Glieck Et Al.
Glieck Et Al.
Glieck Et Al.
21
Privatization of Water
Food and water are basic rights. But we pay for
food. Why should we not pay for water? Ismail
Serageldin at the Second World Water Forum, The
Hague
Water should not be privatized, commodified,
traded or exported in bulk for commercial purposes.
Maude Barlow, International Forum on
Globalization
the purpose of government is to make sure
services are provided, not necessarily to provide
services. Mario Cuomo
One of the most important and controversial trends in
the global water arena is the accelerating transfer of the
production, distribution, or management of water or water
services from public entities into private hands a process
loosely called privatization. Treating water as an economic
good, and privatizing water systems, are not new ideas. Private
entrepreneurs, investor-owned utilities, or other market tools
have long provided water or water services in different parts
of the world. What is new is the extent of privatization efforts
underway today, and the growing public awareness of, and
attention, to problems associated with these efforts.
The issue has resurfaced for several reasons: first, public
water agencies have been unable to satisfy the most basic
needs for water for all humans; second, major multinational
corporations have greatly expanded their efforts to take over
responsibility for a larger portion of the water service market
than ever before; and third, several recent highly publicized
privatization efforts have failed or generated great
controversy.
The privatization of water encompasses an enormous variety
of possible water-management arrangements. Privatization
can be partial, leading to so-called public/private
partnerships, or complete, leading to the total elimination of
government responsibility for water systems. At the largest
scale, private water companies build, own, and operate water
systems around the world with annual revenues of
approximately $300 billion, excluding revenues for sales of
22
The New Economy of Water: The Risks and Benefits of Globalization and Privatization of Fresh Water
23
History of Privatization
Private involvement in water supply has a long history. Indeed,
in some places, private ownership and provision of water was
the norm, until governments began to assume these
responsibilities. In the United States, municipal services were
often provided by private organizations in the early 1800s.
Toward the latter half of that century, municipalities started
to confront problems with access and service and began a
transition toward public control and management. In
particular, private companies were failing to provide access
to all citizens in an equitable manner. Private water companies
provided 94 percent of the U.S. market in the 19th century,
24
The Players
There are a handful of major international private water
companies, but two French multinational corporations
dominate the sector: Vivendi SA and Suez Lyonnaise des
Eaux (soon to be called Ondeo). These two companies own
or have interests in water projects in more than 120 countries
and each claims to provide water to around 100 million people
(Barlow 1999, FTGWR 2000: Vol. 94, http://www.suez.fr/
metiers/english/index.htm) (Tables 4 and 5). Vivendis water
activities are, themselves, a small part of the larger company
Vivendi Universal, which was created in December 2000
when it merged with the Seagram Company to form a global
media and telecommunications company. As an example of
the diversity of Vivendis activities, in spring 2001, Vivendi
purchased MP3.com. The total annual revenue from the
interlocking subsidiaries of Vivendi in 2000 exceeded $37
billion, of which more than 25 percent came from the water
business (Market Guide 2001).
Population (millions)
France
Western Europe
Central and Eastern Europe
Middle East and Africa
North America
Latin America
Asia
25.0
18.5
6.3
8.5
16.8
7.8
14.6
The New Economy of Water: The Risks and Benefits of Globalization and Privatization of Fresh Water
Population (millions)
43
14
25
23
5
110
Source: http://www.suez.fr/metiers/english/index.htm
25
26
Forms of Privatization
Despite the growing debate about privatization, there is
considerable misunderstanding and misinformation
circulating about what the term itself means. Privatization
can take many forms. Only the most absolute form transfers
full ownership and operation of water systems to the private
sector. Much more common are forms that leave public
ownership of water resources unaffected and include
transferring some operational responsibilities for water
supply or wastewater management from the public to the
private sector. Privatization also does not, or should not,
absolve public agencies of their responsibility for
environmental protection, public health and safety, or
monopoly oversight.
There are many different forms of privatization arrangements,
agreements, and models. There is also a fundamental
difference between public and private ownership of water
assets. Private ownership involves transferring assets to a
private utility. Public ownership involves keeping the assets
in the public domain, but integrating the private sector in
various utility operations and activities through contract
(Beecher 1997). Public or private-sector employees can
perform various functions. As an illustration, Table 6 lists
several functions that could be assigned to private or public
employees in thousands of combinations ranging from
completely public to completely private operations. These
different forms have very different implications worthy of
careful analysis.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Operation of facilities
6.
Maintenance of facilities
7.
Pricing decisions
8.
9.
Figure 5: Types of Public and Private Water Providers. Types of public and private
water providers characterized by the public and private nature of the assets and
management.
Source: Blokland et al. (1999).
The New Economy of Water: The Risks and Benefits of Globalization and Privatization of Fresh Water
27
Concession Models
Much of the debate in recent years over privatization has
revolved around more comprehensive concessions to the
private sector. This is especially true in Latin America and
Asia. The full-concession model transfers operation and
management responsibility for the entire water-supply system
28
(e.g., the utility pressurizes pipes only a few hours each day).
In Kathmandu, Nepal, water from privately controlled sources
are sold by tanker truck to both low- and high-income areas
of the city unserved by regular, reliable supply. Customers
may turn to private vendors when they have more money
than time for water collection. The public provision of tankered
water can also involve high costs and even corruption: in
parts of Mexico households dependent on public tankering
services must often tip providers to ensure service (Muoz
2001).
Private businesses and small-scale entrepreneurs often
operate free of regulation in less developed countries. Private
water companies are usually regulated to some extent (e.g.,
water quality) in more developed countries. Without
regulation, high prices or low water quality can cause
significant social problems. Numerous studies have shown
that the poor often pay much more for water from private
suppliers or small-scale vendors than they would pay if a
regulated community water system, piped or otherwise, were
put into place. For example, in El Alto, Bolivia, where a
concession was granted in the mid-1990s, households with
private connections spend around $2.20 per month for 10
cubic meters, while those relying on private vendors pay over
$35.00 for the same account of water (Komives 2001).