN AFRICAN INNOVATION RESEARCH & TRAINING
PROJECT, PLACE-BASED BRANDING FOR LOCALLY SPECIFIC PRODUCTS (2014),
http://openair.org.za/images/Briefing-Note-Place-Based-Branding-for-Locally-Specific-Pro
ducts.pdf (discussing Nigerias hand-dyed Abeokuta cloth and the counterfeit products
threatening it marketability).
118
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
74.
Katz, supra note 23, at 1561.
75.
Strandburg, supra note 4, at 123; Gleick, supra note 35.
76.
See Mark Scott, Google Rebuts Europe on Antitrust Charges, N.Y. TIMES (Aug. 27,
2015), http://nyti.ms/1K9513d.
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
119
All of this suggests that many more incentives for the creation and
distribution of smart information are needed. Smart information
can function as partial trust mechanisms for arms-length
transactions, especially between consumers and firms, but also
among smaller firms that may not be the dominant information
intermediaries within a particular value network. Smart
information can also involve producers of goods and services in
meaningful ways that have not yet been acknowledged. Yet reliable
trust mechanisms via smart information are not yet pervasive.
Ostensibly concerned with regulation of knowledge, IP falls
short of the task of creating incentives for this type of knowledge.
For instance, it has long been observed and more or less accepted
as inevitable that trademarks often fall within the realm of
subjective marketing rather than objective truth claims.78 And of
course, because trademarks have evolved to reflect both subjective
and objective aspects of goodwill, a consumer will buy a product
(and its associated brand image) for reasons having something to
do with the quality of the good (e.g., iPads are reliable as well as
fun), but not necessarily. Most conflations of marketing
information with reliable information are not viewed as actionable
fraud as long as they are not overtly deceptive.79
Of course, one of trademarks primary functions is as a rough
guarantee of the qualities of a good, especially if the consumer can
benefit from repeated purchases in order to experience these
qualities. In other words, it already possesses some aspects of a
trust mechanism for qualities that a consumer can readily
experience. However, as analyzed above, typically and
increasingly, trademark cannot do this important work with
respect to embedded credence (as opposed to experience)
attributes.
77.
Hanson & Kysar, supra note 39, at 72425; see also Jeremy N. Sheff, Marks,
Morals, and Markets, 65 STAN. L. REV. 761, 80809 (2013) (discussing implications of
behavioral economics for trademark law). But see Rebecca Tushnet, Gone in Sixty
Milliseconds: Trademark Law and Cognitive Science, 86 TEX. L. REV. 507 (2008) (voicing
skepticism of the benefits of cognitive science in dilution litigation).
78.
Vaver, supra note 53, at 197.
79.
See id. at 18485 (analyzing an advertisement for coffee liqueur and concluding
that a rational consumer would understand that the product would not turn him from nerd
to knight).
120
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
80.
Keith Aoki, (Intellectual) Property and Sovereignty: Notes Toward a Cultural
Geography of Authorship, 48 STAN. L. REV. 1293, 1304 (1996).
81.
Cohen, supra note 7, at 1011, 38.
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
121
122
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
88.
CAL. CIV. CODE 1714.43 (West Supp. 2015).
89.
Dara ORourke, Multi-Stakeholder Regulation: Privatizing or Socializing Global
Labor Standards?, 34 WORLD DEV. 899, 915 app. A (2006) (listing the standards
promulgated by Social Accountability International).
90.
See OXFAM, THE BEHIND THE BRANDS SCORECARD METHODOLOGY (2014),
https://oxfam.org/sites/www.oxfam.org/files/file_attachments/btb_methodology_document_
final_sept_2014.pdf.
91.
1714.43(a), (c).
92.
See id.
93.
Bus. & Human Rights Res. Ctr., 85 Firms Still Silent on California
Transparency in Supply Chains Act, CORP. SOC. RESP. NEWSWIRE (Feb. 12, 2014, 4:43 PM),
http://csrwire.com/press_releases/36712-85-firms-still-silent-on-California-Transparency
-in-Supply-Chains-Act.
94.
In the apparel industry, the brand PATAGONIA, founded by Yvon Choinard, is
viewed widely as an early innovator in this regard. Its current website has what it calls a
footprint of its suppliers. PATAGONIA, http://patagonia.com/us/footprint (last visited Nov.
14, 2015).
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
123
the source and quality of goodsfor example, that they are made
under fair labor conditionsand have provided means for consumers
to evaluate such information.95 However, other firms refuse to do so
for fear of losing competitive advantage through disclosure of trade
secrets, for example.96 This concern will have to be addressed,97
perhaps through the use of third party verification intermediaries.
Fully private verification systems have been created in the
context of online sales, such as the rating systems for sellers
operated by eBay98 and Amazon. More recently, distributed sharing
economy service providers such as Airbnb or Uber have had to
create robust systems to allow participants to trust each other
based on digital identities (such as the ownership of a Facebook
page) or other kinds of information such as accumulated user
reviews.99 The success of these online firms in connecting smart
information to profoundly physical, face-to-face goods and services
illustrates that trust mechanisms are a critical component to
knowledge governance infrastructure, whether for public or private
entities. As stated earlier, much of the electronic marketplace is
comprised of such credence purchasesthat is, purchases without
previous opportunity to examine the product in detail.
Soft law, such as protocols and standards, potentially
combined with certification marks and trademarks, might also
facilitate the disclosure of smart information. Some scholars have
recently suggested hacks to trademark law to facilitate the
provision of trademarks involving collaborative innovation.100
Others, including me, have examined the role of certification
marks, including the need to ensure the accuracy of third party
certification, in enhancing smart information.101
95.
See, e.g., Max Nisen, How Nike Solved Its Sweatshop Problem, BUS. INSIDER (May
9, 2013, 10:00 PM), http://www.businessinsider.com/how-nike-solved-its-sweatshop-pro
blem-2013-5 (noting that Nikes leadership in corporate social responsibility has allowed it
to transform its reputation).
96.
See Deena Shanker, 11 Food Companies That Wont Tell You Where Their
Meat Comes From, BUZZFEED (Apr. 10, 2014, 1:18 PM), http://www.buzzfeed.com
/deenashanker/companies-that-wont-tell-you-about-their-meat#.qwVjnzB9r
(noting
that Kraft does not disclose its suppliers because the company believes the suppliers
that help [Kraft] make [its] quality Oscar Mayer products are a competitive advantage
over other brands).
97.
See Elizabeth A. Rowe & Daniel M. Mahfood, Trade Secrets, Trade, and
Extraterritoriality, 66 ALA. L. REV. 63, 94 (2014) (noting that trade secrets do not confer a
monopoly but have the allure of perpetuity).
98.
Dillbary, Getting the Word Out, supra note 38, at 101618.
99.
Jason Tanz, How Airbnb and Lyft Finally Got Americans to Trust Each Other,
WIRED (Apr. 23, 2014, 6:30 AM), http://wired.com/2014/04/trust-in-the-share-economy/.
100.
See generally Yana Welinder & Stephen LaPorte, Hacking Trademark Law for
Collaborative Communities, 25 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 407 (2014).
101.
Chon, Marks of Rectitude, supra note 67, at 233530.
124
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
125
108.
Ryan Calo, Code, Nudge, or Notice?, 99 IOWA L. REV. 773, 775 (2014) (citing Omri
Ben-Shahar & Carl E. Schneider, The Failure of Mandated Disclosure, 159 U. PA. L. REV.
647, 64950 (2011)); see THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 14, at 8387 (discussing the
propensity of consumers to select default choices or recommended choices as information
complexity increases).
109.
DAVID VOGEL, TRADING UP: CONSUMER AND ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION IN A
GLOBAL ECONOMY 56, 24870 (1995).
126
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
127
128
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
129
130
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
128.
See Ethical Sourcing: Coffee, STARBUCKS, http://starbucks.com/responsibility
/sourcing/coffee (last visited Nov. 14, 2015).
129.
See, e.g., The Fairtrade Marks, FAIRTRADE INTL, http://www.fairtrade.net/the
-fairtrade-marks.html (last visited Nov. 14, 2015) (conditioning use of the fairtrade mark
on prior written approval from the Fairtrade organization).
130.
Alison Griswold, Whole Foods Desperately Wants Customers to Feel Warm and
Fuzzy Again, SLATE: MONEYBOX (Oct. 20, 2014, 5:39 PM), http://slate.com/blogs
/moneybox/2014/10/20/whole_foods_ad_campaign_can_values_matter_marketing_erase_th
e_whole_paycheck.html.
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
131
131.
A recent example that I have used personally is: EWGs Guide to Sunscreens,
ENVTL. WORKING GROUP, http://ewg.org/sunscreen/ (last visited Nov. 14, 2015). Ultimately,
however, I used the information provided by the website to then purchase the product at a
local food coop.
132.
Initiative Measure No. 502 authorizes the state liquor control board to regulate
and tax marijuana for persons twenty-one years of age and older and adds a new threshold
for driving under the influence of marijuana. Initiative Measure No. 502 1 (Wash. 2011),
http://sos.wa.gov/_assets/elections/initiatives/i502.pdf.
133.
The WSLCB states:
[L]icensed marijuana producers, processors, and retailers are free to employ their
own inventory tracking software solutions as long as it allows for the collection
and submission of the specific information and reports required by the WSLCBs
seed-to-sale inventory tracking rules for Licensees. Licensees are required to
submit specific information and reports to the WSLCB. To ensure compliance with
Washington State regulations, the traceability system provides functionality to
assist with analysis of information, auditing operations, and enforcement by the
WSLCB.
Traceability System, WASH. ST. LIQUOR & CANNABIS BD., http://liq.wa.gov
/mj2015/traceability_system (last visited Nov. 14, 2015).
134.
Anna Staver, How Do Washington, Colorado Track Their Pot?, STATESMAN J.
(Salem) (Nov. 20, 2014, 5:22 PM), http://statesmanjournal.com/story/news/politics
/2014/11/20/washington-colorado-track-pot/70013080/.
135.
WASH. ADMIN. CODE 314-55-105(3) (2015).
136.
Id. 314-55-105(4)(5).
132
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
133
141.
Cf. Dillbary, Trademarks, supra note 31, at 36061 (parsing the 1988
amendments so that the preamble and section 43(a)(1)(B) would read as follows: Any
person who . . . uses in commerce any trademark . . . which . . . in commercial
advertising . . . misrepresents the nature, characteristics, qualities, or geographic origin of
his or her . . . goods . . . shall be liable in a civil action (alterations in original)).
142.
But see BELSON, supra note 116, at 56. I am indebted to Dev Gangjee for his
insights here.
143.
Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights art. 22, Apr.
15, 1994, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex 1C,
1869 U.N.T.S. 299.
144.
Daniel Gervais, A Cognac After Spanish Champagne? Geographical Indications
As Certification Marks, in INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AT THE EDGE 130, 139 (Rochelle Cooper
Dreyfuss & Jane C. Ginsburg eds., 2014).
134
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
Legal scholar Dev Gangjee has recently dived deeply into the
processes of specifying and complying with individual product
specifications. He has found, for example, that even the most
coveted and well-known GIs such as Stilton Cheese in the United
Kingdom or Proscuitto di Parma in Italy sometimes source some
of their raw materials (milk and pork, respectively) outside of the
geographic region associated with them. According to him, these
sourcing practices could cast doubts on the reliability of the
certification system.146 To return to the Ethiopian Sidamo coffee
example, it has been observed that:
As important as branding and delivering a high quality
and distinctive product is ensuring the transparency of the
relevant supply chain. Only if products are traceable to their
origin can consumers be assured that they are receiving the
trademarked product they have purchased, and only then
can the exporters demand that producers receive premium
prices.
The [Ethiopian Coffee Exchange], organised as an
independent publicprivate enterprise, offers an innovative
model for providing such an open and transparent market.
Its provision of market information and quality control
coupled with a trading platform represents an essential
service to the producers and exporters of the Ethiopian
Trademarking and Licensing Initiative. By creating a
transparent trading system, it eliminates the need for a
track and trace system designed specifically for the
trademarked coffee.147
At the heart of this type of IP is the verification of the
provenance of a GI-protected product, essentially its credence
attributes associated with a particular region. But this form of
governance has to be accompanied by vigorous trust mechanisms
in order to work the way it is intended to workotherwise, the GIs
can become just another marketing tool for fuzzy subjective claims
about the product. As Irene Calboli has pointed out, the current
legal framework leaves open the possibility for opportunistic
behavior by large firms that may exploit the trust consumers have
145.
146.
147.
Id.
Gangjee, Proving Provenance, supra note 118, at 7.
KATE BIRD ET AL., OVERSEAS DEV. INST., ETHIOPIAN TRADEMARK AND LICENSING
INITIATIVE: SUPPORTING A BETTER DEAL FOR COFFEE PRODUCERS THROUGH AID FOR TRADE
13 (2009), http://odi.org/resources/docs/5946.pdf.
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
135
136
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2
2015]
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
TRACERMARKS
137
155.
Lemley, supra note 2, at 507 (The Internet certainly undermines the logic of IP
as an incentive to commercialize works once they are created, but it may also undermine
the classic theory of IP as an incentive to create. Once creation is cheap enough, people may
do it without the need for any IP incentive. This suggests that we should pay more attention
to alternative means of encouraging production, rather than assuming the superiority of
IP. IP will continue to exist in a post-scarcity economy, but it is likely to recede in
importance as a driver of creation. (citations omitted)).
138
11/16/2015 9:10 AM
[53:2